UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LIBRARY AT URBANA-CHAMPAIGN BOOKSTACKS o ^^ ^ ^ o V ^: FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO, 927 Ca' usa! and Systematic Reiaticns Among Forvvard, Futures and Expected Spot Prices Hun Y. Park 3Hi JO AMVMan 3H1 CcMegs cf Comrnerrie 'ind Business AdiT!ir!isT''ation ^' -ail of Economic and Sus'ness Research .^rsih/ oi iiiinoiS, IJrtana-Cfiampaign ;.^.;t'v:;;;^jf1^1i BEBR FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 927 College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign February 1983 Causal and Systematic Relations Among Forward, Futures and Expected Spot Prices Hun Y. Park, Assistant Professor Department of Finance Acknowledgment: This paper is a part of my dissertation. I am grateful to my dissertation committee members. Professors Andrew H. Chen, J. Huston McCulloch, Gary C. Sanger for their continuing encouragement and valuable comments. Special thanks are owed to Professor Edward J. Ray for his insightful comments. Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign http://www.archive.org/details/causalsystematic927park Abstract In the absence of transaction costs and in the presence of uncer- tainty, this paper derives implicit and explicit pricing equations of forward and futures contracts, from which causal and systematic rela- tions can be derived among forward, futures and expected prices. The implicit pricing models of both contracts alE developed by using basic raicroeconomic theories, i.e., the market clearing condition and the first order condition for the expected utility maximization. These models conject economic rationale for "normal backwardation" and "normal contango" processes. Adding two assumptions, lognorraality and constant relative risk aversions, permits us to switch from the implicit description of a general equilibrium model to the explicit analysis of systematic patterns to the contract prices, from which empirically test- able hypothesis can be derived in terras of causal relations among futures, forward and expected spot prices. Especially, it will be exa- mined under what conditions forward and futures prices are systemati- cally different and, at the same time, "normal backwardation" and "normal contango" are accepted as accurate descriptions of the contract prices in market equilibrium. I. INTRODUCTION Most recently, several papers have attributed the fundamental difference between forward and futures prices to the different payment schedule due to the property of marking-to-market in futures contracts (see Margrabe [11], Black [2], Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4], Richard and Sundaresan [15], Jarrow and Oldfield [9], Chen and Park [3], and Park [14]). Employing different approaches, they have consistently shown that each price is the value of an asset which will pay a specific number of units of the underlying good on the maturity date. Spe- cifically, the number in the forward price is the total return from "going long" strategy in a default-free discount bond maturing at the same time as the forward contract. The number in the futures price is die total return from "rolling over" strategy in one-period bonds up to the contract maturity date. Based upon this result, the purpose of this paper is to derive implicit and explicit pricing equations of forward and futures contracts, from which causal and systematic relations fan be derived among forward, futures and expected prices. Especially, it will be examined under what conditions forward and futures prices are systematically different, and, at the same time, under wbat conditions '^Jormal Backwardation" and "Normal Contango" are accepted as accurate 2 descriptions of underlying contract prices in market equilibrium. Note that "Normal Backwardation" and "Normal Contango" are referred to the processes in which contract prices (forward and futures) are systematically downward and upward biased estimates of expected spot prices over time respectively. To the author's knowledge, the explicit expressions for -2- che simultaneous relations among forward, futures and expected spot prices have been attracted little attentions so far. In section II, in the absence of transaction costs and in the presence of uncertainty, the implicit pricing models of forward and futures contracts are formulated through the market clearing condition and the first order condition for the expected utility maximization. Some important implications are developed from these models in terms of the economic rationale for "Normal Backwardation" and "Normal Contango." On the basis of models formulated in section II, the explicit form pricing equations of both contracts are developed in section III, adding two assumptions, log- normality and constant relative risk aversion. The simultaneous and causal relations among forward, futures and expected spot prices are derived and analyzed. Finally, section IV summarizes and concludes the paper. II. IMPLICIT PRICING MODELS OF FORWARD AND FUTURES CONTRACTS.^ Notations used in this section are as follows: Xi: commodity X (subscript i represents the specific commodity i) T: maturity date of forward and futures contracts fi(t,T): forward price at current time t on commodity i (T > t) Fi(t, T): futures price at time t on commodity i ?i(T): spot price of commodity i at time t B(t, t): price as of time t of a riskless bond paying one dollar at time t(t > t) rC":): continuously compounded interest rate from time t to time T + 1 -3- COV: covariance VAR = z^: variance £t(«): expected value of the argument (•) at time t (•): randomness of the argument (•) As noted in the section I, the forward price is the value of a claim that pays B(t,T)~ units of the commodity under consideration at its maturity date T: i.e. by entering a forward contract on one unit of commodity i with a forward price fi(t,T), a person who is in the long position is paid B(t,T) units of commodity i at time T. Note however that B(t,T) is known at time t. Once the payoff is known in terns of the number of units that can be paid at time T, a general forward contract pricing model can be developed through the market clearing condition and maximization of the expected utility function that is assumed the same for all individuals. Consider the n+1 goods economy composed of Xo, XI, X2.... Xn, where Xo ser(T) } VarClog Pi(T)} = VarCl)(T) - * (T) } = a-«a2i(T) + b2.a^o(T) - 2Dio abai(T)(jo(T) (16) -12- Thiis, from (11), (13), and (16) EcPi(T) = expTEtZd) + l/ZCa^.a^KT) + b^'O-o(T) - 2pio abai(T)ao(T)}] (17) Equations (14), (15), and (17) show the explicit form pricing models for forward contract, futures contract and the expected future spot price under the given assumptions. The most important implication from equation (14), (15), and (17) is that we can not only specify the causal relations among those three prices, but also derive testable hypotheses. In other words, by exam- ining the variables in the equations, we can investigate under what conditions a "Normal Backwardation" or a "Normal Contango" process of forward or futures prices is possible and under what conditions the forward contract price is equivalent to the futures contract price. 3.2 Relation Between Forward and Futures Prices From equation (14) and (15) , log Fi(t,T) - log fi(t,T) = ar{pir aai(T) - por bao(T)} (18) Then, the following implications follow directly from equation (18) , 1) if ar = 0, then Fi(t,T) = fi(t,T). If the one-period interest rate is nonstochastic, a futures contract is equivalent to a forward contract regardless of the degree of risk aversion and the variance of each commodity. This is intuitively plausible in chat a nonstochastic interest rate implies that the hedge ratio for both futures and forward contract is given at time t when the -13- coatracts are open, and chus the contracts should be equivalent under rational expectations. However, note that zero variance of the one period interest rate is sufficient but not necessary for the equivalence of forward and futures contracts. 2) If the variance of the interest rate is non-zero, the question of whether Fi(t,T) is greater than or equal to or less than fi(t,T) depends on the magnitude of pir aai(T) and por bao(T) . Assuming a cne-period riskfree discount bond as the numeraire good, following implications can be deduced. Hereafter, in this paper, the numeraire Q good is assumed to be a one-period riskfree discount bond.^ T-1 T-1 Then, c;o(T) = cr(T) ; note that Var Z r(T) = Z Var r(T) if T=C T=t interest rate at period t is independent of that at period x + 1. Also, noting that the bond price is negatively correlated with the interest rate, the following causal relations can be derived: If ab pio ci(T) ao(T) = b^«a^o(T), then Fi(t,T) = fi(t,T) This implies that if the covariance between the price of the com- aodity i and the price of one-period riskfree discount bond is less than the variance of the price of the bond, the futures price is greater than the forward price. This result is intuitively plausible in Chat futures prices depend on the correlation of spot prices and interest rates, while forward prices do not. Generally, if interest rates go up, it becomes more costly for speculators to buy commodities and for firms to build up inventories, thus increasing commodity prices. Considering the negative correlation between interest rates and the bond prices, the covariance between bond -14- prices and storable commodicy prices tends to be negative, thus the futures price tends to be greater than the forward price. On the other hand, financial futures such as Treasury bills, are expected to have a high correlation with the one-period bond prices, so that futures prices for Treasury bills tend to be lower than their forward prices. 3.3 The Issue of Normal Backwardation or Normal Contango By comparing equation (14) and (15) with equation (17), we can specify explicitly under what conditions, the forward or futures price is an unbiased estimate of the expected future spot price and when they are supposed to follow the "Normal Backwardation" or Normal Contango" process . Subtracting equation (17) from (14) and (15) respectively after taking logarithm leg fi(t,T) - log EtPi(T) = bao(T){pio aai(T) - bao(T)} (19) log Fi(t,T) - log EtPi(T) = -b^'a^o(T) + ar{pir aai(T) -por b0o(T)} + pio abai(T)ao(T) = ao{a pio 0i(T) - bao(T)}(b-l) (20) assuming the one-period discount bond as a numeraire good; note that if ^,-e subtract equation (19) from equation (20), it turns out to be equal to equation (18) . From equations (19) and (20), following implications can be derived immediately. -15- 1) First, if the interest rate is nonstochastic and thus ao(T) = D, then fi(t,T) = Fi(t,T) = EtPi(T); bcth forward and futures contract prices are unbiased estimates of future expected spot prices. This has intuitive explanation because of the reasons stated in section 3.1. Note however that this is not a necessary condition for the equivalence of forward and futures contract, nor for them to be unbiased estimates of the expected spot price. 2) Second, assuming that b > 1, which is the case of the gener- alized negative power utility function, a fairly striking result follows from the equations (18), (19), and (20); the comparison of futures prices or forward prices with expected spot prices is equivalent to that of forward prices with futures prices. In other words, the simultaneous relations among those three prices hold as follows: If ab oio cri(T) cto(T) = b^-a^od), then EP(T) = F(t,T) = f(t,T) (21) In words, if the covariance between the price of commodity i and the discount bond price is less than the variance of the bond price, both prices, futures and forward prices, will follow a "Normal Backwardation" process and if the former is greater than the latter, both prices will follow a "Normal Contango" process. Concerning the possibility of hedging instrument of the contracts, if commodity i and the one-period discount bond are negatively corre- lated, so that the commodity is a good candidate for a hedging instru- ment against changes in the price of the one-period discount bond, both -16- futures and forward price are doT>mward biased estimates of the expected spot price. "Normal Backwardation" is a natural deduction for the ccirmodity . IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION The fact that we can express the payoff of forward and futures contracts in terms of the number of units of commodities is a fairly important result, which gives us a good deal to go on and from which we can deduce some interesting implications. Based on the number of units of commodities that can be paid for a futures and a forward contracts, this paper developed implicit pricing models of both contracts through the market clearing condition and the first order condition for the expected utility maximization. These models conject economic rationale for "Normal Backwardation" and "Normal Contango." Adding two assiimptions on the underlying process of assets (log- normality) and the utility function (constant relative risk aversions) permitted us to switch from the implicit description of a general equilibrium model to the explicit analysis of systematic patterns to the two contract prices, from which empirically testable hypothesis could be derived in terms of causal relations among futures, forward and expected spot prices. The following implications were immediate; if the interest rate is nonstochastic, futures contracts are equivalent to forward contracts regardless of the degree of risk aversion and the variance of commodities, and at the same time, both contract prices are unbiased estimates of -17- future expected spot prices. If the covariance between the changes in coniLodity prices and the changes in discount bond prices is less than the variance of the changes in bond prices, futures prices are greater than forward prices, and simultaneously both of these contract prices are downward biased estimates of the expected spot prices, so that the "Normal Backwardation" is a natural deduction for describing the contract prices. If the covariance is equal to or greater than the variance, futures prices are equal to or less than forward prices respectively, and at the same time, both contract prices are unbiased, or upward biased estimates of expected spot prices correspondingly. This implies that if a commodity provides a hedging instrument against changes in bond prices, "Normal Backwardation" process can be said to be an accurate description of both futures and forward prices. In the process, it was clearly confirmed that the systematic dif- ference between futures and forward prices, and "Normal Backwardation" or "Normal Congango" are not inconsistent with market equilibrium, or narket efficiency. Nevertheless, since the models are formulated in a simplified economy, the analysis in this paper can never be perfect in explaining the sources of deviations from the models. The purpose of this paper, however, is not so much to introduce all the many factors that can theoretically influence futures and forward prices simulta- neously into one equation as it is to find the best explanation for the causal relations among futures, forward and expected spot prices in the simple economy. -18- Footnotes For descriptions of fundamental differences between futures and forward contracts, see Black [2], Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4], Margrobe [11], Jarrow and Oldfield [9], Richard and Sundaresan [15], Chen and Park [3], and Park [l^]. 2 There is a slight difference between "Normal Backwardation" and "Backwardation." "Normal Backwardation" refers to the situation where the expected future spot price is greater than the contract price while "Backwardation" refers to the situation where the current spot price is greater than the contract price. The terms "Normal Contango" and "Contango" are the reverse respectively. This clarification of terminologies is due to Professor J. H. McCulloch. See Keynes [10], Hicks [7], Houthakker [8], Arrow [1], McCulloch [12] for normal backwardation, and Hardy [6] and Telser [17] for normal contango. Throughout this paper, the consideration of margin requirement is rilled out; it is important to note that margin requirements are v£)t partial equity payments against the market value of the commodity represented by the contract, as it is when buying common stocks, but a guarantee in the event of adverse price movements. Nevertheless, a controversy over margin requirements exists in connection with investors' optimal portfolio construction. For example, Telser [18] argues that margin requirement should be incorporated in the pricing equations because they may disrupt individual investor's optimal portfolio allocation and thus induce costs even though they are in the form of interest-earning securities like Treasury bills. However, as long as individual investors can borrow in a perfect capital market against their portfolios to buy Treasury bills for the purpose of posting them as margin requirements, it doesn't induce any cost. In other words, the opportunity cost for posting margin requirements is zero, assuming no transaction costs in a perfect capital market. J. H. McCulloch [13] derived the same pricing equation in connection with short-lived options pricing when the underlying distribution of price is log-symmetric stable. This was pointed out also by Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4], and Richard and Sundaresan [15]. T-1 _ T-1 °Fi(t,T) = Et{Ui(T)«exp Z r(T) }/Et{Uo(T) -exp E r(T) T"t T=t since a is deterministic T-1 , T-1 = Et{Pi(T)«Uo(T)-exp Z rCx) }/Et{Uo(T) exp Z rd)} T=t T»t from equation (1) -19- r - - T-i _ _ T-i " = COV{Pi(T), Uo(T) exp L r(T)} + Et Pi(T)'EC Uo(T) exp L r(T) |_ T=t T=t T-1 /Et{Uo(T) exp Z r(T)} T=C T-1 . T-1 = Et Pi(T) + COV{Pi(T),Uo(T) exp E r(T) }/Et{Uo(T) exp I r(T)} T=t T=t which is Che equation (10). This equation (10) is quite similar to the ncdels of Richard and Sundaresan [15] obtained from a quite different approach. 'if u(x) = (k/i-Y)x^"^, u-^ = x"^, ir^ = -k/Y x""^"-^ Thus, the absolute risk aversion, R, (X) = -U^/V'^ = -k/Y X"^"^/X"^ = k/Y X"-"- r/ (X) = -k/Y X^ < 0, which implies the decreasing absolute risk aversion. Also, the relative risk aversion, R (X) = R (X)X = k/Y X"-"- X = k/Y r a R^^ (X) = 0. Miich implies the constant relative risk aversion. The general power utility function is given by (Ki/l-Y)Xi ^^. In this paper, Ki is assumed to equal one for simplicity with no loss of generality for comparison between forward and futures prices and expected spot prices. 9 The choice of a discount bond is consistent with an arbitrage argument in a complete market. Suppose that there is a futures contract in every state of the world. In the other words, a futures contract is an asset with a payoff in the next period that is equal to the state price that is uncertain, assuming the existence of a futures contract en each state that expires at every instant and another created that matures in the next instant. Then it is well known that a set of futures contract plus a risk free one-period discount bond can achieve the complete market in Arrow and Debrew sense. In the light of the above reasoning, the choice of the one-period discount bond is believed to be a reasonable choice as a numeraire good. This was indicated by Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4], -20- References Arrow, Kenneth J., "Futures Markets: Some Theoretical Perspectives," Journal of Futures Markets , Vol. 1, Number 2, 1981. I. Black, F., "The Pricing of Commodity Contracts," Journal of Financial Economics , January, 1976. 3. Chen, Andrew and Park, Hun, "Divergencies Between Futures and Forward Prices: A Test on Mar king- To- Market Effects of Futures Contracts," unpublished working paper, September, 19S2. +. Cox, Ingersoll and Ross, "The Relation Between Forward Prices and Futures Prices," Journal of Financial Economics , December, 1981. >. Dusak, "Futures Trading and Investor Return: An Investigation of Commodity Markets Risk Premiums," Journal of Political Economy , October, 1973. 3. Hardy, Charles, "Risk and Risk Bearing," University of Chicago Press, 1940. 7. Hicks, "Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory," Second Edition, Oxford Press, 1939. 3. Houthakker, H. S., "Can Speculators Forecast Prices," Review of Economics and Statistics , May, 1957. 9. Jar row and Oldfield, "Forward Contracts and Futures Contracts," Journal of Financial Economics , December, 1981. 3. Keynes, J. M. , "A Treatise on Money," Harcourt, Brace and Company, New York, 1930. 1. Margrabe, W., "A Theory of Forward and Futures Prices," unpublished working paper, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1978. 2. McCulloch, J. H., "Comment on 'Risk, Interest and Forward Exchange'," Quarterly Journal of Economics , 1975. , "The Pricing of Short-lived Options When Price Uncertainty is Log-synmetric stable," working paper of NBER and Boston College, 1978. A. Park, H. Y., "A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation of Forward and Futures Prices," unpublished dissertation thesis, the Ohio State University, August, 1982. i. Richard, S. F. and Sundaresan, M., "A Continuous Time Equilibrium Model of Forward Prices and Futures Prices in a Multigood Economy," Journal of Financial Economics, December, 1981. -21- 16. Samuelscn, D. A., "Proof chat Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly," Industrial Management Review , Spring, 1965. 17. Telser, Lester G., "Futures Trading and the Storage of Cotton and Wheat," Journal of Political Economy , June, 1958. 18. , "Margins and Futures Contracts," Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 1, No. 2, Summer, 1981. M/E/314 ;';-,t:l,. ::l,. ..\t''' !•■.'. HECKMAN BINDERY INC. JUN95 : _ . KL MANCHESTER. I