UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS IJBRARY AI URBAINA- CHAMPAIGN ENGINEERING NOTICE: Return or renew all Library Materials! The Minimum Fee lor each Lost Book is $50.00. II I M e\ r> 4 A/» t% The person charging this material is'wsrpbnsible for its return to the library from which it was withdrawn on or before the Latest Date stamped below. Theft, mutilation, and underlining of books are reasons for discipli- nary aeflorfcand may result in dismissal from ft* University. To renfew cSll'Telephone Center 33a-8id them. He need only redeem his containers. To summarize this section, the following points suffice: (1) total sales of beverages are unlikely to be reduced very much below the level that would have prevailed without the regulation. (2) benefits to consumers in the form of reduced unit prices of beverages in the event of a complete shift to returnables would amount to about $71 million. (3) consumer savings will be spent on other consumer goods. (4) the shift to returnables is unlikely to be com- plete. (5) retailers will incur increased costs of handling containers which may amount to $27 million in the event of a complete shift to returnables. (6) bottlers and brewers will incur increased labor costs at the rate of a fraction of a cent per unit, but a reduction in purchases of containers of about $100 million. (7) container manufacturers will experience a reduc- tion in container sales of about $100 million. The next section considers the detailed cost and employment effects arising from the shift to returnables. V. Employment Effects of the Deposit Regulation The effects on employment of a complete shift to returnables are estim- ated in this section. This approach permits measurement of the maximum ef- fects on displacement. Such a shift is not to be expected, and the effects of any specific shift, such as 50 per cent or 75 per cent can be made by taking the appropriate proportion of the effects estimated here. A complete shift to returnables would lead to an increase in total em- ployment rather than a decrease according to the estimates presented here. The reason is the high labor intensiveness of the returnable system. This result is true even if the employment created by the diversion of consumer expenditures to other goods is ignored. However, these offsetting expendi- tures and employment effects should not be ignored. 17 Employment Reductions. To estimate the direct effect of the assumed complete shift to returnables, the estimated reductions in sales of con- tainers are applied to total shipments of the industry to determine the proportionate reduction. The same proportionate reduction is then applied to total employment in the industry to estimate the implied reduction. For 1970 the following reductions were estimated in Tables 4 and 5 above: Change in Sales-Millions of Dollars Beer Soft Drink Total Reduction in can sales -53.9 -34.3 -88.2 Reduction in non-returnables bottle sales -12.0 -19.4 -31.4 Increase in returnable bottle sales 8.6 9.9 18.5 Net change in bottles - 3.4 - 9.5 -12.9 Net change in container sales -57.3 -43.8 -101.1 A reduction of $88.2 million of can sales represents a 2.4 per cent re- duction in total national sales of cans [Table 6]. If employment in the metal can industry were reduced proportionately there would be a reduction of 1,605 workers [Table 7], A net reduction of $12.9 million of bottle sales would be about 0.8 per cent of total national glass container sales. If employment were re- duced proportionately in this industry, there would be a reduction of about 554 workers. The reductions represent a significant fraction of Illinois employment in these industries. The 1,605 metal can workers represent about 16.7 per cent of Illinois employment in the industry, and the 554 glass container workers represent about 5.2 per cent of Illinois employment in the industry. Because these industries are heavily concentrated in Illinois, it seems likely that a very large proportion of the reductions in can and glass con- tainer employment induced by a complete shift to returnables would occur in Illinois. Another direct effect of a complete shift to returnables is the expected decrease in litter collection and solid waste disposal costs of about $3.3 million. Such a reduction concentrated entirely in labor costs would repre- sent about 550 workers if such workers earned about $6,000 a year. In addition to these direct effects of the mandatory deposit regulation, there will be indirect effects caused by the reduction of purchases by the directly impacted industries. 18 TABLE 6 Value of Shipments and Value Added by Manufacture In Selected Industries Related to Beer and Soft Drink Manufacture and Sales, United States and Illinois, 1968-1969 ( millions of dollars ) Year 1969 1968 1967 1966 1965 1964 1963 1962 1961 1960 1959 1958 Source ASM ASM Census ASM ASM ASM Census ASM ASM ASM ASM Census Glass containers 3221 Metal cans 3411 Beer Bottled whole- Malt and canned Glass salers liquors soft drinks containers 1,664.7 1,407.3 1,352.4 1,207.5 1,091.8 1,055.9 1,004.5 987.6 967.4 939.2 915.6 862.1 Value added by manufacture 1967 Census 842.2 1963 Census 629.6 5095 2082 2086 3,620.7 3,418.5 3,332.1 3,160.5 2.890.6 4,990.4 2,929.7 2.631.3 2,699.9 2.395.0 2,497.2 2.255.7 2,469.8 2.075.0 3,748.6 2,315.1 2.112.4 2,282.0 2.095.3 2,200.0 1.936.4 2,179.5 1,933.7 2,095.4 1.824.1 1,982.7 1,141.5 830.5 4,065.7 3,574.7 3,173.2 2,734.9 2,505.4 2,408.8 2,210.9 2,030.9 1,911.4 1,806.1 1,714.4 1,558.3 1,679.4 1,233.6 3221 Metal cans 3411 196.5 349.1 121.4 102.9 151.9 140.4 Beer Bottled whole- Malt and canned salers liquors soft drinks 5095 fal 208j_ 2086 340.6 153.8 [b] 178.2 293.2 69.2 62.9 [b] 94.2 69.8 a. Only that part of the Beer, wine, distilled alcoholic beverages industry related to beer and ale. b. SIC 2082, 2083, and 2084 combined. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Census o f Manufactures 1958 196T anrf iqa 7 4 of Manufactures , 1959, 1960, 1961. 1962, 1964, 1965, 1966, 1968 196^ Cens us of^JllLT y^ 7 \ ^f^^L 19 TABLE 7 Estimated Employment in Selected Industries Related to Beer and Soft Drink Manufacture and Sales, United States and Illinois 1968-1970 ( thousands of workers ) United States Illinois Beer Bottled Beer Bottled Glass Metal whole- Malt and canned Glass Metal whole Malt and canned SIC Code containers cans salers liquors soft drinks containers cans salers liquors soft drinks Year Source CBP 3221 3411 65.9 5095 101.9 2082 56.3 2086 3221 3411 9.6 [c l 5095[a] 7.0 2082 2.1 2082 1970 [b] 68.9 [b] 124.6 10.3 6.1 1969 [b] CBP 69.2 [bl 63.9 57.2 122.7 11.6 9.7^ 2.2 6.1 1969 ASM 71.5 68.1 58.1 128.6 1968 ASM 63.9 63.1 59.8 125.2 1967 Census 66.7 60.3 59.6 123.3 10.0 10.4 2.8 [dl 6.3 1966 ASM 64.5 58.7 60.5 117.7 1965 ASM 61.5 54.9 60.4 113.9 1964 ASM 60.4 55.1 61.9 111.1 1963 Census 60.0 53.2 62.6 106.8 9.2 10.1 5.4 5.2 1962 ASM 60.0 53.1 66.0 105.4 1961 ASM 60.2 53.4 68.2 104.1 1960 ASM 58.5 53.6 69.8 103.3 1959 ASM 56.2 53.8 70.9 100.0 1958 Census 54.9 54.9 71.7 97.1 a. Total. Not comparable to industry in Table 6. b. County Business Patterns data based on mid-March covered FICA employment. Not comparable to Census and Annual Survey of Manufactures data. c. SIC 341 d. SIC 2082, 2083, and 2084 combined. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Census of Manufactures, 1958, 1963, and 1967; Annual Survey of Manufacturers, 1959, 1960, 1961, 1962, 1964, 1965, 1966, 1968, 1969; County Business Patterns , 1969 and 1970. 20 To estimate the indirect effects of the reductions in can and bottle sales, an input-output analysis of the industries has been carried out. For 1963 a detailed industry input-output table for the United States is available [11]. For any final product (such as metal cans in our analysis), the total requirement coefficients estimate the amount of input from any industry (such as blast furnace and basic steel products) required to pro- duce a dollar of output delivered to final demand. For steel into metal cans, this coefficient is .53993, indicating that about $.54 of steel is used as input to every $1.00 of metal cans delivered to final demand. The total requirements coefficient includes both direct inputs of steel to metal cans and the inputs of steel to other industries' outputs used in the pro- duction of metal cans (such as railroads) . When the total requirements coefficients for the industries which sup- ply significant inputs to the impacted industries are multiplied by the es- timated reduction in can and bottle sales induced by a complete shift to re- turnables, estimated reductions in inputs to the can and glass container in- dustries are obtained. These estimates are listed in Tables 8 and 9. To obtain estimates of employment reductions caused by the reduction in inputs to the can and glass container industries, the ratio of total employment to total shipments is estimated. When this ratio for each industry is multi- plied by the corresponding reduction in demand, the estimated reduction in employment is obtained. The indirect employment reductions resulting from a complete shift to returnables would be about 3,000 workers in the industries supplying the metal can industry and about 200 workers in the industries supplying the glass container industry. In making these calculations, only industries for which the total requirements coefficient was .01 or larger were considered. The effect of including the omitted industries would amount to at most an- other 100 or 200 workers and these would be widely distributed among the more than three hundred omitted industries. Not all of the reduction in employment estimated in this analysis would occur in Illinois. Illinois has no significant employment in many of the industries affected (such as the mining of iron ore). Lacking an inter-regional input-output model, it is impossible to estimate how many Illinois workers would be affected, but the estimates given are the maximum effects. The analysis was carried out on 1963 data (which is the most recent available) . This old data certainly biases the estimates upwards, since labor productivity has increased in most industries in the past eight years. Thus, such errors of estimation as exist tend in the direction of overestimating rather than underestimating the Illinois employment effects. Increases in Employment . The effect of a complete shift to returnables in increasing employment would be concentrated in retail trade, soft drink bottlers, and brewers and beer distributors. For retailers, it has been estimated that the cost of handling a single container return amounts to ap- proximately $.01. Total costs of a shift from .6 billion containers of beer in returnables to 2.1 billion containers of beer in returnables would amount to approximately $15 million. For soft drinks, the shift from 1.5 billion containers of returnables to 2.7 billion containers of returnables would amount to $12 million. The total costs to retailers of $27 million is quite close to the additional costs to retailers of $30 million which can be de- rived from the estimated reduction in sales of $71 million and the estimated 21 TABLE 8 Total Requirements Coefficients, Shipments, Employment, Ratio of Employment to Shipments, Employment per Million Dollars of Metal Cans Delivered to Final Demand and Estimated Reduction in Employment Resulting from a Complete Shift to Returnables, Illinois, Selected Industries Industry (SIC Code) Coal mining (11,12) Petroleum and gas (1311,2) Paper mills (2611) Paperboard mills (2631) Paperboard cont'rs (265) Commercial printing (2751,2) Ind'l chemicals (281) Paints (2851) Petr. refining (2911,299) Basic steel (331) Prim, aluminum (3334) Alum, rolling (3352) Railroads (40,474) Motor freight (42,473) Water transport (44) Electric util. (491, pt. 493) Gas utilities (492, pt. 493) Wholesale trade (50) Credit agencies (61,67) Misc. bus. serv. (73,769 ) Advertising (731) Employ- Employ- ment per ment per million Input- Total Ship- Employ- thousand dollars Total Output requ' ts ments ment [a] dollars of employment Ind. No. coef . ($million) (thous. ) shipments demand reduction 7.0 .01709 2.636.8 149.0 .0565 .9656 85 8.0 .01180 12,264.7 163.8 .0133 .1569 14 24.02 .01013 5,054.4 ) 2,557.4 65.4 .0086 .2013 18 24.03 .01013 25.00 .02421 4,748.3 189.7 .0400 .9684 85 26.05 .04764 5,307.2 285.9 .0537 2.5583 226 27.01 .03219 12,613.2 284.6 .0226 .7275 64 30.00 .03006 2,462.1 62.9 .0255 .7665 68 31.01 .01728 20,858.5 188.8 .0091 .1572 14 37.01 .53993 19,988.6 589.9 .0295 15.9279 1,405 38.04 .01179 1,969.8 21.4 .0109 .1285 11 38.08 .01843 2,310.1 60.9 .0264 .4866 43 65.01 .03775 11,142.9 771.6 .0692 2.6123 230 65.03 .02452 13,486.3 903.5 .0670 1.6428 145 65.04 .01115 5,033.9 302.2 .0600 .6690 59 68.01 .01912 15,427.1 246.2 .0160 .3059 27 68.02 .01868 11,301.8 153.3 .0136 .2540 22 69.01 .05826 48,440.3 3,104.0 .0641 3.7345 329 70.01 .02755 45,160.9 379.0 .0084 .2314 20 73.01 .01919 13,372.6 ) 12,698.7 943.2 .0362 1.3948 123 73.02 .01934 a. Employment industry may differ slightly from Input-Output Industry by inclusion or exclusion of small three or four-digit industries. Sources: Total Requirements Coefficients, Shipments: U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Input-Output Structure of the U. S. Economy: 1963 , Vol. 3, U. S. Government Printing Office, 1969. Employment: U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment and Earnings, United States, 1909-70 , Bulletin 1312-7, U. S. Government Printing Office, no date. 22 TABLE 9 Total Requirements Coefficients, Shipments, Employment, Ratio of Employment to Shipments, Employment per Million Dollars of Glass Containers Delivered to Final Demand and Estimated Reduction in Employment Resulting from a Complete Shift to Returnables, Illinois, Selected Industries Industry (SIC Code) Employ- Employ- ment per ment per million Input- Total Ship- Employ- thousand dollars Total Output requ 1 ts ments ment [a] dollars of employment Ind. No. coef . ($tnillion) (thous. ) shipments demand reduction Stone & clay mining (141, etc) Petroleum and gas (1311,2) Paperboard mills (2631) Paperboard cont'rs (265) Ind'l chemicals (281) Petr. refining (2911,299) Abrasive prod. (3291) Motor freight (42,473) Electric util. (491, pt. 493) Gas utilities (492, pt. 493) Wholesale trade (50) Credit agencies (61,67) Misc. bus. serv. (73,7694) Advertising (731) 9.0 .02581 2,024.1 81.5 .0403 1.0401 13 8.0 .01180 12,264.7 163.8 .0133 .1569 14 24.03 .03976 2,557.4 20.0 .0078 .3101 4 25.00 .10465 4,748.3 189.7 .0400 4.1860 54 27.01 .12919 12,613.2 284.6 .0226 2.9200 38 31.01 .02387 20,858.5 188.8 .0091 .1572 3 36.16 .01939 744.8 23.4 .0314 .6088 8 65.03 .02047 13,486.3 908.5 .0670 1.3715 18 68.01 .02421 15,427.1 246.2 .0160 .3059 5 68.02 .06352 11,301.8 153.3 .0136 .2540 11 69.01 .03516 48,440.3 3,104.0 .0641 2.2538 29 70.01 .02663 45,160.9 379.0 .0084 .2237 3 73.01 .02033 13,372.6 1 12,698.7 943.2 .0362 1.1055 14 73.02 .01221 a. Employment industry may differ slightly from Input-Output Industry by inclusion or exclusion of small three- or four-digit industries. Sources: Total Requirements Coefficients, Shipment: U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Input-Output Structure of the U. S. Economy: 1963 , Vol. 3, Washington, D. C: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1969. Employment: U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment and Earnings, United States, 1909-70 , Bulleting 1312-7, Washington, D. C. : U. S. Government Printing Office, no date. 23 reduction in container costs of $101 million. Consumer savings are only about 70 per cent of the total reduction in sales of containers, the balance repre- senting the costs to retailers of handling the returns. Assuming that the unskilled labor employed to handle bottle returns is paid $2.00 an hour or about $4,000 a year, the $27 million of retailer costs represents an increase in employment of about 6,750 workers. The estimated additional costs of the returnable system to bottlers is about $.0015 per returnable, representing additional total costs to bottlers of about $1.8 million. Most of this cost represents additional employment of driv- er-salesmen. At an annual wage of $15,000 this represents an increase of about 120 workers. This estimate is perhaps low because it is based on data from one bottler and is much below the additional unit costs experienced by the brewer considered in this study. For brewers and beer distributors, the additional costs of returnables are estimated at $.00625 per bottle, so the increase of 1.5 billion returnables rep- resents increased costs of $9.4 million. At an annual wage for drivers of $15,000, this amount represents an increase of about 627 workers. Most of the increased employment effects in retail trade and soft-drink bottlers will be local Illinois effects. Some of the increased employment for brewers and distributors will be outside of Illinois. The employment reductions and increases resulting from a complete shift to returnables can be summarized as follows: Reductions in employment Metal cans 1,605 Glass containers 554 Litter collection and waste disposal 550 Indirect employment effects from metal cans 2,988 Indirect employment effects from glass containers 214 Total reductions 5,911 Increases in employment Retail trade 6,750 Soft-drink bottlers 120 Brewers and beer distributors 627 Total increases 7,497 Net increase in employment 1,580 2k In addition to these effects, about $71.4 million of consumer expendi- tures will be diverted to other consumer goods from beverages. This rep- resents about .007 per cent of GNP. This expenditure would induce about 5,000 additional jobs in the consumer industries and those which furnish inputs to consumer industries. Thus the total employment effects of the mandatory deposit regulation and a complete shift to returnables should be about 6,600 additional jobs. VI. Summary and Conclusions The previous section indicates that the deposit regulation will increase employment by about 6,600 jobs if there is a complete shift to returnables. There is little reason to expect that the shift will be complete, but there will probably be a substantial shift toward returnables. Such a partial shift will reduce the employment effects of the regulation, and, at the same time, reduce the pressure on the heavily impacted industries. It was not possible to estimate with any precision the location of the disemployment ef- fects. It is likely that nearly all of the direct reductions will occur in Illinois and one-half or more of the indirect effects as well. Except for the metal can industry, the reductions are relatively small in relation to total employment in the industry. No one would ignore a 5 per cent reduction in glass bottle employment, but this industry has a voluntary quit rate of close to 2 per cent per month according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and this suggests that the re- quired reduction in employment could be absorbed through normal quits in no more than three months. This is particularly true in that the immediate im- pact would be substantial stocking up by bottlers of returnable bottles as they shifted to the returnable system. The immediate impact of the regula- tion might well be an increase in employment in glass containers. Later, however, there would probably be a decline to a lower level as demand fell back to replacement rates. The situation is much less simple for the metal can industry. The quit rate in metal containers is much lower than in glass containers, about 1 per cent a month rather than 2 per cent. The much larger proportionate employ- ment effect of 17 per cent would require more than a year to absorb through voluntary quits. This fact suggests that some delay in the imposition of the regulation would ease the necessary employment adjustment. With the less than complete shift to returnables which can be expected and a period of nine months or a year over which bottlers could prepare to shift to returnables, the impact on metal can sales would be less sudden. While there is an increase in employment to be expected as a result of the regulation, it must at the same time be recognized that workers in metal cans, steel, and glass containers face the risk of some injury. Transitions are seldom smooth and there will unquestionably be some layoffs in these in- dustries resulting from the adoption of the regulation. Fortunately, many of the workers in the industries are members of effective trade unions which have negotiated supplemental unemployment benefit programs which will sharply reduce the income loss effects of any necessary displacement. 25 The economic costs and benefits of the employment changes are important components of the dec is ion -making process on this question. The fact that some workers will be displaced and that many new jobs widely distributed across the state will be created are quite worth noticing, but it is not necessary to stress these adjustments too much. The changes induced by adoption of the regulation will not be sudden but will take place at a pace which will allow adjustments to be made by firms and workers. The labor market is likely to improve during the next few years as the nation recovers from the most recent recession. The process of redistribution of employment among economic activities is a normal part of economic development and the changes which are likely to occur in this instance are not particularly large in terms of adjustments which normally occur 26 References 1. Anonymous bottler. 2. Anonymous bottler. 3. Beverage Containers, Recommendations of the Illinois Solid Waste Management Task Force . Illinois Institute of Environmental Quality. Springfield, 1971. 4. Tom Joyce, Solid Waste - - Litter , Memorandum to the Task Force on Solid Waste Source Reduction. Illinois Institute of Environmental Quality, August 10, 1971. 5. Midwest Research Institute, The Role of Packaging in Solid Waste Management . Environmental Protection Agency, Bureau of Solid Waste Management. Washington, D. C. : U. S. Government Printing Office. 1969. 6. Sidney P, Mudd. Letter to Bernard C. Smith, chairman, New York State Senate Committee on Conservation and Recreation. May 24, 1971. 7. National Association of Food Chains. Testimony of Mr. Paul A. Karody, Jr., before Prince Georges County Maryland Council, November 2, 1971. 8. Bernard Udis, Editor. Adjustments of the U. S. Economy to Reductions in Military Spending . U. S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency. Wash- ington, D. C: U. S. Government Printing Office. 1970. 9. United States Brewers Association, Inc. The Brewing Industry in the United States , Brewers Almanac, 1970. Washington, D. C. 1970. 10. U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Census of Business . Vol. III. Washington, D. C. : U. S. Government Printing Office. 11. U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Input-Output Structure of the U. S. Economy: 1963 , Vol. 3. Paper No. 2 EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS OF A BAN ON NONRETURNABLE BEVERAGE CONTAINERS IN MINNESOTA 27 ABSTRACT A ban on nonreturnable containers will have significant employment effects on the soft drink, and beer industries in Minnesota. This report attempts to identify the economic effects and to measure the impact of a ban on consumer costs and employment in Minnesota. The methods followed correspond closely to that in the previous study of the employment effects of mandatory deposit regulations made for Illinois [1], but somewhat better data and industry information has been available for this study. Most of the conclusions reached in this study would also apply to a mandatory deposit law which did not ban nonreturnables . The Illinois analysis, for instance, was based on the assumption that mandatory deposits would lead to an essentially complete shift from nonreturnables to returnables. The degree of such a shift, however, is open to argument, and it can be expected that nonreturnables would persist in some sales situations despite the imposition of a mandatory deposit. 28 I. Expenditure Flows and Employment The analysis is based on the changes in employment that result from changes in the flow of expenditure. The underlying principles are quite simple: 1. A decrease in the sale of beverage in one-way containers resulting from a ban leads to reduced labor demand for production and distribution, which are termed "the direct negative employment effects." 2. A decrease in sales leads to reduced demand for inputs to the production process, which in turn leads to reduced labor demands in the industries supplying the inputs. These employment effects are termed "indirect negative employment effects." 3. A decrease in consumer spending on beverages in one-way containers permits consumers to spend more on purchases of other commodities | generating a stream of positive direct and indirect effects arising from production and sale of the new commodities purchased. 4. If consumers do not spend the same amounts in aggregate before and after the ban, the reduction or increase in consumer spending will lead to negative or positive employ- ment effects which are termed "induced employment effects." 29 In the following analysis it is assumed that consumers continue to spend the same amount before and after the ban on beverages and other products, hence, there are no induced spending effects. This is a reasonable assumption since beverages in cans and nonreturnable bottles have very close substitutes in the corresponding beverages in returnable bottles. Moreover, beverages are a relatively small proportion of all consumer spending, hence, the change in packaging systems should not have a large aggregate effects. As a general proposition, the assumption of no change in spending requires that aggregate national wages will not change as a result of a ban in one state, but employment may change. It may increase, for instance, if spending is diverted from high-wage industries to low- wage industries. Employment and wages within the state may change as well, if the ban leads to a substitution of local production, distribution, and sales employment for out-of-state employment the result could be increase in employment and wages in the state. The principal questions involved are the (1) the effects of a ban on total sales of beverages; (2) the employment generated in Minnesota in the nonreturnable beverage and container industry before and after a ban; and (3) the effects of the ban on the sale of national brand out-of-state beers and nationally canned controlled- label soft drinks canned out-of-state. 28 I. Expenditure Flows and Employment The analysis is based on the changes in employment that result from changes in the flow of expenditure. The underlying principles are quite simple: 1. A decrease in the sale of beverage in one-way containers resulting from a ban leads to reduced labor demand for production and distribution, which are termed "the direct negative employment effects." 2. A decrease in sales leads to reduced demand for inputs to the production process, which in turn leads to reduced labor demands in the industries supplying the inputs. These employment effects are termed "indirect negative employment effects." 3. A decrease in consumer spending on beverages in one-way containers permits consumers to spend more on purchases of other commodities generating a stream of positive direct and indirect effects arising from production and sale of the new commodities purchased. 4. If consumers do not spend the same amounts in aggregate before and after the ban, the reduction or increase in consumer spending will lead to negative or positive employ- ment effects which are termed "induced employment effects." 29 In the following analysis it is assumed that consumers continue to spend the same amount before and after the ban on beverages and other products, hence, there are no induced spending effects. This is a reasonable assumption since beverages in cans and nonreturnable bottles have very close substitutes in the corresponding beverages in returnable bottles. Moreover, beverages are a relatively small proportion of all consumer spending, hence, the change in packaging systems should not have a large aggregate effects. As a general proposition, the assumption of no change in spending requires that aggregate national wages will not change as a result of a ban in one state, but employment may change. It may increase, for instance, if spending is diverted from high-wage industries to low- wage industries. Employment and wages within the state may change as well, if the ban leads to a substitution of local production, distribution, and sales employment for out-of-state employment the result could be increase in employment and wages in the state. The principal questions involved are the (1) the effects of a ban on total sales of beverages; (2) the employment generated in Minnesota in the nonreturnable beverage and container industry before and after a ban; and (3) the effects of the ban on the sale of national brand out-of-state beers and nationally canned controlled- label soft drinks canned out-of-state. 30 II. Effect of a Ban on Beverage Sales There is little experience to draw on in other states concerning the effect of a ban on one-way containers on total beverage sales. Oregon's law requiring a mandatory five cents deposit on all beverage containers and banning the pull tab has only been in effect since October 1, 1972, and there is no report available of its effects on soft drink sales. Beer sales in November and December were higher for 1972 than for the same months in 1971; according to William Moore, assistant director of inventory enforcement for the Oregon Liquor Commission [2]. October 1972 sales were 50 percent higher than October 1971 (probably because of inventory building of returnables), while for the first eleven months of 1972 sales were 6.6 percent higher than in the corresponding period of 1971? according to Mr. Moore. Since Mr. Moore reports that very few drinks are being sold in cans, the Oregon situation may be though compar- able to what would happen in the event of a ban. Such demand estimates for beer and soft drinks as have been made suggest that demand is price inelastic [3]> i.e., that a one percent in- crease in price would lead to only a 0.2 percent decrease in sales. Since beverages packaged in returnable bottles are close substitutes for bever- ages packaged in one-way containers, one would expect at most a small decrease in sales even if consumers treated deposits as part of the price and if the sale price excluding deposit even increased slightly. It is argued below that retail prices for beverages in returnables are not like- ly to increase because of the ban, but even if they did increase as much as ten percent, the predicted decrease in sales would only be 2 percent. Sales of beer and soft drinks have been increasing at rates of 5 to 7 31 percent per year nationally in recent years as consumers substituted these goods for coffee and other beverages, so the assumption made in this study that a ban would not lead to a decrease in sales is probably a reasonable one. It is more likely that beverage sales would increase after a ban, just as beer sales in Oregon increased after a mandatory deposit regula- tion was imposed. Market structure in beverage markets is best described as "monopo- listic competition. " In such markets a firm has some control over the price it charges, unlike the purely competitive firm, but it does not have complete control, like the monopolist. Each firm in such markets strives to differentiate its product by advertising, distinctive and convenient packaging, or other means. At the same time the firm tries to increase its market share by luring away the customers of competing products by imitating their flavors or packages. Some firms are content with lower prices than others and forgo extensive advertising and package variations. It is natural for firms in such markets to believe that the variety of packages and sizes is essential to its sales, for if it restricted itself to a single package type and size in the current mar- ketplace it could expect to lose a major part of its market. What is perhaps true for a single firm, however, is probably not true for the market as a whole. Many beverage firms act as if the con- . sumer was buying a container and not the beverage it contains, but if no firm can offer the particular container because of a ban the consumer must buy the beverage in the container that is available or switch to un- packaged beverages. The fears of the industry that a ban will lead to an 8 percent decline in sales are absurd [h~\. Even strongly biased consumer surveys indicate only a 2 percent reduction [5]. 32 These questions cannot be settled by a priori arguments, and the assumption that there would be no change in beverages sales volume the year after a ban is a conservative one considering the steady and rapid recent growth of soft drink and beer sales. 33 III. Effect of a Ban on Prices It is sometimes agreed that a shift to returnable would lead to increased prices for returnables. This could occur as a result of any of three situations: 1. a decrease in bottle trippage 2. higher retailer and producer costs 3. lower profit margins on returnables than nonreturnables ( i . e ., "current subsidy" to returnables by bottlers, brewers, distributors or retailers ) 4. changes in brand mix 5. capital losses on equipment Lower trippage . If consumers continue to discard containers when only returnable are available, trippage, of course, would decrease and the cost of the returnable system would increase. There is no reason to expect trippage to decrease or that portion of sales which has been in returnables. If anything, trippage should increase with higher desposits and better return facilities. The real question lies in the behavior of persons who have used one-way containers who now must shift to returnables. This is simply a matter of behavior, and behavior can be influenced. Once committed to the returnable system, bottlers and brewers, environmentalists, and agencies concerned with solid waste and litter all have a common interest in making the returnable system work efficiently. The same effort devoted to making the returnable system work as is devoted to cleanup and recycling campaigns would probably make the returnable system quite successful because , with deposits, substantial economic incentive works together with public interest. 3k The deposit can be expected to provide incentives for the purchasers to return bottles, and for scavengers and bottle collection drives to gather containers from those consumers who do not wish to return them themselves . The consumer sometimes purchases one-way containers because it is the only available container for the brand desired. Many major outlets for beer and soft drinks do not handle returnables at all, so the consumer has no choice, and his action in buying one-way containers does not imply a willingness to pay a premium to discard containers. The frequency with which consumer surveys show approval of bans or mandatory deposits suggests that the "convenience" of the one-way container is a convenience many consumers can do without. The effect of a ban is not an obvious decline in trippage as is sometimes argued, but may be no change or even a substantial increase in trippage. Higher producer or distributer costs . Major national brand soft drinks and those beers already returnable are not likely to face higher packaging costs. For out-of-state and imported brands, how- ever, this can be a problem. Imported and remotely bottled beers, for instance, would probably choose to use a standard "multibrewer" return- able bottle which would not be returned to that brewer. The distributer would handle redemptions and return these bottles to domestic brewers. If this were done, the imported beers would probably experience a re- duction in price rather than an increase. The return of these bottles would more than compensate the distributor for any increased price to him arising from use of the multibrewer bottle. 35 Similarly, out-of-state brewers would be forced to handle returns which, with long hauls, would be relatively expensive in terms of transportation costs which are higher for returnables than nonreturn- ables. But returnable beer bottles are cheaper than cans and almost as cheap as one-way bottles. It is hard to see that wholesale prices would have to increase very much even if no bottles were returned. If out-of-state and imported beer were shipped in raultibrewer returnables, local brewers would have a supply of used returnables, since distributers would often prefer to channel returns to local brewers . Since brewer or distributer trucks must return to breweries anyway, neither the return trip nor loading costs have differential cost implication for out-of-state brewers. Nevertheless, transportation costs increase substantially with distance travelled. The growing concentration of brewing in a few major national firms has been permitted by the shift to one-way containers * a forced shift to returnables would benefit local brewers in competition with remote brewers [6], Lower markups on returnables . It is sometimes argued that brewer bottles and distributor profit margins are lower on returnables than on nonreturnables and that a shift to returnables would require higher wholesale prices on returnables than are currently charged if profit levels were to be maintained. This is to say that returnables are subsidized. It is difficult to see why brewers should subsidize return- ables which they seem to be so eager to abandon. The lower wholesale prices of returnables probably reflect costs and selective price discrimination. 36 While good data on markups is lacking because of its confidential nature, it is clear that the cost to the brewer of beer in returnables is somewhat lower than for one-way containers [7], and that the same is true in soft drinks 18]. The differential is smaller at wholesale prices because of higher distribution costs of returnables, and is usually smaller still at retail because of higher handling, sales, and return costs for retailers. There is little reason to believe that there is any consistent pattern of subsidizing returnables, since almost everyone in the production and distribution chain except some brewers and bottlers seems eager to get rid of the returnable system as soon as possible. The belief that the returnable system was doomed, which was widely held throughout industry until the past year, hardly contributed to significant research to speed up or economize on returnable bottle lines and equipment. Many bottlers and brewers have simply continued to use fully amortized returnable lines with little improvement while devoting capital expenditures to the rapidly improving "packaging systems of the future" which are almost uniformly one-way systems. With a revival of interest in returnable systems in those states which have instituted beverage container regulations and growing environmental concern elsewhere, it seems likely that substantial improvements in returnable bottle handling systems will be developed. Certainly there is little reason to expect that bottlers and brewers will be forced to raise beverage prices because they have shifted to a cheaper packaging system. Some may try to do so, but there seems to be little economic justification for such actions. 37 Changes in brand mix . If a bottler or brewer faces a substantial rise in cost because of the ban, he may wish to raise his price. Unless sellers are faced with similar situations it is unlikely that the seller who wishes to raise his price will be able to do so without suffering a reduction in sales. Lower sales by a firm are likely to be caused by an increase in price rather than cause an increase in price. At the same time, the national brewers and controlled-brand soft drink firms may face substantially higher costs and be forced to raise prices and lose market shares. If this happens, then in most instances locally brewed and bottled beverages will replace them and average prices for beer and soft drinks as a whole should change very little. If there is a shift from national to local beers , the result may be a reduction in the average price of beer, (since national brands are usually more expensive) . If there is a shift from controlled and local brand soft drinks, the result may be a slight increase in the all-brand average price of soft drinks since national brands in returnables are somewhat higher in price per ounce than controlled brands in cans, but a decrease could occur with a shift from local brands to returnables. Overall, then, a change in brand mix is unlikely to change average beer and soft drink prices very much, and either increases or decreases could occur. Capital losses and costs . Some producers will suffer capital losses from equipment, such as canning lines and can-vending machines rendered useless. These effects will be unevenly distributed, since some bottlers buy canned drinks and brewers with substantial out-of-state business can continue to employ canning lines in this trade. 38 Only those capital losses which affect bottlers, brewers, and dis- tributers can possibly be passed on, thus the losses of can and glass manufacturers cannot be passed on in beer and soft drink prices. Because Minnesota exports much of its beer, canning line capital losses can be expected to be small. Can venders can be sold second-hand, out-of-state, or possibly exchanged for bottle venders. Losses are likely to be substantial, how- ever. The ability of a firm to pass on capital losses depends on the need of competitors to do so. As a general economic principle, bygones are bygones, and current customers cannot be expected to pay for past mis- judgments. Because the capital losses are unevenly distributed, it is un- likely that they can be passed forward to consumers. Capital costs for new equipment will tend to be largest in those firms which were most com- mitted to one-way container systems, hence to those firms that have the largest capital losses. These costs are ordinarily passed forward as a cost of production, hence should not lead to any increase in price. The total effect of all these possible reasons for higher prices appears to be small. The critical influences on Minnesota prices will continue to be local brewers and national-brand soft drinks, and these are the firms which will face the smallest cost effects. It is reason- able to conclude that prices on returnables would change very little in the event of a ban, a situation which has apparently occurred in Oregon with its mandatory deposit law [2]. 39 IV. Consumer Savings If the prices of beverages in returnable containers do not change and the container-size mix does not change as the result of a ban, then consumers would spend less for the same liquid volume of beverages after a ban than they did before. This reduction in spending, termed "con- sumer savings," results from the ban, but should not be interpreted as a pure benefit. Consumers will lose the convenience of the one-way container which at least some of the purchasers were willing to pay for. This loss of convenience is one of the social costs of a ban. At the same time, the convenience of the one-way container to the individual consumer entails social costs external to the consumer in the solid waste and litter costs associated with and arising from beverage consumption. These include not only the costs of collection and disposal of solid waste and litter by public agencies but by individuals who must dispose of litter and solid waste on private property. In addition, there is the general social cost of litter which is suffered by everyone who contemplates it. Beautiful sights are marred by litter, and since people will pay substantial amounts of money to see beauty, they would presumably pay something to be free of litter. It is this widely held public attitude that justifies public litter collection expense. The net social benefit of a ban is the algebraic sum of the costs and benefits arising from the ban, and it is not to be confused with consumer savings which may be larger or smaller, In the preceeding sections of this paper it has been argued that a ban would cause little or no change in the price and volume of beverages, hence consumer savings can be expected to be positive. In this section consumer savings are based on late 1972 prices and the 1+0 estimated volume of beverages sold in 1972. The prices were collected in a survey in the Minneapolis-St . Paul area in December 1972 and are described in Appendix A. Beer sales of 1972 are stimated from official state data and the distribution package size and type are estimated from various national industry data. Soft drink sales of 1972 are estimated from national data from various sources and from Minnesota's 1967 share of national shipments. Sales and package data are described in Appendix B. Detailed package-mix data are lacking, so that many detailed assumptions have been made in preparing the estimates. The volume of liquid beverages sold in containers has been estimated in 12 ounce equivalents, but the estimated price differentials reflect the estimated size mix of containers and is not based purely on the price differentials of 12 ounce containers. Soft drinks . The consumer savings from a shift to returnables depends strongly on the postban container size pattern. In the 12 ounce size, according to Appendix A, the per ounce price in cans is 1.4c and the comparable 10-12 ounce returnable bottle price is 1.26c, while in the 26-32 ounce size the price in one-way bottles is 1.2c per ounce compared to .85c per ounce in returnables. If all sales in one-way containers were in the large sizes, consumer costs would decrease by 29 per cent, while if all sales were in 12 ounce one-way containers costs would decrease by 10 per cent. It is assumed that two-thirds of soft-drink sales are in the smaller sizes for which the 10 per cent reduction applies, and one-third of sales are in the larger sizes for which the 29 per cent reduction applies. 1+1 This is a somewhat larger proportion for the large sizes than is found in the 1967 data on soft-drink shipments by container size for Minnesota [9, p. 194], but the shift is assumed only to affect the approximately 50 percent of soft-drink sales which are for home consumption [10, p. 30]. It is also assumed that three-fourths of can sales are in national brands, for which the 10 percent consumer cost reduction would apply, and that three-fourths of one-way bottle sales are national brands, for which the 29 percent consumer cost reduction would apply. No cost reduction is assumed for the one- fourth of sales in cans and one-way bottles assumed to be accounted for by local and controlled brands. It is assumed that all returnable sales are in national brands. These figures are set out in Table 10 and the estimated soft drink sales for 1972 with and without a ban on returnables are presented. Soft irink sales are estimated to be $40 million without a ban on one-way containers, and $36.12 million with a ban, indicating consumer savings from a ban of almost $4 million for soft drinks. This estimate of $4 million in consumer savings does not assume any savings for consumers of local or controlled-brand soft drinks, nor does it assume any savings except for the home market. There may be additional savings for customers of vender and restaurant and other on-premise sales , but these are assumed not to be passed on to the consumer". kz d) en cfl o rH cfl •u en o >n H 0) 3 T3 •H 3 cO CO 4-J c •u o CU u X U >•, co CO s 3 CU 0) S 3 o o PC B. c CO u o ^ o -P 14-1 c w CO o en pq Ph cu rH CO T3 cfl 3 co 6 o CO T3 U •> 3 IW X) CO CU 0) 4-J »* M CO 0) 3 o •H •H s > 4-1 3 CO co o cn w u M CN ai CU r-> PL, e a> 3 H cu co CJ 3 •H o « )-i c_> CO P-i 4-J T3 O •» CU co a) *J CU g CO c 3 a c rH •H •H o 4-1 s > CO w ^ 3 •H * }-l CO a CU H ■u CO <4-l CO o CO o H cu rH X> CO H X> ■P W o Ph CO 3 1-4 3i 4-i CU ►, CO cfl a) 3 rH 1 4-1 CU 4J C o o x> rH vO LT| m CO CN 1 • • S • 1 o 1 o CO rH H 1 rH /— V *~^ ^^ H a> CO CTv in 00 in en 1 1 1 oo 00 ti CO i— i m 1 1 1 cfl CU SH P4 vD ■ • CN 00 m >> X> cn cn m 1 1 1 CN r^. • • • 1 1 1 • • rH cn cn rH <-\ CO a CU . 1 CO 1 1 X cO 3 u CU 3 M 4-J !-i CU CO cd rH i>, CO CO CU 3 rH 1 4-1 CU 4-1 c o O X cn cn cn i cn oo i oo I rH m m o r-» cn o ct\ cn cn SO CN I • I in oo X> CN 00 m co CD CJ c 3 o c co •o- CO o 13 T3 •H 3 0) 3 rH cO co CJ cO co rH u T3 3 rJ T3 •H X 3 3 X 3 X CO o cO rH !H rH >-l 3 cfl X rH u cfl Xi •H 3 CO CU 3 o SH ■U & O r4 CU •H CU O •H CU e ■U X H CU 4-> J3 3 cO 4-1 o Cfl 4-1 rH 2 O •H 53 O o rJ > p-l w cj o •H H H •H s -69- in m « i o 1 o m cn l m m m O rH rH ON CN rH m m vO CN oo CN CM CO ON •H • 1 • 3 • • rH CN CN O MD CO H ■H 3 •H rH cfl a rH ■H CJ -69- vO vO ^a cn M N ^< eg 1 CN cn C • 1 • • CQ w rH rH CO 00 CO bJ3 CU (U TJ 3 rH rH 3 •H cfl 4-1 cfl f> CO 4-1 cO O < CO 0) CO X CO r4 cfl M • CU CD CO u 3 N CJ g T3 •H O •H R 3 rH u T3 w CO co Cfl •3 CN 3 3 V4 -3 4-J rH CU O PQ 3 o 4-1 CX O CO H Cr4 14-1 3- rH 1-4 o o 000 hours a year, this implies need for 476 additional full-time equivalent workers in retail stores. The next stage in distribution is at the wholesale distributer level. The function of moving beer from the brewer to the retailer is often handled in local beers by brewery employees and is usually handled for out-of-state beers by independent wholesale beer distributers. h9 Using the estimates of cases of beer distributed per employee from Table 13 based on the estimates of the Research Triangle Institute [3], and assuming that all locally brewed beer is distributed by brewery employees and all out-of-state beer is distributed by distributer employees, it is estimated that brewers will require 85 additional workers to distribute the 4.072 million cases of beer sold before the ban in one-way bottles, 262 additional workers to distribute the 10.74 million cases sold in cans. Wholesale distributers will require 29 additional workers for the 1.702 million cases of out-of-state beer sold in one-way bottles and 107 additional workers for the 4.495 million cases sold in cans. Thus an estimated total of 483 additional workers will be required in distribution of beer. Soft drink bottlers will require 203 additional workers in distribution to handle the estimated 8.33 million additional cases of returnables which were formerly in cans, and 145 additional workers to handle the 6.94 million cases formerly in one-way bottles. Thus 348 additional workers will be required by bottlers in the distribution of soft drinks. The next stage is the bottling of beer and soft drinks. Labor requirements are somewhat higher for returnables than for one-way containers. Labor costs for packaging are estimated at 30.77c a case for returnables, 19.27c a case for one-way bottles, and 8.82c a case for cans [7]. Estimating labor cost for a line worker at $4 an hour, leads to estimates of .0769 man-hours per case of 50 Table 13- Cases Distributed Per Man-Year of Employment Soft Drink Bottlers, Brewers and Beer Distributers Cases distributed per man-year Returnables NR Bo t tles Cans Beer distributers 16,710 25,350 27,750 Brewers 16,740 25,390 27,770 Soft drink bottlers 16,300 24,720 27,040 Source: Tayler H. Bingham and Paul F. Mulligan, An Analysis of the Beverage Container Problem with Recommendations for Government Policy , pp. A-106, A-108 (Research Triangle Park, North Caro- lina: Research Triangle Institute, 1972). 51 returnables, 0.0482 man-hours per case of one-way bottles, and 0.022 man-hours per case of cans. This indicates that local brewers will require 58 additional line workers for the beer formerly in one-way bottles and 293 line workers for the beer formerly in cans. This additional employment is expected to occur in Minnesota. In addition, out-of-state brewers will require 24 workers for the beer formerly in one-way bottles and 123 workers for the beer formerly in cans. Soft drink bottlers will require 100 additional workers for the soft drinks formerly in one-way bottles and 227 additional workers for the soft drinks formerly in cans. The remaining employment effects are the direct and indirect effects resulting from the reduction in purchases of packaging materials. Most of these costs arise in can and bottle production, and the small effects in miscellaneous industries including the production of labels, adhesives, and detergents are ignored here. Koch estimates that costs of crowns, cartons, and glass for beer in one-way bottles is 75.33c per case. This amounts to $4.35 million for the one-way bottles replaced by returnables [7] . He also estimates the cost of cans and lids for beer at 98.23c per case, or $14.96 million for the beer in cans replaced by returnables. Using the same figures for soft drinks, a reduction in purchases of crowns, cartons, and glass of $5.23 million for soft drinks formerly in one-way bottles and a reduction of $8.18 million for soft drinks formerly in cans is obtained. Aggregate reductions in packaging purchases for cans and lids is about $23.8 million and for glass packaging about $9.6 million. 52 The shift of beverages to returnables will entail costs for returnable beverage bottles. There will be an important impact effect in glass container manufacture as "bottlers and brewers build up their inventories and float, but this is not examined. The process will be important in cushioning the employment effects in the glass container industry. Assuming that a returnable beer bottle costs 3.5c and a returnable soft-drink bottle costs 10c and that trippage is twenty for each of these containers, the glass costs of k.2 cents per case of beer leads to total costs of $840,000 and the glass costs of 11.4c a case for soft drinks leads to glass costs of $1,741,000 for containers to replace the one-way bottles and cans. Thus approximately $2.6 million a year of returnable container losses changes the reduction in glass spending from the $9.6 million estimated above to $7 million. Thus the net reduction in container costs is estimated to be $30.8 million. To estimate the direct and indirect employment effects of this reduction in purchases of cans and bottles by the beverage industries input-output analysis is used. A similar analysis has already been carried out in the Illinois study [1], and the results of that study can be adapted for use here. The estimated reduction in can spending in Illinois was $88 million, so the $23.8 million reduction in Minnesota will lead to employment effects that are 27 per cent as large as those estimated for Illinois. The estimated reduction in glass purchases of $7 million in Minnesota is 54.26 per cent of the estimated Illinois reduction of $12.8 million. The direct and indirect 53 employment effects of the reduction in cans and bottles are given in Table lU. Summary of the direct and indirect employment effects is as follows: Reductions in employment Metal cans 433 Glass containers 301 Indirect effects from metal cans 806 Indirect effects from glass containers 118 Total reductions 1,658 Increases in employment Retail trade 671 Beer distribution 483 Soft-drink distribution 348 Beer bottling 498 Soft-drink bottling 327 Total increases 2,327 Net increase in employment 669 These estimates are not complete, but they include most of the major effects. One specific omission is a reduction in solid waste handling and litter collection which might run to 200 or 300 jobs. In addition to these measured effects in the directly concerned industries consumers can be expected to spend the $18 million consumer savings. If they spend some of this on more beverages, 5h Table 1^. Estimated Direct and Indirect Employment Effects of Reduction in Can and Bottle Purchases as a Result of the Ban, Minnesota Input-output Industry (SIC Code) industry Glass containers (322 ) Metal cans (3411) Coal mining (11, 12) 7.0 Petroleum & gas(1311,2) 8.0 Stone fie clay (141, etc) 9.0 Paper mills (2611) 24.02 Paperboard mills (2631) 24.03 Paperboard ctnrs (265) 25.00 Comm. printing (2751,2) 26.05 Ind'l chemicals (281) 27.01 Paints (2851) 30.00 Petr. ref. (2911,299) 31.01 Abrasive prod. (3291) 36.16 Basic steel (331) 37.01 Prim, aluminum (3334) 38.04 Alum, rolling (3352) 38.08 Railroads (40,474) 65.01 Motor freight(42,473) 65.03 Water transport (44) 65.04 Elec. util. (491, pt. 493)68. 01 Gas util. (492, pt. 493) 68.02 Wholesale trade (50) 69.01 Credit agencies (61,67) 70.01 Misc. bus. serv. (73,7694) 73.01 Advertising (731) 73.02 Employment reduction from Cans Bottles ) 433 23 4 3 23 61 17 18 4 379 3 12 62 39 16 7 6 89 5 33 301 8 7 2 29 21 2 4 10 3 6 16 2 8 Source: Derived from Hugh Folk, Employment Effects of the Mandatory Deposit Regulations , tables 8 and 9 (Springfield and Chicago: Illinois Institute for Environmental Quality. Document 72-1. 1972). 55 the glass reductions will be smaller and the increases in employment in beverage production and distribution will be larger. If the $18 million in consumer savings is spent on other commodities and services, it should have a direct and indirect employment effect of creating perhaps 1,200 jobs. This suggests that the total direct and indirect employment effects resulting from a ban on one-way containers could amount to an increase in employment of about 1,500 to 2,000 jobs. The increase in employment arises from the labor-intensive charac- ter of the returnable beverage container system compared with the one-way systems, but ultimately the increase in employment arises from the fact that wages are generally lower in the industries which are positively affected than in the industries which are negatively affected. There is no good way to identify the proportion of the increases and decreases which will occur within Minnesota. It is not debatable, however, that most of the increases in retail trade, distribution, and bottling and brewing that occur will occur in Minnesota. It is likely that most of the reductions in metal can and glass container manufacture will also occur in Minnesota, but it should be remembered that Minnesota is an important exporter of beer and that much of the exported beer going to other states will continue to be in one-way containers. The indirect reductions will probably be much less concentrated in Minnesota than are the direct reductions. 56 VI. Summary and Conclusions A ban on one-way containers can be expected to have significant effects on employment in industries involved in the production and dis- tribution of beer and soft drinks. It does not seem likely that a ban would lead to a decrease in total sales of beer or soft drinks or to in- creases in the prices of beverages in returnable bottles. The major effect of a ban would be to shift consumer buying from beverages in one- way containers to similar beverages in returnable s. Since beverages in returnable s are usually priced somewhat lower than the same brands in one-way containers, the shift would lead to a substantial cost saving for consumers, amounting to an estimated $18 million. The substitution of returnable containers for one-way containers would probably work to the advantage of local brewers and local nationally franchised brands and to the disadvantage of out-of-state brewers and the controlled and local brand soft drink bottlers. Significant employment decreases in can and bottle manufacture and in those industries which supply inputs to the can and bottle iudustries would result from the reduction in sales of containers to brewers and bottlers. Increases in employment in retail trade and in soft drink and beer production and distribution would result from the higher costs of bottling and transporting beverages in returnable containers. Aggregate reductions in employment would be about 1,658 jobs and aggregate increases in related industries would be about 2,327 jobs. In addition, consumer spending of the estimated $18 million of consumer savings would generate about 1,200 addition jobs, suggesting a net increase in employment of 57 1,500 to 2,00 jobs. Most of the increases in employment would occur in Minnesota, while many of the decreases, especially in indirectly related industries would occur outside of the state. This study does not purpose to be a complete study of the costs and "benefits of a ban on one-way containers. It does show, however, that the employment effects in net balance are not unfavorable. It must be recog- nized that the employment reductions are concentrated in the metal can and glass container industries. If a ban is adopted, a lead time of a year would be helpful in cushioning the employment impact of the ban and in permitting bottlers, brewers, and retailers to prepare for the changes which will take place. The occurrence of employment reductions concentrated in particular industries does not constitute a strong argument against legislation which is desirable on other grounds. The employment in the container industries is, in a very real sense, a substitute for employment in the beverage production and distribution industries which once were engaged in operating the returnable system. Changes in the industrial distribu- tion of employment are the normal consequence of economic growth and change, Changes such as those which will occur with the adoption of a ban on one- way containers can be readily absorbed in the economy as long as it remains vigorous and expanding. 58 REFERENCES American Can Company. Carbonated Beverages in the United States -- His- torical Review . 1972. American Can Company. A History of Packaged Beer and Its Market in the United States. New York, 1969. Beverage Industry Annual Manual. 1972-73' Bingham, Taylor H. and Mulligan, Paul F. An Analysis of the Beverage Container Problem with Recommendations for Governmental Policy. Research Triangle Park, North Carolina: Research Triangle Institute, 1972. Booz-Allen and Hamilton, Inc. Study of Distribution Practices in the Soft Drink Industry , 2 vols. Washington: National Soft Drink Association, 196^ Bottle Survey '71» A California Supermarket Report on the Cost of Hand- ling Returnable Soft Drink Bottles. LaHabra, California: Alpha Beta Acme Markets, 1971- Edwards, Tom. "Oregon Beer Sales Have Not Suffered Under New Deposit Law" Peoria Journal Star , January 5, 1973; PP- A- 11. Folk, Hugh. Employment Effects of the Mandatory Deposit Regulations . Springfield and Chicago: Illinois Institute for Environmental Quality Document 72-1, 1972. Folk, Hugh. U.S., Senate, Committee on Commerce, Statement in Hearings before the Subcommittee on the Environment , March o^ 10~j 13/1972 , PP' 298-301. Koch, Robert H. "Bottling Efficiency -- A Myth? " Brewers Digest, January 1970' Midwest Research Institute. The National Economic Impact of a Ban on Nonrefillable Beverage Containers. Kansas City, Missouri: Midwest Research Institute, 1971- United States Brewers Association, Inc. The Brewing Industry in the United States. Washington, D.C.: Brewers Almanac, 1970- 59 Appendix A Minneapolis -St. Paul Beverage Price Survey Prices are needed to carry out the consumer cost analysis. The limited time available for the study and limited resources restricted the price survey to the Minneapolis- St. Paul area. Package prices for major national brands (Coca-Cola, Pepsi Cola, and Seven-Up), local brands (Gold Medal and Tom Moore) and a controlled brand (Brimfull) were collected on the 26th and 27th of December by Ms. Jacquelyn M. Burke, Research Analyst, Minesota Pollution Control Agency, according to instructions of the author. An independent supermarket near the university campus an inner city chain supermarket, a chain supermarket in a middle-class suburb, a middle-class suburban stop-and-shop, a low-income neighborhood grocery, and a liquor store in a middle-class suburb were surveyed. For the beer sample, strong beer was priced in a middle-class suburban liquor store, an inner city liquor store, and a liquor store in a low-income area. The sample for 3*2 beer included a neighborhood grocery in a low income area, a grocery store near the university, and a middle-class suburban stop and shop. Prices were collected for two local premium brands (Hamm's and Grain Belt), two national premium brands (Budweiser and Schlitz), and a local regular beer (Buckhorn). Soft drink prices . Simple averages of prices by container type, brand type, and container size were calculated and are given in terms of price per ounce in Table A-l. 6o Table A-l Average Price of Soft Drink Per Ounce, by Size and Container Type Container size 64-48 26-32 16 10-12 6^-7 Returnable National (a) - .85 1.02 1.26 1.80 Nonreturnable National (a) 1.10 1.20 - 1.40(d) Local (b) 1.08 .86 - - Controlled (c) — - - •75(d) - a. Coca-Cola, Pepsi Cola, 7-Up b. Gold Medal, Tom Moore c. Brimfull d. Can 61 Beer prices. Beer prices were averaged by brand type, beer type, and container size, and average prices per ounce obtained are presented in Table A-2. Table A-2 Price of Beer Per Ounce, by Type and Container Minneapolis - St. Paul, December, 1972 (price in cents per ounce) Container type Returnable Nonreturnable bottle Can Container size 12 32 12 12 16 Strong beer Local premium 1.70 1.86 National 1.75 1.85 Local regular .99 — 3.2 Beer Local premium — 1.78 National — 1.84 Local regular — — 1.94 2.01 1.84 1.98 2.03 1.86 1.52 — 1.98 1.96 1.81 2.07 1.96 1.84 1.51 62 Appendix B Estimated 1972 Minnesota Beverage Sales by Container In the first half of 1972, according to the Minnesota Liquor Control Department, 1,194,944 31 gallon barrels of beer were taxed for sale in Minnesota. It is assumed that 1972 total sales will be twice this level, or 2,389,888 barrels. Assuming that the same proportion of 1972 Minnesota beer sales will be in packages as the 1969 proportion of packaged beer to total production in Minesota [12, Table 9], or 78.3 percent, 7-425 billion ounces of packaged beer will be sold. Assuming that the 1972 distribution of beer packages will be that estimated for the United States for 1972 by the Beverage Industry Annual Manual , 1972-73, Table 2, p. 23, or 59. 1 percent in cans, 22. 4 percent in one-way bottles, and 18.5 percent in returnable bottles, the estimated number of ounces of beer sold will be 4.388 billion in cans, I.663 billion in one-way bottles, and I.663 billion in one-way bottles, and 1-374 billion in returnable bottles. In 1972, an estimated 47 billion 12 ounce equivalent containers of soft drinks were sold, according to the 1972-73 Beverage Industry Annual Manual , Table 1, p. 23, of which 16.4 billion were in cans, 13.6 billion in one-way bottles, and 17 billion in returnable bottles. As- suming that Minnesota's share of 1972 sales were the same as its share of bottled soft drink shipments in the 1967 Census of Manufactures, or 1.22 percent, and that the package mix was the same in Minnesota as nationally, there were an estimated 200 million cans, 166 million one-way bottles, and 207 million returnable bottles of soft drinks sold in Minnesota. This is equivalent to 2.4 billion ounces in cans, 2 billion ounces in one-way bottles, and 2.5 billion ounces in returnable bottles. IDLIOGRAPHIC DATA HEET I. Kcpoii No. UIUC-CAC-DN-73-73 3. Recipient's Accession No. 1 ii U .in J .s,il>t tik' TWO PAPERS ON THE EFFECTS OF MANDATORY DEPOSITS ON BEVERAGE CONTAINERS 5- Report Date January "1973 Author(s) Hugh Folk 8. Performing Organization Kept. No - CAC-73 Performing Organization Name and Address Center for Advanced Computation University of Illinois at Urb ana -Champaign Urbana, Illinois 61801 10. Project/ Task/Work Unit No. 11. Contract/Grant No. . Sponsoring Organization Name and Address Llmois Institute for Environmental iality l>9 W. Washington St. dicago, Illinois 60606 Minnesota Pollution Control Agency 717 S.E. Delaware St. St. Paul, Minn. 13. Type ol Report Si Period Covered Research u. '. Supplementary Notes Abstracts Paper 1: The regulation requiring a five cent deposit on all beverage con- tainers proposed by the Solid Waste Management Task Force of the Illinois Institute for Environmental Quality for adoption by the Illinois Pollution Control Board can be expected to have significant employment effects. This report attempts to ident- ify and measure these employment efects using straight-forward economic impact analysis. Paper 2: This report attempts to identify the economic effects of a ban on nonreturnable containers and the measure the empact of a ban on consumer costs and employment in Minnesota. Most of the conclusions reached in this study would also apply to a mandatory deposit law which did not ban returnables. The Illinois analysis was based on the assumption that mandatory deposits would lead to an essentially complete shift from nonreturnable s to returnables. This is open to argument, and it can be expected that nonreturnable s would persist in some sales situations despite the imposition of a mandatory deposit. . Key Words and Document Analysis. 17o. Descriptors Beverage industry Nonreturnable s Litter Solid waste Mandatroy deposit 1b. Identif ieis/Opcn-I'ndcd Terms 'c. COSATI I ie Id/Group Avai!.u,,iny Statement No restriction on distribution. Available from National Technical Information Service, Springfield, Virginia 22151 19. V 1 uriiy Class (1 In Repi-rt) '7-'.l, A ^ll HP 20. Si. ut it y I la-.'. ( 1 Ins Pare r\< i v>HM D 21. No. ot Paucs Co 22. Price KIM n I is- «'j i ■> i. v . J- /. 1 HIS FORM MAY Ml! Kl PRODIX IP 'JSCOMM-OC 14^3-MjJ