POLITICAL ECONOMY BY HENRY CAREY BAIRD. IRE PRINTED FROM THE AMERICAN CYCLOPMJDIA.-] NEW YOEK: D. APPLETON AND COMPANY. 1875 . P OLITICAL EOOXOMY^ properly, an ex- position of the measures necessary for directing the moYements of society so that man may act in harmony with those natu- ral laws which control his efforts to improve his condition. Social science treats of the laws themselves. Prof. E. Thompson would substitute for the name political economy that of national economy. Great confusion exists not only in regard to the definition of political economy itself, hut as to the meaning of the various expressions used in treating of the subject, and even as to a general understanding of its scope, v^ome writers have treated it as a science, others as an art, and Sir James Steuart speaks of POLITICAL ECONOMY 2 it as a combination of the two. Mr. Senior considers it “ the science which treats of the nature, the production, and the distribution of wealth.” Archbishop Whatelv would give it the name of “catallactics, or the science of ex- changes.” J. E. McCulloch considers it “ the science of the laws which regulate the produc- tion of those material products which have exchangeable value, and which are either ne- cessary, useful, or agreeable to man.” Storch says it “is the science of the natural laws which determine the prosperity of nations, that is to say, their wealth and civilization.” Sismondi considers “the physical welfare of man, so far as it can be the work of govern- ment or society as the object of political econ- omy.” Say defines it as “the economy of so- ciety; a science combining the results of our observations on the nature and functions of the different parts of the social body.” John Stuart Mill considers it “ the science which treats of the production and distribution of wealth, so far as they depend upon the laws of human nature,” or “the science relating to the moral or psychological laws of the production and distribution of wealth.” The progress thus far made in political economy has been slow and uncertain, and in its entire range there is hardly a doctrine or even the definition of an important word which is accepted beyond dis- pute. In 1844 De Quincey acknowledged that it did not advance, and that from the year 1817 it had “on the whole been station- ary;” and he adds: “Nothing can be postula- ted, nothing can be demonstrated, for anarchy even as to the earliest principles is predomi- nant.” Amid all their discords and disagree- ments, it is possible to divide political econo- mists under two general heads: those who treat the subject as a deductive science, “ in which all the general propositions are in the strictest sense of the word hypothetical;” and those who treat it by the inductive method. Tiiey may also be divided into those who fol- low Ricardo with his fundamental doctrine of the theory of rent, and those who have given in their adhesion to Oarey’s law of the occu- pation of the earth. The adverse views as to the practical effects of the application of pro- tection and free trade are quite inadequate to serve the purpose of division, since many of the believers in one or the other of these doctrines quite disagree in regard to other and important questions. The discordant state of this so- called science therefore renders it necessary in this place to trace out the history of economic ideas, and to give an account of the views and opinions at present held by the adverse schools and their various teachers. — A science under- lying the art of political economy was quite unknown to the ancients, although they had brought under observation many facts which gave rise to true and valuable economic doc- trines. These doctrines or rules were how- ever quite empirical, isolated, and not elabo- rated into broad and far-reaching principles. and had in view far more the advancement of the state, its treasury, and its military power, than the prosperity, the happiness, and the freedom of the people. Nevertheless it is im- portant to recognize the fact of the origin of political economy in these early and imper- fectly stated doctrines. The ancient code of India, the Institutes of Mann, contains provi- sions as to the revenues, usury, &c. ; but these provisions are merely designed to establish and fix the respective rights and duties of the sov- ereign and his subjects, and of the subjects among themselves. In Attica agriculture was commended and encouraged, and the price of agricultural produce was generally low ; while the products of various branches of diversified industry were important, but the prices were generally high. Foreign trade was carried on extensively with the various countries on the shores of the Mediterranean and Black seas. Duties were levied upon foreign imports, but almost if not quite wholly with a view to the revenue of the state. Interest was high, and money was scarce and hard to procure. “ In every Greek state,” says Bockh, “ the finances were in the hands of the sovereign power ; and at Athens the legislation on financial matters belonged to the people, the administration of them to the supreme council. Then, as well as now, the administration of the finances was considered one of the most important branch- es of the public affairs, and the statesman who, like Aristides or Lycurgus, succeeded in pla- cing them in a flourishing condition, gained the good will of the people and tlie admira- tion of posterity.” The laws of Lycurgus deal with many economic questions, such as money, usury, taxes, lands, and the employment of the people ; but almost the sole idea through- out these laws is the establishment of the mil- itary power of Sparta. “ Lycurgus, or the in- dividual to whom this system is owing, who- ever he was,” says Grote, “ is the lawgiver of a political community ; his brethren live to- gether like bees in a hive, with all their feelings implicated in the commonwealth, and divorced from house and home.” The earliest treatise on an economic subject is believed to be “ The Eryxias, or About Wealth,” erroneously at- tributed to ^'Eschines Socraticus, a disciple of Socrates. Plato (“The Republic,” book ii.) calls attention to the necessity for separate employments, and in the opinion of Blanqui “ he has pointed out the advantages of a di- vision of labor with perfect clearness, and appears to us to take from Adam Smith the merit of this discovery.” He also regards the passage in which Plato conducts his reader to- ward a definition of money by tracing up the necessity, in a community of diversified em- ployments and wants, of “an established coin- age as a symbol for the purposes of exchange,” as most remarkable, partaking of the nature of most ingenious art. On the other hand, in the opinion of Say, Plato “ has with tolerable fidel- ity sketched the effects of the separation of POLITICAL ECONOMY 'f'iori is the legitimate mode of philosophical investi- gation in the moral sciences,” but “it is the only mode.” The a posteriori method, or that of specific experience, “is altogether ineffica- cious,” although it may be “ usefully applied in aid of the a priori?'' Therefore, “ since it is vain to hope that truth can be arrived at, either in political economy or in any other de- partment of the social science, while we look at the facts in the concrete, clothed in all the complexity with which nature has surrounded them, and endeavor to elicit a general law by a process of induction from a comparison of details, there remains no other method than the a priori one, or that of abstract specula- tion.” “ In all the intercourse of man with nature,” proceeds Mr. Mill, “ whether we con- sider him as acting upon it or as receiving im- pressions from it, the effect or i)henomenon depends upon causes of two kinds, the proper- ties of the object acting and those of the ob- ject acted upon. Everything which can pos- sibly happen, in which man and external things are jointly concerned, results from the joint operation of the law or laws of matter, and the law or laws of the human mind.” “ There are no phenomena,” he continues, “ which de- pend exclusively upon the laws of mind ; even the phenomena of the mind itself being par- tially dependent upon the physiological laws of the body.” Mr. Mill acknowledges that “the laws of the production of objects which constitute wealth are the subject matter both of political economy and of almost all the physical sciences;” but he considers that po- litical economy “presupposes all the physical sciences,” and adds that “it takes for granted that the physical part of the process takes place somehow.” In other words, it matters not to political economy why, how, or under what circumstances these laws of matter oper- ate. Mr. Mill’s design in writing his “Princi- ples of Political Economy ” was to produce “a, work similar in its object and general concep- tion to that of Adam Smith ; to exhibit the economical phenomena of society in the rela- tion in which they stand to the best social ideas of the present time.” He was a full be- liever in the views of Locke, Montesquieu, Hume, and Smith in regard to money ; in those of Ricardo on rent, and Malthus on population. He combats with much energy “protection- ism,” but holds that there is one, and only one case, “in which, on mere principles of politi- cal economy, protecting duties can be defensi- ble;” that is, “when they are imposed tem- porarily (especially in a young and rising na- tion), in hopes of naturalizing a foreign indus- try, in itself perfectly suitable to the circum- stances of the country.” Mill was long among the ablest and most distinguished supporters of the wage-fund theory, which, stated by him so lately as May, 1869, in the “Fortnightly Re- view,” is briefly as follows : “ There is supposed to be, at any given instant, a sum of wealth which is unconditionally devoted to the pay- ment of wages of labor. This sum is not re- garded as unalterable, for it is augmented by saving, and increases with the progress of wealth ; but it is reasoned upon as at any given moment a predetermined amount. More than that amount it is assumed that the wages- receiving class cannot possibly divide among them ; that amount, and no less, they cannot but obtain. So that, the sum to be divided being fixed, the wages of each depend solely on the divisor, the number of participants.” This theory, with Mill as its especial defend- er, was very vigorously attacked in 1866 by Francis D. Longe, a London barrister, in a pamphlet entitled “ A Refutation of the Wage- Fund Theory of Modern Political Economy ” (2d ed., 1869). In 1869 W. T. Thornton pub- lished a volume “On Labor, its Wrongful Claims and Rightful Hues,” in which he also assailed the wage-fund theory, but, as is be- lieved, by no means so ably as Longe had done. Mill, in the magazine article above cited, entirely recanted his belief in the the- ory, on the ground that Thornton had com- pletely refuted it. Hut Prof. Cairnes, among other English economists, has refused to ac- cept the acknowledgment of Mill as evidence of the falsity of the theory. A careful exam- ination of this theory Avill show that it is but an elaboration of the doctrine of Adam Smith 12 POLITICAL ECONOMY quoted above, to the effect that the demand for labor can only increase in proportion to the increase of the “funds destined for the pay- ment of wages.” — zlmong the most prominent of English political economists at the present day is Prof. J. E. Cairnes, whose most elabo- rate production, “ Some leading Principles of Political Economy newly Expounded,” was published in 1874. While the author says that it is “ an attempt to recast some' considerable portion of political economy,” he would “ be sorry it were regarded as in any sense antag- onistic in its attitude toward the science built up by the labors of Adam Smith, Malthus, Kicardo, and Mill.” “ Nor do the final con- clusions which I have reached differ very wide- ly on any important points from those at which they have arrived. The points on which I have ventured to join issue with them are what, in Bacon’s language, may be called the axiomata media of the science — those interme- diate principles by means of which the de- tailed results are connected with the higher causes, which produce them. If I have not deceived myself, there is in this portion of political economy, as at present generally re- ceived, no small proportion of faulty mate- rial.” Prof, W. Stanley Jevons, M. A., pub- lished in 1871 “ The Theory of Political Econ- omy,” in which he endeavors to construct a theory of the subject on a mathematical or quantitative basis, believing that many of the commonly received theories are perniciously erroneous. He treats political economy as the calculus of pleasure and pain, and he applies the differential calculus to wealth, utility, value, demand, supply, capital, interest, labor, &c. Prof. Henry Fawcett’s “ Manual of Political economy” (18G3), which has passed through several editions, is very decided in its advo- cacy of Ricardo’s theory of rent and Malthus’s of population. The book, like almost all of its school, treats solely of a science of wealth. While the author is in the fullest sense of the word a believer in the doctrines of Locke, Mon- tesquieu, and Hume in regard to the effect of the volume of money on prices, he maintains that the use of the various forms of credit and of checks and clearing houses may increase prices in a like manner with an increase in the vol- ume of money. He takes ground against the wisdom and expediency of Sir Robert Peel’s bank-charter act. (See Bank.) — Herbert Spen- cer has projected “Principles of Sociology,” as a part of his system of philosophy, the publica- tion of which was begun in 1860. In 1873 he published “The Study of Sociology.” “ Several years since,” says Prof. E. L. Youmuns, “Mr. Spencer foresaw the difticulty that would arise in working out the principles of social science, from a lack of the data or facts necessary as a basis of reasoning upon the subject, and he saw that before the philosophy could be elabo- rated these facts must be systematically and exhaustively collected;” and he quotes Spen- cer as early as 1859 to show how clearly he then “perceived the nnture, diversity, and ex- tent of the facts upon which a true social science must rest.” — Almost the entire existing school of English political economists advocate “ free trade ” as the rule of intercourse between nations. Exceptions may be named in the Rt. Hon. Sir John Barnard Byles, author of “ So- phisms of Free Trade and Popular Political Economy” (London, 1849; 9th ed., 1870), and Sir Edward Sullivan, “Protection to Native Industry” (London and Philadelphia, 1870). — Dr. Franklin is the earliest American politico- economic writer of whom we have any rec- ord; he published at Philadelphia in 1729 “A Modest Inquiry into the Nature and Necessity of a Paper Currency,” of which at a subse- quent period he said: “It was well received by the common people in general, but the rich men disliked it, for it increased and strength- ened the clamor for more money ; and as they happened to have no writers among them that were able to answer it, their opposition slack- ened, and the point was carried by a majority in the house.” This was followed by “ Obser- vations concerning the Increase of Mankind and the Peopling of Countries” (1751), other papers on paper money before and during the revolution, and various other productions. In some of these he maintained doctrines par- taking somewhat of those of the school of Quesnay; in others he is shown to have pre- sented in advance of Adam Smith views such as were elaborated and brought into promi- nence by that author. “ A Discourse concern- ing the Currencies of the British Plantations in America, especially with regard to their Paper Money,” published in Boston in 1740 and reprinted in Lord Overstone’s volume of “ Scarce and Valuable Tracts on Paper Currency and Banking ” (1857), is a valuable production, evincing much research. In a “Letter from a Gentleman in Philadelphia to his Friend in London,” published in 1765, known to have been written by John Dickinson, afterward president of Pennsylvania, and a member of congress during the revolution, the current of trade with the mother country, the extent to which that trade had exhausted the colonies of coin, the importance of an emission of paper money properly secured, the policy of pro- moting manufactures among themselves, and other questions of this character, are exam- ined. In 1791 appeared in Philadelphia “Po- litical Essays on the Nature and Operations of Money, Public Finances, and other Subjects, published during the American War and con- tinued up to the Present Y"ear,” by Pelatiah AVebster. These essays are full of facts, fig- ures, and vigorous reasoning. The author was a violent opponent of paper money, and espe- cially of its issue in the manner in which it had been done by the continental congress, almost without limit, and Avithout the neces- sary taxation to withdraw it from circula- tion. On Jan. 14, 1790, Alexander Hamil- ton, the first secretary of the treasury un- POLITICAL ECONOMY der the federal constitution, presented to the Iiouse of representatives a report on finance, which was followed on April 23 by one on duties upon imports ; Dec. 13, on public cred- it ; Dec. 14, on a national bank; Jan. 28, 1791, on the establishment of a mint; and Dec. 5, on manufactures. It would be dif- ficult to find, among all the state papers or treatises on political economy which appeared before the close of the 18th century, any pro- ductions of this character surpassing these in a thorough knowledge of the subjects, clear- ness and precision of statement, and logical exactness. The report of Alexander J. Dallas, secretary of the treasury, to the house of rep- resentatives, Oct. 17, 1814, on the national finances, and that of Feb. 12, 1816, in regard to a general tariff of duties, are among the able economic state papers which have emana- ted from this government. The “Addresses of the Philadelphia Society for the Promo- tion of National Industry” (1819), and “The New Olive Branch” (1820), subsequently with other papers collected and published under the title of “Essays on Political Economy ” (1822), by Mathew Carey, dealt almost entirely in facts, figures, and references to history; and thus Carey reached the conviction that “there is a complete identity of interest between agri- culture, manufactures, and commerce.” The first formal treatise on the subject written in the United States is Daniel Raymond’s “ Thoughts on Political Economy ” (Baltimore, 1820). The author endeavors, and with some success, to escajie from the complications and inconsistencies of the economists. His exam- ination of some of the arguments of Adam Smith in regard to stock are original, vigor- ous, and conclusive. John Rae, a Scotchman, published in Boston in 1834 a “Statement of some New Principles on the subject of Political Economy,” which has been quoted and highly commended by John Stuart Mill in his “ Principles of Political Economy,” and he says of it: “In no other book known to me is so much light thrown, both from principles and history, on the causes which determine the accumulation of capital.” — In 1835 appeared at Philadelphia an “Essay on the Rate of Wages,” the first of the works of Henry C. Carey. He took ground against regarding political economy as the science of wealth, and insisted upon considering its “great object” and “its chief claim to atten- tion the promotion of the happiness of na- tions.” This -was followed by his “Principles of Political Economy” (3 vols., 1837-’40), in which he holds that value is determined by the cost of reproduction, and that every improvement in the mode of producing any commodity tends to lessen the value of com- modities of the same description previously existing; that in all advancing countries ac- cumulated capital has a constant tendency to fall in value when compared with labor ; labor therefore steadily growing in its power to 13 command capital, and e converso the power of capital over labor as steadily diminishing; la- bor and capital in their combined action con- tinually producing a larger return for the same outlay, of which larger return an increasing proportion goes to the laborer, while the share of the capitalist diminishes in its proportion, but increases in amount, being taken from a larger yield. In 1848 appeared Mr. Carey’s work entitled “ The Past, the Present, and the Future.” Its object was that of demonstrating the existence of a simple and beautiful law of nature in virtue of which the work of occupa- tion and cultivation of the earth had always of necessity begun upon the higher, drier, and poorer lands, passing thence, with the growth of wealth and population, to the lower and richer soils, with constant increase in the re- turn to labor. Here was a complete rever- sal of the doctrines of Malthus and Ricardo. In his “ Principles of Social Science ” (8 vols. 8 VO, Philadelphia, 185’8-’9), he most clearly draws the distinction between the science, which treats of the natural laws governing the subject, and the art, political economy, by means of which the obstructions to the opera- tion of those laws may be removed. Lie de- fines his subject as being “the science of the laws which govern man in his efforts to se- cure for himself the highest individuality and the greatest power of association with his fel- low man.” The more numerous the differences in the demands of society, the more, complete becomes the development of the individualities of its members, the greater is the power of as- sociation and combination, the more rapid the progress, and the more perfect the responsi- bility for the proper use of the faculties which have been developed. Llere, as everywhere, it is shown that in variety there is unity, and that the nation which would have peace and harmony at home and abroad must adopt a policy which shall develop the infinitely va- rious faculties of its people — the plough, the loom, and the anvil working together, each for the advantage of the others. The social laws are thus, according to Carey, identical with those which govern matter in all its various forms ; differences everywhere exciting forces, forces exciting heat in matter and impulse in mind, and heat and impulse reexciting motion. Nature’s laws being thus universal, the branch- es of science constitute but one great and har- monious whole, the social parts demanding the same methods of study and investigation. The methodical study of nature does, and of neces- sity must, take the place of the metaphysical. The third chapter of the book is devoted to an exposition of the great series of changes which the earth must undergo in furnishing the resi- dence and support of vegetable, animal, and human life in the order of their respective ap- pearances upon it, the relation and dependence of their various subsistence upon each other, and the circulation of the common elements of their structure, beginning with the disinte- POLITICAL ECONOMY grated rock in its simplest forms, and thence ascending through vegetable and animal organ- isms to that of man, in which their greatest complexity and highest sphere are reached, and whence they are again set free to pass through that never ending circuit which constitutes the entire organic and inorganic creation, one per- fectly balanced system of universal exchange ; an incessant flux of the forms of matter in their ascent from the simple to the most com- plex, adjusted precisely to the growing require- ments of the successive orders of being in the great scale of vital development, the higher forms of being never outgrowing or overtop- ping the lower from which they spring, and to which they must of necessity return. Such are the reciprocities of motion, force, and func- tion, in which Carey finds an order and a sys- tem which, as he believes, put to flight the doc- trine of discords and disproportions announced by Malthus, and since adopted by so many of the economists of Europe. A chapter on the new doctrine of the occupation of the earth, already referred to, is followed by one devoted to an examination of the question of value. Utility, according to Carey, is the measure of man’s power over nature. All the utilities de- veloped centre themselves in man, with con- stant increase of his power, and as constant decline of values, which are but the measure of nature’s resistance to the gratification of man’s desires. Wealth consists in man’s power to command the always gratuitous services of nature. Production consists in directing the forces of nature to the service of man. Every act of consumption is also an act of pro- duction, water being consumed in the produc- tion of air, air being consumed in the production of water, both being consumed in the produc- tion of plants, which in their turn are consumed in the production of men and animals, all of which are finally resolved into the elements of which they are composed, to go their round again in the reproduction of plants, apimals, and men. Capital is the instrument by the aid of which the work is done, whether existing in the form of land and its improvements, ships, ploughs, mental development, books, or corn. Trade is the performance of exchanges for other persons, and is the instrument used by commerce, which consists in the exchange of services, products, or ideas by men with their fellow men. As men are more and more en- abled to associate, commerce increases, but the power of trade declines ; the growth of the one being here, as in the case of utility and value, in the inverse ratio of the other. Money is re- garded as the great instrument of association, power growing everywhere with increase in the ability to command the services of the precious metals. Price is the value of a com- modity as measured by money. Prices of land, labor, and all raw materials tend to rise with every increase in the power of associa- tion, that increase being attended by decline in the prices of finished commodities. They tend therefore to approximate, and it is in the closeness of that approximation that Carey finds the highest evidence of advancing civili- zation. In his opinion trade appears first, to be followed by manufactures; and it is not until the latter have been develoi)ed, and a market has been thus made in the neighbor- hood of the farm, that any real agriculture makes its appearance. The more complete the development of diversified industries, including agriculture, the greater is the tendency toward an influx of the precious metals, which like other raw materials tend always toward those places at which finished commodities are cheap- est. Circulating notes diminish the value of the precious metals, but increase their utility, with constant diminution in the rate of inter- est, and equally constant increase in the tenden- cy toward equality among men, and strength in the communities of which they are a part. The power of accumulation is in the direct ratio of the rapidity of the societary movement. Pow- er grows with every increase in the numbers that can obtain food from any given space; and here we reach the law of population pro- pounded by Carey. Agriculture, as has been seen, becomes more productive as men are more and more enabled to combine. The more they can combine, the less is the waste of hu- man power in the search for food, and the less the muscular effort required for producitjg any given effect; the locomotive of civilized soci- ety doing the work that in savage life is done by the shoulders of the man, and the great steam mill grinding the grain that before had required the severest labor. Vegetable food is largely substituted for animal food ; the ten- dency toward this substitution being always greatest in those communities in which grow- ing wealth most manifests itself in the clear- ing, drainage, and culture of those rich soils which, according to Ricardo, are cultivated when men are poor, wmak, and scattered, but which, according to Carey, are last brought under human power, tlieir very wealth forbid- ding their occupation by the early cultivator. The more perfect the development of the la- tent powers q| the earth, and the greater the development of man’s peculiar faculties, the greater is the competition for the purchase of labor, the greater is the freedom of man, the more equitable is the distribution of the prod- ucts of labor, and the greater is man’s feeling of responsibility for his action in the present and of hope in the future. The higher that feeling, the greater the tendency toward matri- mony as affording the means of indulging af- fection for wife and children, and the love of home. The Malthusian theory Carey holds to be irreconcilably inconsistent with the real laws of nature as seen in the occupation of the earth, and the relative powers of increase in vegeta- ble life and in the lower forms of animal life and in man. The sphere of action of govern- ment in directing the commerce of the state is strictly limited to the removal of the obstacles POLITICAL ECONOMY 15 to perfect combination and association. Real freedom of trade consists in the power to main- tain direct commerce with the outside world. To reach it there must be a diversity of em- ployments, enabling the exporting country to send its commodities abroad in a finished shape. Centralization, such as is established by the British system, is opposed to this, and therefore it is that that system is resisted by all the advancing communities of the world, they being enabled to advance in the precise ratio with their power to resist it. Protection being the form assumed by that resistance, its object may be properly defined as being that of establishing perfect freedom of commerce among the nations of the world. Societary organization furnishes additional evidence of the universality of nature’s laws, for through- out her realms dissimilarity of parts furnishes conclusive evidence of the perfection of the whole — the highest organization presenting the most numerous differences. The higher the organization the more complete the subordina- tion of parts, and the more harmonious and beautiful their interdependence ; and the more complete that interdependence the greater the individuality of the whole, and the more per- fect the power of self-direction. In 1873 Mr. Carey published “The Unity of Law as exhib- ited in the Relations of Physical, Social, Men- tal, and Moral Science.” The writers who have adopted in whole or in part the doctrines of Carey, and have published books or papers on the subject, are: in the United States, E. Peshine Smith, “A Manual of Political Econo- my ”(1853); Dr. William Elder, “Questions of the Day, Economic and Social ” (1870) ; Robert Ellis Thompson, “ Social Science and Nation- al Economy” (1875); in Germany, Prof. Eu- gene Duhring of Berlin, Carey'' s Umwdlzungder Volhswirthschaftslehre and Socialwissenschaft (1865), Gayital und Arheit^ neue Antworten avf alte Fragen (1865), Die Verhleinerer Ca- rey'' s und die Krisis der Nationalolconomie (1867), Kritische GescJiichte der Nationaldlco- nomie und des Socialismus (1871), and Cursus der National- und Socialokonomie p873); in France, M. de Eontenay, M. Ra|[pi^, and M. Clapier ; in Italy, Signor Ferrara,"late min- ister of finance and editor of Biblioteca delV economista. — American writers other than those ' already named are Prof. Francis Bowen, Con- dy Raguet, Prof. Way land. Prof. H. Vethake, George Opdyke, Prof. Amasa Walker, Prof. A. L. Perry, and David A. Wells. Prof. Bowen published in 1856 “ Principles of Po- litical Economy,” which was revised and re- published in 1870 under the title “American Political Economy, including Strictures on the Management of the Currency and Finances since 1866.” He says with much truth : “ The entire science of English political economy may be said to be built upon three leading theories, that of Adam Smith concerning free trade, that of Malthus in regard to population, and that of Ricardo in regard to rent.” In none of these does he agree with the English school, although he recognizes that they con- tain a mixture of truth and falsehood. Condy Raguet was a decided follower of the English school, especially in regard to free trade and the theory of money. Profs. Way land and Vethake mainly followed the English writers. Mr. Opdyke believes that “free trade, abso- lute, unconditional free trade, and direct tax- ation, is the true policy of all nations, and of each nation regardless of the course pursued by all others.” He holds that bank deposits payable on demand are money, and is opposed to paper money made convertible with coin, but thinks that the government of the United States should issue inconvertible paper money to the amount of $10 a head of the population, which should circulate in common with coin, each being equally a legal tender. These views were promulgated in 1851 in “A Treatise on Political Economy.” In 1866 Dr. Amasa Walk- er published “The Science of Wealth, a Man- ual of Political Economy, embracing the Laws of Trade, Currency, and Finance,” which has been repeatedly revised and republished. Dr. Walker is a decided adherent of the views of Montesquieu and Hume on money, holds to Ricardo’s theory of rent, but not to Malthus’s law of population, and is strongly in favor of free trade. Prof. Perry published his “ Ele- ments of Political Economy” in 1865, and it has passed through several editions. He re- gards the “word wealth” as “the bane of political economy,” “the bog whence most of the mists have arisen which have beclouded the whole subject.” He adds that the defini- tion given by Archbishop Whately, “the sci- ence of exchange,” or “its precise equivalent, the science of value, gives a perfectly definite field to political economy.” Value, he holds, “is always and everywhere the relation be- tween two services exchanged,” while utility he regards as the “ capacity which anything or any service has to gratify any human desire what- ever.” In regard to Malthus’s law of popula- tion, he holds “that the alleged laws of nature in respect to the increase of population and food, which are said to be antagonistic, have never yet been proved.” In regard to distri- bution he says : “ I wish at this point to bear testimony to his (Carey’s) great merit as the original discoverer of the beautiful law of dis- tribution, in the light of which the future con- dition of the laboring classes of all countries, if they are only true to themselves, seems hopeful and bright.” In regard to the occupa- tion of the earth and to rent, he takes a middle ground between Ricardo and Carey. On the subject of money he is a decided follower of Locke, Montesquieu, and Hume, and upon this and foreign trade is utterly opposed to the doctrines of the mercantile school of former days and the protectionists or the national school of the present. Mr. Wells has princi- pally devoted his attention to the subject of foreign trade, tariffs, and taxation generally, 1 () POLITICAL ECONOMY! 3112 062289852 and is fully in accord with the English school of the present time. — The names and doctrines of most of the leading economists of Great Britain and the United States, other than those who confine themselves to the examination of questions of finance and hanking, have been already mentioned. In this class Henry Dun- ning McLeod, Prof. Bonamy Price, R. H. Pat- terson, and R. H. Inglis Palgrave now hold a prominent position in England. The late Ste- phen Colwell of Philadelphia published in 18o9 (2d ed., 1860) “The Ways and Means of Pay- ment, a full Analysis of the Credit System, with its Various Modes of Adjustment,” which is still the most exhaustive examination of this entire field in the English language, giving both his own views and those of his prede- cessors, and a fuller and more complete state- ment of moneys of account than any previous writer. — In France, among the more distin- guished writers on political economy are Blan- qui, Tracy, Louis Say, Droz, Rossi, Cheva- lier, Dunoyer, Gamier, Baudrillart, Bastiat, Fontenay, Ooquelin, Faucher, Reybaud, and Wolowski. One of the most noted of these was Frederic Bastiat, whose works were pub- lished collectively after his death (6 vols., Pa- ris, 1855 ; new ed., 1862). He was a strong par- tisan of free trade, and a decided follower of Locke, Montesquieu, and Hume in regard to money, holding that “it is quite unimportant whether there is much or little money in the world. If there is much, much will be used ; if there is little, little is required; that is all.” His most important work is his Harmonies economiques (1850), maintaining the doctrine that “all legitimate interests are harmonious,” which he sought to demonstrate by doctrines greatly resembling Carey’s theory of value, and the consequent law of distribution, enunci- ated in 1837. Speaking of the law of distribu- tion, he says : “ Thus the great law of capital and labor, as regards the distribution of the products of their joint labors, is settled. The absolute quantity of each is greater, but the proportional part of capital constantly dimin- ishes, as compared with that of labor.” It need hardly be added that he took issue with the theories of Ricardo and Malthus. M. Michel Chevalier has principally devoted himself to the questions of policy growing out of inter- national trade, and is a thorough partisan of free trade, having taken a leading part in the reciprocity treaty between Great Britain and France in 1860. — Germany has produced many works on all branches of the subject. The formation of the German Zolherein or customs union, establishing entirely free inter-state trade among the states composing it, with such a policy as should protect their domes- tic production from external disturbance, was due to no man more than to Friedrich List. His “National System of Political Economy” (Stuttgart, 1841 ; English by G. A. Matile, Philadelphia, 1856) is built upon observation and history. “ Nationality,” says the English translator, “is the ruling idea of the book; but with his vigorous mind and clear intelli- gence, he enlarges it until it comprehends every topic of human welfare.” “The Ger- man eclectic works,” says Colwell, “ furnish a vast amount of well arranged information, and they may always be consulted with advantage. We would refer,” he adds, “especially to the works of Schmalz, Jakob Volgriiff, Krause, K. H. Rau, Lotz, Hermann, and Schon; but there are others of equal merit.” To these names may be added K. A. Struensee, K. F. Nebenius, J. G. Busch, Schdnberg, Wappaus, Schaflle, Scheel, Hermann, Walcker, and Bren- tano. — In Italy much attention has been given to political economy from an early period, and a collection of Italian economists in 50 vols. 8vo was published at Milan in 1803-’! 6. The Biblioteca delV eeonomista^ another collection of Italian and foreign writers, edited by Fran- cesco Ferrara, professor of political economy in the university of Turin, and an adherent to the school of Adam Smith, has been for several years in course of publication. “In 1764,” says Say, “Genovesi commenced a public course of lectures on political economy from the chair founded by the care of the highly esteemed and learned Intieri. In consequence of his example, other professorships were af- terward established at Milan, and more recent- ly in most of the universities in Germany and Russia.” The disciples of the most recent school of political economy in Italy treat it as a science of observation based on the in- vestigation and study of history and actual life, and reject the notion that it consists sim- ply of deductions from the principle of indi- vidual interest. The first number of their monthly periodical, entitled Giornale degli economist^ appeared in Padua in April, 1875. Among the leading members of this school are Luzzatti, Lampertico, Forti, and Boccar- do. — Among the best books of reference on this subject are: “History of Prices, 1793 to 1856,” by Thomas Tooke (6 vols. 8vo, Lon- don, 1838-’57), which argues strongly against the theory of the economists in regard to the effect of aij, increased volume of money on prices, as maintained by Locke, Montesquieu, and Hume ; “ The Literature of Political Econ- omy,” by J. R. McCulloch (London, 1845) ; Dictionnaire de Veconomie politique (2 vols. 8 VO, Paris, 1852-’3), a most complete, trust- w'orthy, and valuable w^ork ; Histoire de Veco- nomie politique, by A. Blanqui (4th ed., 2 vols. 12mo, Paris, 1860), containing a catalogue rai- sonne of political economy, wTiich is full and valuable; “ A Dictionary of Political Economy, Biographical, Historical, and Practical,” by Henry Dunning McLeod (vol. i., London, 1863) ; “History of Agriculture and Prices in Eng- land,” by J. E. T. Rogers (2 vols. 8vo, 1866); Dilhring, Kritische Gescliichte der Nationalo- Iconomie und des Socialismus (Berlin, 1871); and Roscher, Gescliichte der Kationalohono- mie in Deutschland (Munich, 1874).