CJ 85 ^|.T6 Copy 1 The Numismatic and Antiquarian Society of Philadelphia SOME MODERN MONETARY QUESTIONS VIEWED BY THE LIGHT OF ANTIQUITY A PAPER REAIJ BEFORETHE SOCIETY APRIL i 18 BY ROBERT NOXON TOPPAN PHILADELPHIA PRINTED FOE THE SOCIETY 1880 INTERNATIONAL COINAGE, c cii B Ui V O a o bfi rt ca W {h w-i T3 rt £ 'S p ID u CO 3 O T3 C He* -a an i=5 Pi CU S-i g W o S b0 bO C O rP cu CU e 4J be cu -j— > CU as It CU CU ^ 8 1 Ph ks p. ^ as .s ri ^ 'o > ^3 > bfi in o -J u CO OJ (U T3 rt o CJ eg o g rt g J-H bJD C o aS PI o o -. CJ3 en •--! Pi ^ P! O ■ V P! o g S-i bo P. 00 Tj (U o -^r ^ & 3° id aS cu 1-4 ^ en p 1 a! 2 g a Ph / The Numismatic and Antiquarian Society of Philadelphia SOME MODEM MONETARY QUESTIONS VIEWED BY THE LIGHT OF ANTIQUITY A PAPER READ BEFORE THE SOCIETY APRIL i 1880 BY u/ ROBERT NOXON TOPPAN PHILADELPHIA PRINTED FOR THE SOCIETY 1880 CTsS The Numismatic and Antiquarian Society of Philadelphia. FOUNDED JANUARY ist, 1858. OFFICERS. 1880. PRESIDENT. ELI K. PRICE. VICE-PRESIDENTS. WILLIAM S. VAUX, WILLIAM P. CHANDLER, EDWIN W. LEHMAN, DANIEL G. BRINTON, m.d. CORRESPONDING SECRETARY. HENRY PHILLIPS, Jr. RECORDING SECRETARY. J. HAYS CARSON. TREASURER. HENRY PHILLIPS, Jr. HISTORIOGRAPHER. CHARLES HENRY HART. CURATOR OF NUMISMATICS. ROBERT COULTON DAVIS. CURATOR OF ANTIQUITIES. PHILIP HOWARD LAW. LIBRARIAN. FRANCIS JORDAN, Jr. SOME MODEM MONETARY QUESTIONS VIEWED BY THE LIGHT OF ANTIQUITY Mr. President and Members of the Numismatic and Antiquarian Society of Philadelphia : — The two pieces of money of antiquity exhibited this evening — one the gold stater of Alexander the Great, the other the gold de- narius, or as it is generally called the aureus, of Augustus — suggest some facts in regard to ancient coinage, which it will be well for us to consider with attention, as they have a practical bearing upon some of the monetary questions of the present time. As is well known to the members of this Society, the progressive steps in com- mercial intercourse were, first, direct barter, then a selection of a common medium of exchange, such as cattle or food of some kind, and finally the adoption of a metal which, being in its nature dur- able, easily divisible and of intrinsic value, was found by experi- ence to be the best medium. The selection of the metal depended, of course, upon the locality. In Lydia, where gold abounded, that metal was naturally used and became the standard of values. In Greece, where the silver mines were worked for many centuries, silver became the medium of exchange. In Sicily and Italy, where copper was very abundant, that metal was used and became, of course, the standard of values. When commerce between nations was developed — between nations having different metallic systems of money — the relative values of the different metals adjusted themselves, from time to time. The intrinsic value of gold was found to be superior to that of silver, and the value of silver superior to that of copper. A pound of gold was worth several pounds of silver, and a pound of silver many pounds of copper. The relation, however, between the three metals was never permanent, as was natural. Sometimes the gold mines produced more, sometimes less metal. Sometimes the de- mand was greater, sometimes less. The same rule applied to silver and to copper. Where there is only one metal as the standard, there are only two elements of disturbance — the demand and supply. Where a bi-metallic system prevails, there are four elements of dis- turbance. Where a tri-metallic standard exists or could exist, there would be, of course, six elements to disturb the relation ; it could therefore never be fixed. Only, with all the variations, gold was always more valuable than silver, and silver more valuable than cop- per. This is a matter of so much importance at the present time, and the experience of antiquity bears so directly upon the monetary question that has agitated the country for the past few years, that I venture to give an extract from the recent publication of M.. Francois Lenormant, the French savant and authority in numismatics. In his work, published in 1878, called "La Monnaie dans FAntiquit§," Vol. I, page 173, he says : " On peut poser en principe que les an- ciens ne connurent pas la pretention irrealisable de ce qu'on a appele de nos jours la monnaie bimetallique ou le double 6talon. Chez eux l'on constate, au contraire, toujours le choix d'un seul m6tal adopts comme Stalon fondamental et regulateur de tout le systeme mon^taire. Seulement le m6tal choisi a vari6, comme il devait arriver necessairement, suivant les circonstances particulieres des contrSes et des 6poques." " We can lay down the principle that the ancients knew no- thing about the unattainable pretension of what is called at the present time bi-metallic money, or the double standard. On the contrary, we always find that they adopted one metal as the funda- mental standard, upon which was based their whole monetary system. The metal selected, however, varied, as must necessarily happen, according to the particular circumstances of the countries and of the periods." Language could hardly be stronger to condemn, by the light of experience, the attempt made recently to reinstate in its former position a metal which the force of circumstances has driven to a subordinate place, and if persisted in, it must lead to financial trouble. The same process that has been going on in Europe and America since the addition to the amount of gold in the world by the pro- ducts of California and Australia — the substitution of a gold basis for a silver one — can be distinctly traced in the monetary history of Rome, where the old copper standard was slowly displaced by silver as that metal became more abundant, from conquest and by com- mercial intercourse, and silver in turn yielded to gold when that metal became sufficiently abundant to supply the demands of com- merce, so that silver became subsidiary to gold, just as copper had become subsidiary to silver. Another lesson applicable to the present day can be learned from the weights of the ancient coins. The old idea of money being a valuable commodity, selected as a medium of exchange, its weight was naturally regulated by the standard weight of the country. Before the invention of what is called coinage, irregular pieces of metal were used as a medium of exchange, which passed by weight. At each transaction it was necessary to weigh the pieces, which were definite parts of the standard weight of the country. The same custom still prevails in some of the Oriental countries. For instance, where the Babylonian standard of weights existed, the pieces of metal used as money were definite unfractional parts of the Babylonian mina and talent. So many drachma pieces weighed a mina, and so many a talent. In all the various systems of antiquity we find the same rule. In Athens a hundred drachma pieces of silver weighed a miua, and six thousand a talent. We find the same thing in the Sicilian and Italian systems. Taking Rome as an example, the Aes, or As, as it is most generally called, which was the unit of the old system, weighed originally one libra or pound, divided into 12 ounces, and the subdivisions weighed 6, 4, 3, 2, 1 and J ounces. When the successive diminutions took place, the rule of adhering to a definite part of the pound was still followed. The first reduction is supposed to have taken place after the battle of Allia (390 B.C.) when the As became J of a pound, owing to the scarcity of money. During the war with Pyrrhus and Tarentum (279 B.C.) it was again reduced to ^ of a pound. In 269 B.C. to ^, and in 217 B.C., when Hannibal threat- ened Rome itself, it was again reduced to tV of the pound. There were two other reductions up to the time of Augustus, one in 89 B.C., making the As i^ and the. other tV of a pound. The same rule can be seen in the silver coinage. In the begin- ning 72 denarii were coined out of a pound of silver ; then 84 ; and afterwards Nero reduced the weight of the denarius so as to make 96 to a pound. In the gold coinage the same thing can be observed. Sylla issued an aureus, thirty of which weighed a pound, then 36, which rule Pompey followed. Csesar issued a lighter aureus, divided into 100 sestertii, 40 of which made a pound. Augustus diminished the weight slightly, so that 42 made the pound. The aureus of Nero weighed it, and that of Caracalla A of a pound. Con- stantine made his aureus, or as it is generally called the solidus (from which come the words sol and sou), of the same weight as the original silver denarius, so that 72 weighed a pound. The Merovingian kings, who built up their monarchy upon the ruins of Rome, made their solidus the A part of the Roman pound. It will be seen from these examples that the old idea of money, cor- responding to definite parts of the standard weight of the country, still prevailed, notwithstanding the fact that the silver money was constantly more and more debased, until finally even a trace of silver j i had almost entirely disappeared, and the imperial despotism had gradually accustomed men to consider the imperial effigy as alone giving value to the pieces of metal. If we now examine the monetary systems of modern times, we will find that the idea of coinage corresponding to the standard weight of the country was almost entirely lost sight of, until the French established their new metric system. For instance, the English sovereign, which is their unit, weighs 123 grains and t% of a grain — a fractional part of the Troy pound, which is the stan- dard weight for coins — so that it takes 46 sovereigns and x%% of a sovereign to weigh one Troy pound. To obtain an even number we have to take 40 Troy pounds, which are coined into exactly 1869 sovereigns. The American silver dollar of 412| grains is also fractional, so that out of the 5760 grains forming the Troy pound, 13 and It of a dollar are struck. The gold dollar, which was made the unit in 1873, weighing 25A grains, it requires 223 dollars and H of a dollar to make a pound. It is needless to give further examples. The French law of 1795, conforming the coinage to the new metric system, was Confirmed by the decree of 1803, when Napoleon was First Consul. The change was not simply metric, but also decimal, as before that time the duodecimal prevailed, 24 livres making a Louis d'Or. A five-gramme piece to fine was de- clared to be the unit, and was to be called a franc. In order to obtain an even 5 grammes, the livre tournois was slightly increased in weight and in value about *