THE GREAT FRENCH WRITERS TURGOT €\)t (Sreat JFrendb CKJriterg. MADAME DE SEVIGNE ... By Gaston Boissier. GEORGE SAND By E. Caro. MONTESQUIEU By Albert Sorel. VICTOR COUSIN By Jules Simon. TURGOT By Leon Say. OTHER VOLUMES IN PREPARATION. Uniform in style. Price, $1.00 a volume. Ci)e Oreat iFienci) canters TURGOT Bv LEON SAY OF THE FRENCH ACADEMY TRANSLATED BY MELVILLE B. ANDERSON TRANSLATOR OF HUGO'S " SHAKESPEARE " CHICAGO A. C. McCLURG AND COMPANY 1888 Copyright By A. C. McClurg and Company TABLE OF CONTENTS. Note upon Turgot's Works 7 Introduction : Brief Review of Life, Character, Influence 9 CHAPTER I. His Family, 16. — Youth and Education, 20. — The Sor bonne, 24. CHAPTER II. Leaves the Sorbonne, 30. — Appointed Master of Requests, 34. — Associates with the Philosophers and the Econo mists, 36. — Writes for the " Encyclopaedia," 42. CHAPTER III. Quesnay and Gournay, 45. — The Physiocrats, 46. — Turgot's Economic Doctrine, 48. — Essay on " The Formation and Distribution of Wealth," 48. — Eulogy of Gournay, 64. CHAPTER IV. I. Intendant of Limoges, 70. — The Cadastre, 74. — II. Loans of Money, and Usury, 79. — III. Letters on Free Trade in Grain, 89. vi Table of Contents. CHAPTER v. I. Minister of Finance, 99. — II. Free Trade in Grain, 108. — III. The Bread Riots, 126.— IV. Recall of the Parlia ments, 132. CHAPTER VI. I. Preparation of the Great Edicts of 1776, 139. — II. Aba lition of the Corvee, 144. — III. Suppression of Trade. Guilds ; Freedom of Labor, 161. — IV. The Bed of Justice, 167. CHAPTER VII. Increasing Difficulties, 175. — Resignation of Malesherbes, 179. — Secret Letters to the King, 180. — Turgot's Dis missal, 191. — Retirement, 192. — Death, 198. CHAPTER VIII. Economic and Political Reaction after Turgot's Death, 200. — Definitive Triumph in 1789, 206. — New Reactions under the Empire, the Restoration, and the Republic of February (1848), 210. CHAPTER IX. Radical Socialist School, 215. — Catholic Economic School, 216. — Conclusion: Difficulty of Reconciling the Prin ciple of Freedom of Labor with that of Freedom of Association, 217. Index . 223 NOTE UPON TURGOT'S WORKS. A part only of Turgot's works appeared during his lifetime. Among these are his " Reflexions sur la formation et la distribution des ri- chesses " (1766, i2mo), and his poem, of which but a few copies were printed for private distribution only ; " Didon, poeme en vers me"triques hexametres, divisel en III. chants, traduits du IV" livre de l'Ene"ide de Virgile, avec le commencement de l'Ene'ide et les II", VIII", et X" eglogues du meme" (par Anne- Robert-Jacques Turgot). 1778. 4to, pp. 108. (Re produced in the edition of the works published by Dupont de Nemours.) Turgot's works were collected after his death, — " OZuvres de M. Turgot, ministre d'Etat, pre'ce'de'es et accompagnees de me"moires et de notes sur sa vie, son administration et ses ouvrages " (with this epi graph : " Bonum virum facile crederes, magnum libenter." Tacitus). 9 vols., 8vo. Paris : printed by A. Belin. 1809-1811. " Giuvres de Turgot, nouvelle Edition classed par ordre de matieres, avec les notes de M. Dupont de Ne mours, augmented de lettres inddites, des questions 8 Note upon Turgot's Works. sur le commerce et d'observations et de notes nou- velles par MM. Eugfene Daire et Hippolyte Dussard et pre'ce'de'e d'une notice sur la vie et les ouvrages de Turgot, par M. Eugene Daire." 2 vols., large 8vo. Paris : Guillaumin. 1844. Portions of Turgot's correspondence are found in various publications, especially in the following : — " Correspondance ine"dite de Condorcet et de Turgot, 1770-1779." Edited by Ch. Henry. 1 vol., 8vo. Paris: Charavay. 1882. " Life and Correspondence of David Hume." Edited by John Hill Burton. 2 vols., 8vo. Edinburgh : William Tait. 1846. " Letters of Eminent Persons addressed to David Hume." Edited by John Hill Burton. 8vo. Edin burgh and London : Blackwood. 1849. There exist unpublished letters from Turgot in the archives of several families, particularly in those of the Turgot family (at Lantheuil Castle), and among the descendants of Dupont de Nemours, who are settled in the United States. TURGOT. INTRODUCTION. MUCH has been written about Turgot. We have been told the story of his childhood, of his youth, of his manhood. We have seen him as a timid child hiding under the furniture to avoid the scrutiny of his mother's visitors ; and later, as a young man in a cas sock, playing at shuttlecock with Minette, the beautiful maiden who was soon to become Madame Helvetius. The dissertations read by him as Prior of the Sorbonne, at the open ing and at the closing of the session of 1750, have been preserved. We know the reasons that prompted him to renounce the priest hood, and we have seen him holding offices in the magistracy, first as Deputy-Counsellor of the Attorney-General, next as Counsellor in the Parliament of Paris, then as Master of Re quests. We have witnessed his first breach with the Parliament, on that day in 1754 when 10 Turgot. he accepted a seat in a Royal Chamber em-. powered to judge in the place of the exiled Parliament. We can recall the sayings of his delighted friends at the time of his appointment as Intendant of Limoges, and we know the . hope that appointment awakened in Voltaire's breast: " One of the brethren has just written me that an intendant is good only for evil ; I am sure you will show that he can do great good." At Limoges he remained thirteen years, and during the twenty-five years elapsing between his admission to the Sorbonne and his depart ure from Limoges he did not cease to be the, idol of the economists and of the Encyclo pedists. He became acquainted, successively, with Quesnay, Gournay, Dupont de Nemours, Voltaire, Hume, Adam Smith, Condorcet. His correspondence is very extensive. He was a leader among men; and, what though the Duke de Choiseul could say of him in 1769 that he had not " a ministerial head," his masters, his friends, his disciples, even then deemed him the only minister capable of regu lating the administration and the finances of the tottering monarchy. A collection has been made of his letters, his plans, his memoirs, his opinions, his de- Introduction. n cisions, his circulars, his reports, — of every thing he wrote during the first part of his life. He can be followed almost day by day in the fulfilment of the various official duties with which he was intrusted between 1750 and 1774. Finally, at the age of forty-seven years, prepared by a life of reflection, of study, of administrative experience, he is made a Min ister. He is ready to carry out the widest and the most fruitful plans of reform. He re establishes the freedom of the grain trade, and by this measure, justifiable as it was, he arouses the popular wrath. To the surprise of many he outrides the storm of the Bread Riots,1 and completes his work by proclaiming freedom of labor. The abolition of the exclusive in dustrial corporations, or trade-guilds,2 was the crowning act of his life, and his economical testament. We have his memorials to the king, his notes, his drafts of the decrees of the Council, the preambles which he prefixed to his minis terial edicts. We know the slightest details of all that he thought, wrote, and did, during an administration of twenty months, which, brief as it was, is wonderful for its fulness and excel- 1 La guerre des farines. 2 Les jurandes et les maitrises. 1 2 Turgot. lence. He succumbs after a vigorous struggle, overcome by the coalition of interests and prejudices, or, as Voltaire puts it, " of finan ciers, red-heels, and bigwigs," and his biogra phers indulge in interminable discussions about the causes of his failure. His fall is attributed to his undertaking too much at once, to his want of flexibility of character, to his being animated by a spirit of sect; and writers endeavor to ascertain the qualities of a successful statesman which he lacked. In order the better to understand him, they follow him into retirement, where they find him occupied with scientific experi ments and with the exercises in prosody which interested him from early youth. At last, at the age of fifty-four years, he dies of gout, which had not ceased to rack him for more than twenty years, — a hereditary malady that caused him to reply to Malesherbes, who was reproaching him with too great haste : "What would you have me do? The needs of the people are enormous, and in my family we die of gout at fifty.'' For all those who have told the story of his life and have piously collected his slightest words and writings, Turgot is a great mind, — the greatest, perhaps, after Montesquieu, in the eighteenth century; but they all look Introduction. 1 3 upon him as an unlucky reformer who sank miserably under the blows of adversaries less strong, indeed, but surely better advised than he, — men who were far from being eager to know and apply great economic truths, but thoroughly trained to pull all the wires of profitable court intrigue. All those who have lived most with Turgot, and have never ceased to love and admire him, repeat with one voice : " Turgot had not the qualities that assure success." I would draw from his life-work a very different con clusion, and would treat him, not as defeated, but as victorious. For if he failed in the eighteenth century, he has prevailed in the nineteenth. He is the founder of our present political economy, and, by the freedom of labor which he bequeathed us, he has stamped our century with its most distinctive mark. Thanks to freedom of labor, the nineteenth is the century of industry on the grand scale, of the application of great scientific, geographi cal, economic discoveries to the development ' of labor and wealth. By deeply imbuing the French and European consciousness with the principles "of free labor, Turgot prepared the way for the conquest of the world by Occi dental civilization, and it is the nineteentli j century that has effected this conquest 14 Turgot. It is a remarkable sign of the personal influ ence of Turgot upon the activity of our cen tury, that his inspiration seems to this day needed to animate the principles he enun ciated. In order to prevent the century from deviating from the path Turgot marked out for it, we are compelled to cling more firmly than ever to his person, to his life, to his acts, and to invoke his help in struggles very similar to those he sustained almost a century and a quarter ago. Freedom of labor, which was for him the beginning and the end of all economic laws, is to-day the object of the sharpest attacks. It is no longer the privileged, the wealthy, the magistracy, the classes formerly termed ruling, that combine, as once they did against Turgot.- The present reaction against him is found among the workingmen, among the sons of those who seemed intoxicated with delight when his edict went forth abolishing the exclu sive industrial corporations. The workingmen are seeking to load themselves again with their broken fetters, thinking to find protec tion in what was formerly — though they have forgotten this — the instrument of their oppression. The nineteenth is the true century of Tur got, because it is that in which his ideas have Introduction. 1 5 been applied, and in which he has borne mani fest sway over minds and over things. Is it to be the only century in which his principles shall receive so salutary a vindication? Will the coming century burn what we have adored? There is no lack of gloomy prophets who menace us with this ; but their prognostica tions will not be fulfilled. Turgot has entered into his glory; he has entered into it for all time, and the French political economy, of which he is the real founder, has nailed its flag to the mast. CHAPTER I. HIS FAMILY. — CHILDHOOD. — EDUCATION. — THE SORBONNE. TURGOT'S family was one of the most ancient of Normandy, and Condorcet asserts that the name, in the language of the old Northmen, meant " Thor-God." The fam ily was divided, in the sixteenth century, into two branches, — the Turgots of Tourailles and the Turgots of Saint-Clair. Their common ancestor, Louis Turgot, had been Master of Requests under Francis, Duke of Alencon, and counsellor in the Supreme Court of Caen. His eldest son, John, was the first Turgot of Tourailles, and his second son, Antony, the first Turgot of Saint-Clair. In 162 1 a Turgot of Tourailles had an en counter with a certain Montchretien ; and sin gularly enough this passage at arms connected for the first time the name of Turgot with that of the science it was to illustrate. Montchre tien, the son of a Falaise apothecary, a tragic His Family. iy playwright, and a soldier of adventure, was in trusted, by the chiefs of the Protestant party at the time of the insurrection of La Rochelle, with the task of rallying the Protestants of Normandy. In a letter written from Caen on the 14th of October, 162 1, Malherbe thus re lates the upshot of this expedition. " The rebellion in Normandy was check mated by the death of a certain Montchretien, the organizer of the whole affair. Accom panied by six others of the same class, he came, about a week ago, at eight o'clock in the evening, to the hostelry of a place called Les Tourailles, some twelve leagues from here. Word was immediately sent to the lord of /the place, who forthwith appeared with fifteen or twenty musketeers." The band was destroyed, and the lord of Tourailles, who slew its chief, was named Claude Turgot. Now this Montchretien who was slain by a Turgot had written not merely tragedies, but a book of remarkable sagacity upon trade and manufactures ; and this book, dated 1615, bears the then absolutely unique title of " Treatise of Political Economy." Never be fore had this term been employed in the French language to designate the economic science; and the man who first employed it was slain by the hand of an ancestor of the precursor of 1 8 Turgot. J. B. Say in France, and of Adam Smith in England. The grandfather of the great Turgot was descended from Antony Turgot, of Saint-Clair, but belonged to a younger branch of the fam ily. He had been Intendant of the Generality of Metz and of that of Tours. The great Tur got's father, Michael Etienne, was successively Master of Requests, Provost of the Merchants of Paris, member of the Academy of Inscrip tions and Belles-lettres, Councillor of State, and President of the Grand Council. Among his maternal ancestors he counted the famous jurisconsult Pierre Pithou, and of all his an cestors he was proudest of this one. He gained just celebrity as Provost of the Mer chants. He undertook to drain the marshy quarters of Paris, extending from the boule vards to Montmartre, and constructed an im mense sewer, to which his name was attached, and which still exists, in part, under Saint- Lazare Street. To Michael Etienne Turgot is due one of the finest plans * for the defence of Paris which have been made, and this also bears his name. It was at his initiative that the Gre nelle Street fountain was erected by Bouchar- don, to whom he intrusted its execution. After resigning his post as Provost of the Merchants, he found himself able to devote to 1 Plans cavaliers. His Family. ig his private affairs a part of the leisure left him from his duties as a Councillor of State. His ancestral estates were situated between Caen, Falaise, Bayeux, and the sea, in that part of Normandy which to-day forms the Department of Calvados. In his honor these domains were erected into a marquisate bearing the name of Soumont. Long afterward, in memory of the great Minister, the Marquis of Soumont was authorized to bear the title of Marquis Turgot. The Provost of the Merchants resided not at Soumont but at Bons, — Bons-Turgot, as Du pont de Nemours terms it, — a little commune not far from Soumont. Among his estates, farms, and grazing-lands were those of Laulne and of Brucourt, of which our Turgot bore the name. At the Sorbonne he was called the Abbe de Laulne ; and upon leaving that seat of learning he assumed the name of Turgot of Brucourt. Lantheuil Castle, the cradle of the family, situated near Bons, was then in the hands of the elder branch, the Turgots of Saint-Clair, but was afterward annexed to the marquisate. The present Marquis Turgot has collected the fam ily archives at Lantheuil Castle. To these he has kindly given me access. I have held in my hands the first draft of the letter of the 20 . Turgot. 24th of August, 1774, addressed by the great Turgot to the king, in order, as the writer says, to place before His Majesty's eyes the engage ment His Majesty has made to support his minister in the execution of the latter's plans of economy. The note is written off-hand, with some erasures. It seemed to me I heard the firm thrilling tones of the great man, — those tones so gentle to his friends, so harsh to his opponents. In these same archives I found nu merous traces of the examination of the papers made after Turgot's death by Malesherbes, for the purpose of obtaining the notes, documents, and manuscripts to be published by Dupont de Nemours as the first edition of Turgot's works. On the 1st of February, 1751, the Provost of the Merchants died, leaving three sons and a daughter. The eldest son rose to the bench, and died as Chief-Justice of the Parliament of Paris ; the second son, known as Chevalier Turgot, was scholar, governor, soldier, — for a time he governed Guiana; the third son was the great Turgot. The daughter had married the Duke de Saint-Aignan. Anne Robert Jacques Turgot was born in Paris on the 10th of May, 1727. As a boy] he was studious, shy, and awkward; and his youthful timidity never quite forsook him. He Childhood. 21 said one day to King j^iis XVI., " My words are somewhat confuseaBjTO I am ill at ease." " I am aware that you are shy," replied the king. He was educated at the College of Louis the Great and at the Seminary of Saint-Sulpice. As early as 1743. at the age of sixteen, we find him attending the lectures of the Faculty of Theology ; and in 1746, on account of his youth, a special dispensation was necessary before he could be admitted to the examina tions. This dispensation was granted him by the Faculty " in consideration of the very po tent recommendation of the King, and also in memory of the services rendered during his administration by M. Turgot's illustrious father to the City of Paris and to the various depart ments of the Faculty itself." This dispensation is dated October 1, 1746. Six months later, on the 11th of March, 1747, the Provost of the Merchants, writing to his second son, the Chevalier, then at Malta, re ports that the young Abb6 had sustained his baccalaureate thesis with signal success. He wrote : — "Your brother the Abbe has sustained his thesis with all possible distinction, wholly surpassing my ex pectations ; for he exhibited not the least trepidation, and won the applause of all. He spoke in the im- 2 2 Turgot. mense hall of the outer Sorbonne ; it was admirably furnished and lighted, and, large as it is, was full of listeners during the whole five hours' discussion. " The Archbishop of Tours presided. The Assem bly of the Clergy, at present in session at Paris, of which he is also the chairman, came in a body to hear this thesis. My lord the Archbishop of Paris was there in full canonicals. His surpliced cross- bearer held the cross at the door of his coach, came before him into the hall, and sat in front of him upon a footstool, bearing the great and beautiful archiepis- copal cross of gilded silver. After the Archbishop's departure, the Pope's Nuncio came in and remained above an hour and a half. On going out he remarked to the Abbe, and to the doctors of the Sorbonne who accompanied him, and to your brother, and to M. de Creil, that he had been present on many such occa sions, but that he had never heard a thesis sustained with so much ability. " The Archbishop of Tours descended from his chair and embraced the Abbe, assuring him that he had acquitted himself eminently well. The next day, the Archbishop being at Versailles, the king asked him if he had attended the Assembly of the Clergy on the day before. He answered no ; that he had presided at the discussion of a thesis. The king in quired who sustained the thesis, and was informed that it was the Abbe Turgot. To the king's further inquiry whether the Abbe had sustained it well, the Archbishop was good enough to reply that he had never heard a thesis sustained with equal distinc- First Economic Paper. 23 tion, and added, 'Your Majesty has no greater or better subject than the Abbe Turgot. All this is ex ceedingly flattering to us, and it must give you equal pleasure." Two years later, on the 7th of April, 1749, young Turgot composed the first economic paper that has come down to us from him. It is in'the form of a letter written from the Semi nary to his fellow-student, the Abbe de Cice. Its aim is to refute Law's system, which had been published twenty years before by the Abbe Terrasson. According to Turgot, metallic money is not a mere sign. " As a species of merchandise," said he, " money is, not the sign, but the com mon measure, of other kinds of merchandise." In refuting the widespread notion that metallic coin is a mere token deriving its value from the royal stamp, Turgot made short work of the visionaries who then thought, as they thought later during the Revolution, and as many still think, that the state can defray pub lic expenses by issuing irredeemable bills trans formed by law into compulsory currency. "The king," said he, "would gain a mere temporary relief by the issuing of bills, — or rather by their multiplication, — for this relief would cease as soon as commodities began to 24 ' Turgot. increase in price in proportion to the number of the bills." " If forty years later," comments Dupont de Nemours, " the majority of the citi zens composing the Constituent Assembly had possessed as much knowledge of the subject as Turgot so early exhibited, France might have been spared the Assignats." Early in June, 1749, the young Abbe de Laulne was admitted to the House of the Sor bonne to take his final degrees. The House of the Sorbonne was an association formed for the purpose of attending the lectures and exer cises of the Faculty of Theology. The society was made up of about one hundred ecclesias tics, — bishops, vicars-general, canons, priests of Paris and of the principal cities of the king dom. Their great House, which still exists as the Sorbonne, contained thirty-six apartments, with a chapel, a valuable library, and a garden. The servants were employed by the society, and^the members dined together. As many of the members lived elsewhere, a certain number of apartments were allotted to a half-score of students, and one of these students was the son of the Provost of the Merchants. The master's degree, for which he was pre paring, required a certain number of theses : first, the Tentative for the bachelor's degree, which Turgot had already attained ; then the The Sorbonne. 25 Minor, the Sorbonical, and the Major. On the last day of December, 1749, six months after his admission to the Sorbonne, he was elected Prior. The priorship was an honor rendered to distinguished young men, and to the sons of illustrious parents. The Prior was the chair man of the assemblies, where it was his privi lege and his duty to pronounce discourses in Latin, usually tfpon religious subjects. Turgot presided for the first time on the 16th of May, 1750, when the Abbe Morellet, who was to be come his life-long friend and his passionate admirer, was admitted to take his final exami nations ; and again on the 13th of August, when Morellet was made a fellow of the society. Thus, from 1743 to 1750, Turgot had un remittingly pursued theological studies ; and these studies, with the exercises which formed their necessary complement, had ripened his mind to a very remarkable degree. " In order to win distinction in theological exercises," says Morellet, " some talent was requisite, and some adroitness in singling out and answering objec tions. Turgot often used to say, smilingly, ' My dear Abbe, it is only we who have dis puted for the master's degree who know what it is to reason exactly.' " Turgot read two Latin dissertations, one at the opening and the other at the close of the 26 Turgot. session of 1750. The first of these was upon " The Advantages that the Establishment of Christianity has conferred upon the Human Race." It is a rhetorical exercise, though a re markable one, resembling one of those excel lent Latin discourses that were crowned in this same Sorbonne but a few years since, in con nection with the General Competition between the colleges of Paris. Writing to his brother the Chevalier, on the 30th of July, 1750, Turgot says : " I have had a Latin discourse to make, which I pronounced on the 3d of July with a success most flattering to me. At present I have some four minors a week, with twelve arguments, and on the 27th of November I am to pronounce a second discourse, with which I am even now occupied." And his father, writ ing to the Chevalier under date of October 23, said : " I have told you of the wonderful success of the Abbe's speech last July ; he is to pro nounce another on the 27th of next month." The Abbe's success in November was more splendid than in July. The latter discourse is much more important than the former ; it deals with " The Successive Advances of the Human Mind." It is a pic ture of universal history drawn with great talent, full of reflections surprisingly ripe for a man of his age, marked by great freedom of thought, Experiments in Prosody. 27 and permeated with an extremely warm feeling of human perfectibility. It contains, touching ancient colonies, this oft-quoted expression, written a quarter of a century before the American Declaration of Independence : " Colo nies are like fruit, which clings to the tree only-, until it grows ripe. Becoming self-sufficient, they did what Carthage afterward did, what America will sometime do." At this time Turgot busied himself much with translations from the Latin, thinking that some of the rules of Greek and Latin versifica tion might advantageously be employed in the French language. He wished to see the alter nation of long and short syllables introduced into French poetry, in order to produce upon the delicate and practised ear something of the effect of antique melody. The search for this new prosody was one of Turgot's most constant diversions, to which he returned whenever his engagements permitted it. One of his achieve ments is a translation of the entire Fourth Book of* the ,/Eneid into unrhymed French hexameter verses. He assumed, as a writer of verse, the name of the Abbe de Laage, and sent his verses, under this pseudonym, to Voltaire, requesting his opinion. As one may imagine, Voltaire made no haste to read the efforts of an un- 28 Turgot. known abbe. Pressed, however, by renewed letters he finally replied as follows : — " I have received the letter dated Paris, the 28th of April,1 and have not received that from Genoa. I am full of regard for the Abbe de Laage, and thank him for his kind remem brance. But being an old man harassed by disease and almost completely blind, I am hardly in a condition to enter upon literary discussions. All that I can say is that I have been extremely well pleased with what I have read, it being the only spirited prose version I have seen." The pretended Abbe de Laage was much mortified that the great poet should have taken his verses for prose, and wrote to his intimate friend Caillard that " the man has either disdained to guess, or does not care to express himself; " and passing to a sub ject in political economy, he adds : " I am no more surprised to see this great poet reason ill about political economy than about physics or natural history; reasoning has never been his strong side." 2 If Turgot had no success in French versifi cation, it was his fortune to compose a Latin 1 1770. See Morley's " Voltaire," p. 335. — Tr. 2 It is thought best to omit the specimen, which the author here gives, of Turgot's unscannable verses. — Tr. Cannot wear the Mask. 29 verse which clings to every memory, — the famous verse written by him beneath the por trait of Franklin : — " Eripuit ccelo fulmen, sceptrumque tyrannis." x But the young Abbe de Laulne was not to remain long at the Sorbonne ; he did not feel himself called to the priesthood. His friends had wished to retain him, and told him that the name he bore, and his learning, would win him rapid promotion in the Church. He was assured that he would soon become a bishop, and that he might realize in the direction of a diocese some of the noble administrative dreams that already filled his mind. " My dear friends," he replied, " take for yourselves the advice you give me, since you are able to follow it. For my part, I cannot condemn myself to wear a mask throughout my life." His father, who was very ill, and whose death came three months later, left him free to do as he pleased. He therefore abandoned the Church forever, and left the Sorbonne in the month of December, 1750. 1 " Lightning from heaven he snatched, and the sceptre from tyrants." CHAPTER II. LEAVES THE SORBONNE. — IS APPOINTED MAS TER OF REQUESTS. ASSOCIATES WITH THE PHILOSOPHERS AND THE ECONOMISTS. — WRITES FOR THE "ENCYCLOPAEDIA." TURGOT was twenty-three years old when he left the Sorbonne. His judgment was formed and his method determined. He sought natural laws, and, in order to reach them, he endeavored to distinguish, in all classes of phenomena, causes from effects, being persuaded that all human errors arise from the confusion which people incessantly make between causes and effects. Thus while still very young he had succeeded, with wonder ful accuracy and really incredible swiftness, in unravelling the general causes of all the par ticular facts that came under his notice. It might almost be said that while still at the Sorbonne his mind contained all that it after ward produced ; so that the labor of the last thirty years of his life would be simply to give clear expression to what he had acquired A Consummate Philosopher. 31 during the eighteen months passed at that re nowned seat of learning. A consummate philosopher, considering Na ture and man from the loftiest standpoints, he had, when scarcely twenty years of age, formed the conception of a history of the human mind and its progress. Of this history he had even sketched the plan, which was one day to be developed in a book. This plan we still pos sess, and of it some of his later productions are mere partial developments. Thus already, despite his youth, he was admirably equipped for the life-struggle, and his years of appren ticeship had made him one of the men most competent to give helpful expression to new truths, at a time when prejudice seemed to have irresistible potency. Studying Turgot at the threshold of his ac tive life, and remembering the influence he afterward exerted upon the economic destiny of his country, we naturally ask, " Whose image and superscription does he bear; to what intellectual family does he belong ? " Contrary to the rule, we find no answer, for the simple reason that he proceeds from no one. Plainly he is of his century, but by an energy peculiar to himself, and with no guide but his own reason, he finds a way to break the barriers of that century and to take his 32 Turgot. place in ours. The strength of his genius was not developed by those who directed his studies, but by his severe and philosophical question ing of his own powers. He was the child of ~his meditations. He was a born master, as is proved by the fact that those whose disciple he has been called have survived only because of him, and find access to us to-day simply because they force themselves upon us, as it were, in his train. There is, however, a resemblance to Adam Smith which early becomes well marked. They were of nearly the same age, — Adam Smith was born in 1723. The student at Paris and the student at Edinburgh developed their thoughts separately, for neither knew of the other, and each formed his doctrine by inde pendent reflection. Walking with equal steps upon converging paths, they prepared them selves by the same method for the activities which were to make their names illustrious. Each had been intended for the Church, and each, having completed his theological course, forsook the Church for philosophy ; both held the same faith in the progress of the human mind, and both sought its law, at the same time and by the same method, in metaphysics, in moral philosophy, and in political economy. It is therefore not surprising that they became, Compared with Adam Smith. 33 by turns, the forerunners and the inspircrs of each other. Like Turgot, Adam Smith had thought to write the history of civilization and of progress ; and like Turgot he had never ceased to study man in his consciousness, in his language, and in his moral, social, economical relations. Later on, they met — this time wittingly — upon philosophical and metaphysical ground. They became apprised of each other's exist ence, they came to know each other, and we cannot be mistaken in saying that from the day they became acquainted they derived mu tual aid and profit from each other's works, and from those of their respective masters. Turgot's philosophy owes much to the Scotch school, to Hutcheson, Adam Smith's master, as well as to Adam Smith himself. But the political economy of Adam Smith owes no less to France, to the Physiocratic x economists, and to Turgot. Quesnay, Gournay, and above all Turgot, ex ercised a manifest and happy influence upon the author of " The Wealth of Nations." Tur got's little treatise " On the Formation and Distribution of Wealth " preceded by ten years the publication of Adam Smith's great eco- 1 See the article " Physiocrates" in Lalor's " Cyclopedia of Political Science." — Tr. 3 34 Turgot. nomic work ; and it was during these ten years that the two thinkers met, became ac quainted with each other, and perhaps corre sponded upon economic subjects. Condorcet is authority for the statement that there was an active correspondence between them. Of both it may be said that they are more truly the masters of the nineteenth century than of the eighteenth. In a speech upon the Bank of England, delivered in the house of Commons May 30, 1797, Sir William Pulteney was able to say of Adam Smith that he would persuade the present generation and would govern the next. A similar judgment might have been passed upon Turgot; for although he did not prevail in his own century, he persuaded the enlightened minds of his time, while after his death his ideas governed, and still govern, French society. On the 5th of January, 1752, Turgot was called to the duties of Deputy-Counsellor of the Attorney-General ; on the 30th of Decem ber he entered the Parliament of Paris as Coun sellor; but his connection with this High Court was merely transitory, or rather he continued to be attached to it only by the looser ties that still united the Masters of Requests to the Parliament. Appointed Master of Requests on the 28th of March, 1753, he was occupied exclusively with the duties of the office until Appointed Master of Requests. 35 1 761, when he was sent to Limoges as Inten dant; but during the whole period of his in- tendancy (1761 to 1774) he preserved the title and the prerogatives of the Master of Requests, sharing the labors of his colleagues when he thought proper, and sitting with them when he was at Paris. The functions of the Masters of Requests were both administrative and judicial. They made reports to the Council in presence of the Councillors of State, and sometimes even of the king. They were members of the Parlia ment, in which, however, they had a right to but four seats. The first four masters who arrived took the places reserved to their body. They shared the jurisdiction of the Royal Council in cases of appeal, and possessed, moreover, a kind of special jurisdiction, — that of the requests of the H6tel de Ville. It was the Council that heard the review of the trial of Calas, but it was the Chamber of Requests of the H6tel de Ville — that is, the Masters of Requests alone — that pronounced the judg ment. Turgot sat during this trial. " He was one of the judges," says Dupont de Nemours, " and he spoke on this occasion with a vehe mence unusual to him." Unfortunately his words have not been preserved, as no report of the proceedings exists. 36 Turgot. Turgot had been welcomed with open arms by the society of the philosophers, the men of letters, and the economists. His official duties left him much leisure, which he employed to the full in cultivating his mind and in conver sation with his friends. It was at Madame Geoffrin's that he made the acquaintance of D'Alembert, of Mademoiselle de Lespinasse, of Condorcet, of Helvetius, and of so many others. Madame Helvetius was an older ac quaintance. She was Madame de Graffigny's niece, and while still at the Sorbonne he had often seen her as a young girl at her aunt's. Madame de Graffigny, who nicknamed every one, — who called her friend Devaux, Panpan ; her friend Desmarets, Morocco; her friend Saint-Lambert, the Little Saint, — never ad dressed her niece, Mademoiselle de Ligneville, otherwise than by the name of Minette. She loved Minette, she loved the young Abbe de Laulne, as Turgot was then called, and the two young people were warmly attached to each other. Good Abbe Morellet laments that this intimacy did not end in marriage. He was convinced that such a marriage would have secured the happiness of the two young peo ple, and his own into the bargain. Between \ the two beings whom he best loved, and who returned his affection, he would have passed a Minette. 37 most agreeable life, without being obliged to make pilgrimages from the house of one to the house of the other. " It has always puz zled me," says he, " that no true passion grew out of this intimacy ; but whatever the causes of such great reserve, there remained from this union a tender and abiding friendship." Attempts have been made to convert Morel- let's regrets upon this subject into an historical problem, upon which a wealth of erudition has been expended. Many writers have dealt with the question. If Turgot exhibited the reserve with which Morellet seems to reproach him, and if he let slip the opportunity for so well- assorted a match, it was, say some, because he had already taken orders. Such, at least, is the opinion of Delort, author of " The History of the Detention of Philosophers and Men of Letters in the Bastille." But this opinion is based, in the first instance, upon a very doubt ful text, and upon many other very contra dictory ones. It is certain that Turgot is designated, in some documents of the House of the Sorbonne, as a Parisian deacon ; it is no less certain that in others equally authentic he is classed among the simple acolytes. In the first case, he would have takerL orders ; in the other, he would have remained free^ Other writers do not seek so far; they think him too 38 Turgot. busy, and find it difficult to imagine him divid ing his time between the serious occupational that already filled his life and the thousand cares of family life. Again, — this is a third ver sion, — knowing himself threatened with heredi tary gout, and persuaded that he could not ex pect to live much beyond fifty, Turgot perhaps feared to associate a wife and children with a life so precarious as his. Whatever the rea son may be, Turgot never married ; he left fair Minette free to marry Helvetius, and remained till death her most devoted friend. At Quesnay's he met Mirabeau, " the friend of men," Dupont de Nemours, Baudeau, and the economists. There likewise he met Adam Smith, about 1762, when that celebrated writer, not as yet known as a political economist, vis ited France for the first time with the young Duke of Buccleuch. Morellet says in his Memoirs : " M. Turgot, who had a taste for metaphysics, thought highly of the talent of Adam Smith, whom we met several times." Dupont de Nemours also records this meet ing, and speaks of Adam Smith, of Turgot, and of himself, as having been " fellow-disciples of Quesnay." Turgot also made the acquaint ance of Gournay, of the two Trudaines, of Albert, who was afterward Intendant of Com merce and Lieutenant-General of Police at Associates with Philosophers. 39 Paris, and of many other men of ability, — courageous administrators and defenders of the liberal faith before Councillors of State and the ministers of the day, who were almost all of the school of Colbert. He had access to the salon of the Marchion ess du Deffant, but never was intimate with her. He soon forsook her to follow Mademoiselle de Lespinasse, when the latter, abandoning her protectress, founded a rival salon. Moreover, he had little liking for the friend of the Mar chioness, the Duke de Choiseul, who was to be come his most formidable adversary. Turgot was already, and not without reason, con sidered an enemy of the parliaments, although he had in them relatives and personal friends to whom he always remained faithful. In 1754 he accepted a place in a Royal Cham ber, — a sort of commission set up after the exile of one of the courts of Parliament, to pass judgment upon cases that came within its jurisdiction, — and this made the breach with the parliamentarians and the Choiseul party definitive. He was, moreover, as we have already noted, by principle a supporter of government, and his respect for the king's authority kept him aloof from all the cabals of opposition. Madame du Hausset relates in her Memoirs 40 Turgot. that, dining one day with Quesnay at Paris, she met " a young Master of Requests, hand some of face, who bore the name of some estate that I do not recall [that of Brucourt] but who was the son of Turgot, the Provost of the Merchants. There was much talk of adminis tration, which at first did not amuse me ; after ward, the question of the love of the French for their king being raised, M. Turgot said: ' This love is not blind ; it is a profound senti ment, a confused recollection of great benefits. The people — I will go further, and say Europe and humanity — owe their freedom to a king of France [I have forgotten the name] ; he established the communes and gave civil ex istence to a vast multitude of men.' I begged M. Quesnay to write down what young Turgot had said, and I showed it to Madame [de Pom padour]. She pronounced in this connection a eulogy upon this Master of Requests, and related the incident to the king, who remarked, ' He comes of good stock.' " It must be admitted that the economists had an almost excessive tendency to lean upon au thority. Some of them would have preferred an honest despot by means of whom they could have realized their system, to a freer ^government subject to influences upon which it would have been necessary to act separately. His Theory of Government. 41 While not going to such a length as this, Tur got was no upholder of what was already termed " the distribution of powers," or " the equilib rium of forces," nor of other combinations de vised for the purpose of checking the power of the head of the state. He feared lest ob stacles placed in the path of evil might be come stumbling-blocks to the right. In order that individual freedom might be protected, he wished the sovereign to exercise what in our day has been styled, often abusively, the rights of the state. But he did not confuse the rights of the state, or of the sovereign, with those which certain philosophers claimed for society. " It has been too constantly the practice of governments," said he, " to sacrifice the happi ness of individuals to the alleged rights of so ciety. It is forgotten that society is made for individuals." He considered all unnecessary authority as tyranny; but he never had any clear notion of what to-day goes by the name of political guaranties. He was too prone to think that the deliberative powers of certain local assemblies, and the wide publicity given to their deliberations in the form of votes, might supply the place of political liberties, and might suffice to guarantee the rights of citizens. Through D'Alembert, Turgot became a col- 42 Turgot. laborator upon the " Encyclopaedia," and made the personal acquaintance of Voltaire. It was in 1760 that he made his pilgrimage to the D/lices. " You will soon have another vis itor," writes D'Alembert to Voltaire, " of whom I will tell you beforehand. This is M. Turgot, a man full of philosophy, of enlightenment, of knowledge, and very much my friend, who .wishes to visit you as a matter of adventure. I say adventure because, ' for fear of the Jews,' he must not boast of it too much — nor you either." After having received Turgot's visit, Vol taire replied : " I am still full of M. Turgot. I did not know that he was the author of the article on ' Existence ; ' I have seldom seen a more amiable or a better informed man ; and, what is rare for a metaphysician, he has the finest and surest taste." Although Turgot was completely fascinated by Voltaire, his passion was not blind, and it suffered some eclipses: first, when Voltaire took for prose the metrical experiments of the Abbe de Laage ; again, later, when the patri arch of Ferney published his witty diatribe against the single tax on land, under the title of "The Man with the Forty Crowns." On Voltaire's side there was greater constancy; he felt, as a personal misfortune, the dismissal Writes for the Encyclopedia. 43 of Turgot in 1776. "Nothing is left for me but to die," he writes to La Harpe, " now that M. Turgot is gone. How they can have dis missed him is more than I can conceive. It has fallen like a thunderbolt on my brain and my heart alike." In 1778, two years later, when Voltaire re turned to Paris, where he was received like a conqueror, he desired to see Turgot. "We were witnesses in 1778," says Condorcet, "to the enthusiasm mingled with deep and tender veneration, which the name and the sight of M. Turgot aroused in that illustrious old man. We saw him, in the midst of the public accla mations, bending beneath the weight of the garlands showered upon him by the nation, hasten with tottering step to M. Turgot, seize his hands in spite of him, cover them with tears and kisses, crying, in a voice choked with sobs : ' Let me kiss the hand that signed the salvation of the people.' " In 1755 Turgot wrote for the "Encyclopae dia " five articles, which appeared in the follow ing year : Etymology, Existence, Expansibility, Fairs and Markets, Foundations. He had formed the plan of contributing other articles, as, Mendicity, Inspectors, Hospital, Immateri ality; but when authorization was withdrawn from this publication of the philosophers, he 44 Turgot. deemed further collaboration inconsistent with his capacity as a magistrate. The publication of the article " Existence " was a genuine literary and philosophical event. Men of letters and encyclopedists were struck with the clearness and precision of the style, with the depth and novelty of the thoughts. A writer, a philosopher, seemed to be revealed. To this day a like impression is made upon those who read this remarkable essay for the first time. Victor Cousin greatly admired it, and has assigned to it a place apart in the phi losophical literature of the eighteenth "century. " As a metaphysician," says Cousin, " Tur got belongs to the school of Locke, like all the men of his century, even Hutcheson and Smith, with whom he has so much in com mon ; but, like them, it has been given him to escape all the vices of that school, thanks to the breadth and insight of his mind, thanks especially to the nobility of his character and sentiments. In a letter to Condorcet con cerning the book ' Of Mind,' he metes justice to the absurd and gloomy ethics of Helvetius. . . . But the best remaining trace of his meta physics is the article on ' Existence.' " men- CHAPTER III. QUESNAY AND GOURNAY. THE PHYSIOCRATS. TURGOT'S ECONOMIC DOCTRINE. ESSAY ON THE FORMATION AND DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH. EULOGY OF GOURNAY. TURGOT did not separate economic laws from other moral laws, and he pursued the study of them all simultaneously, with equal enthusiasm. To him, men formed a natural society, and he thought them unable to attain the degree of prosperity of which they are capable, except under conditions which they cannot possibly throw off. These conditions form laws which are unlike positive laws ; which do not, like the latter, find a sanction in pecuniary or corporal penalties; but which cannot be transgressed without real injury. If man disobeys or seeks to evade these laws, he places a stumbling-block in his own path and fails to realize the degree of wealth or comfort that he might otherwise have attained. Such is the general notion 46 Turgot. formed by Turgot of the relations beiwith natural law and political economy. Quesnay was then at the height of his fame; he had published his Maxims and his " Eco nomic Table." His disciples were a brother hood of the initiated who treated the master as a kind of god. They called themselves the " Economists," and formed, in reality, a sect. Turgot did not like the spirit of sect. One of his letters on the freedom of the grain trade contains this passage : " I know very well that those who have for some time been speaking or writing against free trade in grain, affect to regard this opinion as merely that of a few writers who have styled themselves Econo mists, and who have contrived to arouse a cer tain public prejudice against themselves by the sectarian attitude into which they have blundered, and by a fanatical tone that always repels those who do not share it." Although professing the sincerest admiration for Quesnay, Turgot preferred the companion ship of Gournay. Gournay, his second and perhaps more beloved master, had, it is true, adopted the ideas of Quesnay; but he labored in another field of that domain with which they had together enriched the world. Dupont de Nemours takes great pains to prove the iden- ticalness of the views of these two remarkable Quesnay and Gournay. 47 men; and it was he who devised the name " physiocracy " for the science with which they both occupied themselves at the same time. To his mind, Gournay was as much a physio crat as Quesnay. Quesnay's chief postulate was that agricul ture should be brought to the highest pos- -wW^e de§ree °f perfection. He considered all W(jher industries as dependent upon the tillage -ji the soil ; and if he demanded freedom for manufactures and trade, it was because free dom of trade, by facilitating the exchange and working up of the raw products of the soil, would assure to agriculture the means of further development " Poor peasants," said he, " poor kingdom ; poor kingdom, poor sovereign." Gournay, while recognizing the principle that the promotion of agriculture should be the chief care of the statesman, devoted him self more especially to the solution of the eco nomical problems of manufacturing industry and trade. He noted that competition is the most effective spur to labor, and that every man knows better than the government what is most favorable to his own interest. He took as his motto the words : " Let alone, let pass." 1 The ideas peculiar to GournayTas developed 1 " Laissez faire, laissez passer." 48 Turgot. and applied by Turgot, have bec;ions beiwith ern political economy, — the polL-v. of Adam Smith and of Jean Baptia his fame; Turgot's economic doctrine is sum . « Eco- in two of his essays. The first is a sbother- Gournay sent in 1752 to Marmontel, to aiuster latter in composing the eulogy of their cthe mon friend. The second, entitled " An Ess'tt. on the Formation and Distribution of Wealtfyf is an outline of political economy for the ben<» fit of two young Chinese students who were about to return to their Oriental home. The reflections on the formation and dis tribution of wealth form an opuscule of one hundred paragraphs. The first seven are devoted to the principle that tillage of the soil is the only source of wealth. This is the pure doctrine of Quesnay. All things useful to man are products of the earth. The pro cesses of manufacture, the fetching and carry ing of commerce, are operations that add no new product to those that have sprung from the cultivated soil. Agriculture is the only form of industry that increases the wealth of a nation. The soil immediately gives the cul tivator the reward of his labor, and what it gives is worth more than the pains he has taken. This is a physical result of the fertility of the soil, — a result always in excess of the Que Economic Doctrine. 49 men; and it abor by which this fertility has "physiocrac^ about The excesS) over and both occi^ages of h;,g Jabor> that Nature thug 0 lsfas a mere gift upon the cultivator, "¦ Vs him to purchase the labor of other fibers of society, who earn simply so much r% necessary for their support. The farmer who owns his land, and whose superfluity gives work to others, is therefore, according to Tur got, the sole producer of wealth, which by its circulation animates all the industries of society. Society is thus divided into two industrial classes : the first, drawing from the soil wealth that is continually being renewed ; the second, occupied in working up the raw product, and receiving in exchange for its labor a mere subsistence. The first may be called the productive class, the second the wage-earning class. After this preamble, Turgot enumerates in the following paragraphs the different ways of turning the soil to account, and endeavors to prove by new arguments what he has already set forth ; namely, that the soil alone can furnish a net product, — that is, something in excess of the expenses of cultivation and of interest on the capital invested. The following paragraphs, up to the fifty- 4 50 Turgot. first, deal with the questions of capital, of coinage, of trade, and of the circulation of money. Before gold and silver had become the pledge representing every kind of wealth, exchanges, according to Turgot, were made in kind. Measures of wheat were given in ex change for measures of wine. The competi-r tion between those who had more or less need of a given commodity determined the current value of each commodity relatively to all the rest. Any commodity could thus become the equivalent of any other, and could be used as a common measure for comparing other com modities. A given quantity of wheat worth eighteen pints of wine would likewise buy a sheep, or a piece of tanned leather, or a cer tain quantity of iron ; thus all these things had in trade the same value. But not all pints of wine are of the same value; and if eighteen pints of Anjou wine will buy a sheep, eigh teen pints of Cape wine will buy several sheep. In order to avoid the confusion resulting from the application of the same term to things of variable qualities, it was found necessary to choose, as a measure of the value of other commodities, a commodity always identical, easy to transport, and capable of being pre served without alteration. Gold and silver unite to a superior degree all these qualities, His Economic Doctrine. 51 and by the nature of things they have become the universal form of money. The last fifty paragraphs of the work deal with the accumulation of capital and with the various modes of employing it, as in purchas ing a landed estate, in carrying on an agricul tural enterprise, in industrial or commercial pursuits, or, finally, in making loans, in con sideration of interest, to those in need of funds. In analyzing these five ways of investing capi tal, Turgot points out and proves that capital is always prerequisite to" "any undertaking, whatever its nature. Agricultural enterprises can no more dispense with it than others. Hence he concludes that agriculture, like man ufacturing, has its masters and its workmen, — the masters furnishing the capital, the work men the labor. The mere farm-laborer, like the mere operative, has no property but his muscles, and no profit but his wages. Without capital there can be no large farms, and large farms are necessary to progress ; for, except by culture on a large scale, the soil cannot produce all that it is capable of producing. Thus the tillage of the soil and industries of all kinds depend upon a mass of capital, — that is, accumulated personal property, — which re turns every year into the hands of those to whom it belongs, to be again advanced the 52 Turgot. following year in order to permit the same enterprises to continue. Returning at the end to the theory dear to Quesnay, Turgot concludes that the product of capital should be exempted from all cpn- tribution to the public "expenses, because it is a product previously deducted from that of the soil. The revenue of landholders can alone be considered free, because it is availa ble, and only available wealth can be employed for the expenses of the state. Such is Turgot's famous little work. On the subjects of capital, money, competition, it set forth truths as useful as they were novel. It was necessarily and constantly present to the mind of Adam Smith nine years later, when he wrote his " Wealth of Nations." But one is forced to admit that while it is full of truths it abounds also in errors, being saturated with Quesnay's doctrine of the net product, and constantly affirming that the soil must be considered the only source of wealth. While regretting the errors that led Turgot astray, one cannot help honoring him, as well as the other physiocrats. They should be hon ored even for their errors, because these are due to a false application of laws eternally true, — laws of which Quesnay is the discov erer. The false application made of these Fundamental Truths. 53 laws by Turgot has given them such celebrity that they have been recognized and accepted as true by all thinkers. The physiocrats affirmed in the first place that there is a natural law of the formation of wealth, and that, in order to permit this law to produce all its effects and to enable men to acquire wealth, three kinds of freedom are es sential : First, men united into communities and organized into nations must be left free to produce ; secondly, they must be left free to buy, sell, and transport the products of agri culture, of manufactures, and of trade ; finally, they must be left free to accumulate, to circu late, to lend capital, and to employ it for the development of the general wealth. This is the most important of the truths discovered by the physiocrats. Another of the truths they taught is, that taxes are subject to a natural law of incidence. The state can compel a class of citizens to pay taxes, but it cannot prevent them from obtain ing reimbursement from others in case the natural economic law permits or commands it. The physiocrats proved conclusively that the tax-payers are in many cases mere intermedi ate agents, whose function is to pay the taxes for those who, in the last analysis, must dis charge them. Such taxable middlemen thus 54 Turgot. make to the real debtors of the state advances recoverable with more or less delay and diffi culty. From this observation it was concluded that such repercussive taxes should not be imposed upon men whose sole reliance is the labor of their hands, for this would be com pelling the poor to advance money to the well- to-do. Thence also they deduced the equally evident principle that taxes should, as far as possible, be assessed upon the fortune and the income of those who are bound finally to pay them. But with these great truths discovered by Quesnay and so ably expounded by Turgot, how much error is mingled ! Is it possible to believe with them that the soil is the only source of wealth, of " continually renewing wealth," to use Turgot's own expression? We know to-day that all forms of capital indistin- guishably, whatever be their method of invest ment or the use made of them, — provided this investment and this use be productive, — have, like the soil, the power of constantly giving birth to new wealth. Of this principle Adam Smith and Jean Baptiste Say have given proofs that have closed the debate. Equally contrary to truth is that theory of taxation which recognizes no legitimate re source for the budget of public expenditure, Missing Page Missing Page An Economic Lesson from Hume. 57 nies there are next to no taxes, and manual labor is three times as dear there as in any European country. In Holland there are heavy taxes upon commodities, and the Republic possesses no land upon which they can fall. The price of manual labor invariably de pends upon the quantity of labor and upon the amount of demand for work, and not upon the taxes. The dealers who manufacture cloth for ex port jcannot raise the wages of their operatives, be cause this would make their cloth too dear to be sold in the foreign market ; nor can those who supply the home market raise the wages, for there are never two prices for the same kind of manual labor. This is true of all products of which any quantity is ex ported, — that is, of all products ; and even were there a product of which no quantity was exported, the wages of the operatives could not be raised, for the rise in wages would attract so many laborers into that industry, that a fall in the price of labor would immediately result. It seems to me that when a tax is levied upon a commodity, laborers either consume less or work more. A man acquires no more pro ductive power, but he can add some hours to his week's work. Seldom is he so poor as not to be able to cut off something from his expenditure. What happens when the price of grain rises? Has not the poor man to live more scantily and to work harder? A tax produces the same effect. I beg you also to consider that besides the landowners and the poor laborers, there are always a consider able number of opulent people who invest their capi- 58 Turgot. tal in trade, and who spend a large income in .giving work to the poor. I am convinced that in Erance and in England incomes of this kind are much glreater than those derived from the soil. For besides! mer chants properly so called, I include in this clajss all shopkeepers and all master tradesmen of every de scription, and I deem it very just that these should contribute toward the public expenses; this, how ever, cannot take place unless taxes are levied upon commodities. It seems to me unreasonable to say that this order of citizens necessarily throws its pro portion of the taxes back upon the landowners, since its revenues and gains are certainly able to bear some reduction." J This excellent lesson in political economy was given Turgot a year before he produced his " Essay on the Formation and Distribution of Wealth," and nine years before Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations." Turgot's reply, dated March 25, 1767, has been preserved by Hill Burton. Turgot admits that the price of labor is determined by the law of supply and demand. " You observe truly," said he, " that it is not the degree of taxation that determines the rate of wages, but merely the relation of the supply to the demand. This principle has never been 1 This letter is not to be found in the collections of Hume's correspondence, and is here perforce translated from the French. — Tr. His Defence of his Doctrine. 59 denied : it is the one principle that immediately fixes the price of all things that have a com mercial value." And in order to explain the apparent contradiction between this and Ques- nay's doctrine, Turgot distinguishes two prices, — "the current price, determined by the rela tions ofsupply and demand ; and the fundamen tal price, which, for a commodity, is what the object costs the workman." In this distinction Turgot found an answer to his detractors, who accused him, and still accuse him, of condemn ing the workman to eternal poverty by the iron law of wages. With Quesnay, Turgot divided mankind into two classes : the producing and the wage- earning, — the productive and the sterile. The workman cannot co-operate in the formation of a net product, and his wages assure him noth ing beyond the strict necessaries of life. " In all kinds of labor," said Turgot, " it must and does happen that the wages of the workman are restricted to what is necessary for his subsistence." Louis Blanc takes ground against this theory. " Turgot," he says, " had the misfor tune to adopt the principle from which has been derived in our day that base and cruel formula: 'Every man for himself and every man in his own house.' This principle once 60 Turgot. admitted, what if the consequences are fatal? 'This must be so.' Certainly, it 'must' hap pen that the workman is reduced to the strict necessaries of life, when individual right has been taken as the point of departure; but would this be so in a system of fraternal association?," The germ of Turgot's defence is found in his letter of March 25, 1767. The " iron law," he would have answered, determines the fun damental price of labor ; the law of supply and demand determines its current price. " Al though the fundamental price is not," said he, " the immediate principle of the current value, it is nevertheless a minimum below which the current value cannot sink : for if a dealer loses on his merchandise, he ceases to sell or to manufacture ; and if a workman cannot live by his labor, he becomes a beggar or an emigrant. Moreover, the workman must find a certain profit in order to provide against accident, and to bring up his family. ... As you say, the workman contrives to labor more or to consume less, but this can be only for a short time. Doubtless no man works as much as he might work. Nor is it in nature that men should work as much as they might, any more than that a cord should be strung as tensely as it might be. In every machine a certain de- The Economists. 61 gree of slackening is necessary, without which it would run the risk of breaking down at any moment. . . . This species of superfluity upon which, when worst comes to worst, one can fall back, is another essential element in the ordinary subsistence of workmen and of their families." Turgot deemed the English hardly fitted to understand Quesnay. " Our economic philoso phers," he wrote to Hume on the 23d of July, 1766, "zealous for their master, will stoutly uphold Quesnay's system. This system is now very remote from the minds of English writers ; in fact, the difficulty of harmonizing its principles with the ambition of monopoliz ing the world's commerce is too great to per mit the hope of their adopting it for a long time to come." He was not converted by his friend's letters ; his mind was made up, — he was a physiocrat, and a physiocrat he remained. David Hume could not but lament this ; for with all his lik ing for Turgot, he did not like the sect of the economists, — witness this sally in a letter to the Abbe Morellet (May 15, 1769) : 1 — " I see that in your prospectus [of a new Diction ary of Trade] you take care not to disoblige your 1 In J. Hill Burton's " Life and Correspondence of David Hume," this letter is dated " London, July io, 1769." — Tr. 62 Turgot. economists by any declaration of your sentiments; in which I commend your prudence. But I hope that in your work you will thunder them, and crush them, and pound them, and reduce them to dust and ashes ! They are, indeed, the set of men the most chimerical and most arrogant that now exist, since the annihilation of the Sorbonne. I ask your pardon for saying so, as I know you belong to that venerable body. I wonder what could engage our friend, M. Turgot, to herd among them, — I mean among the economists ; though I believe he was also a Sorbonnist." Turgot always remained faithful to Quesnay's doctrine, always affirming it with deep convic tion. One may even say that he made it his own by the strength with which he set it forth. It is not, however, to be forgotten that he did not belong to the inner sanctuary; that he would himself have protested more loudly than any one else had he been taken for the official interpreter of the master ; and that he recoiled from attributing to Quesnay's maxims that dogmatic value with which the sectaries of every age have invested the ideas of their founder. Outside of this school of economists he had friends and even masters. For Gournay he expressed as much respect as for Quesnay, and with Gournay he lived upon terms of more Net Contribution lo Economic Science. 63 familiar intimacy. The " Essay on the Forma tion and Distribution of Wealth " is not, there fore, sufficient to give us a full understanding of Turgot's doctrine, the development of which must be sought in the conversations with Gournay. But this does not imply that, in consequence of his studies with Gournay, Tur got modified the fundamental ideas he had derived from Quesnay touching the function of the soil in the production of wealth, nor that he recognized that he had previously fallen into any errors. The " Essay on the Formation and Distri bution of Wealth " is posterior to Gournay's death ; yet the theories of free labor, free trade, and free industry, which really made up the whole of Gournay's system, have received such illustration from Turgot's application of them and from his admirable tests exhibiting the happy results that might flow from them, as to have overshadowed the errors of the net prod uct and of the exclusive predominance of the land over personal capital. The net product which was to furnish a basis for taxation, the theory which sees in the soil the only source of wealth, have become mere hypotheses ex plaining the great law of the natural incidence of taxes, and illustrating the incontestable maxims that no state is rich whose people are 64 Turgot. poor, and that no state can grow rich by ruin ing its tax-payers. Considering certain eco nomic prolegomena as hypotheses, we may say that Quesnay's theories have been as use ful to the progress of economic science as other now abandoned hypotheses touching the emission of light and the nature of electricity have been to the progress of physical science. Like the most eminent men of his time, Tur got made use of these hypotheses ; it was, how ever, not these, but his assertion of the free dom of labor and of trade, his establishment of the doctrine of free labor upon imperisha ble foundations, that made him Adam Smith's precursor, perhaps his master, and that give Turgot a claim to be considered the real head of the modern economic school. Gournay, whose real name was Vincent, was born in 1 712, at Saint-Malo. At the age of seventeen he was sent by his parents to Cadiz, to learn trade; he succeeded. In 1744 his business brought him to France, and into re lations with Maurepas, who perceived his merit. Two years later his partner left him a fortune, and with it the estate of Gournay, whose name he thenceforward bore. He had visited and studied in detail England and Hol land, and he read with great eagerness books dealing with the science of trade. From the Schools of Quesnay and of Gournay. 65 treatises of Josias Child and the memoirs of John De Witt he drew the first elements of his economic knowledge. In 1748 he withdrew from business and removed to Paris. M. de Maurepas urged him to seek the position of Intendant of Trade, and in 1751 helped him to obtain it. It is at this time that he comes into relations with the economists. Dupont de Nemours, who lays great stress upon the unity of the economic school, tells us that Gournay and Quesnay arrived from differ ent sides at the same results ; and that they met at the goal with mutual congratulations upon the exactness with which their diverse but equally true principles led to identical con clusions. He admits, however, that the two standpoints from which they viewed " the prin ciples of political administration" had formed two schools. The principal members of Ques nay's school are the Marquis de Mirabeau, Abeille, Fourqueux, Bertin, Dupont de Ne mours, the Abb6 Roubaud, and Le Trosne. Mercier de La Riviere and the Abbe Baudeau form, says Dupont de Nemours, a special branch of .this school. They believed that it would be easier to persuade a prince than a nation, and that freedom of trade and labor, as well as the true principles of taxation, would be sooner established by the authority of sov- 5 66 Turgot. ereigns than by the progress of reason. Al though these views were not shared by all the economists, there were many who slipped upon this treacherous ground ; and, as we have seen, Turgot has been reproached not altogether unjustly : wTtTThavmg' attached too little importance to the political liberties of a nation. The other school is that of Gournay: it comprised Malesherbes, the Abbe Morellet, Trudaine de Montigny, Cardinal de Boisgelin, the Abbe de Cice, — in general, the particular friends of Turgot, and Turgot himself. K was while Gournay was Intendant of Trade that his relations with Turgot were most intimate. Condorcet, speaking of their interviews, says: " They were of great benefit to M. Turgot, who learned from M. de Gournay to recognize in detail all the advantages of free trade and all the disadvantages of prohibitions." From 1753 to 1756 Gournay made a series of official tours in the provinces in order to judge for himself of the state of trade and manufactures. Taking Turgot with him, he visited succes sively Burgundy, Lyonnais, Dauphine, Pro vence, Upper and Lower Languedoc; and, later on, Maine, Anjou, and Brittany. On his return from the journey of 1756 he fell sick, languished some years, and died Eulogy, of Gournay. 67 June 27, 1759. Marmontel thought of writing his eulogy, and asked Turgot for notes. Some days later Marmontel received from Turgot a paper containing a very clear and faithful ex position of Gournay's doctrines. This paper, which was published by Dupont de Nemours under the title, " Eulogy of Gournay," sup plements the " Essay on the Formation and Distribution of Wealth," and constitutes with that essay the doctrinal portion of Turgot's works. Gournay thought that it did not belong to government to regulate the market price of commodities, or to prohibit one kind of in dustry in order to cause another to flourish. For a century past, said he, all educated men in Holland and in England have regarded the abuses still existing in France as relics of bar barism, — as the mark of the ignorance and weakness of those who have hitherto governed France without recognizing the importance of freedom, or, recognizing it, without being able to protect it against the spirit of monopoly. Universal freedom to buy and to sell appeared to him the only way of assuring to the vender a selling price high enough to encourage pro duction, and to the consumer the lowest possi ble price for the best goods. He recognized the fact that some dealers are scamps and some 68 Turgot. consumers dupes, but thought it the business of the individual to be watchful; saying that we do not furnish all children with padded caps for fear lest some of them may fall and bump their heads. In the three following propositions Turgot sums up and appropriates Gournay's doctrine : First, " To give back to all branches of trade that precious freedom of which they have been deprived by centuries of ignorant preju dice, by the facility of government in lending itself to private interests, and by the desire of a misconceived perfection;" secondly, "To facilitate the labor of all citizens in order to arouse the greatest competition in sale, whence will necessarily result the greatest perfection in the making and the most advantageous price for the buyer ; " thirdly, " To give the buyer the greatest possible number of competitors by opening to the seller every outlet for his commodity, — this being the only means of assuring to labor its recompense, and of per petuating production, which has no object but this recompense." Such was Gournay's system as adopted and interpreted by Turgot, — a system resting upon the maxim that " every man knows his own in terest better than another to whom that interest is entirely foreign." Those who opposed Gour- Eulogy of Gournay. 69 nay's opinions represented him as the enthu siast of a system. " This reproach, ' a man with a system,' has become," says Turgot, " a sort of weapon in the hands of the prejudiced, or of persons interested in maintaining abuses, against those proposing any kind of change whatever." CHAPTER IV. I. INTENDANT OF LIMOGES. THE CADASTRE. II. LOANS OF MONEY, AND USURY. — III. LETTERS ON FREE TRADE IN GRAIN. FOR two years after Gournay's death Tur got continued to perform his functions as Master of Requests; but, with a view to preparing himself for an intendancy, he asked permission of M. de La Michodiere to accom pany him in his tours of inspection. France was divided into forty provinces, and into thirty-five revenue districts called generali ties. The province was a military division com manded by a governor ; the generality was an administrative circumscription presided over by an intendant. The province did not coin cide, either in extent or in boundaries, with the generality. There were almost always several governors to every intendant, and several intendants to every governor; but their re spective functions were independent. The in tendants were financial agents like our present Intendant of Limoges. 71 tax-commissioners, and were judges in certain disputed matters in relation to taxes, like our prefectoral councils ; moreover, like our pre fects, they had charge of the police, of public charity, and of the militia. Their powers were the more considerable from the fact that they stood in constant relations with the Council of State, and that, preserving the title of Master of Requests, they sat during their frequent sojourns at Paris with the other masters of requests. On the 8th of August, 1761, Turgot was appointed Intendant of Limoges. Writing to Voltaire on the 24th of the same month, he says : " It is to Limoges that I am sent. I should have much preferred Grenoble, whence I could have made little pilgrimages to the shrine of Confucius in order to learn of the High Priest." The Generality of Limoges was divided into five sub-districts called elections ; namely, Brive, Tulle, Limoges, Bourganeuf, Angouleme. The country was poor and tax- ridden. " I think myself within bounds in affirming," says Turgot, " that the taxes of the Generality of Limoges amount to forty-eight or fifty per cent of the total product, and that the king derives about as much from the land as the proprietors." For thirteen years Turgot devoted himself 72 Turgot. with unslackening zeal to the interests of his generality; but he could not satisfy every body. When, in 1774, he was called to the Ministry, some said that he was worshipped in Limousin, others that he was detested there. Probably both classes were right. The Limou sin nobility had been accustomed to make use of the intendant to obtain favors, to reduce the taille1 and the poll-tax of its dependents, and to cut down its own twentieths to the low est figure. The nobles did not pardon Turgot for breaking with such easy customs, and af fected to treat him, like Gournay, as a doc trinaire. " Yes, madame, he is a man with a system," exclaims Abbe Baudeau, writing to a lady whom he does not mention, but whom he describes as a witty court prude and a mother in the Jesuitical Church. "... What ! think you that incoherent ideas strung together with red tape suffice for the governing of a kingdom like France ? " Turgot had there fore made many enemies among the petty nobility of the country. But not so among the peasantry. His departure was announced from the pulpit by all the parish priests of the province, who everywhere said mass for him. The peasants left their work to attend 1 The tallage or tax levied upon all who did not belong to the nobility or clergy. — Tr. Intendant of Limoges. 73 this service, saying to one another, " The king does well to take M. Turgot, but we are very unlucky to lose him." We cannot write the history of his ad ministration, nor make a complete analysis of what he called his Limousin labors; this would involve an extended work full of de tails now devoid of interest. But in order fully to understand Turgot's genius, it is neces sary to study the unfailing breadth of view which he brought to the treatment of admin istrative problems. No piece of business was too insignificant to afford an occasion for laying down principles. His circulars to his subordinates, his letters to the minister, his advices to the Council, are so many essays upon economic laws and theories. Such are his " Advice Concerning the Levy and Distri bution of the Taille" (1762 to 1770), his " Memorial on Interest-bearing Loans and on Usury " (1769), his " Letters on Free Trade in Grain" (1770). And, surprising enough, all that he writes seems improvised ! He has no need of protracted study to enable him to trace effects to their causes; his early education, "his mental habits, his accuracy of judgment, enable him to penetrate immediately, without hesitation or confusion, to the bottom of every subject. Not that he was satisfied with a first 74 Turgot. glance, or neglected details, or was not labo rious; on the contrary, he was a prodigious toiler, and his frequent attacks of gout never took him from his business. His only rest was the writing of private let ters, and he had many correspondents. With Caillard he talked poetry, sending him trans lations of Horace or of Pope, and employing him to forward to Ferney, under the veil of an assumed name, those metrical verses that Voltaire took for prose. He reasoned about the pronunciation of the ancients, and could not pardon David Hume for thinking that the ancient Romans pronounced Latin in the English fashion. With Condorcet he ex changed opinions upon philosophy, ethics, science. Never was his mind so free as when it was most occupied. Meantime the interests of those under his jurisdiction were his constant solicitude. One of his most engrossing tasks during the first years of his intendancy was the revision of the tax-rolls. In Limousin the taille was at that time levied in accordance with a scale drawn up twenty years before by M. de Tourny, the former intendant. Wishing to correct the abuses of the arbitrary taille, Tourny had con ceived the plan of recasting all the old valu ations of the products of the land, and of The Cadastre. 75 founding upon a sort of cadastre an equita ble scale of assessment. But' the surveys had been finished only throughout some two thirds of the Province, and the valuations had been based, for the most part, upon a mere inspec tion of premises or a bird's-eye view of sections of cultivated land. There had resulted such shocking inequalities that the people had found no relief in the abandonment of the arbitrary taille. Turgot found it necessary to do the work all over again. What he had in view was a real cadastre, — a methodical, geometrical description of the Province, estate by estate, — which could be kept abreast of successive changes in the com position and nature of each piece of property. But the establishment of a cadastre with sur veys and valuations has always been, and will always be, a very long, difficult, and costly work. " Had I then known," writes Turgot in 1 762 to the Comptroller-General, " the vastness of the labor necessary, not merely to perfect the future working of the system, but to draw it from its present confusion, I should perhaps not have had courage to undertake the task." He did not, however, spare his pains. He made every effort to instruct the commission ers, the proprietors, the peasants, touching all questions raised by the tax-revision. With a 76 Turgot. view to public education, he caused the Li moges Agricultural Society to offer a prize for an essay on the theory of taxation ; and in or der to overthrow administrative prejudices, he continually broached in his letters and reports to the Council and to the Comptroller-General — no matter how small the immediate question at issue — the most general topics, even that of the principle of taxation. According to Turgot the land-tax should be fixed and real. It should be fixed : " It is very important to apportion the land-tax according to a fixed valuation." It should be real : that is, " apportioned only upon the basis of the real estate of each tax-payer and of the reve nue he derives from it." A tax upon indi viduals is, Turgot thinks, a manifest absurdity, since the individual is nothing but " a bundle of wants." In his " Plan of a Memoir on Taxation," Turgot examines the comparative merits of the quota system and of the apportionment system. The state may ask of each individual a portion of his revenue, — this is the quota system ; or the state may content itself with asking of the nation, of each province, of each community, a lump sum to be assessed proportionally upon the proprietors, — this is the apportionment system. Turgot sees great The Cadastre. 77 advantages in the quota system. Collecting a proportional part of the revenue, the state would be, in his opinion, the real proprietor of that part of the revenue. Bargains would be arranged upon this understanding. It would finally come about that purchasers would not purchase the state's part, so that in the end no one would pay any more taxes. The public revenue, being a quota of the national wealth, would increase with it. " The king's wealth would be the gauge of the people's wealth, and the administration, always smitten by the counter-stroke of its own errors, would learn wisdom from continual experience, by the mere calculation of the product of the tax." Notwithstanding all these advantages, the quota system appears to him impossible ; be cause here the government is alone against all, and every man is interested in concealing the value of his property, while no one is interested in establishing the truth. He adds a consider ation which has lost none of its force, — for the general method of cultivating land has changed much less in France within one hun dred and twenty years than many imagine. It is, that while in districts where agriculture is pursued on a great scale the value of rentals gives a control of the revenue from land, this kind of control does not exist in districts where 78 Turgot. farming is carried on upon shares, — that is, where there are no leases. And he adds that it is far from true that all the land is rented : " Scarcely a third of the kingdom is cultivated by tenant-farmers." As to trusting to the honesty of declarants, he deems this an impracticable method of collecting the tax ; and he ends with this not very consoling but very penetrating observa tion : " Fraud would become very common, and would cease, from that time, to be dishonest!' He therefore advises the state to adhere to the apportionment of a fixed amount. j' In his opinion, the land-tax must be an ap portioned tax levied by means of a permanent cadastre to be established upon the survey and classification of lands according to their quality. This system is none other than that which was established in France by the Na tional Assembly, and which still exists. Its advantages and disadvantages are still those ipointed out by Turgot; and the same questions are raised to-day as at the time when the at tempt was made to perfect the apportionment in the provinces where apportionment was in force, and to introduce it into those in which the contrary system still prevailed. Loans of Money, and Usury. 79 II. In 1769 there occurred at Angouleme one of those commercial crises which we now very improperly call " monetary crises." The cause of this one lay in the inability of speculators to sustain an excessive circulation of accom modation bills. Suspensions of payments, fail ures, and even bankruptcies resulted ; engage ments falling due were not renewed, discount became impossible, trade was paralyzed ; mon ey was not to be had for any purpose, and the best merchants were absolutely discredited. Local dealers in fabrics had as usual sent their orders to Lyons, and had been answered that no business would be transacted with gentlemen in Angouleme except for ready money. Since that time many similar crises have been suffered. The excessive circulation of paper always ends in an advance in the price of money, compelling speculators to liquidate, and dragging down along with the guilty ones the imprudent lenders who have confided in them. But the Angouleme crisis of 1769 had a peculiar character that seriously aggravated its consequences. The authors of the accommodation bills were a parcel of rogues who had connived to 80 Turgot. profit by their own bankruptcy, by accusing the lenders of usury and by laying informations against them before the Seneschal of Angou leme. "This disturbance of the operations of trade," says Turgot, " this stoppage of the circulation of money, this alarm among the merchants of a city, this wrecking of their for tunes, is a great evil ; but an equal evil is the triumph of a set of knaves who, after imposing upon the credulity of individuals to procure money upon fraudulent bills, have had the criminal cunning to find in misinterpreted laws not only a screen from prosecution, but also a weapon of cruel vengeance, — a means of slandering and ruining their creditors, and of enriching themselves with the spoils." Turgot proposed, therefore, to appeal to the Council the accusations of usury pending before the Seneschal of Angouleme, and to remove the cognizance to a commission, which was also to be intrusted with the duty of drafting a decla ration, and of determining the law touching the use of interest-bearing loans in trade. The Council, accordingly, took cognizance of the appeals; the proceedings against the lenders were annulled, and the institution of similar proceedings was forbidden; but there was no declaration, no new law, and the legis lation touching rates of interest remained as Loans of Money, and Usury. 81 obscure as ever, being left to the arbitrary interpretation of the judges. In support of his request for an appeal, Tur got, faithful to his habit of treating particular cases with the greatest possible breadth, sent the Council of State a Memorial, which remains the completest and most perfect work ever written upon the question of interest-bearing loans and usury, and which immediately placed its author among our foremost writers. Dividing his subject into three parts, in the first he establishes the necessity of interest- bearing loans for the exigencies of trade and industry, and proves that the rate is variable in proportion to the abundance or scarcity of capital and to the nature of the risk. In the second part he refutes the arguments of scho lastic philosophers, of jurisconsults, and of theologians. In the third part he seeks the historic causes of the hatefulness of usury and of the bad reputation of money-lenders. Finally, in a strong-based conclusion, he prays that interest-bearing loans be legalized, that the_ rate be left to the free agreement of borrower' and lender, and that usurers who prey upon the passions and inexperience of youth be pun ished only by the laws relating to breach of confidence and other kinds of imposition. In every commercial centre, according to 6 8 2 Turgot. Turgot, a majority of the enterprises are based upon borrowed money, and no capitalist will deprive himself of money of which he could make use, without a prospect of some adequate return. If money brought no interest, no one would lend it; if the law forbids interest- bearing loans, either the law will be violated or trade will be crippled. But if interest-bearing loans are necessary, and if money is an article of commerce, money must be regarded as actual merchandise, the price of which depends upon the agreement of the parties, and is sub ject, like all other merchandise, to the law of supply and demand. What fault is to be found with the borrower for consenting to pay a high rate of interest to the lender who takes a risk on his behalf, or with the lender who secures himself from risk by an increase of price? No law, either civil or religious, obliges a person to furnish another gratuitous assistance ; why should the civil or the religious law forbid the procurement of money at the price which the borrower finds it to his advantage to pay? The lawfulness of interest is an immediate con sequence of the right of ownership. The owner of a thing may sell it or lend it, the rate of the sale or loan being always just, when the will of both parties is free, and when there is no fraud on either side. These principles are Loans of Money, and Usury. 83 admitted by every one touching everything but money ; why should they not be applicable to money, as to everything else? If it be said that it is need which constrains the borrower to submit to the lender's conditions, may it not be replied that it is also need which compels a man to buy bread of the baker? Has the baker on this account any the less right to receive the price of his bread ; and may the buyer, on the score of need, take possession of the bread without payment? In their attack upon interest-bearing loans, the scholastic philosophers started from an ar gument which is said to be in Aristotle ; and, on the pretext that money does not produce money, they concluded that it was wrong to make loans produce interest. The pretended barrenness of money is a palpable error, based upon a wretched juggle with words. The holders and spreaders of this doctrine forget that money is the necessary instrument of all agricultural, industrial, and commercial under takings ; and that, although called barren, it is throughout the world the equivalent not only of all merchandise, — of everything that might be called barren, — but also of land, which pro duces a very real revenue. The argument of the jurisconsults, of Po- thier among the rest, is different. " Equity re- 84 Turgot. quires," says Pothier, " that in a contract which is not gratuitous the values given on both sides shall be equal ; so - that neither party shall give more than he receives, or receive more than he gives. Now, all that the lender exacts beyond the principal of his loan is something over and above what he has given; since in receiving the mere principal he receives the exact equivalent of what he has given." Pothier's argument was also advanced by Saint Thomas Aquinas. The fungibles forming the material of a loan have no use distinguish able from the thing itself; to sell this use in consideration of interest is to sell something that does not exist. Turgot considers this rea soning to be a tissue of demonstrable errors and verbal jugglery. In any agreement rest ing upon mutual conditions there can be no injustice done except by violence, fraud, bad faith, or breach of confidence. Between values exchanged, or between articles given and re ceived, there is no such thing as nfetapnysiral equality or inequality. Equality of~value-de- pends upon the opinion of the contracting parties touching the degree of utility of the articles exchanged, for the satisfaction of their desires or needs. Having discussed inequality, they allege as an example of inequality the fact that the borrower, in returning more than Loans of Money, and Usury. 85 the principal, gives back more than he re ceived ; and they infer that this is unjust. Such reasoning takes it for granted that the money received to-day, and the money which is to be returned in a year, are two things perfectly equal. Is there not, on the contrary, an ob vious difference between the two values, — so obvious as to be recognized by the vulgar proverb, " A bird in the hand is worth two in the bush"? The final argument against the lawfulness of interest-bearing loans is drawn from Holy Writ. We read in the Gospel of Saint Luke : " Lend, hoping for nothing again." 1 Sensible men would have seen in these words merely a precept of charity, and, placing them in their context, it would be impossible to interpret them otherwise : " But love ye your enemies, and do good, and lend, hoping for nothing again ; and your reward shall be great, and ye shall be the children of the Highest : for he is kind unto the unthankful and to the evil." Ac cording to Turgot, any man reading this text without prejudice will see in it a mere precept of charity. The true sense of the passage is as if it had been said : " As men, as Christians, you are all brothers and friends; help one 1 In the revised version of 1881 : " Lend, never despair ing," or, " Lend, despairing of no man." — Tr. 86 Turgot. another in time of need, let your purses be open to one another, and do not sell the help you ought to give." The real origin of the sentiment against in terest-bearing loans is the outcry of the people ; for to the people usurers have always been hate ful. It is pleasant to receive money, and hard to return it. In primitive society men borrow little for purposes of trade; they borrow only for their support, and can return the loan only in case of some fortunate circumstance. As the lender takes the risk that the fortunate cir cumstance may not occur, the rate of interest is naturally very high. In Rome, it was ex cessive. The severity of the laws against debt ors — laws always made by the rich — aroused the people against their creditors. In all an cient republics abolition of debt was always the desire of the people, and the watchword of demagogues seeking to gain popular favor. Christianity, upon its appearance, offered itself as the religion of the poor ; an opinion which had become the passion of the poor was natu rally adopted by its preachers, who confused interest-bearing loans with the harsh prosecu tion of insolvent debtors. Hence the tendency among the ancient doctors of the Church to regard interest-bearing loans as illicit. Meanwhile, the causes that formerly made Loans of Money, and Usury. 87 the taking of interest unpopular have ceased to act with so much force. Trade has infi nitely increased, and requires immense amounts of capital. The sums borrowed by the poor for subsistence are now but an insignificant fraction of all the money loaned. The great est borrowers are the rich captains of industry who expect large returns from their borrowed capital. The name of usurer is now applied only to lenders for a short term and at a high rate, to pawnbrokers, and to the contemptible men who make a trade of furnishing the prodigal sons of great families with sums of money at enormous interest wherewith to support their vices. The lenders for short terms are use ful, after all, in placing petty tradesmen in a position to earn their own livelihood; pawn brokers make their loans upon articles which it is possible for the borrower to do without, and the poor man esteems himself happy to obtain temporary relief with no risk but that of forfeiting his pledge. People entertain a feeling of gratitude rather than hatred toward these petty usurers who relieve them in time of need, although they sell this relief very dear. The only usurers injurious to society, there fore, are those who make a trade of lending 88 Turgot. to dissipated young men. Their real crime is not, however, usury, but that of aiding and abet ting vice. For this they should be punished, and not for their high rates of interest. Reading through in the original the Me morial which we have summarized, one is struck with the strength of the arguments; and one cannot help admitting that Turgot has really said the last word upon the sub ject. This discussion has frequently been renewed since that time ; it is not yet closed, perhaps will not soon be closed. The advo cates of free rates of interest have made many excellent speeches ; but whatever their merit, their eloquence, their ease of exposition, they have done nothing but reproduce in the lan guage of the day the arguments of Turgot. There is but one arsenal where are to be found perfect weapons against the successors of Po thier and the Scholastic philosophers. That arsenal is the " Memorial on Loans of Money," sent to the Royal Council in 1769, in support of the appeal to the Council of the prosecu tions for usury pending before the Seneschal of Angouleme. Letters on Free Trade in Grain. 89 III. After the dearth of capital, the story of which we have told, the Generality of Limoges was visited with another dearth much more dreadful than that of money, — a dearth of grain. This is at any time a fearful scourge ; but it was especially to be dreaded in the France of those days, where means of com munication were so imperfect, and where pop ular prejudice, countenanced by the most influential personages of the administration and the magistracy, rendered the grain trade extremely perilous. The royal declaration of 1763 and the edict of 1764 had decreed "the free circulation of grain " throughout the king dom ; but this freedom was constantly threat ened by parliaments and municipal officers. Thus the Parliament of Bordeaux, by a de cision of Jan. 17, 1770, had ordered the own ers of land and farmers of land of Limousin and Perigord to convey each week to the markets a sufficient quantity of wheat to pro vision the said markets, and had forbidden them to sell, either by wholesale or retail, any portion of the grain anywhere save at these markets. The aldermen of the little town of Turenne had an equally small respect for the law. They 90 Turgot. forbade any grain to be taken away, ordering the owners to " relinquish their wheat upon receiving the market price in ready money." Again, at Angouleme, the lieutenant of police took upon himself to order that all persons who had grain, either in store or otherwise, should keep no more than was absolutely sufficient for feeding themselves and their families, and that they should bring the resi due to market on pain of a fine of one thou sand francs. Thus, in addition to the local scarcity — which on account of the loss of the harvest was very real — there arose a general dearth, owing to the impossibility of making up by means of trade for the defi ciency existing in the Generality. Warned of the danger, Turgot took the most energetic measures. He prevailed upon the Council to quash the Bordeaux decision. He commanded the Turenne municipality to withhold opposi tion to the export of grain. He obtained a decree of the Council forbidding the Angou leme lieutenant of police to execute his ordi nance. At the same time he distributed a great many copies of the royal declaration of 1763 and of the edict of July, 1764, decreeing free trade in grain; likewise the work of Le Trosne entitled " Free Trade in Grain always Useful, never Injurious." Turgot was wont Letters on Free Trade in Grain, g i to say : " Orders themselves must be sown in prepared soil." Moreover, he did not stop at these somewhat passive measures: he organ ized charitable workshops, compelled land-' owners to feed their laborers, and took active1; measures for the construction of highways. Meanwhile, political difficulties which did not fail to raise the price of grain, not only at Limoges but in many provinces, had strongly shaken the confidence of the Comptroller- General, Abbe Terray, — if ever he was sincere, — in the efficacy of the freedom of the grain- trade, which had been granted by Comptroller- General Bertin's edict of 1764. Abbe Terray therefore resolved to revoke the edict. Before carrying out his intention, — although he was perfectly decided to do so, being actuated by all sorts of reasons, some of them far from honest, — he made it known to the intendants, and asked their advice. This was the occasion of Turgot's famous letters on Free Trade in Grain. He impro vised them during a tour he was making for the purpose of apportioning the taxes among the " elections," the " sub-delegations," and the " communes." The winter was cold among the mountains, and inns were infrequent and wretched. It was while travelling amid such conditions, painful enough for a victim of 92 Turgot. rheumatism and gout, that he dashed off these letters. Nothing is more surprising than the ease with which our Intendant finished this classic work in circumstances so unfavorable. In these famous seven letters, all the questions at issue are stated with perfect clearness, and solved in the interests of freedom, by means of good sense and unanswerable logic. The first is dated from Limoges, October 30, 1770; the second, from Tulle, November 8 ; the third, from Egleton, November 10; the fourth from Egleton, November 11, and from Bort, Novem ber 13 ; the fifth, from St. Angel, November 14; the sixth, from Angouleme, November 27 ; and the seventh, from Limoges, December 7. Un fortunately, three have been lost ; the originals were handed to Louis XVI. by Turgot himself at the time of the Bread Riots, and were never recovered ; the minutes have disappeared, and nothing remains of them but abstracts and fragments. The rest are complete. Some months previously the Comptroller- General, Abbe Terray, being at Compiegne with Turgot, had expressed his doubts touching the advantages of free trade in grain. " Three classes of persons," said he, " are interested in the regulation of the grain trade, — the landowners, the cultivators, and the consumers. I concede that the free system is extremely Letters on Free Trade in Grain. 93 favorable to the landowners. As to the culti vators, the profit they derive from it is merely temporary, since at the expiration of their leases the landowners take advantage of the in crease in the price of grain to raise their rents. The consumers, finally, suffer the greatest in jury from the free system, which raises the price beyond their means of subsistence, and increases all their expenses." So the Abbe Terray concluded that free trade was favorable only to a very small number of citizens, indif ferent to the cultivators, and very prejudicial to a large majority of the king's subjects. To this course of reasoning Turgot under takes to reply in his letters. In the first place, he deems it an error to hold that free trade can result in raising the average price of grain ; the contrary is true. He has no difficulty in proving that if landowners and cultivators can not dispose freely of their harvests, — if they are compelled to sell cheap when the crop is small, and are not allowed to make up for the scarcity of the product by an enhancement of price, — then they will naturally prefer some kind of crop exposing them to less persecution. The policy of intervention in trade can have no result but to diminish the harvests, and this inevitably raises the average price of grain. Under the system of police regulations the 94 Turgot. prices are more variable than under the free system. " Regulations and restrictions do not produce a single additional ear, while they pre vent the superfluous grain of one place from being carried to places where it is scarcer." Turgot next examines what he calls the three branches of Abbe Terray's opinion. To begin with, he agrees with Terray that the land owners are interested in free trade ; but not, as the latter thinks, because free trade raises the price, for, in fact, the contrary is true. One of the results of restriction is, that in good years the owner dares not store the excess of his harvest, for fear of being prosecuted as a fore- staller in the time of dearth. Thus it happens that in times of abundance wheat is wasted, fed to cattle ; and this amounts to a diminution of production, and consequently to a lessening of the income from the soil. In one of the three letters that were lost with the papers of Louis XVI., Turgot had made a comparative and detailed estimate of the expenses of pro duction and of the average price of the bushel of wheat in France, in good, average, and bad seasons; and had calculated that, under the system of restriction, the impossibility of off setting the years of scarcity by the years of abundance represented an annual loss of reve nue to the landowners alone, — not to speak Letters on Free Trade in Grain. 95 of laborers and consumers, — of fifty million francs. In his sixth letter, Turgot passes to what he calls the second branch of Abbe Terray's argu ment; namely, the cultivator's point of view. The Comptroller-General considered the culti vator's interest as not at stake, because, should the farmer of land obtain any profit, the owner of the land would be sure to take it from him whenever his lease expired. But Abbe Ter ray forgot that the cultivation of great estates by tenant-farmers occupied, then as now, but a portion of the territory of France. Four sevenths of the land was cultivated by me tayers, whose tillage was as wretched as their income. These cultivators had no leases; they received half the produce.1 Here the interest of the cultivator could not differ from that of the landowner, and free trade, which accord ing to Terray must be profitable to the one, could not but be profitable to the other. Tur got hoped so to improve the condition of the wretched metayers of his time as to enable them to escape by degrees from their penury, 1 For an instructive account of the relations existing be tween the metayers and the proprietors, see John Morley's " Turgot " (Critical Miscellanies, vol. ii.); an essay which will be found to furnish an admirable supplement to this volume. — Tr. 96 Turgot. gradually to accumulate a small estate in cattle, and to transform themselves into farmers pay ing a fixed rent to their proprietor. In his opinion, this transformation would have resulted in raising the agriculture of the most backward provinces to a footing of equality with the richest parts of Normandy, Picardy, and Ile-de-France. " Though the free system should produce no advantage save that of raising the agriculture of these prov inces to an equality with that of the provinces now cultivated by tenant-farmers, though the revenue and the productions of the latter should not be equally increased, you cannot fail to perceive the immense advantage accru ing to the state from this revolution alone, the immense increase of revenues and food-stuffs, and in general all that agriculture everywhere gains by freedom." Turgot's last letter was devoted to Terray's delusion that the consumer's interests would be hurt by the suppression of the old-time po lice restrictions. Turgot here reproduced and developed all the arguments he had already brought forward to prove that free trade, by increasing the total production, could not fail to diminish the general market price for the benefit of consumers. There is no need of recapitulating these arguments ; but a curious Letters on Free Trade in Grain. 97 thing is his discussion of the state monopoly of the sale of grain. It was in reality the royal wheat speculations — so it was then said — that Terray wished to favor by abrogating the edict of 1764; and by entering upon the discussion of monopoly, Turgot touched the tender spot. He could not imagine how a privileged company could exercise so disas trous a monopoly, — a monopoly of purchase against the laborer, a monopoly of sale against the consumer. Moreover, were the company composed of angels, it would be incapable of equalizing prices and of providing for the sub sistence of all, and men would still maintain that it was composed only of rogues. " If a series of losses is occasioned by a series of poor harvests, — or, still more inevitably, by the mal administration, the mistakes, the slackness, the knavery of all kinds, connected with the man agement of an unwieldy enterprise conducted by too large a number of men, — what will become of the food-supply which the com pany is bound to furnish? The directors will be hanged, but that will not give the people bread." Meantime, Abbe Terray paid no attention, contenting himself with praising the letters and with holding them up to the other in- tendants as models. By the edict of Dec. 23, 7 98 Turgot. 1770, he abrogated the main provisions of the edict of 1764. All who wished to engage in the grain-trade were required to inscribe in the police registers their names, rank, places of residence and storage, together with the papers relative to their enterprises, and were compelled under very heavy penalties to sell no grain ex cept in the market-place. " The lords, the parsons, the laborers, the artisans of twenty villages, were compelled," says Voltaire, " to go or to send to the place of the market; and if any one sold at his own granary a bushel of wheat to his neighbor, he was condemned to a fine of five hundred francs, his wagon and horses being turned over to those who came with a troop of sol diery to perpetrate this outrage. Every lord who gave wheat or oats to a vassal in his vil lage was subject to punishment as a crimi nal." To break up this abuse of power, it was necessary that Turgot should be made a minister. CHAPTER V. f. THE MINISTER. — II. FREE TRADE IN GRAIN. III. THE BREAD RIOTS. — IV. RECALL OF THE PARLIAMENTS. I. ON coming to the throne, Louis XVI. had appointed old Count de Maurepas his Prime Minister. This appointment broke up the triumvirate of Aiguillon, Maupeou, and Terray; but D'Aiguillon alone was dismissed, the others being provisionally retained. But although Abbe Terray still bore the title of Comptroller-General, it may be said that his successor was already found, and this successor was Turgot. This choice had been deter mined by Abbe de Very and the Duchess (D'Enville. Very was an old schoolfellow of Turgot, with whom he had never ceased to keep up the closest intimacy. At Bourges, where he had spent some years as Grand Vicar, Very had become acquainted with Count and Countess de Maurepas, then exiles from the Court of Louis XV., and had often told ioo Turgot. them of his friend. The Countess admired Turgot's character, and was won over to his way of thinking. When, therefore, her hus band became Prime Minister, she vigorousl urged him to take into his ministry a ma; whose genius and probity had inspired hejr with such deep esteem. The Duchess D'Enville belonged heart anc soul to the party of the philosophers and econo mists, whom she was wont to receive at her fint castle of La Roche-Guyon. Being passion ately in favor of free trade in grain, she wa? not spared in the satires, the ballads, and the caricatures with which the adherents of Courl and Parliament incessantly pelted the new reformers. She belonged to the La Roche foucauld family, to which Count de Maurepat was very proud of being related. She recom-i mended Turgot to him with great urgency, at the very time when Countess&de Maurepas and Very were likewise recommending him. Thus Turgot became a minister, — not, per haps, called by public opinion, for, properly speaking, public opinion did not yet exist, or was at most but newly born, but pointed out by admirers and friends to an omnipotent Prime Minister. Great was the joy in the camp of the economists and the Encyclopedists, though the disappointment was sharp when it was The Minister. 101 leWned that Turgot had been made Marine Minister, instead of Comptroller-General of the finances. T This choice meets general approbation," writAes Mercy to Maria Theresa; " not that Turwot is supposed to have much talent for marine affairs, but because he is known to be ^..wpright and honest to the core." Marie An toinette is not ill pleased, and tells her mother that " Turgot has the reputation of being a very honest man." The Marine Ministry was, however, a mere transition. A month later (August 24, 1774), he was appointed Comp troller-General. Upon thanking the king, Turgot was greatly moved. Mademoiselle de Lespinasse relates that he said, " I give myself not to the king, but to the honest man ; " and that the king, taking both his hands, replied, "You shall not be deceived." Abbe de Very gives a similar account of this scene. The whole court was collected at Compeigne, when Maurepas came to announce to Turgot his promotion to the post of Comptroller-General. Turgot called im mediately upon the king, and, on returning, gave Very the following account of the inter view he had just had with Louis XVI. " ' I must beg leave, Sire, to set down in writing my general views ; and, if I may venture to say so, 102 Turgot. my stipulations touching the way in which yoi must needs support me in the administratic of the finances ; for, I confess to you, I treij ble on account of the superficial knowledge have of the subject.' ' Yes, yes,' replied king, ' as you wish ; but I give you my of honor in advance (taking Turgot's hanc he spoke), to enter into all your views, arid t\A support you always in the courageous courses that you will have to take.' " The next day Turgot laid before the king his celebrated programme : " At this moment, Sire, I confine myself to recalling to your mind these three phrases, — no bankruptcy, no in crease of taxation, no loans. No bankruptcy, either avowed or masked by forced reductions ; no increase of taxation, the reason being found in the condition of your subjects, and still more in your Majesty's heart; no loans, because every loan inevitably diminishes the available revenue, necessitating after a time either bank ruptcy or increase of taxation." He proposed but one method of carrying out this programme; namely, to reduce ex penditures below the sum total of the receipts. He knows well, he says, that all those who con trol expenditures in the different departments will insist that these expenditures are all in dispensable, and he does not doubt that they The Minister. 103 will support their claims with excellent rea sons. He knows, however, that all their rea sons must yield to the absolute necessity of economy. He forcibly represents to the king that the people can be relieved only by reform of abuses, and that this is difficult because so many persons are interested in maintaining these abuses, " for there is no abuse that does not give some one a livelihood. ... I shall have to struggle against the natural kindness and generosity of Your Majesty and of the persons dearest to Your Majesty. . . . Your Majesty will recollect that it is to you personally, to the honest man, to the just and good man, rather than to the king, that I give myself." It is plain that Turgot feared the queen's influence. I have seen the original draft of this programme. After having written the words, " generosity of Your Majesty," Turgot had already traced the words " and of the qu — " when he checked himself, and wrote instead, the word " persons." On the morrow Turgot began his task. Ap pointed Comptroller-General, Aug. 24, 1774, he was to be dismissed May 12, 1776, at the end of twenty months and eighteen days. He enjoyed good health during but thirteen of these months, and was racked with gout during the remaining seven ; but disease took no hold 1 04 Turgot. upon his work. It may be affirmed that he never ceased for an instant frankly and straight forwardly to pursue his policy: namely, res toration of the finances, war upon abuses, de struction of privileges, emancipation of labor, trade, and manufactures, which were crushed by restrictions and monopolies. Tlms^Jifteen years before the Revolution of 1789, Turgot sought to carry ouPwithout violence all the reforms in the civil and economic order that had afterward to be conquered at such a cost of blood and tears. Those who defended abuses in order to live by them found Turgot implacable, whenever he judged such persons intelligent enough to be accountable for their deeds ; but to the igno rant he was indulgent, although he vigorously repressed the disorders. to which the ignorant might be led. Moreover, he dealt prudently with vested interests, never failing to offer equitable compensation for the offices he sup pressed. His arrival at the control of the finances had struck the farmers-general with consternation. " It is said that the financiers are panic-stricken," wrote Abbe Baudeau; " they need not be ; M. Turgot is not the man incontinently to cancel the revenue-leases and the other financial arrangements." At the time of his discussion with Miromenil, The Minister. 105 in I77^» about the suppression of the Corvdc, he made notes in reply to the observations of the Keeper of the Seals. In these notes is a passage that should be taken to heart by those who make of Turgot the chief of a sect of/ fanatics. " I know as well as any one that it is not always advisable to do the best thing possible, and that, though we should not tire of correcting little by little the defects of an ancient constitution, the work must go forward! slowly, in proportion as public opinion and the) course of events render changes practicable." | In order to convince public opinion, and to remove prejudices which he thought sprang from ignorance, he had conceived the plan of a Council similar to our Ministry of Public Instruction. On this subject he wrote to the king: — " I think I can propose nothing more advanta geous to your people, and better suited to maintain peace and good order, to give activity to all useful industry, to make your authority respected, and to attach more closely your subjects' hearts to Your Majesty, than to instruct them all touching their ob ligations to society and to your protecting power, touching the duties which these obligations impose, touching their interest in performing these duties both for the public good and for their private welfare. This moral and social instruction requires books made 106 Turgot. for the purpose by competing authors, and a silchool- master in every parish who shall instruct the cli-iildren in these subjects, and shall likewise teach the tt;tts of writing, of reckoning, and of surveying. . . . The civic education which the Council of Instruction would cause to be given throughout the kingdom, and the rational books which the Council would cause to be made, and would require all professors to teach, would contribute still further to form an enlightened and virtuous people." While preoccupied with the destruction of prejudice for the future, and with the forma tion, as he expressed it, of a new people, Tur got did not forget the present, and sought the readiest and surest means of healing the rooted sore of financial disorder, — a sore made deeper still by the corrupt administration of Abbe Terray. He lost no time in confiding to those of his collaborators in whom he had most confidence the task of bringing together the elements of what we to-day call the Budget of Receipts and Expenditures. Says Dupont de Nemours : " He ordered the construction of a methodical and circumstantial table contain ing the smallest details of all receipts and ex penditures." This table has been preserved. We likewise possess a similar statement drawn up by his predecessor a few days ear lier. Abbe Terray had hoped that he might The Minister. 107 retain his place in the ministry by adapting his policy to the new reign, and by changing his principles at a time when new principles appeared to be more in fashion. In his me morial and table Terray threw the responsi bility for the deficit upon D'Aiguillon and De Boynes, the Ministers of War and of Marine Affairs, and made a great show of his own efforts to reduce expenses. Weber relates that the Abbe said, in conversation with his friends, that " he had succeeded by dint of injustice, of bankruptcies, of spoliations, in re ducing the deficit to five millions. He had left fifty-seven millions in the Treasury, besides fourteen millions as an emergency fund ; while anticipations upon the revenue were reduced to three months. He had supplied money for ordinary expenses, for preparations for war, for three weddings, and for many extraordi nary expenses that must remain secret." Turgot's enemies contrasted the condition of the Treasury at the time of his fall with its condition at the fall of Terray, and pretended that Turgot had exhausted the reserve left by his predecessor. Linguet called Terray a Sully, because he had amassed a treasure of fifty-six millions. According to this view, Turgot could be compared only to Sully's suc cessors, who squandered the millions heaped 108 Turgot. up at the Bastille. Discussion of the question at this time of day would be futile; posterity has made its choice between the unscrupulous minister of Louis XV. and the honest minister of Louis XVI. II. One of Turgot's first official acts was to remove the Master of Requests, Brochet de Saint-Prest, Director of the Wheat Monop oly. " I am delighted," wrote Mademoiselle de Lespinasse, " that M. Turgot has already dismissed the ringleader in the wheat affair." It will be remembered that four years pre viously (in 1770) Abbe Terray had annulled the liberal provisions of the declaration of 1763, and of the edict of 1764, concerning the grain-trade, and that he had subjected this trade anew to the former harsh police regula tions. By this return to ancient usage he had flattered the prejudices of the people and of the parliaments, and had satisfied those publi cists who thought the nation's food should not be abandoned to what they termed the unre strained cupidity of tradesmen. He had found, moreover, a valuable defence of his policy in a book by a man of considerable intelligence, a particular friend of the men of letters and the Free Trade in Grain. 109 Encyclopedists, Abbe Galiani, whose illiberal economical ideas contrasted strangely with the opinions of the majority of his friends. Galiani had composed a series of dialogues on Free Trade in Grain, full of keen thrusts, of wit, and of examples drawn from general history, wherein he asserted that the policy of the state concerning grain must be merely an occasional policy, — that it must differ in different coun tries, and that in the same country there must be one rule for the interior and another for the seaboard. Though Abbe Terray did not despise Gali- ani's help, he cared very little for his argu ments. At bottom, it was neither the groans of the people, nor the wishes of the parlia ments, nor Galiani's theories, that decided Terray to abrogate the edict of 1764. He was no more influenced by the arguments of those who reasoned in his favor than he had been by the advice of Turgot in the seven admirable letters from Limousin. His aim was nothing less than the establishment of the monopoly of the wheat-trade in the hands of his friends, of his partners, and perhaps, as has often been asserted, of the partners of Louis XV. It was his purpose to realize, if not the grain-ring, to which the too strong name of Pactede Famine ("starvation-contract) has 1 10 Turgot. been given, at least a monopoly of speculation in the commodity of prime necessity, — the people's bread. Much has been written concerning this grain-ring. Popular rumor has considerably magnified its importance; but there is no doubt that its operations in wheat were accom panied by theft, by embezzlement, by shame ful speculation, — although no historian has succeeded in giving an accurate account of it, nor in furnishing a list of those who made a fortune or otherwise profited by it. A lawyer and man of affairs named Leprevost de Beau mont had got wind of a partnership-agreement between Malisset, a former Parisian baker who had invented a more perfect process of grind ing wheat, and a certain number of capital ists. The aim of this society was to make a contract with the state for handling the king's wheat. This was in 1765. The agreement in ques tion contemplated a permanent supply. The wheat, or the flour into which it was made, was to be constantly kept in a good state of preservation ; and to this end the wheat mo nopoly was authorized to sell the old stores and to replace them with new, according to the movement of prices. Thus speculation was excused, authorized, encouraged. Leprevost Free Trade in Grain. 1 1 1 de Beaumont saw in this agreement a contract to starve the people, — the Facte de Famine. He intended to inform against it; but before he could remit to the Parliament of Rouen a copy that he had prepared, he was seized and thrown into the Bastille, whence he was re leased only on the 14th of July, 1789, by the Revolution. " It is not," said he, " on the faith of suspicions, reports, conjectures, or false statements, that I inform against this horrible conspiracy ; it is on the faith of its contract." And when Laverdy, the comptroller-general who had signed this contract in 1765, appeared before the Revolutionary Tribunal on the 3d Brumaire, Year II. , Leprevost voluntarily came to add his accusation to that of Fouquier-Tin- ville. In the mean time all those who had formed this company, who had been parties to the alleged starvation-contract, and who were accused by Leprevost de Beaumont with having gained " tens of hundreds of millions," had successively died ruined or insolvent ; and Malisset himself, the general agent of the com pany, though still alive in 1791, was languish ing in extreme penury and partial insanity. The accusations of Leprevost de Beaumont were evidently exaggerated. It is possible that the wheat company shared its profits with in fluential personages, with the favorites of the 1 1 2 Turgot. king, — perhaps with the king himself; there is proof that such disposition was made of the shares of the Farmers-General. No less clear is it that certain agents of the company spec ulated on their own account, and that some clerks committed embezzlements and thefts, squandering the products in a lordly luxury inconsistent with their patrimonial fortunes; but no traces have ever been found of the tens of hundreds of millions, — that is, of the billions, — which, according to Leprevost de Beaumont, were wrung from the wretched peo ple by the accomplices of Malisset during the last years of Louis XV. In consequence of the accusations of Lepre vost de Beaumont, — whether it was feared that they might become public, or whether there were other reasons, public or private, — the Malisset lease had been cancelled by Abbe Terray himself. In its place a new combina tion, that of the profit-sharing Commission (re'gie intiresse'e), was devised. The aim of this Commission was to be the same as that of the preceding monopoly; namely, to su pervise the distribution of the wheat, to the end that well-provided provinces should send of their abundance to those that lacked. " A Commission had been formed," say the records touching Terray, " to take charge of the wheat Free Trade in Grain. 113 business. Under it were two directors, or gen eral agents for purchase and transportation [Sorin de Bonne and Doumerc] ; so that it should seem that all abuses in this quarter must have been instantly checked. But the Councillors of State complained that they were not consulted, that nothing was communicated to them ; and in fact Abbe Terray had been wont to bring them the business all cut and dried. What had rendered this conduct more suspicious was that his underling, Brochet de Saint-Prest, who had entered the Council a beggar, now made a prodigious show of opu lence and luxury; whence it was inferred that Messrs. Terray and Brochet, far from putting down the monopoly, were carrying it on through their henchmen, who were likewise enormously rich." A month after the dismissal of Brochet de Saint-Prest, on the 17th of September, 1774, two fishermen found under a great stone in the Seine, near Suresnes, a bundle of papers con cerning the Grain Commission. It came into the hands of the Intendant of Trade, Turgot's friend Albert the economist, who had taken the place of Brochet. Albert immediately placed seals upon the papers of Sorin and Doumerc, and clapped them both into the Bastille. Overwhelming evidence was discov- 1 14 Turgot. ered against Brochet and his wife, who had borrowed large sums from the treasury of the Commission, but the accounts of the agents appeared correct. Traces were indeed found of some embezzlements, to which Comptroller- General Terray had doubtless shut his eyes ; but nothing came to light to justify a criminal prosecution. Albert released the two agents, and declared that their accounts could be set tled before the ordinary tribunal. As to the irregular profits gained in private speculations, it was impossible to make any estimate of them. After so many scandals and scandalous ru mors, there was but one course to take, — to return to free trade in grain, and to djssolve all those companies and bureaus which "had they been composed of angels " could not escape popular wrath and suspicion. The Comptroller-General rightly resolved, therefore, to annul the law improvised in 1770 by Terray. He returned to the freedom — very restricted, indeed — of the declaration of 1763 and the edict of 1764. The decree making the grain-trade free was signed in the Council of Finance, Sept. 13, 1774, but it was not published until the 20th. As early as the 7th, Baudeau announces in his journal that "the declaration of 1763 con cerning domestic free trade is about to be Free Trade in Grain. 1 1 5 reaffirmed by a decree of the Council, which thus blots out all trace of Abbe Terray ; " but on the 1 8th he was still in the dark as to the decision, and said : " There are fine contradic tory rumors about the future decree of the Council concerning the grain-trade. Some say it will confirm the old principles, or will at most but change one company for another. The purveyors, Sorin and Doumerc, brag that they will continue their jobbery." The truth is, that in the week following Turgot's proposition there had been a debate in the Council. The Minister of Agriculture, Bertin, who as Comptroller-General had pro mulgated the liberal declaraticgi of 1763 and the edict of 1764, while sharing Turgot's opinions, feared to shock popular prejudice. He was convinced that in the grain question experi ence sanctioned but one method, — that of " advancing by slow and successive steps." In September, 1774, after the first communi cation of the plan to the Council of Finance, and before anything had been made public, Bertin wrote to Turgot: "The documents you sent me, while arousing my hopes both for the general welfare and for that of my depart ment, have renewed all my regrets touching the past. ... I exhort you to proceed slowly and cautiously. I should venture to pray you, 1 1 6 Turgot. if this were possible for you, as it is for me, and had you not long since shown your colors, to conceal your views from the child whom you have to govern and to cure. You cannot help playing the part of the dentist." Bertin was not the only one to counsel pru dence ; there were others who wished to divert Turgot from his aim. These persons, being less attached to him, were repulsed with a certain disdain. Necker, who had just been crowned by the French Academy for his Eulogy of Colbert, requested an audience for the purpose of setting forth his views upon the wheat ques tion. Morellet gives the following account of the interview : " M. Turgot replied to the author somewhat dryly, giving a personal turn to his observations, telling him he might print what he liked, that nothing was feared, that the public would judge, refusing moreover a copy of the manuscript, — all with that dis dainful air which he too often had in dealing with ideas opposed to his own. I do not get this at second-hand. I saw it and heard it. M. Necker came with his manuscript ; I heard the replies to his offers, and I saw him go away with the air of a man wounded but not cast down." Here is a glimpse of the minister of whom Madame de Boufflers said, " He is freezing." Free Trade in Grain. 1 1 7 Necker had his book printed and exposed for sale at the time of the disturbances ; he sent a copy to Turgot, who acknowledged its reception by this laconic and cutting note of April 23, 1775 : — " I have received, Sir, the copy of your work that you caused to be left at my door ; I thank you for this attention. If I had had to write upon this sub ject, and had felt bound to defend the opinion you have adopted, I should have awaited a more peace ful moment, when the question would have interested only those who can judge dispassionately. But upon this point, as upon others, each man has his own way of thinking. Sir, I have the honor to be," etc. Necker did not delay to reply. He humbly bases his justification upon the date of the authorization to print, — a date anterior to the disturbances, and even to the rise in the price of grain. " At that time," says he, " there was not the least dearth anywhere. If the dearth that has since arisen in some places had seemed to you, Sir, or to the Lord Keeper, a motive for suspending the publication of this work, I should have shown respectful defer ence to your wishes. ... It is distressing enough to me to differ with you upon some subjects of political economy; I would not have you suspect me of any other fault. Your 1 1 8 Turgot. opinion on this subject is of great moment to me." Necker's book had an immense success, and went into a great number of editions. Turgot's adversaries, the parliamentarians, the adminis trators of Colbert's school, extolled it to the sky. Partisans of the protective system made of it, and can still make of it, their manual; and this they fail not to do, drawing from it arguments whose value is increased by the honesty of the man who furnished them. There is another school attached to the doc trines of certain adversaries of Turgot, and pro fessing for Necker's book a no less passionate admiration, — the socialistic school of labor organization. Thus Louis Blanc writes in his " History of the French Revolution " : " Then Necker seized his pen, and, upon a subject that Galiani seemed to have exhausted, wrote a powerful book, a book pervaded with grave eloquence, with restrained feeling, a book of which certain pages might have been acknowl edged both by a statesman and by a poet. Seeking in the grain question only an oppor tunity for opposing, in the interests of the people, the system of individualism, Necker went back to the first principles of society, and subjected them to an examination as lofty as it was audacious." Free Trade in Grain. 1 1 9 M. de Molinari, in his edition of the Grain Laws, pronounces a very different judgment, — a judgment which some may deem severe, but which no Liberal can call unjust. He finds in this book " much method and a certain warmth of style, but a complete want of prin ciples and a puerile ignorance of facts. The author constantly goes by hypotheses, and more often than not his hypotheses are false. M. Necker's book has contributed more than any other to darken counsel on the important question of food." The decree of Tuesday the 13th of Sep tember, 1774, was again submitted to the Coun cil on the 20th, and finally published. Among the Minister's friends there was great rejoicing. What first struck every one, and secured the approbation of all men of elevated views, was the care taken by Turgot to explain in a long preamble the reasons for this change in legis lation. Such public discussion was a novelty ; thus Turgot is the inventor of the now general usage of free governments, — of accompany ing bills with a recital of motives. Mademoi selle de Lespinasse writes to M. de Guibert: " There will appear in a few days from now an edict on the grain-trade ; it will he justified, — this form is new." Condorcet says : " He set the useful example of giving the public a de- 1 20 Turgot. tailed and reasoned statement of the principles upon which bills were drawn up." La Harpe writes : " He is the first among us to convert acts of sovereign authority into works of reason and persuasion." Nor does Voltaire withhold his praise : " Till now, we have not seen edicts in which the sovereign condescends to instruct jhis people, to reason with them, to point out their true interests, to persuade before com manding ; the substance of almost all com mands from the throne has hitherto been summed up in the words, ' for such is our good pleasure.' " The preamble of the decree of the 13th of September is, in fact, a genuine discussion of principles, wherein Turgot triumphantly de monstrates that free trade in grain secures, more fully and conveniently than police regu lations, the food-supply of nations. It is in some sort a new exposition of the doctrines so well upheld by him some years before in the seven letters on grain addressed to Terray. ' * " The freer, more active, more extended is trade," says this admirable statement, "the more promptly, efficiently, and abundantly are the people supplied: Prices become more uni form, and vary less from that average scale of prices in accordance with which wages are nec essarily regulated. Food cannot be supplied Free Trade in Grain. 121 with equal success by the agency of the gov ernment* Its attention, divided among too many objects, must be less alert than that of merchants occupied with their own trade. ••Government ascertains needs and resources more tardily and less exactly.' Its agents, hav ing no interest in economy, buy at a higher rate, transport at greater expense, preserve with less precaution." Much grain is lost and damaged. »For want of skill or through unfaithfulness these agents may enormously increase the expense of their operations.1 Without the knowledge of government, they may permit themselves illicit manipulations. Even when most innocent they cannot avoid being suspected ; and the* suspicion is always reflected upon the administration employing them, which becomes odious to the people by reason of the very efforts it makes to relieve public distress."- " No minister," says the Metra correspond ence, " has made our masters speak a nobler and gentler language." Baudeau writes in his journal : " It is received with great applause by the public. The enemies of the good Turgot are somewhat abashed by the form of this decree, and by the wisdom of the princi ples which it most clearly explains." Vol taire writes to D'Alembert: " I have just read 122 Turgot. M. Turgot's masterpiece. It seems to me that I behold new heavens and a new earth." Unfortunately, the situation grew more and more difficult. The crops, scanty in 1774, promised to yield nothing in 1775. Bachau- mont wrote in his " Secret Memoirs " : " The Comptroller-General persists in his system of free trade in grain, and is not moved by the universal scarcity. He insists that it will be no severer than in the time of the monopoly, that the distress will be transient, and that the forestallers, punished for their greed, will lose forever the desire to hold their grain." On the 18th of April, 1775, a band of peas ants invaded Dijon, sacking houses, plundering mills, and making search for suspected stores of grain. The governor was threatened with death, and was accused of having said, " My men, the grass is beginning to sprout; go browse upon it." The bishop came into the street and harangued the peasants, finally pre vailing upon them to leave the town. It has been often asked, then and since, what was the cause of an uprising so sudden and so soon suppressed? Is it to be regarded as simply a spontaneous movement on the part of a suffer ing people ? It is certain that those who took part in the Dijon insurrection had not read Turgot's statement, and that they would not Free Trade in Grain. 123 have understood his earnest and lofty discus sion of the principles of free trade ; they were, therefore, certainly not provoked by the pe rusal of the edict and its preamble. It is related that Turgot had smilingly said, as he gave a copy of this preamble to a friend : " It will be pronounced diffuse and flat; my mo tive was this, — I wished to make it so clear that every village magistrate could explain it to the peasants ; this is a matter in which the popular opinion avails much." The popular opinion was potent indeed for evil, but the village magistrates had not yet had time to mould it for good. The task is not so easy to dissipate the choke-damp of prejudice, which sometimes clings to the low levels of society for several centuries after all enlightened men have emerged from it. Always to explain popular movements by the theory of a conspiracy is as cheap a pro ceeding as to attribute the recurring phe nomena of Nature to the special intervention of a supernatural power. Such judgments are for the most part a mark of short-sightedness, and we should not be too ready to accept them. Nevertheless, there occurred circumstances at Dijon, as afterward at Pontoise, Versailles, and Paris, which are difficult to explain except by supposing that there was a junto of more or 1 24 Turgot. less masked ringleaders egging on and guid ing the multitude. " The first topic of my ser mon," writes Voltaire to Condorcet, " is the baneful popular superstition against free trade in grain and against free trade in general. You see what outrages have just been perpetrated at Dijon. God grant that the fetiches have not underhandedly instigated this little Saint-Bar tholomew! " And a month later to Madame de Saint-Julien : " Had you been at Dijon, you would have prevented the criminal upris ing underhandedly instigated by M. Turgot's enemies." Turgot replied to the Dijon insurrection, not by making a concession to the party of re striction, but, most characteristically, by giving new pledges of freedom of trade at Dijon, at Beaune, at Saint-Jean-de-Losne, and at Mont- bard. He endeavored to meet the dearth by diminishing the taxes. In a decree of the Council issued four days after the insurrection (April 22, 1775), and at the moment when he was informed of it at Paris, he said : " The king, desirous of preventing the grain neces sary for the subsistence of his people from ris ing above the price which it must justly and naturally have according to the variation of seasons and the condition of the harvests, has by his decree of Sept. 13, 1774, and by his Free Trade in Grain. 125 letters-patent of November 2, established free dom of trade, which by its sole activity will bring grain to the districts that may be in need, and will prevent by means of competition any excessive enhancement of price. . . There- \ fore the collection of all duties upon grain and flour, whether at the city-gate or on the market-place, whether as town-dues, or corn- dues, or alnage, or market-dues, or any other j dues whatsoever, is suspended in the towns of; Dijon, Saint-Jean-de-Losne, and Montbard." Meantime the high prices continued, and all whose interests had suffered by the destruction of the monopoly incessantly accused the Comp troller-General of looking with indifference upon the popular distress. But far from being indifferent, Turgot endeavored, as formerly at Limoges, to relieve the utterly destitute by theTesfablishment of charitable workshops. In anticipation of a possible renewed rise in the price of provisions, he distributed through the priests of Paris a tract upon the means of pro viding for the Parisian people by an increase of work; and he sent instructions to all the provincial intendants for the establishment and management of charitable workshops in the country. These two documents are dated the 1st and 2d of May, 1775. On the very day of their promulgation the Bread Riots broke out. Turgot. III. MOBS had been formed in the country, ap pearing first at Pontoise near the domains of the Prince of Conti, plundering, burning houses, demanding bread, and destroying grain ; incit ing the people to seize boat-loads of wheat and to divide the contents, as at Mery-on-Oise ;. and invading towns in order to disorganize the mar kets. Turgot's brother, the Chevalier, after ward told Soulavie that " the pillagers appeared to be supplied with gold and silver, and that their movements were directed according to the best principles of the art of war, doubtless by an experienced general." On the 2d of May, 1775, the mob ap peared at Versailles before the palace, filling the courts and vociferating for bread. Turgot was at Paris, whither he had gone to confer with the Lieutenant of Police and with Mar shal Biron. The king appeared upon the bal cony and attempted to speak, but was not heard. The report was spread that he had yielded to the urgency of those about him, and had promised to reduce the bread-rate to two sous; to this assertion the king's corre spondence with Turgot, preserved by Marquis Turgot in the archives of Lantheuil Castle, The Bread Riots. 127 gives a crushing denial. During the day the king wrote two autograph letters to Turgot, at eleven in the morning and at two in the after noon, respectively.1 In the evening Turgot returned to Versailles, countermanded M. de Beauveau's order reducing the bread-rate, and forbade any one to require the dealers or the bakers to sell grain or bread below the market price. The next day (May 3) the mob entered Paris and began to plunder; "there were some streets where one would have thought one's self in a city taken by storm." The po lice were lax, and did not interfere ; it is even asserted that they forced several bakers to open their shops so that the rioters could carry off bread without paying for it. Turgot, who was continually on the road from Ver sailles to Paris, and return, called a meeting of the Council in the night of the 3d and 4th of May. He spoke with the greatest energy 1 These two letters are given in full by M. Say, but are omitted in this translation. They relate merely to matters of detail, and derive their special interest from their correc tion of the histories touching the king's conduct on this oc casion. It should be added, for the sake of the connection, that during this afternoon the bread-rate had been reduced at Versailles by M. de Beauveau, without the sanction of the king, who seems to have behaved with spirit and firm ness. — Tr. 1 28 Turgot. against Lenoir, the Lieutenant of Police, who had done nothing for the suppression of dis order. Obtaining his dismissal, he appointed his friend Albert to the place. The com mander of the night-watch of horse and foot was likewise dismissed, and Marshal Biron or ganized the resistance on a war footing. Two armies were immediately formed, — one for the interior of Paris, commanded by Biron ; the other for the exterior, commanded by one of his lieutenants. On the 4th, the rioters at tempted to continue their pillage, but were overawed by the attitude of the troops. The plunderers retired, and the Parisians went out of doors to look for the riot, — so they said, — and did not find it. During the day Parliament assembled and caused a decree to be posted, forbidding tu multuous assemblages, adding that the king would be urged to reduce the bread-rate. Turgot immediately stopped the distribution of this decree, and had the parliamentary post ers covered with placards, forbidding, in the king's name, tumultuous assemblages, on pain of death. At the same time he issued an edict assigning the prosecution of the sedi tious to the Criminal Chamber of La Tour nelle. The Parliament met a second time to reply. It asserted that the edict assigning the The Bread Riots. 129 jurisdiction to La Tournelle was an infringe ment of its immemorial prerogative of " gen eral police supervision." It issued a second decree claiming the jurisdiction, and again urging the king to reduce the bread-rate. Turgot immediately summoned the Parliament to Versailles, to receive the king's orders in a bed of justice. The sitting was held on the morning of the 5th. Turgot not being present, the king in formed him, in a note dated at six in the even ing, that everything had passed off quietly, and that the counsellors " had much abated their impertinence." He continues : " My memory almost failed me during my first speech, but I went on as well as I could with out becoming confused." The decree of the day before was quashed, and the jurisdiction assigned to the Provosts of the Marshalsea. The provostal court immediately sentenced two poor men to be hanged ; these men mounted the scaffold crying that they died for the people. There were some engage ments in the country, and it is said that twenty-three peasants were killed on the road to Versailles. Meanwhile, in order to reassure the grain- dealers, Turgot had them indemnified for the merchandise of which they had been robbed. 9 1 30 Turgot. The communes were compelled to pay for the damage done by the rioters. A friend of the Marquis de Mirabeau, named De Butre, wrote to Turgot asking to be relieved of the tax levied upon his estate in consequence of the riots. Turgot answered : " Touching the tax imposed upon you in order to make good the injury to the grain-trade, I agree that it is dis agreeable to you, as well as to many others who certainly took no part in the riots; but you must feel that although the general ap portionment of such indemnifications is an evil to the innocent individuals upon whom it falls, yet it is indispensable for the purpose of estab lishing in the minds of merchants confidence against popular uprisings, and for interesting the whole country in the prevention of such movements." It was a great victory for Turgot. The king had firmly supported him. " You are right," wrote the king to him on the 6th of May, " but all this will cost a great deal of money, and will necessitate great retrenchment; but, a little more or a little less, to this we must needs come. As good issues sometimes from evil, it will be seen from this that I am not so weak as was imagined, and that I shall have power to carry out my resolves. This will make our future proceedings easier ; the truth is that I The Bread Riots. 131 am more embarrassed with one man than with fifty." Thus Turgot was at this juncture in posses sion of the entire confidence of the king; he had triumphed, not merely over the riot, but over the opposition of the Parliament, over the captious spirit of the Parisians, over the indiffer ence affected by his colleagues. The Parisians had said that they had looked for the riot and had not found it; they made songs about it; the women wore caps a la rivolte ; and the movement was derisively dubbed " The Flour War." Every one believed in the existence of a conspiracy. Turgot explicitly asserts it in his instructions to the king, and in his decrees. " Brigandage has been instigated," says he, " by strangers to the parishes which they came to desolate. . . . The aim of this conspiracy seems to have been to cause a real famine in the provinces around Paris and in Paris itself, so as to lash the starving and despairing peo ple to the last degree of excess." 1 Writing to the King of Sweden on the 15th of July, fol lowing, Louis XVI. said : " The bad harvests and the evil spirit of some conspirators have incited rascals to plunder some markets." Maria Theresa, replying to Marie Antoinette, 1 " Instructions sent by the Order of His Majesty to all the Parish Priests of the Kingdom," May 9, 1775. 132 Turgot. says, " I think with you that there is some thing underneath it. " A great many person ages were accused of taking part in this con spiracy. Some said it was Sartine; Turgot thought the Prince de Conti to have been at the bottom of it. " I should not venture to assert that he was wrong," writes Marmontel in his " Memoirs." At all events, the hopes of the instigators were thoroughly disappointed; never had Turgot more ascendency over the king than during the days following the suppression of the riots. The support given him by Male sherbes in his Remonstrance of May 21, and the entrance of that great and good man to the ministry (July 6, 1775), sealed the triumph of Turgot. Even the queen, who was the sur est support of the Choiseul party, appeared disarmed, for a time, alas ! too brief. IV. BUT we must turn back. In order not to interrupt the narrative of the grain troubles, from the restoration of free trade (September, 1774) to the Bread Riots (May, 1775), we have passed over the greatest event of the begin- Recall of the Parliaments. 133 ning of the reign, — the recall of the Parlia ment.1 Maupeou's Coup d'Etat, as it was then called, had produced in 1771 a profound sensation, which still existed with unabated intensity at the accession of Louis XVI. The suppression of the parliaments and the cruel violence exercised against their members had aroused an opposition in public sentiment, in support of the formidable opposition of inter ests aroused in the magistracy by Maupeou's radical change. The new reign had been strongly urged to return to the ancient organization of justice. Maupeou had not, indeed, been able to avoid a rock that generally proves fatal to revolutions in which are involved the interests of a large body of office-holders. The appointments, made in haste, left much to be desired ; the new judges were men of less weight than the old. It was not without reason that these " sham judges '' failed to command popular re- 1 It may not be amiss to remind the reader that the French parliaments (of which there were thirteen, that of Paris being the most important) were courts of justice rather than legis latures. Unlike the English Parliament, they were in no sense representative bodies, their members forming a judicial aristocracy, practically hereditary (noblesse de robe). With infinitely more integrity and public spirit than the nobility proper, they were, as might be expected, conservative in sen timent and stubbornly reactionary in tendency. — Tr. 1 34 Turgot. spect. A kind of public opinion, even beyond the circles of those interested, seemed to de mand the dismissal of the new judges and the recall of the old. Let us not, however, suffer ourselves to be misled. The destruction of the ancient parliaments, and the organization of a magistracy with the sole function of ad ministering justice without meddling with gov ernment or politics, was the essential condition of the civil, economical, and political reforms that might have anticipated the violence of the closing century, and might have permitted the French Revolution to accomplish its work by a gradual substitution of the principles of modern government for those of the Old Regime. M. de Larcy considers the recall of the parliaments as the first step in the direction of a policy that could end only in danger.1 Turgot agreed with all his colleagues save Maurepas in opposing the recall. " We are assured," says the Metra correspondence, " that the king was obliged to take everything upon himself, and even to make use of his authority to bring it about, the members of his Council being of a contrary opinion." But Maurepas, more dexterous than Turgot, finally isolated him. Condorcet wrote to Turgot to urge him 1 " Le Correspondant," August, 1868. Article on Louis XVI. and Turgot. Recall of the Parliaments. 135 to maintain his opposition, and there is no doubt that Turgot inwardly assented to most of Condorcet's arguments. In October or No vember, 1774, Condorcet writes: — " It is said that the old Parliament is about to be recalled unconditionally, — that is, with all its in solence, claims, and prejudices. The following will be the results of this arrangement : First, all reform in the laws will become impossible, for our laws are ad mirable for the judges and detestable for those judged. The more cruel, secret, oppressive, is criminal juris prudence, the more powerful are the parliaments. Secondly, as these gentlemen are either ignorant of public opinion or despise it, they will be solicitous only of retaining favor with the masses ; they will defend all the tyranny of the prohibitive system, will oppose all freedom, and will arouse sedition against any minister who may wish to establish freedom. Thirdly, as these gentlemen still cherish the opinions entertained by the fools of the fourteenth century, as they are absurdly ignorant of everything outside the covers of the Olim Register, as they despise all light, all philosophy, and as they are puffed up with the pride of ignorance, they will continue to be hostile to all enlightenment, will persecute it, and will endeavor to plunge us back into the barbarism which they style in their remonstrances ' the simplicity of antique manners.' . . . Adieu, Sir; I cannot bear to think that while you are minister, the right is to become impossible." 136 Turgot. Doubtless Turgot took care not to communi cate Condorcet's letter to the Council, and his opposition to the restoration of the parliaments was probably based simply upon the interests of the royal authority. He had not been a pupil of the Physiocrats without being influ enced even by such of their doctrines as may have appeared to him extreme. Moreover, he very sincerely believed that the king had power to alter ancient institutions whenever the public welfare required it, and he did not admit that the intervention of the Parliament was neces sary in order to give the royal decisions the binding force of law. The phrase so often re peated by the Jacobin school — that is, by the men who have always been most opposed to his economical doctrines — is said to have originated with Turgot: "Give me five years of despotism, and France shall be free." It must be acknowledged that Turgot was not entirely free to oppose, in the Council and before the king, Maurepas's proposition for the recall of the parliaments. He had con curred in the dismissal of Maupeou, and of Terray, whom he had succeeded after endur ing him as a colleague for more than three months, with what impatience we know. The exile of Terray and Maupeou had been deter mined upon at a meeting of the Council, in Recall of the Parliaments. 137 which Turgot sat as Minister of Naval Affairs, on the 24th of August, 1774, the anniversary of Saint-Bartholomew. He therefore shared with his colleagues the responsibility for what has been called a ministerial Saint-Bartholomew; and he certainly would not have contradicted the Count d'Aranda, who, hearing the jest, had added : " Yes, but not a massacre of the inno cents." The necessary consequence of Mau peou's exile was the return of the parliaments. When Maurepas proposed it, Turgot was forced to submit, for it was a natural result of a policy with which he had been identified. On the 1 2th of November, 1774, Louis XVI. held a bed of justice, at which he restored the members of the Parliament of Paris to the functions of which they had been deprived on the 21st of January, 1 77 1 ; while in a series of edicts registered at the same bed of justice he took — or thought he took — precautions against the administra tive and political encroachments of the judiciary bodies. Some days later the Parliament as sembled to protest against the curtailment of its authority; and soon, in spite of the royal edicts, things resumed their former course. The Parliament held that it was bound, even more than formerly, to defend what it called the ancient constitution of the kingdom against the proposed reforms. 1 38 Turgot. The day when the Parliament recovered its authority was a fatal day for France. It was easy to foresee that the Parliament would be come the fatal instrument of Turgot's fall, and that its stubborn adherence to the Old Regime would render a peaceful revolution more and more difficult. CHAPTER VI. I. PREPARATION OF THE GREAT EDICTS. — II. ABOLITION OF THE CORVEE. — III. SUPPRES SION OF TRADE-GUILDS ; FREEDOM OF LABOR. — IV. THE BED OF JUSTICE. I. INTERRUPTED by the Bread Riots, but ever resolved to pursue prejudices, privileges, and abuses, encouraged moreover by his recent victory, by the king's confidence, and by the entrance into the Ministry of his friend the wise Malesherbes, Turgot resumed the already very advanced study of his vast plans with all the activity of which he was capable. This he did without either ostentation or mystery, so that those whose interests were to suffer had full opportunity to prepare for defence. In the front rank of his adversaries was the Parliament, and behind it the clergy; then the Court, the Choiseul party, the Parisian middle class threatened in its six merchant-guilds; and finally, in the Ministry itself, Hue de Miromenil, Keeper of the Seals, and the Prime Minister, Maurepas. 140 Turgot. By the clergy Turgot was regarded, not without reason, as a philosopher. They re membered that phrase from the " Conciliator," in reference to the Revocation of the Edict of Nantes : " Religion was disgraced for the sake of flattering Louis XIV. ; " and that other vigorously worded opinion that the king should not be the head of the Church, any more than the head of the Church should be king. " The English royal supremacy, the temporal power of the popes, — these are the two abusive ex tremes." Nor had the clergy forgiven the ef forts he had made to obtain a modification of the king's coronation oath. Turgot had urged Louis XVI. to suppress the passage in which he swore " to entirely exterminate from his states all the heretics expressly condemned by the Church." Louis was moved by Turgot's representa tions, and would probably have consented, had he not been overreached by Maurepas, who had no stomach for a quarrel with the bishops. After feebly holding off, the king yielded, and pronounced the ancient formula, — confining himself, however, to some j inarticulate mum blings. There remains in jthe Lantheuil ar chives an interesting proof; of the impression that Turgot had made upon the king's mind by his spoken and written observations, and Preparation of the Great Edicts. 141 by going to Rheims to expostulate with the king at the last moment touching this grave declaration of intolerance. This is an auto graph note from the king to Turgot, dated at Rheims, June 10, 1775 : l — I have not had you summoned, Sir, to give you an answer to your yesterday's letter, because I pre ferred to send you a written token of my appreciation of your course on this occasion. I think that the step you have taken is a proof of your honor and of your attachment to me. I am deeply indebted to you, and shall always be grateful if you will address me with equal frankness. Nevertheless, I cannot at this moment follow your advice ; I have considered the matter since, and have conferred with several per sons, and I think it will be less embarrassing to make no change. But I am none the less obliged for your advice, and you may be sure that it will remain se cret, as I beg you to keep this letter. Louis. Turgot made no secret of his course, nor did he consider himself beaten. After the king had mumbled the famous formula at the coro nation, Turgot addressed to him a long letter containing the most admirable advice and in struction touching toleration. " Can religion then command, can it permit, crimes? To decree a crime is to commit one ; he who 1 The day before the coronation. — Tr. 142 Turgot. commands another to murder is looked upon as a murderer. Now, the prince who orders his subject either to profess or to renounce a religion in which the subject does not believe, commands a crime. The subject who obeys, acts a lie, betrays his conscience, does what he believes that God forbids." Turgot does not, however, believe in the binding nature of for mulas " drawn up in unenlightened ages. All is not lost; Your Majesty cannot be bound to do a thing that would be unjust." The zealots, headed by the Count of Pro vence, expressed themselves with the extrem- est violence touching the Comptroller-General. The future Louis XVIII. condescended even to write with his own hand a diatribe against the minister ; but his pamphlet, entitled " The Dream of M. Maurepas," produced little effect. It converted no one, being read only by those whose opinions were already formed. The zealots sought to disturb the king's conscience by telling him that Turgot did not attend mass. "Does M. Turgot not go to mass?" inquired the king of Maurepas. " I do not know, Sire," replied that vivacious functionary; " M. Terray went every day." The queen submitted unwillingly to the con trol of her expenditures. Bailly relates that Turgot had obtained a promise from the king Preparation of the Great Edicts. 143 that no order for cash should be issued within a certain time. Not many days later a check for 500,000 francs was presented at the Treas ury in the name of "a certain personage of the Court," presumably the queen. Turgot went straight to the king for instructions. " I was taken by surprise," apologized the king. "Sire, what am I to do?" "Do not pay it." The minister obeyed. Marie Antoinette passionately defended her favorites. It was in connection with an affair involving one of Choiseul's friends, Count de Guines, Ambassador to England, that she gave Maurepas to understand that he had better not fall out with her. This ambassador's secretary claimed from his chief considerable sums that the plaintiff had been compelled to pay, or still owed, for margins in stocks. The plain tiff alleged that he had acted as the ostensible agent of his ambassador, who — so the plaintiff said — was wont to gamble at the Exchange on the strength of the diplomatic secrets of which he was cognizant. Count de Guines solicited permission to produce in his defence before the court some of his despatches to the king. This permission the Council refused. Greatly incensed by this decision, the queen obtained from the king the permission which the Council had unanimously denied. It is 144 Turgot. said that Maurepas was amazed at the ascen dency exercised by the queen, on this occa sion, over the king's mind ; and that Maurepas forthwith resolved to leave Turgot to himself, to take no further interest in his reforms, and, in case of need, to throw the Comptroller- General overboard in order to save the Prime Minister. Although warned of the plots that were rife about him, Turgot's activity in the furtherance of his plan did not slacken. On the 5th of January, 1776, Turgot laid before the Council the six edicts that are his glory. These he prevailed upon the king to accept after a most thorough-going discussion ; these he compelled the Parliament to register in a bed of justice, despite the most strenuous opposition; and these finally brought about his downfall. His triumph was his ruin. II. The Six Edicts were of unequal impor tance. The first required the suppression of the corvde, or forced labor; the second, the sup pression of the grain-police at Paris ; the third, the suppression of the offices on the quays, at the markets, and on the wharves of Paris ; the ^ 4 bolition of the - o^'6 • 1 4 7 urth, the su n nrivileg^Jf the exclusive ^ ustrial corpora^ equ? trade-guilds {jurandes s maitrises~).\ the fifth, the suppression of the easury of Poissy ; the sixth, the modification f the duty on tallow. We shall dwell only upon the edicts relating the corvie x and to the jurandes. Several ars before, while Intendant at Limoges, urgot had made his first attempt to relieve e peasantry from the burden of forced labor. e recognized its extreme oppressiveness, and w that the work thus done for the Board of blic Works was very unproductive.. He h|d therefore endeavored to substitute a tax in money. Being powerless to modify the law, he had given to this exemption-tax the same distribution that obtained in the case of the corve'e, making it a money-payment sup plementary to the taille (ordinary tax). This purchase in money of exemption from forced labor was not without analogy with the present method. It is needless to state that the money- 1 "Until the Regency," says John Morley, "this famous word had described only the services owed by dependents to their lords." From that time to the Revolution, it meant to the peasants twelve or fifteen days of forced labor each year for the construction and repair of roads, which, after all, were of little advantage to the peasants, but of great advan tage " to the town merchants and the country gentlemen, who contributed not an hour nor a sou to the work." — Tr. 10 / 144 urgot. . , ,/ment is to-day c , .A all the ta^ said , , nmazed at , i payers take advantage i. d the proportiol between the payments in money and paymen| in labor varies from department to depail ment Statistics have brought out, howev^ a remarkable fact, — the departments where til largest proportion of this exemption-money- paid, are those of the old Generality of LimJ ges. This is a tradition dating from Turgot.l In the general preamble to his six edicj Turgot recalled this conversion of the a>r?B into a tax payable in money, — a conversii^ effected in some other generalities in imitatid of his example. Had he aimed simpljrat sul pressing the corve'e, or if, converting it ir a money-tax, he had imposed it only upd those subject to the taille} he might, as believed, have proceeded by decree withe insisting upon the registration of a law. 1) aim is, however, far wider: in the very fir' line of his preamble he declares that what he seeks to realize is nothing less than a revolu tion in the assessment of taxes. His purpose is, in fact, to abolish privileges, and to subject the nobility and the clergy to taxation upon an equal footing with other citizens. It was because it embodied so formal and so direct 1 From which the clergy and the nobility were exempt.— Tr. Abolition of the Corvee. 147 an attack upon privilege, and because it was a first step toward equality of taxation, that the Jedict concerning the corve'e was singled out for [the most strenuous opposition. * " The weight of this burden falls," says the preamble, " and must fall, only upon the poor est class of our subjects, upon those who have no property save their hands and their indus try, — upon the husbandmen and the farmers. The landowners, almost all of them privileged, are exempt, or contribute but little ; yet it is to the landowners that the roads are useful by the increased value of the products of their estates due to improved facilities for communi cation and transport. ... It is therefore the landowning class that reaps the fruit of the labor expended upon roads ; and since it en joys the interest, it alone should make the in vestment. How can it be just to make those pay who have nothing of their own, to force them to give their time and their labor without wages, to deprive them of their only resource against penury and hunger, for the benefit of citizens wealthier than they? . . . According to the account that we have caused to be made of the roads to be built and kept up in our different provinces, we think we can assure our subjects that the expenditure for this purpose will in no year exceed ten million francs for 148 Turgot. the entire territory of the elections.1 This tax having as its object an expenditure ad vantageous to all landowners, we desire thatf all landowners, privileged and non-privileged, contribute to it, as is usual in the case of all ' local expenses." The preamble and the purview of the edict abolishing forced labor had been the subject of very long study before they were sub mitted to the king, and were afterward thor oughly sifted and discussed by the Keeper of the Seals, Hue de Miromenil. Cherest, in his history of "The Fall of the Old Regime," says that the king asked also the advice of another member of the Council, whom he believes to have been Malesherbes. The me morial attributed by Cherest to Malesherbes is preserved in the National Archives. In drawing up his observations, Miromenil followed the preamble and the provisions of the edict, paragraph by paragraph and article by article. He begins by declaring his impar tiality; he does justice to the intentions of the author of the plan, and announces the intention of setting up no formal contradiction, but of 1 Pays d'ilection : provinces subdivided into fiscal dis tricts (Elections), in which. the taxes were assessed by officers appointed for that purpose. The other provinces (pays d'itat) had provincial Estates (assemblies) for granting or assessing the taxes. — Tr. Abolition of the Corvee. 149 discussMng an important matter upon its merits. He thoiaJn recalls the labors of Orry and of Tru- daine.ti who thought the corvie could be re- formejJd but not abolished, and endeavors to prover <# that all classes profit by the good con- ditioi) Ii of the roads. " The landowners are not the Qarfnly ones," says he, " to derive advantage fromjt J ^veil-kept highways ; travellers, wagoners, evenj tf' peasants who go on foot, derive equal advfisjntage." T S°t as serted, not without reason, that his pre £ osition had always been held by the statesmen tfn who had attempted to regulate the financespeCrei> from the time of Desmarets, of Orry, and cp0f \ Ma- chault, to his own. ( " All the finance-numb, ^ters," said he, " have thought and done the !^edi|lrnei all have sought to consolidate the tweneikjejphs^ and to restrict the exemption from the ^l^uRr* The author of the memorial shares this ttho^jP'n_ ion ; he begins thus : " Not every noble, inieW jjjeed, is rich, but every rich man is noble. . . . «l \0he tax which in all reason and justice shouldle,'| be proportioned to wealth, is, on the contrary o'. a tax from which men are exempted on the scdfo ire of wealth." And he closes as follows : fe... From all this I conclude that the objectiokiMi of the Parliament in favor of the privileges c\ uf , the nobility is unfounded, and that it would bale ''; most dangerous for the king to allow this sysi,- I tern to gain favor, because it tends to counter-l ; ; act all the great things that have been done fori I a century, and all the good that can be donel 'j in the matter of taxation, j Finally, while as'i, unfriendly to despotism as ever, I shall say con- ' stantly to the king, to the Parliament, and, if necessary, to the whole nation, that this is one of those matters that must be decided by the absolute will of the king, — and for this reason : (c Abolition of the Corvee. 153 at bottom, this i.i a lawsuit between the rich and the poor. Now, of what is the Parliament made up? Of men wealthy in comparison with the masses, and all noble, since their of fices convey nobility. The Court, whose clamor is so powerful, — of what is it composed? Of great lords, the majority of whom own estates that will be subject to the tax, and that have not been subject to the corve'e. Of what is the Parisian public composed ? Of many nobles, or rich men enjoying the privileges of nobility, — these are they whose talk, is loudest, — and of a people subject to other taxes, but not to the taille or to the corve'e. Consequently, nei ther the remonstrances of the Parliament, nor the applause of the Parisian public, nor even the clamor of the Court, should in any wise prejudice this case. . . . Let the States Gen eral or the States Provincial of France be as sembled, — this is the wish of my heart, and of all good Frenchmen. Let these estates be so constituted that the people may make itself heard, — and not have, as its sole representa tives, bailiffs, seneschals, officials, whose inter ests are not those of the true people, and who are always dependent upon a great lord or a minister; then, indeed, will it seem just to re fer to such an assembly the question of the distribution of the taxes. But so long as the 1 54 Turgot. people shall have no voice in the parliaments, the king, after hearing them, must judge for himself, and he must judge in favor of the peo ple, because this estate is the most unhappy." Turgot yielded to Miromenil only upon the question of the clergy, but preserving his opinion: 'J The privilege of the clergy is open the same discussion as that of the nobility ; I think it no better founded. As, however, after deducting tithes and surplice-fees, eccle siastical property forms no very considerable object, I will consent to adjourn the discussion of the principle, and to sacrifice the provision relating to the clergy, notwithstanding the jus tice of it." And, alluding to the opposition of Maurepas, he adds : " And perhaps the opinions of the king and of the Ministry are undecided enough to make it worth while to avoid having two quarrels at once." Miromenil had asserted tfc*at there were in France three great orders, 4->ihe Clergy, the Nobility, and the Third Estate;) and that each of these orders had its rights, its privileges, perhaps its prejudices, which it was necessary to preserve intact. Turgot replied : " The honorable Keeper of the Seals talks of the privileges of the Third Estate. It is known that the Nobility and the Clergy have privi leges, and that, in the Third Estate, some Abolition of the Corvee. 155 cities and some private corporations have them. But the Third Estate, as a whole, — that is, the people, — is far from having privileges ; it has them in inverse order, since the burden that the exempted should have borne is always shifted to the backs of those not exempted." M. de Miromenil read the answers that Tur got had written in the margin of his manu script, and returned the packet with this note : " M. de Miromenil sends, with a thousand compliments to M. Turgot, the plan of an edict concerning the corve'es, and his observa tions. He also returns the papers concerning compulsory feudal service {les banalite's") , and confesses himself to be little impressed by the replies to his observations." The king was more impressed by them than the Keeper of the Seals, and permitted the edicts approved by him to be sent to the Par liament on the 9th of February, 1776. The time that had elapsed between the submission of the edicts to the king and the 9th of Feb ruary had been employed by opponents in organizing their opposition. Turgot's friends, made anxious by this, were eager to have the matter settled. " The well-intentioned mem bers of the Parliament," wrote Trudaine, " who are few in number, desire a firm course, and for that, haste is requisite. The more delay 156 Turgot. there is, the more chance there will be for systematic opposition." The Parliament reg istered the edict suppressing the Treasury of Poissy, and appointed commissioners to ex amine the others. On the 17th of February the Attorney-General and the commissioners reported unfavorably on the edict for the sup pression of forced labor. A vote was taken, and it was decided " that a Remonstrance should be laid before the king, entreating him to graciously withdraw the said edict, as being inadmissible both in substance and in details." There was no longer any doubt that the bed of justice was inevitable. As, however, Male sherbes hesitated to have recourse to this final measure, nearly a month was lost, and during this time the cabals grew extremely violent. Trudaine did not cease to urge haste. " All interests," so he wrote, " are affected by the public suspense ; a thousand cabals, active, violent, audacious, openly attack the existence of the Ministry. The ministers seem tranquil, slow, often undecided ; they are thought to be uncertain of their position, anxious, dismayed. It is not even known that they are united among themselves. In this condition, all de lay is dangerous. . . . Since the assembling of the Parliament, securities have considerably Abolition of the Corvee. 157 declined on Change. This decline will continue so long as the king remains undecided." Meanwhile, the king appeared unshaken. " The king has made edicts," wrote Marie Antoinette to Maria Theresa, "which will per haps occasion new broils with the Parliament; I hope matters will not go so far as during the last reign, and that the king will maintain his authority." But Malesherbes, Turgot's friend and collaborator, asked for modifications in the purview of the edict concerning the cor- vees, in order to prevent certain administrative abuses ; and he desired, in case the consent of the Parliament could not be obtained, that recourse should be had to the Court of Aids. Trudaine held that these half-way measures would be taken for weakness, and Turgot was naturally of his opinion. The king being with Turgot, it was determined to proceed to the bed of justice. In the interval, the pamphleteering war fare went forward with increasing vigor. Each day saw the hatching of a new petition, a new memorial, new ballads, epigrams, and puns. " M. de Malesherbes does all ; " M. de Sartine doubts all ; " M. Turgot spoils all ; " M. de Saint-Germain routs all ; "M. de Maurepas mocks all." 158 Turgot. Turgot's friends allowed themselves to be moved by all these stings, — a great error ; they even became angry, and thus put them selves doubly in the wrong. The Council sat isfied them by taking severe measures against the authors of the memorials and pamphlets, suppressing these works by a decree of the 22d of February, 1776. The Parliament saw in this act of severity a challenge on the part of Turgot's friends, and responded on the 23d by proscribing a book against the privileged classes, entitled " The Inconveniences of Feu dal Laws," which was just then making a great stir. The author, Boncerf, was one of Tur got's secretaries ; he acknowledged the work, and was ordered to be committed. This book seems very moderate to those who read it to day. The author enumerates, without exag geration of language, the disadvantages of feu dal laws, and proposes simply to authorize or to command the purchase of exemption from them. Present vassals were to be allowed to redeem their lands ; their heirs were to be obliged to do so. The Parliament looked upon the discussion of this system as a kind of criminal offence, and condemned the bro chure "as prejudicial to the laws and customs of France, to the sacred and inalienable rights of the crown, and to the right of private own Abolition of the Corvee. 159 ership of property, — as tending to shake the whole constitution of the monarchy by arous ing all vassals against their lords and against the king himself, and by representing all feu dal and domanial rights as so many usurpa tions, vexations, and outrages, equally hateful and absurd." Turgot immediately called Boncerf to Ver sailles to protect him from the Parliament, to which he sent orders to desist from prosecu tion. Hearing of this vigorous course, Vol taire cannot contain himself for joy, and writes to Audibert, February 28 : " Perhaps you already know that this Parliament, having burned by the hangman at the foot of its great staircase an excellent book in favor of the people, composed by M. de Boncerf, Chief Clerk to M. Turgot, and having ordered the author to be committed, His Majesty has commanded them to annul their decree, and has forbid den them to condemn books. His Majesty gives them to know that such condemnations must proceed from his Attorney-General, and that he cannot make them without the king's orders. Here are judgments worthy of Titus and Marcus Aurelius; these legal gentlemen are, however, not Roman senators. As to M. Turgot, he has all the bearing of an ancient Roman." 1 60 Turgot. All these skirmishes had preceded the open ing of grand hostilities. A war without quar ter was about to begin, — to end, alas ! in the downfall of the defenders of equality, and in the triumph of the coalition of the privileged. On the 2d of March, 1776, the Parliament drew up the text of its Remonstrance. It sent a deputation to Versailles to bear the Remon strance to the king, and to ask him to fix a time for its formal presentation by the Parlia ment. On the 7th, Louis replied as follows to a second deputation : " I have examined the Remonstrance of my Parliament; it contains nothing that had not been foreseen and ma turely considered." The Parliament urged in its Remonstrance that if it had failed to register the edict on the suppression of the corvee, this was because such suppression would be a violation of jus tice. " The first rule of justice is to preserve to each one his own: a fundamental rule of natural law, of the law of nations, and of civil government, — a rule which consists not only in maintaining the rights' of property, but in conserving those which are attached to the per son, and which grow out of the prerogatives of birth and rank. . . . The right of the corve'e belonged to the Franks over their men. . . . When their serfs obtained emancipation, in Suppression of Trade-Guilds. i6'i becoming free citizens but commoners, they j became subject to the corve'e. . . . To subject the nobles to a redemption-tax for the corve'e^ to the prejudice of the maxim that ' no one is\ liable to the corve'e who is not liable to the! taille! is to decide them liable to the taille like' commoners." The refusal to listen to the Remonstrance was the announcement of the bed of justice ; before describing it, we must examine the edict suppressing the trade-guilds. III. The suppression of the Exclusive Indus trial Corporations1 and the establishment of Freedom of Labor constitute Turgot's greatest reform, — that in which his personal influence is most plainly seen, and which won its final triumph in the Revolution by the sheer force of liberal ideas. Civil equality and the aboli tion of privileges may be, and have been, the result of another passion than that of freedom, — of this our whole history since 1 789 is the proof. The protective system and the organi-j zation of labor are not incompatible with what^ 1 Jwrandes and maitrises. Literally, wardenships and masterships of guilds. — Tr. 1 62 Turgot. are called modern governments, — the govern ments that have succeeded the Old Regime. Thus it is to Turgot much more than to the Revolution that we are indebted for freedom of labor; and it is to the freedom of labor inaugurated by Turgot that, after the defini tive triumph of his ideas, the France of the nineteenth century owes the astonishing out burst of industrial force which the present generation has witnessed. The preamble of the edict for the suppression of the trade-guilds is a masterly work, of which it is proper to give an analysis, with extracts embodying the main considerations. TJie__right to labor is a natural right. It has been infringed, indeed, by"ancieiit Ihsfitu- tions, but these infringements have been justi fied neither by time, nor by public opinion, nor by the acts of authority which seem to have sanctioned them. I In almost all towns the exercise of the different arts and trades was centred in the hands of a small number of masters united in guilds, who alone had the freedom to manufacture and sell the articles of the particular industry of which they held the exclusive privilege. J He who devoted himself to any art or trade could not exercise it freely until after attaining the mastership, to which he could be admitted only by submitting to long, Suppression of Trade-Guilds. 163 tedious, and superfluous tests, and at the cost of multiplied exactions depriving him of a part of the capital requisite for establishing a business or for fitting up a workshop. ( Those who could not afford these expenses were j reduced to a precarious existence under the [sway of the masters, with no choice but to live ;in penury at home or to carry to some foreign land an industry that might have been useful to their country. ) Citizens of all classes were deprived of the right of choosing the workmen whom they would have liked to employ, and of the advan tages in price and execution secured by com petition. Frequently the simplest piece of work could not be executed except by appli cation to the members of different guilds, and one had to bear the delays, the bad faith, the exactions, encouraged by the claims of these different corporations and by the caprices of their arbitrary and selfish system. (_[" These abuses crept in by degrees. They were originally the outcome of the selfishness of individuals, who established them against the public. It was after a long period of time that authority — now taken by surprise, again deluded by a semblance of utility — gave them a kind of sanction. The source of the evil lies in the very permission granted to artisans 1 64 Turgot. of the same craft to assemble and to unite in an association." J The preamble shows that the guilds origi- nated with the fre^cities."" When towns began to emancipate themselves from feudal bondage, and to form free communities, it became the custom to classify citizens according to theirj trade. " Thus the various crafts became so) many different communities, of which the gen-i eral community was made up. The religious' brotherhoods, by tightening the cords that united the individuals of the same craft, gave them more frequent occasions to assemble, and to occupy themselves in these meetings with the common interest of their particular society, — an interest which they pursued with continued activity, to the prejudice of the in terests of society in general. Once formed, the guilds enacted statutes, and under various pretexts of public welfare obtained their au thorization by the magistracy." The preamble goes on to enumerate the provisions of the majority of the statutes of the guilds, — provi sions tyrannical, and opposed to public welfare. The main object of these guilds was to restrict the number of masters as much as possible, and to render attainment of the mastership almost insuperably difficult for all but children of masters. Freedom of Labor. 165 " ProTThe spirit of monopoly which dictated tk °f Henactment of these statutes went to all leriglnet *56 j opposes half-way meas ures, 157; his prophecy touching the end of Turgot's ministry, 177. Turgot, Anne Robert Jacques (1727- 1781), introductory outline of life, character, influence, 9 ; ancestors, 16 ; father, 18 ; brothers, 20 ; shy ness, 20; theological education, 21 ; on money, 23; dissertations, 25; verse translations, 27 ; refuses to wear the mask of the Churchman, 29; early maturity, 30; resemblance to Adam Smith, 32 ; master of re quests, 34 ; philosophers, econo mists, men and women of letters receive him, 36 ; writes for the " Encylopasdia," 42 ; Voltaire's friendship, 42; economic doctrine: " Essay on the Formation and Distribution of Wealth," 48 ; economic doctrine : " Eulogy of Gournay," 67; Intendant of Li moges, 71; "Advice concerning the Levy and Distribution of the Taille" 73 ; " Plan of a Memoir on Taxation," 76 ; " Memorial on Loans of Money," 81 ; " Letters on Free Trade in Grain," 91 ; minister of marine, 100; Comptroller-Gen eral, 101 ; exact length of his minis try* 103 5 plans for education of the people, 105 ; attacks the grain mo- Index. 231 nopoly, 108 ; decrees free trade in grain, 114; his haughty treatment of Necker, 1 16 ; preamble of the de cree, 120 ; Dijon insurrection, 122 ; diminishes taxes, 124 ; the corn- riots, a victory, 130; vainly opposes the recall of the parliaments, 134; the coronation oath, 140; economy, 142 ; the great edicts, 144 ; General Preamble, 146 ; discussion of the corvie, 148 ; Preamble of the Edict for the suppression of trade-guilds, 162 ; articles of the edict, 165 ; the edicts become law, 167 ; struggle with the queen, 175 ; loses the king's confidence, 179; Secret Letters to the king, 185 ; dismissal, 191 ; liter ary and scientific pursuits, 192 ; death, 198 ; reactions, 200 ; his in fluence triumphant in the Revolu tion, 206 ; more reactions, 210 ; what we owe him, 213 ; his concep tion of freedom, 221. Usury, Turgot's memorial on loans and, 81 ; real origin of the sentiment against, 86 ; what usurers are inju rious to society? 87. Vergennes, Count de, unites with Turgot in urging the recall of Count de Guines, 175, 176. Vergil, Turgot's translation from, 27, 198. Versification, Turgot's experiments , in, 27 ; Voltaire's opinion of Tur got's verses, 28. Very, Abbe* de, contributed to the choice of Turgot as minister, 99 ; his memoirs contain a famous letter by Turgot, 180 ; that letter sent to him by Turgot, 183, 185 ; his good influence over Maurepas, 188 ; Maurepas prefers Amelot to him as successor of Malesherbes, 189. Voltaire, on Turgot's appointment as intendant, 10; on Turgot's enemies, 12 ; takes Turgot's verses for prose, 28 ; Turgot's visit to him, 42 ; sati rizes Turgot's theory of taxation, 42 ; his constant loyalty to Turgot, 42 ; his description of the tyranny of the grain laws, 98 ; on the pre amble to Turgot's edict of 1774, 120; tbid. to D'Alembert, 121; to Con dorcet touching the Dijon insur rection, 124 ; on the burning of Boncerf's book, 159. Wages, regulated by the law of supply and demand, 56 ; Turgot's theory of, 58, 60 ; that theory criticised by Louis Blanc, 59. Wealth, Formation and Distribution of, Turgot's treatise on, preceded " The Wealth of Nations," 33 ; analysis of this treatise, 48; agri culture the source of wealth, 48 ; threefold freedom essential to, 53. "Wealth of Nations, The." See Smith, Adam. Workingmen, their condition under the guilds compared with their pres ent condition, 217-220. (See Guilds, Freedom, Association.) Works, Turgot's, note upon, 7. THE END. M8 5459