, H HB 171 5'=Q--"U"'vers,ty Library Outlines of social economics, '"iii'iili'i I I II iiii Ill mil nil Mill mil I 3 1924 002 238 479 ■ Vjvjl trit) hb II 1.5" ^1 THE LIBRARY OF THE NEW YORK STATE SCHOOL OF INDUSTRIAL AND LABOR RELATIONS AT CORNELL UNIVERSITY 6 Q (y j^ i^ iy\m^m^ GAYLORD PRINTED IN U.SA The original of tliis book is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924002238479 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS BY GEORGE GUNTON AUTHOR OF "TRUSTS AND THE PUBLIC," "WEALTH AND PROGRESS," " PRINCIPLES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS," ETC. AND HAYES ROBBI NS DEAN OF THE INSTITUTE OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS PROPERTY OF LIBRARY NEW yr:^^ state scijool mmimi / :b laesr relations CORNELL UNIVERSITY NEW YORK D. APPLETON AND COMPANY 1900 p.f. . Copyright, igoo By George Gunton and Hayes Robbins PREFACE. This volume is especially adapted for study clubs, lit- erary and debating societies, and high schools. It may be used independently or, if desired, supplemented with Gunton's "Principles of Social Economics" chiefly, and other works to which reference is frequently made. It is believed that the method of arrangement will be found very practical. Dividing the subject into twenty- four distinct lessons, while it does not forbid a different division when circumstances may require it,, as in high school classes perhaps, makes it peculiarly well suited for clubs and societies holding weekly or bi-weekly meetings. By covering two topics each time, a club holding fort- nightly meetings would complete the course in six months ; so that this volume is a very convenient basis for a winter's work. School classes, which must make their work conform to the division of time by "terms," can easily subdivide or group these lessons according to their requirements. It should be clearly understood that the present volume is entirely complete in itself, and may be used without reference to supplementary text-books or other litera- ture. At the same time, for the sake of those who wish to go more deeply into the subject, references have been given in connection with each lesson to appropriate chapters and sections in Gunton's "Principles of Social Economics" and various historical and economic works. iii IV PREFACE To each lesson is appended a number of brief extracts from some of the suggested readings, and a series of questions on the topic, intended either for class work or in preparing programs for club meetings. Special attention is called to the extracts from sug- gested readings. These throw interesting and helpful side-lights on the study at every step, besides indicating the views held by various economists and historians of prominent reputation. A bibliography, giving the prices and publishers of every book quoted or referred to for collateral reading, appears as an appendix. There can be no more important group of subjects for study by young men and women throughout this coun- try, whether in school or out, than those treated in this volume. They deal with problems which lie at the root of intelligent, useful, American citizenship. Therefore, the constant eflfort in preparing this book has been to treat each topic in a clear and obvious fashion with familiar illustrations so that every step may be readily under- stood. Especially, the aim has been to give such practical applications of the laws and principles brought out that the reader will complete his study with a real "grip" on the meaning and merits of our increasingly acute eco- nomic, social, civil and municipal problems. This under- standing is far more important than to know the techni- cal details of government administration or the mechani- cal working of our political system. It is even more im- portant to young American citizens to-day than the schol- arship implied in a college degree. In fact, the safety and success of our free democratic institutions depend upon the education and good sense of the people on the great industrial and social questions which underlie and determine our opinions and action as citizens. CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE I. Meaning and Scope of Social Economics . . i II. How Industrial Life Affects Social Pro- gress 8 III. Wealth 17 IV. Production of Wealth 24 V. Causes of Production 29 VI. Factors and Methods of Production 36 VII. Factors and Methods of Production {Con.) 47 VIII. Consumption of Wealth 55 IX. Value or Price 62 X. Cost of Production 70 XI. Distribution of Wealth 81 XII. Wages 86 XIII. Wages {Continued') 94 XIV. Rent 105 XV. Interest 112 XVI. Profits 119 XVII. Socialism 128 XVIII. Socialism {Continued) 139 XIX. The Single Tax 154 XX. Cooperation and Profit-sharing 166 XXI. Labor Organizations 176 XXII. L,a.hor Organizations {Continued) 185 XXIII. Panics and Depressions 193 XXIV. Are We Really Progressing } 200 CHAPTER I. MEANING AND SCOPE OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS. I. Early fleaning of Economics. In entering upon the study of social economics it is necessary to have definite idea as to the meaning and scope of the sub- ject ; inchiding, first, the ground it covers ; second, its practical usefulness ; third, the point of view from which it should be considered. The word economics was first used by Aristotle, who meant the economics of the household, because in that early, patriarclial stage of societ}- the family was the real social group. So that, economics was the science of domestic economy. Later, with the development of po- litical institutions, economics was used as applying to the state, or the economies of government, and hence took on the name "political economy" as distinguished from household economy. Political economy was really intended to convey the idea of economy in tlie administration of government, that is, in the collection and expenditure of public reve- nues. This was the idea of Adam Smith, the so-called ''Father of Political Economy," who published the first great work on economics. "Tlie Wealth of Nations," in 1776. 2. flodern "Social" Economics. \Mth the de- velopment of industry and progress of civilization during the nineteenth century the subject has expanded and now inchules not merely the economy in public revenues 2 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS but the economy of the production and distribution of wealth, and, finally, everything which afifects the indus- trial and social welfare of the community. In this way it has outgrown the limits of the old name, political econ- omy, and has really become the science of "social" eco- nomics. 3. What It Includes. Social economics, then, in- cludes all questions which afifect the industrial and social welfare of the people. Politics is different from social economics, but depends upon it. Politics is public action. It is the public expression of the wishes or poHcies of the people, but these wishes and policies are usually based upon economic considerations. Economics is in reality the foundation of politics. Thus, for instance, whether it is the better statesman- ship to annex far-away islands or keep our hands off, to have a protective tariff or free trade, to have bimetal- ism or the gold standard, to have an eight-hour working day in factories or permit them to run as long as their owners may decide, to regulate the employment of wom- en and children or leave it entirely to competition, to have the government own the railroads and telegraphs or let them remain in private hands, to allow sweatshops in our large cities to continue or to suppress them by law, — these and a multitude of similar questions are properly political issues, but the wisdom of our decision regarding each of them depends upon understanding their effect on the daily life, welfare, conditions and char- acter of the people, and this knowledge is what social economics aims to give. Therefore, social economics is at the very basis of intelligent, useful citizenship, and to understand it is indispensable to good government where the people rule, as under democracy. MEANING AND SCOPE OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS 3 4. nany=Sided Questions. But the questions that arise in social economics are not always simple and easy to understand. Frequently they seem complex and puz- zling. There are always seemingly two sides to every question; as, for example, a labor strike. The laborer demands higher wages and shorter hours, because these will improve his condition. The employer sees it in an- other light. He objects, because the higher wages and shorter working day will increase the cost of running his establishment and for a time at least make it more diffi- cult to do business. So, too, when the legislature is asked to suppress sweatshops, it is urged to do so in the interest of humanity, health and decent industrial condi- tions. But, on the other side, it is urged that the poor people who work in these tenement houses, sweating and sweltering during sixteen or more hours a day for a mere pittance, will be deprived of the means of getting even that scanty livelihood if the law forbids sweatshops. We meet these differences of view on every hand. 5. Right Point of View. Therefore, it is neces- sary first of all to have a correct point of view from which to see these matters. Politics can never furnish this point of view. We must get it from social economics. The object of all government is the welfare and progress of the people. Therefore, the welfare of the people is the point of view from which all industrial and social prob- lems should be decided. To go one step farther, it may be said that the welfare of the public is best reflected in the welfare of the great wage-earning class, and their welfare is indicated in general by the amoimt of wealth and comfort and advantages of higher civilization that can be obtained for a day's work. Wealth of itself is of no account unless it is consumed and broadens the civili- zation and happiness of the community. 4 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS 6. The Great Test of a Public Policy. The real question to ask, therefore, in considering the majority of industrial or political propositions, is, how will it affect the opportunities and income of the laboring or wage- earning class? If the measure will tend directly or indi- rectly to improve their opportunities and increase their income, it will almost always increase the prosperity and improve the character of the whole community. What- ever helps the income of the laborers sooner or later pro- motes the possibility of profits in business and prosperity for all other classes. Indeed, the expenditures of the wage and salary earners furnish much the larger part of the market for the products of industry. There are two things which really indicate progress and improvement to the working class. One of these is a gradual cheapening of the necessaries, conveniences and comforts of life; the other is an increase in wages, without any lengthening of the working day. Whatever will promote either of these movements, by proper eco- nomic means, will promote the progress of society tow- ards a higher and better civilization. Industrial pros- perity is the soil in which all the superior phases of social life grow. Moral improvement, social culture, intellectual advancement, justice and integrity, broad altruism, and a high conception of human life, extending throughout the community generally, have their root in the subsoil of industrial welfare. 7. Definition. Consequently, the laws and condi- tions which govern industrial welfare are at the root of progress and improvement. Social economics deals with these laws and conditions. It is the science which treats of man as a producer and consumer of wealth. MEANING AND SCOPE OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS 5 SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," the Preface and Chapters I. and II. of Part I. ; discussing social progress and the law of social progress. Additional References. Address of Nicholas Murray Butler, Ph.D., before the graduating class of the Univer- sity of Michigan, June 22, 1899, on "The Education of Public Opinion." In Alfred Marshall's "Economics of Industry," Chap- ters I., IV., and V. of Book I.; defining economics, trac- ing the growth of economic science and showing its scope. In Arthtir T. Hadley's "Economics," Chapter I., on "Public and Private Wealth," including a sketch of economic science and pointing out standards of public welfare. In "My Young Man," by Rev. Louis Albert Banks, D.D., Chapter IX., on "My Young Man as a Citizen." EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Good and Bad Citi::cns. "The political vitality and in- tegrity of a modern state must rest, in the last instance, upon the character and clearness of the political opinions held by men who are without official station. No admin- istrative vigor and no legislative wisdom can long sur- vive in the vacuum of public ignorance and indifference. A supporting body of opinion is essential to the conduct of legislative or administrative policy, and a serious and high-principled opposition is necessary to prevent its exaggeration and abuse. . . . "Burke pointed straight at the typical bad citizen when he described those 'who think their innoxious indolence their security.' The man who submits to public imposi- tion to save trouble or trifling expense, or who pays to 6 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS be 'let alone/ or who, priding himself upon his integrity and business success, affects to 'despise politics,' is con- tributing his mite to the degradation of government and to the tearing down of the structure so laboriously and so painfully builded by the fathers. . . . "Are you politically alert? Are you politically honest? If not, you are a bad citizen and a corrupter, however innocent, of public opinion. If so, the standard which you set is a high one, worthy of imitation." — From ad- dress by Nicholas Murray Butler on "The Education of Public Opinion." Duty of Young Men. "The individual citizen has no right to be indifferent to the problems of citizenship. If this is true, then it is the duty evidently of every young man to look well to his own education in citizenship. A man ought to count himself ignorant and uneducated who does not have on his tongue's end a clear analysis of all the general conditions of the government under which he lives. ... I urge upon young men as a most solemn duty that they read books on political economy and on the functions of government, those comparing different forms of government, and especially those dis- cussing questions of municipal government. . . . An hour a day devoted to such subjects for the next year would make any young man a bright, wide-awake, well- informed citizen, capable of thinking about and discuss- ing the public issues of the day with intelligence, and able to find his way through the mists and haze of politics to sensible decisions. The country suffers terribly in its government because a great many of the best class of citizens, so far as reliability and character are concerned, fail to take that interest in politics, and in the conduct of the government, which they should." — From Rev. L. A. Banks' "My Young Man," Chapter IX. MEANING AND SCOPE OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS 7 QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What was the early meaning of "'economies'' and "political economy?" 2. Who was Adam Smith? What was his great economic work? 3. What broader aspect has economics gradually taken on? 4. How does social economics differ from politics? 5. What kinds of subjects and questions are included in social economics? 6. What is the great object of governments? 7. On what class of people does the welfare of the community chiefly depend? 8. How is the welfare of this class determined? 9. What is the great test to apply to proposed reforms or public policies? 10. What two movements or tendencies are necessary to the progress of the wage-earning class? 11. What is social economics? CHAPTER II. now INDUSTRIAL LIFE AFFECTS SOCIAL PROGRESS. 8. What Progress Is. We are accustomed to talk of progress as if everybody understood it, whereas few peo- ple have any clear idea of what progress really is. How shall we define it, then, so as to know it when we see it .'' Herbert Spencer has well said that progress is change, but all change is not progress. Then progress must be a change in a certain direction. Progress in a plant or ani- mals is a change of structure or formation towards a greater variety of parts or features, and a greater sub- division of special activities or "functions." This is true also of communities or races or nations of human beings. Progress is a change towards more com- plex relations and a larger variety of interests and ac- tivities. For example, wild tribes of savages probably represent the earliest form of society, meaning by "so- ciety" the human race associated together in groups, as communities, tribes, nations, et cetera. Among these wild tribes is very little variation in the habits, customs and duties of the people. Hunting and fishing and fighting for protection are practically the only tasks, and every- body does about the same things. In his "Origin of Civ- ilization," on the authority of the greatest investigators. Sir John Lubbock tells us that in some of the simplest tribes even family life does not exist at all. From this to our present state of civilization society has passed through numberless changes, towards greater INDllS'l'RlAl, LIFE AND SOCIAL I'ROCRKSS 9 vai'icty oi diilios, Icatliiig lo greater variety of action, ideas, tastes, habils, and qualities of eliaracter. In this process the intellect is sharpened, morals are developed, human sympathies expanded, and the social character of man elevated. In the earliest slai;e of society we generally find abso- lute tlespotisni antl chattel slavery. The members of the cununnnity must simply oi)ey the despot. With the growth of variety in occupations, interests and expe- riences we find t;'ro\vlh of intelIi,L;ence, desires for new privileges, and assertion of new rights, until gradually society is transformed from a despotism to a state of political and religious freedom, education, wealth and so- cial refinement. Progress is the change by which this great revolution t;ikes place. 9. Cause of Progress. What is the cause of this progress? How does it arise? We shall see as we pro- ceed that all these great changes in industries and poli- tics and social life have their rise in the necessities and desires of the ]ieople. Oespotism is overthrown and free government established by the expanding desires of the ])eopIe. Nearly always these at first relate to industrial interests or rights. If we study into the real causes of great movements, like the .\nierican Revolution or the overthrow of the Stuarts in England, decline of the feudal system, or the winning of magna charta, we find at bottom industrial iiiotircs. or else social motives arising out of industrial interests. These were the moving caiLses. There is nothing \-ery strange about this, because industrial life is the basis of all life. (Kitting a living is the first absolute necessity 10. Effects of Industrial life. It is easv to see wh)', therefore, the character of the occupations and in- dustries of a (leople has everything to do with iletermin- lO OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS ing the kind of government and general civilization they possess. In simple pastoral life, for instance, v/here herd- ing and hunting were the chief modes of industry, the chief frequently claimed to rule by authority direct from a god; that is, the government was a "theocracy." The people would not recognize and obey their leaders and rulers without the force of a superstition like this to con- trol them. But with the slow change from pastoral to agricultural life, where cultivation of the soil became the necessary means of getting a living, a variety of new experiences arose. A mere roving life became impossible. It was necessary after planting to care for the crops and wait for the harvest. This brought with it comparatively set- tled social relations, regular trade, usually by "barter,"'" and more permanent homes. It also made it necessary that men should recognize some sort of a moral law. It ceased to be allowable to take whatever one saw. When one planted it was necessary that he should have the right and opportunity to reap. Therefore, protection to prop- erty, recognition of personal rights, and security of fam- ily life grew up largely with this new order of settled in- dustry. Consequently, with this era, while they usually had despotism, backed by some pretence of "divine right," still there was the beginning of regular govern- ment distinct from religion, recognition of civil laws, obedience to authority, protection of personal rights, and. some crude semblance of justice. With the further progress from purely agricultural oc- cupations to the point where manufacture and commerce came in, still new variations in experience and interests developed. Simple as early manufacture was, it had far more individuality in it than had agriculture. The manufacture of clothing, furniture, military weapons, INDUSTRIAL LIFE AND SOCIAL PROGRESS II and so on, called for ingenuity, invention and skill. Ex- panding trade brought increased personal contact in busi- ness, and more frequent social intercourse, if only at the markets and fairs. Manufacture brought people to- gether in towns, partly for self-defence, partly for the convenience of trade. This clustering in towns in pur- suit of various industries gave people many common in- terests. 11. Early Towns and Rise of Liberty. The towns were the great strongholds of the people in the middle ages, against the barons, who constantly raided them for the sake of plunder. This very necessity of common de- fence against the barons compelled the citizens or "burghers," to organize municipal governments. Thus, some of these towns were practically little republics, in which each burgher had full political rights and shared fully in the government. It was under these influences and by the growing power and influence of the towns that the burgher or middle classes first gained entrance to the English parliament, and popular government be- gan. To be sure, this progress was slow, tedious and painful. At first it was scarcely observable, from cen- tury to century; but every important change in the di- rection of greater variety of industry and occupation was followed sooner or later by some advance in industrial, political, social or religious freedom. England led in this great movement; the continental countries were much more backward. 12. The Industrial Revolution. In the eighteentli century, as a natural consequence of this progress, came a series of remarkable inventions in the great industry of cotton spinning and weaving; Hargreaves' spinning jen- ny in 1764, Arkwright's spinning frame in 1769, Cromp- ton's "mule" frame in 1779, and Cartwright's power loom 12 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS in 1785. During the same period (1769) James Watt patented the first steam engine, and this applied to cotton mill machinery gave us the beginning of the modern fac- tory system. This was practically a revolution in the character of industry. Factory methods supplanted the "home" or "domestic" system of hand labor. This created a whole series of new interests, new evils to be remedied, new ad- vantages to be enjoyed. It was followed by the great movements of the nineteenth century in England, for political and religious freedom, first for the middle class and then for the laboring class. England still has the remnants of a monarchy, but it remains only by sufifer- ance and on good behavior. In reality, the English peo- ple have practical democracy. In this country, although we were largely agricultural up to the time of the Revolution, our people were the best product of centuries of English progress. Liberty came early, therefore, and our civilization has expanded along with our wonderful industrial growth. 13. Summary. Briefly, then, it may be said that the social life and quality of a people is largely determined by the character of its occupations. Nations rise in civ- ilization, freedom and enlightenment in proportion as their industrial life is varied and expanding. Anything, therefore, which tends to increase the variety of industrial life may be considered favorable to progress, and any- thing which tends to put us back to simple and crude conditions of industry, or diminish the number of in- terests and duties, is certain to deaden the spirit of im- provement and restrict progress, perhaps entirely arrest it. INDUSTRIAL LIFE AND SOCIAL PROGRESS 1 3 SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Chapters III. to VII. inclusive, of Part I. Two of these chapters are theoretical, dealing with the cause of social progress and giving proofs of the law of progress ; the other three are historical, describing the rise and fall of the medieval free cities and tracing the progress of political and re- ligious freedom, chiefly in England and America. Additional References. In Marshall's "Economics of Industry," Chapters II. and III. of Book I.; on "The Growth of Free Industry and Enterprise," in early civili- zations, down through the middle ages, and under our modern factory system, pointing out the influence of climate, custom, etc. In Hadley's "Economics," Sections 29 to 45 inclusive, in Chapter II. ; describing primitive life, slavery, the be- ginning of private property, and emancipation. In Lubbock's "Origin of Civilization," Chapter I. ; Chapter III. as far as the bottom of page 85 ; and Chap- ter IX. ; describing the social conditions, superstitions, marriage customs, laws, etc., of savage tribes. In Henry T. Buckle's "History of Civilization in England," Chapter II. ; which is a marvelously fasci- nating and suggestive account of the "Influence Exer- cised by Physical Laws Over the Organization of Society and Over the Character of Individuals," although defec- tive in some of its economic reasoning. In H. de B. Gibbins' "Industrial History of England," Chapter II. of Period II. ; on "The Towns and the Gilds." EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Savage Life. Speaking of the wild men in the in- terior of Borneo, Mr. Dalton says that they are found living 'absolutely in a state of nature, who neither cuiti- 14 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS vate the ground, nor live in huts; who neither eat rice nor salt, and who do not associate with each other, but rove about some woods, like wild beasts ; the sexes meet in the jungle, or the man carries away a woman from some campong. When the children are old enough to shift for themselves, they usually separate, neither one afterwards thinking of the other; at night they sleep under some large tree, the branches of which hang low. On these they fasten the children in a sort of swing; around the tree they make a fire to keep off the wild beasts and snakes, — they cover themselves with a piece of bark, and in this also they wrap their children ; it is soft and warm, but will not keep out the rain. The poor creatures are looked upon and treated by the other Dyaks as wild beasts.' . . . "No savage is free. All over the world his daily life is regulated by a complicated and apparently most in- convenient set of customs (as forcible as laws), of quaint prohibitions and privileges ; the prohibitions as a general rule applying to the women, and the privileges to the men. 'To believe,' says Sir G. Grey, 'that man in a savage state is endowed with freedom, either of thought or ac- tion, is erroneous in the highest degree.' " — From Sir John Lubbock's "The Origin of Civilization," Chapters I. and IX. Early English Tozvns. "The inhabitants of the towns were of all classes of society. There was the noble who held the castle, or the abbot and monks in the monastery, with their retainers and personal dependents ; there were the busy merchants, active both in the management of their trade and of civic affairs; and there were artisans and master workmen in different crafts. There were free tenants, or tenants in socage, including all the burgesses, or burgage-tenants, as they were called; and there was INDUSTRIAL LIFE AND SOCIAL PROtlRESS 1 5 the lower class of ■i'llh-iiis, which, however, always tended to rise into freemen as they were admitted into the gilds. To and fro wont our forefathers in the quiet, quaint, narrow streets, or worked at some handicraft in their houses, or exposed their goods round the market-cross. And in those old streets and houses, in the town-mead and market-place, amid the murmur of the mill beside the stream, and the notes of the bell that sounded its summons to the crowded assembly of the town-mote, in merchant-gild and craft-gild was growing up that sturdy, industrial life, unheeded and unnoticed by knight or baron, that silently and surely was building up the slow structure of England's wealth and freedom." — From Gibbins' "Industrial History of England," Chapter II., Period II. How flic Towns Bought Frcrrdoiii. "It is interesting to see what circumstances helped forward this emancipa- tion of the towns from the rights possessed by the nobles and the abbeys, or b)- the kings. The chief cause of the readiness of the nobles and kings to grant charters during this period (from the Conquest to Henry III.) was their lack of ready money The}' could not indulge their love of fighting, which in their eyes was their main duty, without money to pay for their fatal extravagances in this direction, and to get money they frequently parted with their manorial rights over the towns which had grown up on their estates. Especially was this the case when a noble, or king, was taken prisoner, and wanted the means of his ransom. . . . And the glories and cruelties of that savage age of so-called knightly chivalry, which has been idealized and gilded by romancers and history-mongers, with its tournaments .and its tortflre- chambers, were paid for by that despised industrial pop- ulation of the towns and manors which contained the real l6 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS life and wealth of medieval England." — From Gibbins "Industrial History of England," Chapter II., Period II. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is the scientific meaning of "progress"? 2. What is the great underlying cause of human progress? 3. How were people governed under simple pastoral life? 4. What changes in government and ethics came with agricul- tural life? 5. What have been some of the great effects of the rise of manufactures and commerce? 6. In the middle ages what part was played by the towns and free cities? 7. Mention the great inventions that brought in the modern factory system, and name the inventors. 8. In what ways did the factory system revolutionize industry? 9. What country led the movement of industrial growth and free government down at least to the nineteenth century? 10. How do you account for the more rapid progress of our own country, especially in political and religious freedom? CHAPTER III. WEALTH 14. What Wealth Is. We have seen, in our brief his- torical review, that as people advanced in wealth and prosperity they acquired new rights and advantages, political freedom, and a higher state of general culture and civilization. In order to understand the reasons for this it is important to have a clear idea of the meaning of wealth. This is all the more important because there is a good deal of careless talk about wealth, as if exact- ness were of no special importance. Wealth is every- thing outside of and apart from man, which, by human effort, is made use fid to man. 15. Gifts of Nature Not Wealth. Every part of this definition is important, as we shall see. There are many things, for instance, that are useful to man but are not wealth; such as sunshine, air, gravitation, and wind. They are not wealth, because they are gratuitous, and do not require any human effort to make them useful. They should be described as free gifts of nature, never as wealth. Wealth requires some kind of human exertion. Natural resources not yet utilized, but which are capa- ble of being made useful to man by human effort, such as unoccupied land, virgin forests and undeveloped min- eral deposits, may be regarded as potential wealth. They are not actual wealth until some productive effort has been actually applied to them, but as potential wealth 17 1 8 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS they may have value or command a price, due to the an- ticipated possibiHty of producing wealth from them. i6. Kinds of Wealth. In the next place, nothing should be called wealth which is not entirely distinct from man. To understand clearly the reason of this we should divide wealth, for convenience, into two classes, consumable wealth and productive wealth. By consumable wealth we mean all wealth which is directly used to satisfy desires, such as food, clothing, shelter, art, literature, music; in fact, everything which is used not as a means to a further end, but as the final means of satisfying some desire. This wealth directly ministers to human happiness. It serves the final end for which wealth is produced. Hence it is called consumable wealth. Productive wealth, or "capital," is wealth which is not used directly to satisfy final desires, but is used indirectly to aid in producing consumable wealth. Productive wealth includes everything used in the whole process of producing commodities for consumption — tools, ma- chinery, factories, railroads, steamships, etc. 17. Capital is Distinct from flan. Since man him- self plays the most essential part in producing wealth, it is very easy to make the mistake of saying that man is capital ; or, as is more usual, that a man's muscle or skill or talent are his capital. For instance, Adam Smith spoke of the education and apprenticeship and training of a man as part of his capital. So careful an economist as John Stuart Mill said that the education and skill of a people may be included in the capital of the country. Except in a very narrow personal sense this is a grave error. It is a very confusing one, too. It blots out any sharp line of distinction between man and wealth, and it is very important to keep this distinction clear, be- WEALTH 19 cause we have exactly the opposite kind of interest in man that we have in wealth. Labor and natural personal faculties, as skill, strength, and genius, are human; they are a part of the individual person and cannot be sepa- rated from him. They are inseparable personal qualities, but wealth is material and capable of being transferred from one to another. Every addition to a man's capacity or expansion of his character is a growth of the man and not an increase of wealth. Capital is wealth used as a tool. Skill is not wealth used as a tool ; it is personal quality, personal ability, an evidence of training and natural talent. When actively employed it is simply skill used in production, not wealth used in production. 18. Importance of the Distinction. This distinction is more important than at first appears. The object of consumable wealth is to gratify human desires. The ob- ject of productive wealth (capital) is to aid man in producing consumable wealth. Both these uses of wealth are for the well-being of man ; one directly, the other in- directly. This means that wealth must be used, most of it used up in fact, for the sake of man, which in turn means that our progress, if we are to have any, depends upon wealth becoming cheaper and man becoming dearer. These are two opposite movements, and of course both of them cannot take place if man and wealth are the same thing. Anything that gives man more wealth for less labor, whether by higher wages, lower prices or shorter hours, or all three, promotes human progress. Thus wealth and man are unlike in their very nature, and hu- man welfare depends upon one being used for the sake of the other. 19. Evil Effects of tlie Wrong View. The early economists failed to keep this distinction in mind, and 20 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS SO fell into the habit of describing labor as a form of capital. This led directly to the idea that labor should be cheap. Everybody agreed that commodities should be cheap, and this required that they should be cheaply produced. Since capital (including labor) was the in- strument of production, of course labor must be cheap. This justified the lowest possible wages and longest pos- sible hours of work and poorest factory conditions, and the employment of women and children ; whereas, if man and capital had been kept entirely distinct no such course could ever have been justified. Cheap production could have been sought through better machinery (capital), never through cheaper human labor. The more perfect human faculties become and the more important the service men render, the higher price they may and should command. Every such upward movement tends toward higher social life. On the other hand, the more perfect the commodities we consume be- come the lower their price should be, so that people can have more of them without working harder or longer, and thus get more happiness and opportunity for culture out of their efforts. 20. Summary. Wealth, then, is everything outside of man, procured by human effort, which directly or indi- rectly satisfies human wants. Consumable wealth is everything which is directly used for this end. Capital is wealth which is used for the production of more wealth. But under no circumstances or conditions are human faculties and qualities to be considered as wealth. Capital is non-human and labor is human. Wealth exists for man, but not man for wealth. Wealth should be produced and used for man, but man should not be used for wealth. The mercury of human progress rises only when man is growing dearer and using more wealth, and WEALTH 2 1 wealth is gowing cheaper and serving man more effec- tively and abundantly. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Section I. of Chapter I., Part II. ; on definitions of wealth and its es- sential characteristics. Additional References. In John B. Clark's "Philoso- phy of Wealth," Chapter I. ; which points out very clearly the distinction between wealth and personal human qualities. EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. The Broader Meaning of Wealth. "Wealth, then, con- sists in the relative-weal-constituting elements in man's material environment. It is objective to the user, ma- terial, useful, and appropriable. Let us apply the term with logical consistency to whatever possesses these four essential attributes, and note the effect on the traditional conception of wealth. Mr. Mill and the orthodox school will be found to exclude from their classification things which possess these attributes, and to include some which do not. They recognize as wealth only those things which are sufficiently substantial and durable to con- stitute a more or less permanent possession, things which would appear on the inventory, if society were suddenly to cease producing and consuming, and apply itself, for, say, a month or two, to taking an account of stock. It is here maintained that durability is not an essential at- tribute of wealth. Durability is a factor of value, and determines, in so far, the measure of wealth in any par- ticular product. But products are of all degrees of dur- ability, and there is no ground for excluding any of them from the conception of wealth on the ground of this sim- 22 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS pie difference of degree. Even the school of writers re- ferred to would not hesitate to class the ices of the con- fectioner in the same category with the stone wall of the mason, though they are at opposite extremes in the scale of durability. They would, however, exclude music from the conception, on the ground of its insubstantial and perishable character. It is maintained in this discussion that, in that which constitutes wealth, there is no differ- ence other than one of degree between music and a stone wall. The difference in their durability is, indeed, one of the factors in their relative value ; but both alike possess the four essential attributes above specified ; they are ob- jective and material products ; they are useful and ap- propriable, and fall within the definition of wealth. "Having unduly limited their conception of wealth in one direction, the orthodox writers have unduly extended it in another. They have, for example, classed as wealth the acquired skill and the technical knowledge of the laborer. Personal attainments, as subjective and imma- terial, are excluded from the meaning of the term. They are not a possession ; that implies externality to the pos- sessor. They are what he is, not what he has. Popular thought and speech broadly distinguish the able man from the wealthy man. A man has a potential fortune, not an actual one, in his abilities. The term indicates a state of being able and implies a possibility — not an attained re- sult. Labor creates wealth, and acquired abilities are po- tential labor. They are to be regarded as the potentiality of the human factor of production, and it introduces an element of confusion into the science to class them with the completed product. If these considerations were not sufficient to settle the economic status of a man's subjec- tive qualities, it would, at least, suffice for that end to apply to them the test of the traditional definition itself. WEALTH 23 in which 'exchangeable vakte' is made to be the essential attribute of wealth. In every exchange two commodities are alienated, and transferred to new ownership. Noth- ing can be subjected to this process which is an insepara- ble part of one man's being. . . . "If wealth-creating abilities are to be confounded with the product which results from exercising them, every power acquired by effort, involving, in practice, the whole man, will have to be classed as a commodity. The error is mentally confusing, and it is disastrous in its practical results. Man produces wealth and consumes it ; but man himself is always distinct from it." — From John B. Clark's "Philosophy of Wealth," Chapter I. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is wealth? 2. Name several things which are not wealth and explain why. 3. What are the two great classes of wealth, and what is the usefulness of each? 4. How did the mistake arise of confusing man with wealth? 5. Should skill, strength, education, etc., be counted as capital' Give reasons for the answer. 6. Why is it so important to make a clear distinction between man and capital? 7. On what great opposite movements does progress depend? 8. Describe some of the evil results of regarding labor as a form of capital? CHAPTER IV. PRODUCTION OF WEALTH. 21. fleaning of Production. Production is such a simple and commonplace word that it seems hardly to need any explanation. The first thought is, why, every- body knows what production means, yet there is great misunderstanding and difference of opinion about it. If we have our idea of wealth clear and distinct we ought to have no trouble in deciding what kind of efforts are to be called production, since production is simply the process of creating and supplying wealth. 22. Early Ideas of Production. In the early eighteenth century the leaders of political economy, such as it was, were the French "physiocrats." They taught that nothing was production which did not really bring something from the earth, like mining, agriculture and forestry. Manufacture and trade were not regarded as production. While these pursuits were rather useful they did not increase wealth. Adam Smith in his "Wealth of Nations" completely demolished this view and estab- lished the "mercantile-school" doctrine that manufacture and commerce are both productive ; that to take wool and convert it into clothing is production as much as to raise the sheep. But even Adam Smith did not consider that govern- ment officials, clergymen, teachers, scientists, musicians, literary men and soldiers were producers. They were consumers, but were what he called "non-productive con- 24 PRODUCTION OF WEALTH 2$ sumers." John Stuart Mill, who was the great ex- pounder and sustainer of Adam Smith, added soldiers, policemen, judges and jailers to the list of producers. He said they were producers because they were necessary to the security of production. A policeman is a producer because he is needed to stop the thief from running away with the product, or the incendiary from setting fire to it. Soldiers are producers because production could not be secure in any country if foreigners could invade by force and destroy property. But Mill thought that teachers and clergymen, actors, scientists, literary men and lecturers (which group in- cluded himself), ct cetera, were not producers. He said they might be very useful but that the country was the poorer for having them. This idea of production has led to a great deal of con- fusion and class prejudice. The idea that anybody who does not by his labor directly increase the amount of marketable goods is not a producer, but is only what Mill calls an "unproductive consumer" by whose presence "society or mankind grow no richer . . . but poorer," has led to the idea that middlemen and professional men are parasites on society. This idea is partly responsible for the socialist claim that the laborers produce all the wealth, and hence, of course, that all wealth by right be- longs to them, and that for anybody else to share in it is robbery. This shows what serious mistakes can arise out of a wrong conception of important terms. Adam Smith could see that the physiocrats were wrong in denying that manufacturers and merchants are producers. John Stuart Mill could see that Adam Smith was wrong in denying that policemen and soldiers are producers, but he could 26 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS not see that he himself was wrong in denying that teach- ers, clergymen, artists and musicians are producers. 23. The Broader View. The broader and altogether truer view is that everything is production which directly or indirectly aids in creating and supplying wealth. So far as the article itself is concerned, a barrel of flour is as completely produced before it leaves the flour mills of Minnesota as when it gets to the pantry of the con- sumer, but all the handling, transporting, storing and delivering is a part of its production. Production is not complete until the wealth is finally delivered into the hands of the consumer. Therefore, all that takes place between Minnesota and the millions of consumers' homes is as much production as was the plowing of the field or the grinding of the wheat. So that, middlemen are pro- ducers just so long as they are needed in this process. When they are supplanted by a better organization of industries they cease to be needed and are dispensed with, because they are no longer producers. From this point of view, also, teachers, clergymen, lawyers, singers, in fact, all professional people whose efforts develop and refine the character and tastes of the community, promote justice and security, and stimulate variety of wholesome wants and activities, are producers, because indirectly they stimulate production, increase its safety and cause the making of a finer and more useful quality of products. Their service, therefore, is not un- productive, but is really productive. When we understand that everything is production which is necessary to make consumption possible, the mistaken idea about middlemen being parasites and rob- bers disappears. Going further, when we broaden the idea of production to include everything which stimulates and increases production, then it is perfectly clear that PRODUCTION OF WEALTH 2/ refinement and cultivation of tastes, ideas and habits, the raising and expanding of character, are a part of the pro- ductive effort of society, and those engaged in these Hnes are as truly productive as those who plow the soil or plant the seed or weave the cloth. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Section II of Chapter I., Part II. ; this section treats of production and producers, showing why the old definitions must be broadened. Additional References. In Marshall's "Economics of Industry," Chapters III. and IV., of Book II. ; discussing production, some phases of consumption, necessaries of life, capital and income. It will be noticed that Prof. Marshall retains some of the old-school idea as to "pro- ductive consumption," etc. In Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations," Chapters I. and II., of Book I. ; on the division of labor and its economic causes; also Chapter IX. of Book IV.; in which Dr. Smith attacks the physiocrats' notion of pro- duction and shows that manufacturing and mercantile industries are as much a part of production as agri- culture. In John B. Clark's "Philosophy of Wealth," Chapter II. ; pointing out the reasons why writers, speakers, mu- sicians, etc.j should rightfully be considered producers of wealth. EXTRACT FROM READINGS. Music Is Wealth. "Dr. Roscher has called attention to the intrinsic absurdity of calling a violin manufacturer a productive laborer, and the artist who plays the violin an unproductive one, as is expressly done by Mr. Mill 28 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS and his followers. The violin would, thus, be classed as wealth; the music, the sole end of its manufacture, not wealth. The product, music, satisfies a direct want, the violin only an indirect one; the latter is an instrument for producing that which satisfies direct desire. The direct want-satisfying product is, if anything, more ob- viously wealth than the indirect one. Relative durability and tangibility are non-essential attributes. The me- chanic who makes the violin imparts utility to wood ; the artist who plays it imparts utility to air vibrations. One product is perceived by the senses of sight and touch, the other by the sense of hearing. One is extremely durable, the other extremely perishable; but both alike come under our definition. In both a natural agent has received a utility through human effort; both products are wealth, and both laborers productive." — -From John B. Clark's "Philosophy of Wealth," Chapter II. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. On what does a clear idea of production depend? 2. What is production? 3. Who were the physiocrats and what was their idea of pro- duction? 4. How did Adam Smith succeed in modifying this doctrine? 5. What classes of people did John Stuart Mill regard as "un- productive"? 6. What is the broader view of production and producers? 7. For what reasons may professional persons, clergymen, law- yers, teachers, musicians, etc., be considered producers of wealth? CHAPTER V. CAUSES OF PRODUCTION. 24. Necessities and Desires. All production is the outcome of desire, springing either from necessity or vol- untary wishes, tastes and habits. The first efforts of man are, of course, to satisfy the desire for food, because food is the original necessity of life which absolutely must be supplied before anything further can be accomplished. In some very poor and barren countries it requires nearly the entire time and strength of the population to supply merely these food necessities, with such rude shelter and clothing as the climate makes imperative. Just so soon as people get a little be)ond this state of abject poverty and battle with starvation, other desires begin to expand and claim attention ; such as the desire for personal adornment, for recreation, for better shelter, for a larger variety of more palatable food, for travel and adventure, even for warfare and plunder ; later, for more order and security, for settled homes and government, for justice, broader knowledge, and finally for all the re- fining, cultivating and elevating features of civilized life. In truth, desire is the first motive force in progress. It is the disturbing element which makes one grow dis- satisfied with what is and struggle for what ought to be. Without it there is no motive for the new and the better, no motive for change, and hence no impulse to act. All desire, of course, does not result in action, but only when the desire becomes so strong that it is harder to endure the 29 30 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS privation than to make the necessary effort to satisfy the want. So that, at bottom, the great work of human progress, of civilization, of ethical and spiritual growth, begins with stimulating the variety and raising the quality of human desires. Of course, all desires are not good. It is never true that all newness is good. People first learn to want things, and in their ignorance and inexperience they often reach out for the bad as well as the good. Getting rid of the bad and keeping the good is an after process of refine- ment and correction. Take, for instance, the matter of our food. It used to be very meager and simple. Even potatoes were not known till a few hundred years ago. The list of foods was slowly enlarged and sometimes in- cluded new things which were poisonous, creating sick- ness and death. But people learned through experience to distinguish things that made them ill from those that did not, and with the aid of chemistry foods were puri- fied and improved, and those that were poisonous were ruled out and placed on the list of poisons to be used as medicines only and procured by doctors' prescriptions ; — hence the drug store, which is largely a poison shop. 25. Habit and Sentiment. This same process goes on in almost all other lines. Progress always begins with new desires, and is perfected by weeding out the bad desires from the good. As this goes on habits are gradually formed, which come to be recognized as "sec- ond nature." Habit, because of its tenacity and persis- tence, is stronger than government. There is no govern- ment, be it ever so despotic, that is powerful enough sud- denly to run contrary to the established habits of the people. Habit, continued for generations, creates a deep- rooted sentiment which is a part of the very life and character of the people, and will support or overthrow CAUSES OF PRODUCTION 3 1 forms of government or religion if they come into violent conflict with it. Habit comes of constant repetition. When habit or custom becomes general throughout the community it is the ratchet wheel, as it were, of progress ; that is, it is the greatest of all influences which prevent society from slip- ping backward. What the people have learned to want, learned to consume and learned to do, habitually, noth- ing can take away from them except social revolution or anarchy. Forms of government may come and go, but national habits can only be changed by the slow process of time. Of course, habits may be modified and refined, but this must come by exactly the same process that brought the original habit. It cannot be done by arbitrary force, but by gradually substituting new and superior tastes and wants which lead to new and superior habits. 26. Influence of Education. When we get beyond the period where absolute necessity controls all our ac- tions, to where habits and seutiments are formed, our opinions and ideas come to have a great deal to do with determining our desires. Thus, very much depends on the kind of education people have, because education has a great influence on our ideas and beliefs. For instance, if we teach that monotonous simplicity is superior to va- riety of life, and that to desire new things that were not used by our fathers is to be frivolous and flippant and selfish, — in short, if the education we give tends to re- press all new tastes and desires it will stand in the way of progress. For example, in China the growth of va- riety and newness has been repressed both by religious teaching and social caste, and the social desires and cus- toms have become fixed and immovable; hence social activity is one monotonous round of repetition. The 32 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS Chinaman wears the same cut of smock and the same type of shoes to-day that he did a thousand years ago. To the extent that education encourages variety and im- provement, hails experiment and invention, it helps progress. Sanitation is another great influence in progress. It adds to the wholesomeness and healthfulness of life, which increases the vigor and activity of the people. Pub- lic parks and playgrounds and clean streets contribute to this same result. Public libraries, churches, museums, art galleries, wholesome entertainments and recreation, kindergartens and social settlements all share in elevat- ing and broadening the tastes and ideas of the people and so increasing consumption and improving its quality. 37. Effect of High Wages on Production. The necessities, habits and customs of a people all combine to make up what is called their "standard of living." This standard of living, as we shall see later on, is the great influence that determines rates of wages. Where the habits, ideas, tastes and general progress of the people have brought about a high standard of living, wages are high, and it is through wages (including salaries) that the great majority receive their living. Therefore, it is easy to see, if wages are high it means that the people buy and consume a great amount and variety of products, thus giving a large market for producers in every line. The purchases of the great body of wage and salary earners forms the basis and stimulus of modern indus- tries. Hardly any important industry, except such as make expensive luxuries, could exist at all if nobody but rich persons, business and professional men, etc., bought the products; Wage and salary earners form about three-quarters of the whole working population of the United States. CAUSES OF PRODUCTION 33 Therefore, the amount of wages exercises a most im- portant influence upon the extent and methods of pro- duction. As wages rise and the demand for products in- creases, a market basis is furnished for larger and larger investments of capital in industries to supply these de- mands. This also justifies expensive experiments to de- velop the most perfect tools and machinery that inven- tion can furnish. The use of these improvements lessens the cost of production and cheapens the products to all who buy. When products are cheapened by this method they are no less profitable to the capitalists, and hence do not lead to depression and loss ; but when products are cheapened through inability to sell, which comes from diminishing low-wage markets, it ruins the producers and inflicts all the ills of business depression and "hard times" upon the community. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Section V. of Chapter I., Part II., showing that social consumption (demand) is the basis and cause of production. Additional References. In John B. Clark's "Philoso- phy of Wealth," Chapter III. ; showing the effects of ex- panding wants and the real nature of wealth consump- tion. In Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations," Chapter III. of Book I. ; pointing out how the division of labor, and hence progress of industry, is limited by the extent of the market. In Gunton's "Wealth- and Progress," Chapter II. of Part I; the title of the chapter sufficiently explains its contents: "Increased Consumption by the Masses the Real Cause of Improved Machinery." 34 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Employments Limited by Market. There are some sorts of industry, even of the lowest kind, which can be carried on nowhere but in a great town. A porter, for example, can find employment and subsistence in no other place. A village is by much too narrow a sphere for him; even an ordinary market town is scarce large enough to afford him constant occupation. In the lone houses and very small villages which are scattered about in so desert a country as the Highlands of Scotland, every farmer must be a butcher, baker, and brewer for his own family. In such situations we can scarce expect to find even a smith, a carpenter, or a mason, within less than twenty miles of another of the same trade The scattered families that live at eight or ten miles' distance from the nearest of them, must learn to perform for themselves a great number of little pieces of work, for which in more populous countries they would call in the assistance of those workmen. Country workmen are almost every- where obliged to apply themselves to all the different branches of industry that have so much affinity to one another as to be employed about the same sort of mate- rials. A country carpenter deals in every sort of work that is made of wood; a country smith in every sort of work that is made of iron. The former is not only a car- penter, but a joiner, a cabinet-maker, and even a carver in wood, as well as a wheelwright, a ploughwright, a cart and wagon maker. The employments of the latter are still more various. It is impossible there should be such a trade as even that of a nailer in the remote and in- land parts of the Highlands of Scotland." — From Adam Smith-'s "Wealth of Nations," Chap. III. of Book I. CAUSES OF PRODUCTION 35 QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is the great active cause of all production? 2. From what does this force spring, in the first instance? 3. Name some of the varieties of desires that are developed after absolute necessities are supplied. 4. Under what conditions only do desires result in action? 5. How are habits and sentiments developed, and what are their effects? 6. Why .is the kind of education we give an important factor in progress? Give an example of the wrong kind of edu- cation? 7. Name some of the institutions and public policies that pro- mote wholesome consumption. 8. What is the "standard of living" and what has it to do with wage rates? 9. What class furnishes the largest part of the market demand for products? ID. What is the eflfect of high wages on the amount and methods of production? Give the reasons for this. CHAPTER VI. FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION. 28. The Great Factors. Strictly speaking, there are but two great factors in the production of wealth, man and nature. Man's contribution is his personal efiforts of hand and brain, grouped under the general head of "la- bor." Nature's contribution is two-fold : the great forces of gravitation, heat, sunlight, wind, electricity, animal ])ower, the germinative power of seeds, ct cetera; and the passive resources from which wealth is extracted, such as soil, mines, forests, and living creatures suitable for food supply. In economics, however, we cannot take account of the vast immeasurable forces of nature in general, as to their total power and usefulness to mankind; that belongs to the field of abstract speculation. We can reckon with these forces only to the extent that they are or can be ac- tually utilized, by means of various machines and struc- tures, which are usually managed or guided by some form of labor. These machines and structures are sim- ply so many forms of "wealth used in the production of wealth," — that is, capital. Therefore, instead of trying to deal with natural forces by themselves, as factors in production, we can only take account of them through the means by which we utilize them, namely capital and labor. Therefore, we speak of capital and labor as the two active agents in production, and whatever produc- tive power they yield is considered to include whatever 36 FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 37 natural forces are utilized by their aid. Capital also in- cludes all unfinished wealth in process of production, since this is for the time being simply "wealth used in production." Natural resources, which are nature's other great con- tribution, are grouped for convenience under the head of land. This includes all of the earth surface occupied or available for human use, with whatever it naturally con- tains and spontaneously bears; even sea food is brought under this head to avoid an unnecessary separate classi- fication. Oceans and lakes, except restricted fishing grounds, occupy the same position in economics as free land which pays no rent. Thus, for the purposes of economic reckoning, we speak of three great factors in production ; labor, capital and land. Labor includes all forms of productive human efifort. Capital includes all machines, tools, structures and arrangements contrived to utilize natural forces or assist human labor ; also all unfinished wealth in process of production. Land includes all natural resources, meaning principally of course the occupied or available earth surface and all its natural qualities and elements, such as fertility, mineral deposits, forests and wild ani- mal life. Land not yet available for human use is not within the range of economics ; it is not wealth, and we can only take account of it as "land" when it does be- come available. 29. Hand Labor Era. Division of Labor. In the earliest and simplest state of society practically all in- dustry was carried on by hand labor. Men lived by gath- ering roots and fruits and by taming and herding animals. Very early the use of crude tools began, — traps and weapons to capture or kill wild animals, tackle for fish- ing, stone hatchets, kettles, baskets and canoes. As agri- 38 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS culture developed, implements for tilling the soil were devised, and structures built for storing the crops. In this early period, also, began the division of labor, which has ever been one of the most important and really in- dispensable features of all industrial progress. So long as each individual had to supply all his own wants by his own direct efforts, nothing but poverty and degradation could be the result. As soon as men began to act and live together in any sort of settled relations, the custom arose of dividing pursuits among different groups; the men hunted and fought while the women guarded the huts and property and made baskets; then some of the men herded while others followed the chase, and still others did the fighting and governing; later on, some began to devote their whole time to agriculture, some to trade, some to crude mechanic arts. Every new division of labor brought a prompt and notable increase in pro- ductive power, order and safety, and a larger social life. This has been true of every successive subdivision or speciali::ation of industry down through all the vast de- velopments of capitalistic production. Simple manufacture began, of course, with the making of crude weapons and tools, and later on developed into higher forms, such as metal-working, spinning and weaving, cobbling and tailoring, — all done with very simple and primitive instruments. Although these crude aids to industry were forms of capital, they were merely aids to direct hand labor and it was still the hand-labor era. There came to be masters and apprentices, but no employers and wage-earners as we know them. Every man or family worked separately, and made practically no use of natural forces ; all was done by human effort, aided by simple tools and machines. This was the slowest and dearest method of production, requiring the most FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 39 labor for the least results. Some industries in our own limes are still in the hand-labor era in many respects, such as frontier agriculture, cobbling, peddling, small store- keeping, sweatshop clothing-making, et cetera; and back- ward countries like China and India are almost entirely in the hand-labor period. 30. Capitalistic Production. The use of capital on a large scale, accompanied, by the sub-division of labor within each industry, marks a great step in the progress of society. Under the capitalist and wages system all the tools, machinery, structures and raw materials of production are owned by the "capitalist" or group of capitalists, who employ workers for definite and agreed amounts of pay, the workers furnishing only their labor. The rise of "capitalism" as a separate factor neces- sarily came with the wages system. There cannot be wage laborers without employers ; so that, when the villeins and serfs in the middle ages gradually bettered their lot and became wage-workers, with the freedom at least to choose their own employers, this brought with it the employing or capitalist system. For a long time the only difiference was that the capitalist, instead of owning material, land, tools, laborers and all, as before, now only owned material, land and tools. It was a change which took the laborer away from the master or lord as property and made him a social and bargaining factor. From the fourteenth to the eighteenth century freedom of in- dividual action in industry gradually developed, some laborers became employers, and thus competition arose between employers or capitalists. In the eighteenth cen- tury, with the inventions which started the factory sys- tem, the capitalists became a distinct group. These in- ventions gave us the capitalist system of production. 40 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS which has revolutionized industry and commerce and the relations of the different classes in society. The great feature of capitalist production is that it sub- stitutes natural forces, by the use of machinery, and wage-workers on machinery, for the older and more di- rect hand labor. Like every other great change this has been the subject of long and sharp discussion. For a long time it was declared, and there are many who still believe, that this is an injury. While the use of ma- chinery clearly results in more wealth being produced, it is charged that the capitalist gets all the increase. This is a very one-sided view, which is not at all sustained by the facts. Capitalist production does introduce great labor-saving appliances, which either ' produce more wealth with the same expenditure or the same amount of wealth at less cost. In either case, the result is a surplus which some people, especially the socialists, insist is all kept by the capitalists, which they declare is robbery of labor. But this charge is not true. If it were, there could have been no reduction in the prices of commodities furnished by capitalist production. The multitude of articles of food, clothing, furniture, books, papers, public conve- niences, and what not, would cost just as much now as they did when furnished by hand labor. We all know they do not. If they did we could have not half, perhaps not a quarter, of the number of things which are now a part of our regular daily use. If food and clothes and shelter cost as much to-day, quality considered, as when produced by hand labor, coarse food and coarser cloth- ing and very poor housing would be all that most of us would now get. Prices have fallen steadily wherever capitalist production has been successfully carried on. FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 4 1 31. Effects of Machinery on Labor. Does ma- chinery injure labor? is a very important question in con- sidering this subject. It is charged that it does, because it displaces laborers and creates enforced idleness. There is a half truth in this. It cannot be denied that an im- proved machine will produce the same wealth with less labor or more with the same labor than the old one, else there would be no gain in it. That means, of course, that it will supply a certain market demand with fewer la- borers than before. If it were true that this demand never became any larger, then it would be true that fewer and fewer laborers would be needed as machinery was introduced. But the market does increase, not only by the higher wages made possible by the better ma- chinery, not only by the natural growth of population, but largely because the new machine so reduces the cost of producing an article that it can be sold at a much lower price, which greatly enlarges the demand for it. The producer is tempted to lower the price, not by any gen- erosity to the public, but in the hope of getting this larger trade. Almost always the result of this, sooner or later, is that as many and even more laborers are needed in the business than before the new machinery was introduced. It is probably safe to say that there are not two per cent, of the well-established industries in which much im- proved machinery has been introduced that have not had to increase instead of diminish the number of laborers employed. If we compare some sixty or more machine- using industries from 1880 to 1890 we find that in nearly every instance the number of laborers employed in the industry increased, the price of the product was lowered, and the wages per laborer rose. In the long run it may be safely said that machinery is 42 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS the friend and helper of labor, and not its enemy and oppressor. 32. Effect of Corporations and " Trusts." Where an industry requires a large amount of capital it has be- come customary to organize "corporations," in which large numbers of people are enabled to unite their cap- ital, some in small amounts and some in large, and em- ploy skilled and able managers to conduct the business. A few years ago many corporations attempted to form "trusts," or agreements to control all the product in their special industries and raise prices. Every one of these attempts failed, sooner or later, but they have been fol- lowed by a great tendency to reorganize numbers of small corporations into large ones, for the sake of econ- omy and more stable business. The old name "trust" is commonly applied to these large corporations, but they are not trusts at all. They are simply large corporations. The effect of these large concerns upon the public is regarded with a great deal of distrust. Indeed, they are regarded in much the same way that laborers and hand workers regarded machinery when it was first intro- duced. But these large corporations are simply the latest form of capitalist production. They are to small con- cerns what machinery is to tools, and the latest is the best because it will work most cheaply and effectively ; if it did not it would not be adopted. This latest form of cap- italist production saves a great many wasteful expenses which the small, petty concerns make necessary. This saving by large corporations operates exactly like the saving created by better machines. First, it increases the profits of the management ; then, by competition and the efforts for larger sales, that profit is shared by the community in the form of lower prices. Wh^re very large concerns exist, lower prices and usually better FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 43 products are the results in the long run. Concerns which try to avoid this movement, and keep up prices arbi- trarily, almost certainly -collapse or are driven out by competition. Large concerns also tend to give permanence to busi- ness. They are conservative. They look ahead with the view of keeping steady business, because to stop for a month or two in the year involves a great loss. This steadiness is a great advantage to wage-workers. Few things are more important to them than steadiness of employment, and few things are more important to the public in general than stability of business. Large con- cerns contribute more to this business stability and per- manence of employment than any one factor in modern times. So that, large corporations, while they sometimes have arbitrary and foolish and even dishonest management, and while they have some bad features which call for improvement, just as every new thing has, do contain the elements of improved industrial conditions. They contribute cheapness of commodities, stability of busi- ness and permanence of employment, — ^three things that are of vast importance to modern society. We ought to be careful, therefore, in attempting to reform corpora- tions, not to strike at the vital features which give these results, but only seek to get rid of the temporary defects, and protect the rights of investors and the public in general. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Sections III. and IV. of Chapter I., Part II. ; on the three factors in pro- duction and the conditions under which natural forces can be used; also Chapter VI. of Part IV.; discussing 44 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS the question of large corporations, or "combinations of capital." Additional References. In Marshall's "Economics of Industry," Chapters I., II., IX., X. and XL, of Book IV. These chapters deal with the agents of production, land and its fertility, division of labor, concentration of in- dustries and production on a large scale. In Hadley's "Economics," Chapter VI., on "Combina- tion of Capital," and Chapter XL, on "Machinery and Labor." In John Stuart Mill's "Principles of Political Econ- omy," Chapter IX. of Book I. ; on "Production on a Large and Production on a Small Scale." In Gunton's "Trusts and the Public," Chapters I., V. and XVI. ; discussing various features of the so-called "trust" problem in the light of recent developments. In Frederick Starr's "First Steps in LIuman Progress," Chapters I. to XII., inclusive; describing the primitive arts and industries of mankind. In Sir John Lubbock's "Origin of Civilization," Chap- ter II. ; describing industrial life among savage tribes. EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. The Earliest Tool. "Perhaps the oldest implement of man we know is the flint hache from the glacial gravels of France and other parts of Western Europe. It is a coarse, heavy, rude implement, chipped to shape by great spalls being broken from its surface. It is somewhat almond-shaped; may average about a hand's length; is thick and heavy. It is probable that this object was used for many purposes. It would be a weapon grasped in the hand and used in close combat ; it would be a hatchet for breaking open bones to get at the marrow ; it would be a knife for forcing open shells of mollusks ; it might FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 45 be an ice-pick for cutting holes through the ice in winter in order to get at fish. Taylor mentions that the spear- point of iron which the African has made for himself may be used by him as a knife for smoothing the spear- shaft itself. The stick which the primitive man picked up in the woods he would use for every purpose. Hurled at a passing bird, it was a missile ; held in the hand and wielded for defense, it was a war-club ; used for thrust- ing, it became a spear ; as a digger of roots it was, per- haps, the first agricultural implement ; to the man astride a floating log upon the river, the same stick became a help in handling the primitive craft."— From Frederick Starr's "Some First Steps in Human Progress," Chapter X. Labor Not Displaced. "Machinery has not displaced labor. On the contrary, there has been a most con- spicuous increase of employment in those lines where improvements in machinery have been greatest. The number of persons engaged in manufacturing and trans- portation to-day bears a far larger proportion to those engaged in agriculture than was the case two or three generations ago. The urban population makes more use of machinery than the rural population ; and it is a con- spicuous fact that our cities have grown faster than the country as a whole. Whatever else machinery may have done, it certainly has not kept labor out of mechanical industries." — From Hadley's "Economics," Chapter XI. Advantages of Large Production. "The possibility of substituting the large system of production for the small, depends, of course, in the first place, on the extent of the market. The large system can only be advantageous when a large amount of business is to be done ; it im- plies, therefore, either a populous and flourishing com- munity, or a great opening for exportation. Again, this 46 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS as well as every other change in the system of produc- tion, is greatly favored by a progressive condition of capi- tal. It is chiefly when the capital of a country is receiv- ing a great annual increase that there is a large amount of capital seeking for investment; and a new enterprise is much sooner and more easily entered upon by new capital than by withdrawing capital from existing em- ployments. The change is also much facilitated by the existence of large capitals in few hands. It is true that the same amount of capital can be raised by bringing to- gether many small sums. But this (besides that it is not equally well suited to all branches of industry) supposes a much greater degree of commercial confidence and en- terprise diffused through the community, and belongs al- together to a more advanced stage of industrial prog- ress." — From Mill's "Principles of Political Economy," Chapter IX. of Book I. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What are the three factors in the production of wealth? 2. What is meant by "labor"? 3. What is meant by "capital"? 4. What is meant by "land"? 5. Describe the early and simple methods of producing wealth. 6. How did the division of labor and use of capital begin? 7. What are the distinct features of the capitalist and wages system? 8. Do the capitalists receive all the benefits of capitalistic pro- duction? What do the facts show? 9. What are the temporary and permanent effects of m;icliinery on the employment of labor? 10. What is the object of corporations? 11. What were the "trusts," what became of them, and why? 12. Describe the advantages of large corporations. 13. Are the defects of large corporations a necessary part of them or due to unwise management? What should be our attitude toward them? CHAPTER VII. FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION— CoutillUcd. 33 Beginnings of Exctiange. In primitive society, as soon as industries became at all specialized or sub- divided, the necessity arose of exchanging products. Those who minded flocks of sheep or herds of cattle could not attend to the plowing, planting and harvesting of crops, and neither could the shepherds or farmers very well attend to the making of clothing, when woven garments took the place of skins. Therefore, those who raised sheep had to exchange the wool and mutton for food and clothes, and those who raised crops had to ex- change the grain and vegetables for wool and meat and clothing, and those who made clothing had to exchange what they did not themselves need for meat and grain and wool. This exchange was at first a direct "swap- ping" of goods for goods, and whenever or wherever that takes place it is known as "barter." As the number and variety of commodities increased, the feasibility of this direct barter diminished. It was quite easy to ex- change simple commodities in bulk, as wheat for sheep, but when articles became more unlike and numerous this barter system grew to be very cumbersome and difScult. So it came to be necessary to have some one thing whose value should be a standard by which the value of other things could be measured, and for this purpose money came into use. 34. rioney. Money has been made of all sorts of 47 48 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS materials at different times and in different countries, — skins, shells, grain, cattle, even tobacco, etc. In selecting the material from which it shall be made it is necessary to have in mind the uses to which it is to be put. In the first place, money must be made of a commodity which is itself valuable, so that those who receive it in exchange or payment for a commodity may get something which is as valuable as that with which they part. Then, in order to do the work of money, it must be something which can be divided into very small portions, so that small quantities of different things can be purchased and pieces of money to the exact value of the purchases be given in exchange. Aftei- a great deal of experimenting with different ma- terials, the countries that were most advanced began to use metal coins as money. Iron, copper, nickel, silver and gold have been used. Certain quantities of metals were stamped to show that they were of the right weight and quantity, and so the system of coinage was developed. As civilization advanced, the most expensive metals came into use as money because of their greater convenience and less liability to change in value. But gold, for in- stance, could not be used in poor and semi-civilized coun- tries as money. It is so valuable that it could not be made into pieces small enough for the people to make their ordinary purchases. In China, gold coins could not be made small enough to pay a week's wages, and of course no one could use money which required paying a whole week's wages in a single coin. It had to be made of material which could be divided up into pieces small enough for their small wages and purchases. The wages are so low in China and India that most purchases can- not be made even with silver, so they are compelled very largely to use copper, and even iron. FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 49 But as people become better off and large purchases are made, the more valuable metals become indispensable. For instance, it would be impossible to make some of the large purchases that are common in this country to-day with iron money. The cost of handling the money would make the transaction immensely expensive. In advanced civilization the most valuable metals become the most economical and best fitted for use as standard money. That is why, as nations grow in wealth and com- merce, they tend to substitute gold for silver standard money, but even gold becomes too burdensome. When trade and commerce reach great proportions another in- novation has to be made, namely, the use of paper money, representing gold or silver and redeemable- in these metals, but much more convenient to use. In small dealings, not only coin, but coin made of cheap material can be used and everything paid for in cash, but, as com- modities multiply in number and business increases in volume, cash payments become burdensome and impos- sible. Then comes the use of this paper money, and banking is developed as a further and most effective ad- dition to the methods of exchange. 35. Banking. Banks are established to aid exchange by the use of business faith or "credit," so that business can be carried on without money changing hands at all. Money is deposited in these banks by large numbers of people, who, when they wish to buy something, instead of handing over the cash give a check or order on their bank ; and the person receiving the check may often de- posit it to his own credit in the same bank, so that no money changes hands. Probably nine-tenths of the busi- ness of this country is done in this way, and without any use of money. Of course, in the constant round of business some of 50 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS these checks are redeemed in coin. Then, too, checks given on one bank will be deposited in several other banks, but this does not mean that each bank pays the others in cash for all the checks they hold against it. Every bank holds checks against many of the other banks, and so a large part of the accounts are cancelled and only the balances are paid in cash. In large cities, messengers from all the banks meet every morning at a "clearing house" and exchange checks, taking back the cash balances due them. If, for instance, one bank has checks against another amounting to $500,000, and the second bank has checks against the first amounting to $490,000, the second bank pays the first bank only $10,- 000 ; the rest of the account is mutually cancelled because the one offsets the other. In this way checks have be- come the civilized world's great instrument of exchange, by which commodities or properties from one dollar's worth to a million dollar's worth are exchanged to suit the convenience of the wage-earner as well as the rich. Banks do more than this. A great deal of money is usually left with them on deposit all the time, and this they loan out to others who want it for business purposes. So the banks serve as an instrument by which the unused money of those who have a surplus is made available for others who temporarily have a shortage. Banks usually have the right, also, to issue their own notes — "bank- notes," secured and guaranteed in various ways, and these they can loan out for business purposes. Bank- notes serve the same ends as money. 36. Transportation and Markets. The final stage in production is getting the goods to the consumer, and this requires transportation and markets. As society grows more complex, exchanges are not limited to special lo- calities, but extend to the extreme parts of the earth. FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION 5 I The American dinner table calls for the products of al- most every part of the globe. To accomplish these great exchanges transportation is indispensable. At first, the products were carried on men's backs, then domestic ani- mals like the pack-horse and the mule were used, and canoes and rafts where possible; then wagons and coaches, and, finally, through the application of steam and mechanical invention, steamships and railroads were developed. Without railroads, probably more than 90 per cent, of the present exchanges of products would be impossible. Clearly, therefore, production is not merely the securing of materials and manufacturing articles, but includes distributing them over the face of the entire globe, wherever required. Commodities are not generally shipped direct to the consumer, but are sent first to local merchants or deal- ers, — "middlemen," — all over the country and perhaps world, who hold them in stock and sell in large or small amounts to the final consumers as they may desire to buy. This is also a necessary part of production, and is usually a real economy. If every consumer had to order direct from the farm or factory, the expense of shipping such small quantities would greatly increase the price, to say nothing of the loss of time. Exchange, therefore, requires the use of money, of banking, of transportation, and of stores or markets, and all are necessary factors in the production of wealth. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Chapter VI. of Part II., on "Money and Its Economic Function." This chapter goes rather fully into the money question. Its va- rious sub-divisions explain what money is, its economic functions, how its value is determined, the depreciation 52 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS of money, and by whom money should be coined or is- sued. The sections involving the question of the value of money will be understood better after the chapter in this volume on "Value or Price." Additional References. In Charles F. Dunbar's "Theory and History of Banking," Chapters L to VI., inclusive. These chapters explain in detail, for those who wish to go into the subject carefully, the nature of banks and the operation of the banking system, including discounts, deposits, banking accounts, checks, bank-notes and reserves. In Hadley's "Economics," Sections 201 to 215, inclu- sive, in Chapter VII. These sections discuss the uses of money, its forms (including paper money), seigniorage and depreciation. In Hadley's "Railroad Transportation, Its History and Its Laws," Chapters I. and II., describing "The Modern Transportation System" and "The Growth of United States Internal Commerce." The rest of this volume deals largely with the problems of railroad rates, dis- criminations and management, and foreign railroad sys- tems; it is useful for special students of transportation. EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. The Bank Check System. "The depositor, or the cred- itor of a bank, who has to make a payment to some other person, has his choice between two methods of making it. He may demand money from the bank, in the exer- cise of his right as a creditor, and deliver this money ; or, with the assent of the person to whom he has to make payment, he may give to this person an order on the bank for the money, or what is commonly called a check. If he adopts the latter method, a payment for goods or of a debt is effected by the simple transfer of a right to de- FACTORS AND METHODS OF PRODUCTION S3 mand money from ihe bank ; and so too if the recipient of the check gives it in payment to some third person, and he to a fourth, and so on. To this extent the check is plainly made a substitute for the sum of money for which it calls. It represents no particular money or group of coins, for, as we have seen, the deposit is likely to have been created by the bank in exchange for some security bought by it, and is, therefore, a naked right to demand and not a claim to any particular cash ; and even if the deposit originated in the lodging of money by the deposi- tor, it has in this case also become a naked right to de- mand and does not imply any claim to the money actually deposited. But the transfer of this naked right, in the case supposed, is made by the agreement of the parties to serve the same purpose as the transfer of money, and the right thus becomes a substitute for money. "The effectiveness of this substitution, however, is in- creased and the use of the deposit greatly prolonged, where it is the practice for the transferee himself to de- posit the check instead of demanding its payment by the bank, or seeking his opportunity to use it in some pay- ment of his own." — From Dunbar's "Theory and His- tory of Banking," Chapter IV. Transportation a Century Ago. "One hundred years ago the United States had no system of transportation. Except on natural water courses it had very little transportation of any kind. The roads were built by local authorities for local purposes — and badly built at that. Wagon conveyance was slow and expensive. It took a week to go from Boston to New York by stage, and nearly three weeks to reach Charleston. Although this was the most frequented route, there was only a tri- weekly mail at best. The postal service was irregular and unsafe. Passenger journeys were attended with discom- 54 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS fort, and not infrequently with danger. Long-distance freight movement was absolutely impossible. The charge for hauling a cord of wood twenty miles was three dol- lars. For hauling a barrel of flour one hundred and fifty miles it was five dollars. Either of these charges was sufficient to double the price of the article and set a prac- tical limit to its conveyance. Salt, which cost one cent a pound at the shore, would sometimes cost six cents a pound three hundred miles inland, the difference repre- senting the bare cost of transportation. It was on these cheap articles of common use that the charge bore most heavily. It forced every community to live within itself." From Hadley's "Railroad Transportation, Its History an.d Its Laws,'' Chapter II. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. At what stage in progress did exchange first become nec- essary? 2. What is money, and why did it come into use? 3. Of what materials has money been made at diflfercnt times and in different countries? Why has the tendency been to use more and more expensive metals? 4. Mention some of the necessary qualities of money. 5. What is paper money, and what purpose does it serve? 6. How do banks make it possible to use "credit" as a means of exchange? Describe the check system. 7. In what way are the accounts of banks against each other settled, especially in large cities? 8. In what other ways do banks render aid to industry and enterprise? 9. Explain the importance and methods of transportation, as a factor in wealth production. 10. Who are the "middlemen"? What service do they render in production, and are they a burden or a saving to con- sumers? CHAPTER VIII. CONSUMPTION OF WEALTH. 37. Consumption the Object of Production. Con sumption is both the first and the final object of produc- tion. Whatever the form of production, whether it is near to or remote from consumption, it is governed by consumption. The primitive producer, even of the Rob- inson Crusoe type, is governed in his fishing and hunting entirely by his desire to consume fish and game. If he did not wish to consume fish or game he would neither take the trouble nor run the risk of hunting and fishing. When production reaches a more advanced state, where the first producers sell their products to whole- salers, and they to retailers, the connection between pro- duction and consumption is not so obvious, at first sight, but it is none the less real. The farmer who raises wheat in Dakota or wool on the plains of Australia is none the less producing for consumption because he is far from market. He sells to the speculator, who in turn sells to the miller or manufacturer, and he to the merchant ; but merchant, speculator and farmer are all finally governed by what the consumer will actually buy. Beyond the elementary products required to sustain life, consumption is wholly a matter of habits, tastes and cus- toms ; in other words, it is a social rather than industrial fact. The variety and character of the objects consumed determines what will be produced. In China or other pagan countries they produce idols, for which in Chris- 55 56 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS tian countries there is absolutely no demand, and lience none are produced. There are some industries, how- ever, in this country and elsewhere that produce com- modities for use in India and China. These things could not be sold in England or the United States, but their character is as much determined by the kind of consump- tion in China as if the Chinamen themselves had made them. Consumption is in reality the final expression of desire and demand. Business is based upon it. Every- day regular consumption is the basis of future produc- tion. The market for the future is estimated by the market of the past. Production is always and every- where the effort to supply something which is demanded for consumption. 38. Public and Private Consumption. Private con- sumption is the direct consumption of wealth by indi- viduals. Public consumption is the use of wealth by the people in common. For example, public expenditures for streets, water, drainage, parks, museums, police, board of health, etc., are forms of public consumption. Both of these kinds of consumption, private and public, affect production in practically the same way. Both kinds of consumption are governed entirely by the tastes and habits of the people, and in turn affect human quality and character. Both contribute to the education of the people. Private consumption, represented by houses, clothing, literature, art, music, amusements and social contact, tends to refine, cultivate and improve the tastes, habits and character of the individual. Every beautiful building, every clean street, every new appointment which adds to the convenience, sanitation or attractive- ness of the streets or homes, is just so much civilizing and refining influence. 39. Social Effects of Consumption. The social ef- CONSUMPTION OF WEALTH 57 feet of all this is shown in the habits, tastes, manners, in- telligence and character of the people. Indeed, it might be safely laid down as a general proposition that the civilization of a community or nation is broadly deter- mined by the extent and variety of its consumption. Small consumption per capita always means crude and relatively costly products, because where the demand is small the production is sure to he carried on by primitive methods, mainly by hand labor. Wherever hand labor prevails the variety of products is slight. When the con- sumption is very large it is sure to be varied. When- ever the products consumed are few in number and of uniform st}'le the total amount used is always relatively small. For instance, if all clothing were made alike there would be no motive for change, and hence a single suit would do as well as twenty. But when commodities have to satisf}' the artistic sense and taste for beauty and comfort then the forms become practically unlimited. Large consumption is always expressed in a large and varied market, and this is what calls out inventions and experiments and large investments of capital in new lines of production. All our ^complex machinery, from the first spinning frame to the modern printing press and electrical plants, which have lessened the cost and low- ered the price of products, have come because of and depend entirely upon the growth of the market, or in- creased consumption. So that, the social effect of consumption is really to give a higher standard of living and larger measure of civilization in proportion as it is large and varied; or, to give primitive barbarism in proportion as it remains small. Consumption is the key to civilization. Progress comes with the increase and diversification of consump- tion. Let science, art and statesmanship stimulate and 58 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS diversify desires and demands, leading to consumption, and self-interest will set in motion the producing forces to furnish the required supply. 40. Useful and Wasteful Consumption. There is a good deal said about "wasteful" consumption. This is a part of the old idea that consumption is waste unless it is for the special purpose of further production. In reality, all consumption leads to production. Of course, there is useful and less useful consumption. Consump- tion may be regarded as wasteful which results in op- pression, crime and imrnorality. While this class of consumption stimulates production it serves no useful end in the community, but actually results in harm. But it is a great mistake to suppose that all wealth which is used to satisfy the demands and tastes of people who are not engaged in business is wholly wasted ; such, for instance, as the highly expensive furnishings of the homes of the rich or the lavish expenditures on social entertainments. This cannot be regarded as wasteful consumption. It is this very class of consumption that constantly brings in and develops variety of products, which gradually come within the reach of larger and larger numbers. New artistic products, or "luxuries," are first introduced for the seemingly extravagant people who can pay for the experiments and high-priced hand labor required to bring out the small quantity at first demanded. This is the beginning of the market for new and improved prod- ucts. As soon as the use of them becomes established and the methods of production permit a little lower prices, the demand spreads among people of smaller pur- chasing power. This increases the market and leads to increased production, which, in turn, calls for more scien- tific and effective methods. This so lowers the price that CONSUMPTION OF WEALTH 59 a larger and larger proportion of the community can af- ford to buy the products. It is in this way that carpets, furniture, pictures, Hter- ature, musical instruments, stoves, sewing machines, and the multitude of common furnishings of the laborer's home, were first introduced. They were made at first only for the royalty and nobility, but now, produced by capitalist factory methods, have become the daily pur- chases of the laboring class. Therefore, whether consumption is useful or waste- ful is not necessarily or even usually a question of whether the thing used is expensive or even "extrava- gant," if the buyer can afford it, but it is a question of whether it leads to higher refinement, comfort or con- venience, or to coarseness, excesses, ill health, immo- rality or crime. This is the real test. SUGGESTED READING. General References. In Marshall's "Economics of In- dustry," Chapters IV., V. and VI., of Book III. These chapters contain many interesting comments on the na- ture and elasticity of various desires and demands, the effects of wealth consumption, the kinds and amounts of gratification yielded by different forms of wealth, etc. In John B. Clark's "Philosophy of Wealth," Chapters III. and IV. Chapter III., which relates more directly to desires and demands as the causes of production, has already been suggested in connection with the reading in Chapter V., but in its latter portion especially is very applicable to the present topic. Chapter IV. is on "The Elements of Social Service," and contains many excellent observations on the nature and effects of consumption. 6o OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Consumption the Social Object of Production. "To draw a line between that which, when consumed, gives capacity for labor, and that which does not, is impracti- cable. Comforts, as well as necessities, may increase the ability to work, and necessities, as well as comforts, may give gratification. The food of nearly every man satisfies wants higher in the scale than that of simple nourish- ment; it gives a sensuous gratification distinct from its nutritive action. The clothing of every one above desti- tution satisfies higher wants than those of warmth and protection, those, namely, of personal adornment and of social consideration. So with the dwelling, and the entire surroundings. It is impossible to say that food, cloth- ing, and shelter are productively consumed, or even that distinguishable portions of them are so. "To consume only productively one must eat the cheap- est food that will adequately nourish, wear the simplest clothing that will completely protect, and live in the rudest dwelling that will fully shelter. All higher wants must remain unsatisfied, and the man must become a ma- chine, content with the fuel that keeps him in motion. Here is the chief weakness of the classification, and the reason for mentioning it in this connection; to make a man a machine is to make him anything but productive. "That such a result can never be realized in fact is self- evident ; that it should never be conceived of in thought is an evidence of how little trouble even the greatest writers on political economy have given themselves con- cerning the real nature of the being with whose actions they deal. If the laborer is an engine, his motive power is fuel ; if he is a man, his motive power is hope. It is pyschological rather than physiological forces which CONSUMPTION OF WEALTH 6 1 keep him in motion. His will, and not merely his muscle, is an economic agent, and he is to be lured, not pushed, in the way of productive effort. Ambition may have feeble sway in individual cases, but, this side of the gate of Dante's Inferno, it is never entirely extinct." — From Clark's "Philosophy of Wealth," Chapter III. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. ' I. \\'lial is the object of all productive effort? -?. On what does the extent and variety of consumption depend? 3. Explain how consumption is really the basis of all industry, and how production is regulated by it. 4. What is the difference between private and public con- sumption? 5. Is there any real difference in the primary causes of private and public consumption? 6. What are some of the social and individual effects of con- sumption, whether public or private? 7. What effect has the largeness or smallness of consumption on the variety and price of products? 8. In what way have most of our comforts and conveniences first come into use? 9. Are luxuries to be regarded as wasted wealth? Give reasons for your answer. 10. What is the real test of whether consumption is "useful" or "wasteful"? CHAPTER IX. VALUE OR PRICE. 41. Value and Price are Identical. Value and price are two names for the same thing. Both mean, simply, the ratio in which commodities, including money, are ex- changed for each other or for human service. We often speak of value as something different from price. John Stuart Mill said that value is the ratio in which things will exchange for one another, and price is the ratio in which they will exchange for money. For all practical purposes this is confusing and unnecessary. The price of a thing, it is true, is what it will bring in exchange for something else, but if it will bring a dollar in money it will bring a dollar's worth of anything else. The ratio in which a hat will exchange for wheat, potatoes or corn is the same as the ratio in which it will exchange for the money price of any of these things. In modern society, where money is used, value and price are the same thing. In primitive society, where money is not used, value and price are not spoken of. It is simply barter, "swapping" things. When barter or swapping becomes too incon- venient to be practicable, money is used; this furnishes, as we have already seen, a common standard article which anybody will accept in exchange for what he has to sell, because he knows that others will accept it in turn in ex- change for what he wants to buy, and so on. Therefore, while it is correct enough to speak of the value or price of one commodity in some other commodity, as "the value 62 VALUE OR PRICE 63 of a hat is two bushels of wheat," nevertheless, for con- venience, when we speak of the value or price of any- thing we nearly always mean its value or price in money, the commonly accepted instrument or measure of all ex- changes. 42. Value and Utility. Value is a much used and misused word, the meaning of which has been unneces- sarily confused. For instance, Adam Smith and a great many others who have written since speak of two kinds of value, "value in use" and "value in exchange." But when we speak of "value in use" (meaning the usefulness of, say, a coat to the wearer) we are not really talking of value at all, any more than we are when we speak of the "value" of a friend. That use of the word value has no relation whatever to exchange or to price. It relates to usefulness, to esteem. One never thinks of trading his friend when he speaks of his value. He thinks only of his esteem for him. Or, when one speaks of the "value" of a fur coat in a blizzard he does not mean its price, he means its warmth, its usefulness. When Adam Smith spoke of water as having a high "value in use" but no "value in exchange" because it can be had for nothing; or the low "value in use" and high "value in exchange" of diamonds, he was really making a wrong use of the word value. The high value in use of water is simply its utility for quenching thirst and irrigating land, and for cleanliness. In the same way we may speak of the value of sunshine and air and gravitation, when we do not mean value at all, but utility, usefulness. If we make a clear distinction between the two it will help us very much in understanding the subject. Value, then, does not mean the quality of a thing but the ratio or proportion in which it will exchange for some other thing. When cotton cloth cost fifty cents a yard it 64 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS was no more useful for making sheets and shirts than it is now at four cents a yard, but it was more valuable. It had a higher price. When steel rails cost $120 a ton they were no more useful than when they were sold at $18 a ton ; in fact, they were not so useful because they were not so good ; but they were more valuable. They had a higher price. It often happens that the usefulness of a thing increases while its value or price diminishes. Clearly, then, they are not the same thing at all. How this value or price is determined is one of the most important questions in social economics. We find, that some things which are very useful, even indispensa- ble, like air and sunshine, have no price at all. We get them for nothing. And we find other things, like dia- monds and gold plate, which are useful in satisfying cer- tain desires, but are not indispensable because millions of people get along without them, yet have a very high price. Now, why have diamonds a high value and sunshine no value at all ? Clearly it is not because of the difference in their usefulness. If it were, sunshine would have an enormously higher value. Then what is the reason? It is because sunshine costs nothing. It is a free gift of na- ture. Diamonds cost a great deal to obtain. Nature is very niggardly in supplying diamonds and lavish in sup- plying sunshine. Diamonds have a very high price; gold has also a very high price, though not so high ; silver is less high, and so on down through the multitude of articles, until a ton of some things is of less value than an ounce of others. Why should there be such dif- ferences ? 43. Supply and Demand. The most usual theory by which this is explained is that price is determined by supply and demand. This theory holds, first, that the VALUE OR PRICE 65 value of everything rises in proportion as the demand for it exceeds the supply, and falls in proportion as the sup- ply exceeds the demand ; second, that this rise or fall con- tinues until the demand and supply are equal. Sometimes this theory appears to be true, but it fails to explain why any given commodity has any given price, and does not account for the great changes in prices, but only for some of their temporary variations. If supply and de- mand determined it, when there was an over-supply of an article the price would keep falling until all the supply was sold, but it does not. Such a thing almost never oc- curs, except at a bankruptcy sale. Even in times of panic and business depression, while prices do fall they do not fall to the point of taking off the whole supply. When a merchant has a large supply of goods, part of which he cannot sell, does he keep marking down and down and down until the last is sold ? Not at all. He marks down, until he reaches a certain point, and stops. He will carry a large part of his stock over till the next season. Why? Because he reaches a point where any further fall of price means loss. It gets down to what the article costs him, and then he halts. He will borrow money if needs be, to carry the stock over, before he will do as this theory of supply and demand says he will, because that would take him to bankruptcy. The same is true of the price of labor. When there are some laborers out of employment is it true that wages fall till they are all employed? No. On the contrary, though the demand for labor has never been as great as the supply for a whole twelvemonth, probably, during the entire century, yet wages have kept rising and rising. Why is this ? It is because another force has been at work, which is altogether stronger than supply and demand, namely the cost of production. The laborer's living is 66 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS more expensive, because he uses more and lives better, and so his wages have risen steadily, although the de- mand for labor has not increased any faster than the supply, and very often not so fast. 44. What the Law of Value flust Explain. If there is any law governing the value, or price, of articles and of services, it must be able to explain several essential points : First, it must explain why any particular article or quantity of labor is worth a given sum of money (that is, has a certain price) at any given time. If the supply of diamonds equals the demand, and the supply of cot- ton equals the demand, there is nothing in the supply and demand theory to show why diamonds and cotton should not have the same value. Clearly, this theory is insufficient here. Second, it must explain why and how prices change, and how far the change will go in either direction, up or down. As a part of this, it must explain why the price of any article frequently stops falling long before the over-supply is sold off; also, why the prices of some articles may steadily decline from decade to decade, while the relation between the supply of and demand for these articles remains practically the same all the time ; and, on the other hand, why the prices of other articles, and wages of labor, may steadily rise from decade to decade, while the supply and demand keep in about the same pro- portion to each other. Third, it must explain why prices for the same com- modities or for the same amount of labor may be very much higher in one country than in another, while the relation between the demand and supply is practically the same in both countries. It should be said, here, for the sake of clearness, that VALUE OR PRICE 67 when we speak of demand, in the ordinary sense, we mean the demand of those only who actually ask for the given article, or can reasonably be expected to ask for it, when it is offered, and will pay the price at which the owners are willing to sell ; we do not mean the unknown desire for the article by those who for any reason do not at- tempt to buy it. Also, when we speak of supply, we mean the commodities or labor actually offered for sale in the market; we do not mean the whole possible supply that could be offered if all the raw materials were worked up into finished products. Briefly, we mean only the actual (including the reasonably expected) market demand, and the actual (including the proposed or planned) market supply. It is important to remember this in seeking the true law of value or prices, because it is only this actual supply and actual demand that are factors in fixing the price of a commodity at any given time. In the next chapter we shall see that, while changes in the proportion between supply and demand often do cause temporary variations in prices, the great controll- ing influence that fixes the value or price of commodities and of labor and underlies all the important changes, is cost of production. It is because sunshine does not cost anything that it has no price. It is because diamonds do cost a great deal to produce that they have a high price. It is because gold costs about thirty-two times as much to produce as silver that it is about thirty-two times as valuable, even though more gold is being produced than silver. When gold only cost sixteen times as much to produce as silver, then its value was only sixteen times as much, and that is when the much-talked-of ratio of "sixteen to one" originated. There is a definite law ac- cording to which cost of production determines prices, and this we shall study next. 68 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Chapters II. and III., of Part II. The first of these chapters is on "Eco- nomic Value," explaining what it is and showing the dif- ference between value and utility. The second chapter takes up the theories about value and is entitled : "De- mand and Supply Not the Law of Economic Prices. Additional References. In Mill's "Principles of Po- litical Economy," Chapter II. of Book III., on "Demand and Supply, in Their Relation to Value." This chapter is suggested because it contains the standard accepted statement of the demand and supply theory as presented so long a time by the "English-school" economists. EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Usefulness and Cost. "That a thing may have any value in exchange, two conditions are necessary. It must be of some use; that is (as already explained) it must conduce to some purpose, satisfy some desire. No one will pay a price, or part with anything which serves some of his purposes, to obtain a thing which serves none of them. But, secondly, the thing must not only have some utility, there must also be some difficulty in its attain- ment. 'Any article whatever,' says Mr. De Quincey, 'to obtain that artificial sort of value which is meant by ex- change value, must begin by offering itself as a means to some desirable purpose ; and secondly, even though pos- sessing incontestably this preliminary advantage, it will never ascend to an exchange value in cases where it can be obtained gratuitously and without effort ; of which last terms both are necessary as limitations. For often it will happen that some desirable object may be obtained grat- uitously; stoop, and you gather it at yoiu' feet; but still. VALUE OR PRICE 69 because the continued iteration of this stooping exacts a laborious effort, very soon it is found, that to gather for yourself virtually is not gratuitous. In the vast forests of the Canadas, at intervals, wild strawberries may be gratuitously gathered by shiploads; yet such is the ex- haustion of a stooping posture, and of a labour so mo- notonous, that everybody is soon glad to resign the ser- vice into mercenary hands.' " — From Mill's "Political Economy," Chapter II. -of Book III. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is meant by the "Value" of an article? 2. Is there any real difference between value and price? Ex- plain. 3. What is barter, and what service does money perform in exchange? 4. In what way is value different from utility or usefulness? 5. Give illustrations of commodities that have very high utility and low value, and others that have a high value and small relative utility. 6. What is the supply and demand theory of value? 7. Mention some of the defects of this theory. 8. What conditions and changes must the true law of value be able to explain? 9. When we are speaking of their influence on value, just what do we mean by "demand" and what by ''supply"? ID. What is the real controlling influence that determines prices and the changes in prices? Illustrate. CHAPTER X. COST OF PRODUCTION. 45. Elements of Cost. Before discussing the relation of cost of production to value, we ought to understand just what we mean by cost. In economics, the cost of producing a commodity includes all the expenses in- volved in the whole process, from securing the original raw materials down to the final delivery of the finished product to the consumer. For example, in the produc- tion of wheat bread, scores of dififerent expenses are in- curred, — the cost of the seed, the labor of the farmer and his men, the miller's charge for grinding, the ex- pense of bags and barrels, the service of the railroads and steamships in transporting the flour, the time and effort of the merchant in storing, selling and delivering the flour to the buyer, or the labor of the baker in making it up into bread ; and at every stage is added the taxes and insurance and repairs which farmer, miller, railroad, merchant and baker have to pay in order to carry on their respective industries. 46. Surplus is Not Cost. It is important to note that rent of land is not included among the economic costs of production ; nor is the interest paid for use of capital ; nor is the profit earned by the managers of any of the various industries concerned in the process. The reason for this is that rent, interest and profits are all forms of surplus, left over in the hands of some of the pro- ducers after their expenses of production are paid. In 70 COST OF PRODUCTION 7 1 every industry many of the concerns have one or more of these forms of surplus left on hand, but there are also some concerns which are running very "close to the wind," not earning enough to pay either rent, interest or profits. This means that the price of the products is only high enough to cover the bare costs of these poorer concerns, and, so long as they are needed to help supply all that is demanded, the price cannot be lower. Now the price of an article, at wholesale, is practically uniform in any given market, no matter where the different parts of the supply come from, provided of course they are all of equally good quality. Therefore, it is clear that the necessary price of an article at any given time does not include rent, interest or profits; it includes only the items of real cost, and these, when we follow them back, all turn out to be items of labor and service. The cost of the raw materials is, in the first place, the expense of the labor to take them out of the earth, mines or forests. The cost of manufacturing, transporting, and selling the product is the labor of the employees, services of managers and salesmen, and generally the expense of replacing and repairing machinery, buildings, etc., which simply calls for different extra forms of labor, and for more raw materials, whose cost we have already seen is labor cost. Taxes go to pay for services rendered by the government, while insurance is simply a means of dividing up the losses from fires and accidents in small amounts throughout the business community. 47. How Profits Arise. Much of this may at first seem quite unclear. We all know of cases where farm- ers and manufacturers and merchants have to pay rent for their land and interest on their capital ; in fact, we know that the majority do. To them, these are items of cost just as much as labor or taxes. But it must be re- 72 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS membered that we are not now considering the costs in- curred by any given producer, but only the case of those whose cost of production is just covered by the price they receive for the product. These are the producers who are not paying or cannot pay rent or interest, and are not earning any profits, above the owner's or manager's salaries. That is why we say that rent, interest and profits are not elements in the price-fixing cost of production, whatever they may be to the better managed or located concerns that are producing at less than the price-fixing cost point. In the conclusion of the last chapter it was stated that cost of production is the great controlling factor that de- termines value or price. Of course, this does not mean that the price of each particular article is determined by the cost of producing that article, because, as we have just seen, the cost is different in the case of each different factory or farm, while the price of the product in the same market is practically uniform. Prices have a kind of fluidity ; that is, within the limits of the same market they are, under ordinary competition, very much like water, as Mr. Mill expressed it ; constantly seeking a level. They do not always reach that level, and neither does water. The swells and breakers of the ocean surface make it always uneven, but there is a force constantly at work tending to smooth out this unevenness. Wind and tide are constantly creating disturbances, but gravitation is all the time tending to force each particle of water to seek the general level. Hence it is truly said that water, if not obstructed by artificial barriers, finds its level. This is also true of prices, provided there are no ar- bitrary obstructions. Within any given market where competition operates there is a constant tendency to- wards uniformity of prices for the same article. Speak- COST OF PRODUCTION 73 ing of this tendency David Ricardo, the great English economist, said: "There cannot be two prices for the same thing in the same market." But this is not strictly true ; there are nearly always temporary disturbances. There may be two prices for the same article for a little while, until the consumers find it out. But it is strictly true that there is a constant tendency towards a uniform price for the same thing in the same market. Of course, then, if the cost of furnishing the different portions of the supply to this common market is differ- ent, while the price is uniform, some of the producers will have a large surplus, divided between rent, interest and profits ; others will have a fair surplus, others only a very small margin, and still others, whose cost is highest, will have no surplus at all. For convenience, the word "profit" is often used in the broad sense of surplus, in- cluding rent, interest, and profits in the narrower sense of the owners' or managers' income. Since the cost is different for each different portion of the supply, how can cost of production determine what this uniform level of prices shall be, for any given com- modity? Manifestly, it must be the cost of some special portion of the supply that establishes the price level for all. The process is as follows : Competition between producers, together with the ef- forts of consumers to buy at the lowest price, tends to force the level of prices downward. This is a common- place fact, familiar to everybody. On the other hand, the upward resistance to this competitive pressure is cost. Suppose, for illustration, the costs of supplying a given commodity from different factories to be posts of differ- ent lengths under a common platform. We can easily see that the platform will be maintained at a height equal to that of the longest posts, so long as they are strong 74 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS enough to hold it up. If a few of the posts are ten feet high, and some others only nine, eight and a half and seven, the shorter ones will do nothing towards holding up the platform. It will rest entirely on the ten-foot posts. If for any reason the long posts give way, the platform will drop to the level of the next longest ones, and so on. Now if we will think of these posts as being costs of production in as many different concerns, and the plat- form as being the level of prices, we will get an idea of how the level of prices is held up by costs. Those longest posts represent the greatest cost, and the price must at least be equal to that cost so long as they remain stand- ing. At these points the price and cost meet, and of course there is no profit. Those concerns represented by the longest posts, or highest cost, hold up the price as long as they can. They have no margins of profit. Those concerns that produce at less than this largest cost represent the shorter posts ; they get the same price for their product as the dearer producers, and so of course have the diflference in profits, varying according to their respective costs per unit of product, or, in our illustra- tion, the lengths of the various posts. So we find in every market the price level maintained by a few of the dearest producers. In other words, prices tend to a level on the basis of cost of production ; not the cost of producing each particular article, nor the cost of producing the cheapest article, but the cost of producing the most expensive part of the supply which the market demands. If some of the cheaper producers increase their supply so that the dearest group are no longer needed, these dearest producers are forced to adopt cheaper and better methods of production or else they will be crowded out by competition. In either case, COST OF PRODUCTION 75 the price of the product soon falls to the cost level of the next dearest group of producers. So, when a manu- facturer introduces new and successful machinery, which increases his output without much if any increase in his cost of production, he reaps an increased profit for a time, until his competitors get similar improved machinery or until some of the poorer competitors are crowded out of the field. Then the price falls again, and the manufac- turer no longer gets any special advantage from his ma- chine, except that it prevents him from falling behind in the race. What was for a time his profit is now being en- joyed by the public in the shape of lower prices. 48 High Cost and Low Cost Production. Of course, many factors enter in, to determine whether the cost of production in different concerns is high or low. Near- ness to supplies and fuel, nearness to market, efficiency of machinery, expertness of management and skilfulness of labor, all are elements in giving a low cost of produc- tion as compared with concerns that have to bring their raw materials and coal from a distance, or that have to go a long way to find a market, or that use old, slow and worn-out machiner\-, or that are managed by old-fash- ioned, illiberal methods and employ a poor grade of labor. Right at this point we should correct the very serious error that "cheap" labor necessarily means cheap produc- tion. We think of low-wage laborers as cheap producers. Sometimes these are the very dearest producers; that is, the most expensive. The measure of cheapness in labor is not always the amount paid per day but the cost of the labor per unit of product. If a laborer employed at a dollar a day only produces half as much as one employed at a dollar and a half, the dollar-a-day man is dearer than the dollar-and-a-half man. The dearness or cheapness of laborers depends upon the cost of the labor necessary ^6 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS to turn out a given quantity of product. If everything were done by hand it would generally be true that low- paid laborers would be cheap producers, but the great cheapening power in' production is not muscle but machin- ery. The productiveness of human muscle can never be increased very much. The fifteen-cent-a-day Japanese and ten-cent-a-day Chinaman are as dexterous and expert with their fingers as the average three-dollar-a-da\' American. The difference in this respect is very limited. The great gain in productive power comes from the use of science and machinery. For instance, fifty years ago a weaver could attend to only two looms. Some weavers would do a little more with two looms than others, but the best could not do twice as much as the poorest. These looms would only make about sixty to seventy-five revolutions a minute. With the improved machinery used to-day some weavers can mind twenty and even more than twenty looms, run- ning at the rate of two hundred and twenty revolutions a minute. This is a reduction in the cost which no amount of hand dexterity could ever produce. This leads directly to the greatest of all reasons why low-wage labor is really dearer than high-wage labor; namely, the fact that high wages make a large market for products, and it is only when there is a large market that machinery and other cheapening processes can be used in the production of wealth. This point was emphasized, it will be remembered, in the lesson on "Causes of Pro- duction." Twenty looms minded by one operator and making two hundred and twenty revolutions a minute will produce one thousand yards of cloth a day, which is about twenty times more than the weaver of fifty years ago could produce. Of course, the use of such looms can only be made profitable if this immensely increased prod- COST OF PRODUCTION TJ uct of cloth can be sold. The poorer the working people of the country are — that is, the lower their wages — the less they can buy of the cloth, and hence the less they, can con- tribute toward making this improved machinery possible. Large consumption, which nearly always depends upon high wages, except in the case of luxuries sold to (he rich, is necessary to the development and profitable use of the most economic and cheapest methods of produc- tion. In the long run this is always true. The forces which give lower prices, then, are not merely the forces which develop the dexterity of human muscle but are chiefly the forces which bring improved machinery and productive methods into use. These forces are not physical but social. They arise not out of the laborer's personal endurance and excessive drudgery, but out of his social refinement, education, high standards of life and large consumption, all of which result in high wages. The continuous lowering of prices, which means cheapening of wealth for everybody, comes not through low wages but through larger use of machinery, and this results from the increasing demand for an increasing va- riety of products by the community. In other words, this demand comes chiefly from a higher standard of so- cial life among the wage-earning people. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Chapters IV. and V of Part II. These chapters are entitled respectively "The Law of Economic Prices" and "The Law of Cost of Production," and explain in more detail the points we have just covered. Additional References. In David Ricardo's "Princi- ples of Political Economy and Taxation," Chapter XXX., "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Prices." 78 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS Mr. Ricardo, whose "Political Economy" was published in 1817, was practically the only great English economist to deny the demand and supply theory and assert that prices are governed by cost of production, but even he did not see the full application and wide scope of his doctrine. Some of his reasoning as to how cost of pro- duction is determined has been discarded in the light of later economic investigations. In Mill's "Principles of Political Economy," Chapter III. of Book III. Although Mill was the strongest of all defenders of the supply and demand theory, he recog- nized the influence of cost of production in determining prices under certain conditions. This chapter treats "Of Cost of Production, in Its Relation to Value." EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. Cost^ Not Quantity, Determines Value. "It is the cost of production which must ultimately regulate the price of commodities, and not, as has been often said, the propor- tion between supply and demand; the proportion between supply and demand may, indeed, for a time, affect the market value of a commodity, until it is sup- plied in greater or less abundance, according as the de- mand may have increased or diminished ; but this effect will be only of temporary duration. "Diminish the cost of production of hats, and their price will ultimately fall to their new natural price, al- though the demand should be doubled, trebled, or quad- rupled. Diminish the cost of subsistence of men, by di- minishing the natural price of the food and clothing, by which life is sustained, and wages will ultimately fall, notwithstanding that the demand for laborers may verv greatly increase." — From Ricardo's "Political Economy and Taxation," Chapter XXX. COST OF PRODUCTION 79 The Tendency of Value to Equal Cost. "Adam Smith and Ricardo have called that value of a thing which is proportional to its cost of production, its Natural Value (or its Natural Price). They meant by this, the point about which the value oscillates, and to which it always tends to return; the centre value, towards which, as Adam Smith expresses it, the market value of a thing is constantly gravitating; and any deviation from which is but a temporary irregularity, which, the moment it ex- ists, sets forces in motion tending to correct it. On an average of years sufficient to enable the oscillations on one side of the central line to be compensated by those on the other, the market value agrees with the natural value ; but it very seldom coincides exactly with it at any particular time. The sea everywhere tends to a level ; but it never is at an exact level ; its surface is always ruffled by waves, and often agitated by storms. It is enough that no point, at least in the open sea, is permanently higher than another. Each place is alternately elevated and de- pressed; but the ocean preserves its level. . . . "To recapitulate : demand and supply govern the value of all things which cannot be indefinitely increased ; ex- cept that even for them, when produced by industry, there is a minimum value, determined by the cost of pro- duction. But in all things which admit of indefinite multiplication, demand and supply only determine the perturbations of value, during a period which cannot ex- ceed the length of time necessary for altering the supply. While thus ruling the oscillations of value, they them- selves obey a superior force, which makes value gravitate towards Cost of Production, and which would settle it and keep it there, if fresh disturbing influences were not continually arising to make it again deviate. To pursue the same strain of metaphor, demand and supply always 8o OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS rush to an equilibrium, but the condition of stable equi- librium is when things exchange for each other according to their cost of production, or, in the expression we have used, when things arc at their Natural Value." — From Mill's "Principles of Political Economy," Chapter III. of Book III. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. Name some of the elements in the economic cost of pro- ducing a commodity. 2. Why are not rent, interest and profits included in our reck- oning of economic costs. 3. When we trace back the various items of real cost, into what one form of cost do they resolve themselves? Il- lustrate. 4. Explain how some industries have an economic surplus, including rent, interest and profits, while others do not. 5. Since we know that rent and interest are items of cost to some producers, in what sense do we mean tlial they are not part of the economic cost of production? 6. What is the general tendency of prices in the same market? What can you say of the variations from this tendency? 7. Explain just how cost of production determines prices. Is - it the cost of each particular article or of some definite part of the whole supply? If the latter, what part is it, and why? 8. How does competition affect prices? What is the effect of improved machinery and belter methods of produc- tion? 9. What are some of the conditions that cause high and low cost of production, respectively? 10. Why is low-wage labor in the long run the most costly of all labor? Explain just how the use of improved machinery, giving cheap production, finally depends on a high level of wages throughout the community. CHAPTER XL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH. 49. What Distribution Means. Distribution is some- times spoken of as if it meant the transportation and selling of goods. What is meant by distribution in eco- nomics is the division of wealth among the various fac- tors that share in its production. There are really but four economic avenues or channels by which wealth is distributed throughout the community,. They are wages (including salaries), rent, interest and profits. Every- body, except those supported by charity, gets his or her income and share of the wealth produced in one of those forms. 50. Wages. Wages are a definite kind of income, dif- ferent in character from either rent, interest or profit. Wages are often spoken of as if they meant any and every kind of reward for labor. This is a mistake. If a man plants a hill of potatoes the product is the reward for his labor, but it is not wages. It is simply wealth he has helped produce. Wages are a specific agreed sum paid by one person to another for a certain amount of service. Wages are the price of labor, and are always a definite stipulated income. They are not an uncertain variable in- come, depending for their amount on the success or otherwise of the industry. They are a definite sum agreed upon before the service is rendered, and must be paid if the business is to be carried on at all, because the laborer must at least be fed before he can work. All 81 82 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS forms of stipulated income paid for services may be properly classed as wages. Moreover, wages are nearly always a part of the cost of production, because all pro- duction involves labor and under modern conditions practically all labor is performed for wages. Conse- c[uently wages are never a division of profits, because profits are the surplus remaining after all costs are paid. 51. Rent, Interest and Profits. Rent is different from wages in that it is not a necessary part of the cost of production. There is a good deal of production that does not involve rent-paying at all. Rent is a part of the surplus or profit arising from the use of land, just as in- terest is a part of the surplus arising from the use of capi- tal. If a producer owned all the land he used and all the capital invested in his business, there would be neither rent nor interest to pay. He might pay wages, or if he did the work himself his own cost of living would constitute the labor cost equivalent to wages. All the remaining value of the product above what it costs to produce it would be his profits.- If he did not own the land but did own the capital he would then have to pay, first, wages for the labor, and out of the remaining profits he would have to pay a part for rent of land. The surplus created by any special fertility or advantageousness of the land he uses is paid to the landowner for the use of it, and is called rent. If he does not own the capital he uses he then has to pay interest for borrowed capital, and thus his profits are still further reduced by the amount paid for interest. If anything is left after paying wages, rent and interest, it is his profits. If the total surplus is no more than equal to the rent and interest, he will have no profits, as very often happens. Thus it may be said that wages are a stipulated amount paid for labor, rent is a stipulated amount paid for the use of land, interest is a DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 83 Stipulated amount paid for the use of capital, and profits are the possible surplus left after everything else is paid. It should not be forgotten, however, that rent and in- terest, while stipulated in amount, are not always ele- ments in cost of production, while wages, or labor cost in some form, are always an element. There is no produc- tion without paying the labor cost in some way or other, almost always in wages. Rent and interest are payments out of the surplus or profit. If, for instance ,a farmer wants a piece of land, and the owner asks ten dollars an acre for the use of it, the farmer will only pay ten dollars provided he can clear that much or more by using it. If he cannot realize from the product of the land above all costs more than ten dollars he will refuse to take it at that rent. If he can realize fifteen dollars he will gladly pay ten or even twelve dollars as rent, but he will not pay sixteen dollars, because that would be giving more than the gain obtained by using the land. In other words, rent is a part of the surplus created by, a given piece of land, and is paid by those who use it to those who own it. Sometimes all the surplus coming directly from the land is paid in rent, sometimes only a part of it, but of course more than the surplus will not be continuously paid. Interest is exactly like rent, only it is paid for the use of capital, such as machinery, tools, stock, etc., but a per- son will pay interest for capital to use in business only on condition that he can make more than the interest by so doing. If new capital will not increase his remainder of profit he will refuse to use it, but in some industries, like bonanza gold mining, very high rates of interest are paid because large margins of profits are realized. In- terest is generally higher in this country than in Europe, because profits are usually larger here than abroad. 84 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS Rent and interest, therefore, are divisions of the total gain among the owners of borrowed land and borrowed capital. The remainder goes to those who conduct the industry, to the extent that the total profits are larger than the amount due for rent and interest. To illustrate : if a business will yield 15 per cent, surplus, and the person conducting it owns both the land and capital employed, then he will have the total profit of 15 per cent. If he owns only the capital but has to hire the land at a rent equal to one-third of his surplus he will have only a profit of ID per cent. If he also borrows his capital and has to pay another third of his surplus in interest, he will only have 5 per cent, profit left. Rent and interest are not parts of the cost of pro- duction, which aifect the price of the commodity, but are a portion of the general surplus or profit. In other words, wages or labor expense are cost of production ; rent, in- terest and profits are surplus. They may all go to one person or be divided among many, according as the land and capital employed is owned by one or by diflferent people, but if the latter the total gains or surplus created by the industry will be divided among these three. It may all go to rent and interest and leave no profits, or it may go equally to all three, but there will never be profits without first paying the rent and interest, though there may be rent and interest without any profits. Rent, inter- est and profits are divisions of the surplus created by the quality of the land, and by the use of capital, and by the skilful management of the business. SUGGE.STED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Chapter I. of Part III., on "The Distribution of Wealth." In this chap- ter special attention is devoted to showing the order in DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 8$ which wealth is distributed through the four economic channels; first wages, then rent and interest, lastly profits. For Additional References see subsequent chapters, on Wages, Rent, Interest and Profits, respectively. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is the economic meaning of "distribution" of wealth? 2. How many channels of economic distribution are there? What are they? 3. Define wages. What other form of income does the term wages, in economics, include? 4. Do wages always include all labor cost? If not, what forms of labor cost are not represented by wages? 5. What is rent? How does it differ from wages? 6. For what is interest paid? How does it differ from wages, and wherein is it similar to rent? 7. Define profits. What is the difference between general or total profits (or "surplus") and the employer's final prof- its? 8. In what order is wealth distributed through these four chan- nels? 9. Explain by illustrations how the method of distribution varies according to the ownership of the land and capital used. 10. Why are wages the first and unavoidable item of distribution, while rent and interest are uncertain, and profits wholly dependent on the success of the business? CHAPTER XII. WAGES. 53. Wages an Index of Civilization. Wages and salaries are the forms of wealth-distribution through which the great majority of the community receive their income, especially in modern countries. The class whose income reaches them in this way is constantly increasing as civilization advances. Strictly speaking, wages are a stipulated amount paid for services. It may be by the day, week, month or year, only when it is by the year it is called salary, and is usually larger in total amount. Wages in the broad sense include all stipulated amounts paid for services. They are the price of labor. Since wages are the means by which the laboring class secures command over the necessities, comforts, con- veniences and luxuries of life, it is clear that the stand- ard of wages is a very good sign of the material and social condition of the people of any nation. Whatever else may be said of a nation, if wages are low the masses of the people are sure to be poor, and if the people are poor civilization is backward. There is no more reliable general index to a nation's welfare and progress than the wage conditions of its people, and nothing more surely contributes to a people's progress than a general permanent rise of real wages, although there are many other things that affect their welfare in various ways. 53. Real and Nominal Wages. From the laborer's standpoint, the mere amount of money he earns does not 86 WAGES 87 prove whether his wages are relatively high or low ; it de- pends on what and how much he can buy, with his wages. For instance, when wages were $10 or $15 a day in the Klondike gold fields, prices of ordinary necessities were so very high that the laborer was unable to buy as mttch with his money as a New England factory operative on $1.50 or $2 a day could with his. Therefore, we make a distinction between the money rate of wages and the purchasing power of the laborer's earnings. The amoinit received in money is his "nominal wages ;" the amount of commodities or whatever he can buy with his money in- come is his "real wages." When we are considering wages as an item in cost of production we can take ac- count only of the nominal or money wages, but when we speak of wages as a measure of the workingman's wel- fare or standard of living or advancement in civilization we mean, of course, real wages. 54. Standard of Living. How are wages, or the "price of labor," determined? By the operation of the same principle of cost that determines the prices of com- modities. The influences that operate upon a manufac- turer in compelling him to demand a certain price for his output operate upon laborers in compelling them to demand a certain price for their labor. In the case of a manufacturer it is the expense involved in furnishing the product that fixes the minimum level of price at which he can afford to sell. In the case of laborers it is the normal, customary and established expense of living that furnishes the basis of their demand for wages. This is not always understood by the laborers them- selves, but, like the silent operation of forces in nature, it is an unconscious fact that is ever present and finally decides the result. In other words, what it has become necessary for the laborers to have, according to the social 88 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS conditions under which they Hve, constitutes the real force of their demand and the measure of the amount of their wages. Laborers in China will seldom get more than ten or twelve cents a day,, because the material and social requirements under which they live can be satisfied with the meager supply that ten or twelve cents a day will fur- nish. In more advanced countries this amount is not only inadequate but it is so far short of fulfilling the living- necessities that even employers do not think of offering it. The standard of life, for instance, in England and the United States has advanced so far that no industry could exist at all, whose life depended upon paying ten cents a day for labor. The thought would be dismissed as impossible; in fact, it becomes a part of the primary estimates of a business, before it is started, that it must be able at least to pay the scale of wages that the estab- lished standards of living of the country demands. If it is in a community or industry that rec^uires five dollars a day to be paid, as in some cases in the United States, a new business will only be established if its prospects will afford that, but if it is an industry or community where twenty-five cents a day can be paid, the business will be started on that basis. Whether the wages are twenty-five cents a day, or two, three or five dollars a day, is not determined by the desire of the capitalists to pay more or less. They will nearly always pay the least they can. The wages, are determined by the necessary expensiveness of the labor- ing class in that country or community ; in other words, by the minimum amount the established standard of liv- ing requires in order to continue. 55. Influences that Affect Wages. Clearly, then, wages are affected by whatever influences affect the tastes and habits of the laboring class, because the expen- WAGES 89 siveness of labor is governed by the laborers' standard 111" living. Where they are content and can live nndcr conditions that compel them to eat and sleep and cook in the same room, they can with comparative ease be in- duced to accept low wages that will cover that sort of living. But where the laborers' social and domestic habits, education and standards of life are such that they refuse to eat and sleep in the same room, refuse to live under conditions where they cannot have decent housing and sanitation, carpets and modern furniture and some literature and social entertainment, they will not forego these without discontent, strikes and disturbance, and cannot be induced to work for wages that will not supply these conditions. This difference in habitual tastes and desires makes the difference in rates of wages. Nothing but habitual acceptance of lower conditions can establish low wages, and nothing but the education and social re- finement which demands better conditions can exact high wages. All the influences, therefore, of education, social opportunity, varied experience, cultivation of new ideas and tastes, are forces which push wages upward. In short, all the influences which awal. Under what state of society has socialism actually existed? What were its characteristics under those conditions? 13. What efifect has the progress of society had on these social- istic forms of government? 14. Show the steps by which the movement towards greater individual liberty has developed. CHAPTER XVIII. SOCIALISM — ContiiiKcd. 79. What Socialism Promises. Just as socialism is the most thoroughgoing in its plan of reorganizing so- ciety, so it is the most sweeping in its promises of the universal comfort and justice it would usher in. Edward Bellamy, in his "Looking Backward," a hook which at- tained wide popularity some }oars ago, described in de- tail an imaginary perfected state of society, wherein every man, woman and child received a generous income, the same to each one, regardless of the service per- formed ; inequality, injustice, crime, poverty, ignorance and intemperance had disappeared, and happiness was all but universal. This had come about entirely by making the government the sole owner and manager of all pro- ductive industry, with an elaborate and complicated method of determining the lines of industry or labor which each man should follow. This is only one of many books that have appeared from time to time, pur- porting to describe an ideal state of society, some writ- ten pm-ely as fanciful works of imagination, others as \ery earnest and sincere attempts to point out a swift and easy solution for most of the great problems of hu- man life. Perhaps the most famous of them all is Sir Thomas More's "Utopia." published in 15 16, describing the conditions and customs of life in a supposable ideal comnuuiity where all things were held and enjoyed in common. 139 140 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS Such pictures are always alluring, and appeal strongly not only to the sentimental and visionary, but to thou- sands of earnest, sympathetic people who are tormented by the hardships and suffering they see about them and readily turn to the most summary and radical proposi- tions that are offered as a cure. No one can be blind to the defects, injustices, poverty and misery that are still such prominent features of human life ; and ought not to if he could. It is not here that those who believe in preserving our present social system differ with the so- cialists. The faults, the shortcomings, excepting heated exaggerations, are admitted, but the great point of dif- ference is how to get rid of them ; what remedy will root out these evils without sacrificing in the process more than is gained ? It must be remembered that poverty, ig- norance, crime, oppression and the thousand forms of human suffering have existed since the beginning of the human race, and under almost every conceivable form of government, laws and religion. On the other hand, it is becoming clear, as our knowledge of history in- creases, that all along the lot of man has, by slow and painful steps, with many and wearisome delays, been growing better. By comparing the condition of the masses in the most advanced countries to-day with that in the most backward, or with that in the same advanced countries several hundred years ago, this fact of pro- gress, of improvement, is made very clear. There are still great numbers who are deep in poverty, but the proportion of these to the whole is less than ever before. Comfort is more general than ever before; that is, it is enjoyed by a much larger proportion — the great majority in several countries — ^than ever before; and the same is true of personal freedom in religion and government, se- curity in personal and domestic rights, reasonable and SOCIALISM 141 healthful conditions of labor, decent conditions of living, opportunities for education, recreation and culture. None of these things are yet anywhere near so abundant, foi the mass of the people, as they should be; indeed, from the standpoint of the more advanced the life and oppor- tunities of the millions seem pitifully meager. But, since it is true that the lot of the average man is improving, and never more rapidly, certainly and universally than during the century just closing, we are compelled to ask ourselves, soberly and without prejudice, whether we are not likely to approach the ideal, or at least vastly im- proved, social conditions towards which we are strug- gling, sooner, more safely, and with less sacrifice of the great rights of personal liberty for which men have labored and fought all down the ages, by preserving our present industrial and social system, developing its ad- vantages and weeding out its defects, than by running the fearful risk of a radical, strange experiment. Especially, we ought to ask this when the experiment is one that takes little account of the imperfections of human nature, but would overturn our existing institutions, abolish pri- vate industry, abolish the personal right to choose occupa- tions, take away the stimulus to industrial progress which is now offered by the hope of making profits, and in gen- eral place every man's work and opportunities absolutely in the hands of the government, which would of necessity have to be a despotism, — a despotism of the mass rather than of a prince, to be sure, but a despotism nevertheless. In other words, ought we to put our faith in the method of natural evolution or of arbitrary revolution ? 80. Difference Between Socialism, Communism and Anarcliism. To determine this question we must see just what socialism proposes to do, and judge how it would probably work in practice. There is a great dif- 142 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS ference between the plan proposed by socialists and that offered by the communists and anarchists. "Commun- ism" merely proposes that all property shall be held in common, consumable products as well as productive cap- ital, and used freely as each one desires. "Anarchism" would abolish all government and allow every man to work and live as he chose, produce what he pleased and do what he liked with it, free from any hindrance or in- terference by authority of any kind. The only limit it would place to the domination of one man by another is the personal resistance of that other man, and anarchists believe this would lead to voluntary recognition by each of the rights of all, without government of any kind. The theory only needs stating to show its utterly vision- ary and impracticable character. 8i. Proposed Methods of Socialism. SociaHsm is the very opposite of anarchism. It proposes that the community, through the government, shall take pos- session of all the means or instruments of production ; — capital, including all factories, railroads, steamboats, etc., and land, including, of course, mines, forests, oil wells and all natural resources whatsoever. Private ownership of the means of production in any form is to be pro- hibited. All production must be under public manage- ment, with instruments owned by the public, and then, of course, the public would get all the benefit. The capitalists and middlemen would become .unnecessary ; they would be ordered into other branches of the productive system as the government might provide opportunity. Socialism promises by this method to abolish all injustice, to make poverty on the one hand and large wealth on the other impossible. Although nearly all socialists are agreed on the general features of this program, there is the widest difference SOCIALISM 143 among them as to details. Some believe that the man- agers or superintendents of the various industries should be chosen by popular vote; others think they should be selected by test examinations. Some insist that each man's share of the wealth produced should be the same ; ethers advocate a so-called "scientific" division, according to the hardship of the task, or else according to the value of the service to society, — which would come back dangerously near to our present system of wages and profits. Some demand that socialism shall be estab- lished by a sudden, forcible revolution ; others want it to come by a majority vote in the regular political method ; still others expect it to develop naturally, through co- operative experiments, municipal ownership of street railroads, gas plants and the like, government ownership of railroads, and so on. 82. Economic Effects of Socialism. The complete scheme of modern socialists has never, of course, been applied anywhere, but there have been many approaches to it and many experiments on a small scale. As we saw in our brief review of the history of socialism in prac- tice, wherever the paternal or socialistic element in gov- ernment has been most prominent, progress has been least. In such countries as Russia we find the greatest amount of collective authority and paternalism. In not a few instances in these countries the primitive village community with its many common-ownership features still exists, and the progress of industrial diversification has been very slight. Under these conditions individual rights have scarcely been born, and authority, both po- litical and religious, is despotic. The individual counts for but little. He is not recognized or consulted about the government or even about himself, and if he ven- tures to have an opinion it may cost him his life. 144 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS As we ascend in the scale of progress we find in the different nations an increasing diversity of industry and individual enterprise, extension of personal rights, re- ligious and political freedom, and a narrowing of the range of the government's activity. Thus Germany and France are less paternal and communistic than Russia or Persia. England and America are still less paternal than France or Germany, and correspondingly higher in free- dom and civilization. Socialism asks that the individual freedom and initia- tive which have been won by centuries of struggle and hardship shall be replaced by a social despotism of ma- jority rule. The right to engage in industry, to have and keep or dispose of the fruits of one's labor, to exercise individual judgment and responsibility, is to be super- seded by the collective authority of the community through the government. Of course modern socialism would not try to duplicate the early village community or the Persian type of authority. It would not have a divinely-appointed czar, but it would have mediocre pop- ularly-elected bureaus and officials with power to regu- late absolutely all the most important interests that affect the individual. Nothing, probably, could be more clumsy, costly and inefficient as a director of industrial affairs than such a committee, elected by popular vote or by any political machinery yet devised. To take the tools of in- dustry out of the hands of private individuals and turn them over to the government would at once put industrial enterprises into the control of inferior and very often in- competent management. It has been found from long experience that under democratic government the very best are seldom chosen for any position, from president of the United States down to ward alderman. The criticisms of the press and SOCIALISM 145 complaints of citizens testify that our really ablest and best qualified men are rarely elected to any public office, executive or legislative. The reason for this is simply because they have to be elected, instead of reaching their positions by natural merit-testing competition. Whoever has to be elected to any position will necessarily have to represent those who elect him, and whoever represents either a party or the public at large is almost invariably below the best. He must represent not the best but the majority, which is always mediocre. Control and man- agement of industry by majority vote is a long way be- hind what the individual expert could give. This has been demonstrated by all the experiments that have yet been made, and they are very numerous. Many experiments have been made in this country and Europe in socialistic industrial communities. Robert Owen's settlement at New Harmony, Indiana, in 1825 ; the nu- merous experiments based on the ideas of the French reformer Fourier, a little later; the Brook Farm com- munity near Boston, in the early forties ; and several so- cialistic communities of Americans in California, Mexico, etc., all have had to be abandoned. Not one proved an economic success, because they lacked individual initia- tive and personal enterprise, and lost the advantage of expert effort and management. They were organizations in which the mediocre majority tried to make everything equal and uniform, and so suppressed the growth of the best. Socialism could only achieve what it promises by caus- ing some immense economies or increase in the produc- tion of wealth, but all experience shows that removal of competition has just the opposite effect, leading to greater waste in methods and general lessening in productive activity. Mere equal division of what is now produced 146 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS would leave nothing for new enterprises and would add but little to the income of the wage-earning classes, while even this would tend to disappear with the slackening of productive energy. Numerous experiments have been made in manufac- turing industries on a plan of co-operation very much like socialism. A large number of cooperative cotton factories were built in the north of England in the sixties and seventies. The management of these mills was de- termined by the majority vote of the stockholders as in- dividuals, each counting one, regardless of the amount of stock he might hold. The theory of this was that one man was just as wise and efficient as another, and that the man who had one share of stock was entitled to just as much voice in the management of a business enter- prise as the man who had a hundred shares. In other words, they assumed that human beings are not only equal in their rights and opportunities but also equal in their industrial abilities. They believed that the acquisi- tion and ownership of property is no sign of industrial superiority. The result was that these concerns, which were at first among the best-appointed factories in Lan- cashire, little by little dropped behind in the competition with regular capitalistic factories, through inferior man- agement, internal quarrelings, and short terms of office for their managers and overseers, until, one after another, in order to avoid bankruptcy, they had to be converted from socialistic or cooperative factories into joint-stock corporations, and they are now successful enterprises. Thus far, any attempt on any considerable scale to con- duct industry on the socialistic principle has resulted in failure and arrest of progress. This is not surprising, because socialism attempts to reverse the whole course of natural progress by which every advantage in scientific SOCIALISM 147 wealth production, personal opportunities, religious free- dom and democratic government, has been evolved. Progress is a movement towards greater variety of hu- man effort and complexity of methods, and any theory which proposes to substitute collective paternalism for individual initiative, uniformity for diversity, is an effort to retrace the steps of progress. In the nature of things such an attempt must either fail in itself or else put so- ciety back. However plausible a theory may be, how- ever attractive its promises, if it proposes to accomplish its reforms by turning society backward to any earlier and cruder forms of human institutions, it will prove a blow to freedom and progress. 83. Effects on Individual Life Socialism, beyond question, would have very deep and far-reaching effects on the development and quality of individual character, aside from its economic results. This phase of the sub- ject is too broad for proper discussion here, it involves so much of psychology and sociology, but in general it may be said that any scheme which proposes to take all elements of individual initiative, risk, enterprise and re- sponsibility out of human society could only result in a weakening of purpose, deadening of ambitious energy, and general settling down to a monotonous routine of appointed tasks. It would lead to a decay of that spirit of personal independence, self-reliance, excellence, and sense of responsibility, which develop strength, sound- ness and breadth of character. It would tend to remove most of the strongest influences which discipline, train and develop the personal life and at the same time invest it with variety, interest, deep significance and promise. 148 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics," Section III. of Chapter II., Part IV. This section is on "The Function of Government ; or, The Controlling Principle in States- manship," and points out the dividing line between the ■ class of undertakings that should be carried on, or con- ditions regulated, by the government, and those that should be left to private enterprise and individual choice. Additional References. In Rae's "Contemporary So- cialism," Chapter XL, on the practical aspects of "State Socialism," pointing out how the various socialist propo- sitions might be expected to work in practice. In Gunton's "Wealth and Progress," Section III. ot Chapter I., Part III. This also deals with the short- comings of socialism in practice ; it is entitled : "Inade- quacy of Socialistic Methods." In George Plarris's "Inequality and Progress," Chap- ters I. to VIII. inclusive ; but the whole book of twenty chapters might be read with great profit. It is a lucid, philosophical treatise, showing the impossibility of bring- ing about actual equality in any department of human life. Dr. Harris points out how in fact all the progress of the race comes from inequality or variety, and how, from the opportunities thus offered and responsibilities imposed, the highest development is attained, of which the race is capable at any given time. In Henry Wood's "Political Economy of Natural Law," Chapter XIIL, on "Socialism as a Political Sys- tem." Mr. Wood here contrasts the effects of the so- cialist proposition and the workings of natural law, on character and progress. In Graham's "Socialism, New and Old," Chapter VI., on "The Distribution of Wealth," as proposed by so- SOCIALISM 149 eialism, and Chapter XIII. on "The Supposed Spon- taneous Tendencies to Socialism." The Ann Arbor address of Nicholas Murray Butler on "The Education of Public Opinion," referred to and quoted from in Chapter I., might well be read again for the contrast it draws between healthy individualism and social uniformity. EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. What "Equality" Would Mean. "Nature knows no such thing as equality; it is a human invention thrown up as an artificial barrier against selfishness and tyranny. The law of life is the development of the heterogeneous, the dissimilar, the unequal; it tends away from the dull inefficiency of uniform equality toward the high effective- ness of well-organized differences. Destroy inequality of talent and capacity, and life as we know it stops. De- mocracy becomes unthinkable. The corner-stone of de- mocracy is natural inequality, its ideal the selection of the most fit. Liberty is far more precious than equality, and the two are mutually destructive. If all the hills and mountains of Europe were leveled off, it would result in producing a barren, dismal plain some nine hundred and odd feet higher than the present shore line. The beauty and productiveness of a continent would be gone. If all the wealth of the United States were divided equally among the population, it is estimated that we should each possess a capital of $1,100. Industry would be reduced to the lowest level ever known in modern times, every- thing which makes life agreeable would go out of it, and we should all be driven to a conflict and struggle for a bare subsistence to which the state of primitive war de- scribed by Hobbes would be as nothing." — From address ISO OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS of Nicholas Murray Butler, at the University of Michi- gan, June 22, 1899. Coercion Under Socialism. "Socialistic agitators des- cant upon 'wage-slavery,' but that is nothing compared with a coercion which would sweep away all liberty. The employer — and, the vast majority of employers are not rich — is a 'slave' to the markets, as much as the wage- earner to his toil, and often more, for he cannot so easily change his position. It would indeed be slavery to have eating, sleeping, clothing, working, and all the social and personal activities conducted upon the compulsory plan, in which each is assigned his place by the 'majority,' which would really consist of a few official dictators. The blotting out of individual liberty would mean real slavery. There would be no incentive for personal effort, such as is now afforded by the hope of providing for in- firmity or old age, or for the wants of family and kin- dred. The fruits of a man's industry would belong to 'The State.' The choice of occupation would be dictated by the office-holders of the dominant party." — From Henry Wood's "Political Economy of Natural Law," Chapter XIII. Defects of State Management of Industry. "What are the conditions of efficient state . administration ? The state possesses several natural characteristics which give it a decided advantage as an industrial manager, some for one branch of work, some for another. It has stability, it has permanency, and it has — what is perhaps its principal industrial superiority — unrivalled power of securing unity of administration, since it is the only agency that can use force for the purpose. On the other hand, it has one' great natural defect, its want of a personal stake in the produce of the business it conducts, its want of that keen check on waste and that pushing incentive to exertion SOCIALISM 151 which private undertakings enjoy in the eye and energy of the master. This is the great taproot from which all the usual faults of government management spring — its routine, red-tape spirit, its sluggishness in noting changes in the market, in adapting itself to changes in the public taste, and in introducing improved methods of produc- tion. Government servants may very generally be men of a higher stamp and training than the servants of a private company, but they are proverbial, on the one hand, for a certain lofty disdain of the humble but val- uable virtue of parsimony, and, on the other, for an un- progressive, unenterprising, uninventive administration of business. "Now, the branches of industry which the state is fitted to carry on are of course those in which its great fault happens to have small scope for play, and in which its great merit or merits have great scope for play ; those, for example, which gain largely in efficiency or economy by a centralized administration, and suffer little harm comparatively from a routine one. That is the reason governments always manage the postal service well. In post-office work the specific industrial superiority of gov- ernment carries its maximum of advantage, and its speci- fic industrial defect does its minimum of injury. The carrying and delivery of letters from one part of the em- pire to another require, for efficiency, a single co-ordina- ted system, and, on the other hand, those operations them- selves are of so unvariable and routine a character that little harm is done by their being carried on in a routine spirit ; they involve so little capital expenditure — the en- tire capital of the department in England is only £80,000 — ^that the opportunity for waste and corruption is slight ; and being conducted much more largely under the public eye than the affairs of other departments of state, they 152 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS are consequently subject to the constant and interested criticism of the people whose wants they are meant to satisfy. The same reason explains why government dockyards and arms factories are always managed so un- satisfactorily. There is, on the one hand, no need in them for any higher unity of administration than is wanted in any ordinary single business establishment; but, on the other, progressiveness and adaptability are of the first moment, routine and obstruction to improvement being indeed among their worst dangers. Then the risk of prodigality and corruption is high, for their capital ex- penditure is great, and the check of public criticism very distant and ineffectual. So exceptional a business is the post, that the telegraphs, though managed by the same department, have never been managed with the same suc- cess. They were bought at first at a ransom, they have involved an increasing loss nearly ever since, and the public have to pay practically as much for their telegrams — perhaps more — ^than the public of the United States pay to their telegraph companies. Even in the postal de- partment, government administration shows the usual official slowness in adopting much-needed and even lucra- tive reforms. Of this, a good example occurred only the other day. It was not until a Boys' Messenger Company was already in the field and doing the work that the post- master-general was brought to recognize, as he said, 'the desirability of providing a more rapid means of trans- mitting single letters for short distances and under special circumstances than at present exists.' " — From Rae's "Contemporary Socialism," Chapter XL, Section IV. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. I. What are some of the benefits promised by socialism? SOCIALISM 153 2. Mention two of the best known descriptions of an imaginary ideal socialistic society. 3. In considerinig remedies for poverty and other social ills, what great facts about human progress should be re- membered? 4. In the light of these facts, what question ought we to ask ourselves as to the best and safest methods of further ad- vancement? 5. Explain the diflference between socialism, communism and anarchism. 6. What system of production does socialism propose? Men- tion some of the diflferences in details advocated by dif- ferent groups of socialists. 7. What are some of the methods by which socialists hope to see their system established? 8. What is true of the comparative civilization of countries with different degrees of "paternalism" in their government? Give instances. 9. What would be the effect of substituting elected officials for private management of industries? 10. Why does popular election almost always result in the choice of mediocre men? 11. Mention some of the experiments in socialistic community life that have been made; what has been the result, and why? 12. Describe the great experiment in rnanufacturing coopera- tion in England, and explain the outcome. 13. In what chief respect is socialism contrary to the natural law of progress? 14. What would probably be some of the effects of socialism on individual character? CHAPTER XIX. THE SINGLE TAX. 84. The Single-Tax Theory. To put a "single tax" on land, equal to its economic rent, and abolish all other forms of taxation, is a scheme of social reform pro- pounded by Mr. Henry George in his "Progress and Pov- erty." It is advocated as one of those comprehensive re- forms which will solve every phase of industrial and so- cial injustice and hardship. On the score of simplicity it leaves little to be desired. It is probably the simplest scheme for solving the ills of society that was ever pro- pounded. It is much simpler than socialism. It does not propose that the government shall take possession of and operate all the industries of the country. The single-tax plan proposes to abolish poverty and injustice by* im- posing a single tax upon land, to the full extent of the economic rent derived from it. The basis of this doctrine is that God gave the earth to all the human race, and therefore individual ownership of any part of the earth's surface is a violation of God's moral law. It is held to be robbery, because it is taking for individual benefit what the Creator gave to everybody. 85. Its Fundamental Error. The great error in this proposition is that it assumes the value of land to be a part of its original condition. This is a mistake. In its original state land had no value. Value comes only when the land is utilized for human purposes, which al- ways means that effort is bestowed upon it. Nature sup- 154 THE SINGLE TAX 1 55 plies the substance but man supplies the value. There was just as much land in this country when the Pilgrims came as there is now, but it had no value. When the Indians were roaming over the country the iron and coal and gold and silver in our mountains was all there, but it had no value. The value came only when labor and capital were applied to appropriate it. Of course, man did not create land, neither does he create wool or iron. He tends the sheep and nature grows the wool. He clips the wool, washes it and manufactures it, and it is the clipping, washing and manufacturing, together with the expense of raising the sheep, that gives the wool its value. 86. How Land Values Are Determined. But, in considering the value of particular pieces of land, we find there is a great deal of productive land that has a high value, but upon which the expenditure has been small, compared with its value, while other land requiring pro- portionatel}- larger expense to utilize it has a low value. This is strictly in accordance with the general law of value; the law of land values, indeed, is simply a deduc- tion from or continuation of the law of rent. Rent arises on any given piece of land used in production in propor- tion to the surplus which it will yield over and above that derived from the least productive land whose prod- ucts compete in the same market. The value of the piece of land itself is reflected from its earning power ; it will be high or low according as this rent or surplus-yielding capacity is large or small. In other words, the value of a piece of land used in agriculture or any form of indus- try depends tipon its profitableness as compared with its poorest or dearest competitors. Some land is so barren or so far from a market that it cannot be made to pay the expenses of any kind of productive effort applied to it ; such land yields no rent and has no value, unless it be 156 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS a speculative value due to anticipated profitableness. Other land, more fertile or nearer to markets or offer- ing superior business advantages, will yield a surplus, and hence will have a value in proportion to this surplus derived from it ; and this surplus arises only because the price of its products is determined by the cost of produc- tion on the poorest or dearest land competing with it. It is for exactly the same reason that some manufacturing plants are much more valuable than others, because they can be operated at less relative cost and so will yield a larger profit. Land used for residence purposes is really in the group of commodities ; it is not an instrument of production. Productive land is what the single-tax proposition chiefly attacks, although the theory includes all kinds of land. Residence property is judged, not by the wealth that can be derived from it, but by its convenience, beauty of sit- uation and general social desirabilit}-. Its value is deter- mined by the same law that fixes the prices of commodi- ties. Plots of land of equal residential utility, conve- nience, etc., are like so many hats — they are all alike, and tend to be uniform in price. That price, whatever it is, is determined just as in the case of hats — ^by the cost of production of the dearest portion for which there is a market demand. In the case of land, cost of production means cost of developing, advertising, improving, making accessible by streets, supplying water and drainage, and a score of expense items. The owners of a certain portion of the plots of any given class, judged as residence prop- erty, find that these costs, including loss from unsold portions, etc., are greater than in the case of any of their competitors. They, therefore, will resist any competitive effort to force the price of the plots below a point that will at least repay their investment; sometimes they will THE SINGLE TAX I 57 hold land for jears rather than sell at a loss. This tends to establish the general line of value for residence prop- erty of that same class, and the other landowners will rate their property, or offer it for sale, at approximately the same price. Some, -of course, for the sake of quick returns, will sell their holdings for less, but this seldom affects what is recognized as the actual value of that class of property, so long as the dearer portions are also in demand. The great differences in the value of different kinds of residence property, are due simply to the fact that they belong in different groups, differing in residen- tial utility, just as caps, derbys and silk hats differ in so- cial utility. In each separate group, however, the price for all is determined by the cost of supplying the dearest portion. 87. Cost Qoes With Value. Therefore, it is not true that the value of land, either for production or resi- dence, is a free contribution of nature. It would have no value at all if human effort were not exerted to utilize it, make it accessible and available, and, in the case of pro- ductive land, to conduct industry upon it. Almost inva- riably, the most valuable land is that on which the largest actual amounts of effort and capital have been expended to give it its superior productivity, and which costs the most in gross amount, though of course less relatively, to maintain it; for example, the lots on Broadway in New York city. All that has ever been expended on har- bor and transportation facilities, on street improvements, on water and light supply, on fire protection, on all the phases of city government for which land taxes have been exacted, not to mention the expense of the buildings erected on these lots, have been items of cost, contribu- ting directly and indirectly to the earning power of the land and hence contributing to its value. Therefore, so IS8 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS far from land value being a free gift, the almost universal rule is that the greater the earning power, and hence value, of land, the greater has been the expenditure of labor and capital, directly and indirectly, upon it, and the greater is the cost, in taxes, assessments, improvements, etc., of continuously utilizing and maintaining it. 88. Rent Does Not Absorb All Economic Gain. It is asserted by advocates of the single tax that because rent of land apparently tends to increase, therefore rent absorbs all the gain in wealth production. This is a com- plete mistake. The rent of a piece of land used in pro- duction increases only when and because that land be- comes more productive, yielding not merely enough to pay the higher rent but also a surplus to the user of the property. Where rent is rising rapidly it is the best of evidence that the wealth-producing capacity of the land is rising still more rapidly. If rent absorbed all the gain, everybody would prefer to hire cheaper property, by using which the same profits could be earned without the risk of a high rent investment. In reality, it is the high- est-rent properties that are most eagerly sought for, by those who have sufficiently large enterprises to conduct, because the profits that can be made by using such prop- erty are so much greater, even after paying the high rent, than could be realized in other and lower-rent situations. For example, the cities are the places of highest rents, and they are also the places of the largest surpluses of wealth produced over and above the rents. On Wall Street and lower Broadway rents are very high, but it is just there that business is most profitable. So far from rent absorbing the whole gain in production, it really represents, in all probability, a diminishing relative pro- portion of the total wealth produced, just as truly as in- terest on capital to-day represents a diminishing relative THE SINGLE TAX I 59 proportion of the earnings of industry. Interest rates are slowly falling, and rent, while nominally increasing in many quarters, is actually not increasing, but prob- ably decreasing, in proportion to earning power. It should be remembered, moreover, that rents in some localities and sections are always falling while elsewhere they are rising. In the same city, even, some property is almost always declining in value while other property is increasing, according to changes in the drift of business, trade and residence. When rents were rising on the rich farms of the Northwest they were declining on the hill farms of New England, and some landlords were losing while others were gaining. It is not true, therefore, that land is a natural monopoly, constantly and everywhere in- creasing in value, and absorbing an increasing portion of the products of industry. There is no so-called "landlord class," in this country at least, for land is constantly changing ownership. It is simply one form of invest- ment, judged by comparison with the opportunities in manufacturing, mercantile and all other industries. If any particular land is exceptionally productive, whoever buys it must pay a proportionately high price for it, so that the return he receives in rent is not materially dif- ferent from what he would have received by putting out the same amount of money at interest. In fact, the price of land tends to rise or fall according as the rate of rent income on it becomes greater or less than the normal rate of interest on capital. 89. Single-Tax Would Be Robbery. Land in this country changes ownership so often that by far the larger part of it is owned by persons who have bought and paid for it at its full value within, say, a generation. To them it represents actual cost, money, savings or whatever, in- vested in this land ; while families that have held land l6o OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS for several generations have as a rule expended, first and last, considerable sums in improving and increasing its productive capacity or residential desirability. To tax away the full value of land, therefore, as the single-tax proposition demands, would be sheer robbery and would never be tolerated by a free people. The government that should attempt such an act of despotism would be swept away by revolution before it could begin to enforce it. 90. It Could Not Abolish Poverty. The claim that the single tax would abolish poverty must be considered a delusion. If all the value of land were confiscated by a tax, nobody, would care to own any, and land would then be taken by the state and become its property. So far as land is concerned, this would be socialism, but in what way would it affect poverty ? Who would get more if the state owned the land than at present? If the state owned the land it would become the landlord, and who- ever used it would merely have to pay rent to the state in- stead of to private owners. The rent exacted by the state would be governed by the same law as now, because it could not be governed ,by any other. If the state de- manded equal rent for all kinds of land, good or bad, near or far from markets, it simply could not get it. Nobody would hire any land except that which would yield more than the cost of using it. Nobody would pay rent for land so barren or far away that it took all the profits to pay the rent, whether the state owned it or anybody else. Even the state cannot make people continuously do busi- ness at a loss. The same different degrees of utility would exist in the land that exist now, and that would govern the rent anybody would pay for its use. There- fore, rents would either have to be the same as now, or the state, by trying to fix uniform rents, would have the larger part of the land left idle on its hands and the THE^SINGLE TAX l6l rest earning enormous profits for the fortunate occupiers. There is one primary condition without which nobody will use land, whether for building, agriculture, or any other purpose ; and that is, a demand or market for the products. The single tax, therefore, could not compel people to use land which they were holding for specula- tive purposes. If there were not a sufficiently, profitable opportunity for using the land, the owner would sur- render it to the government rather than lo^e money by trying to conduct an industry upon it while paying the government's assessed tax of the full rental value. The government could not force industries into existence in any such way, because that is a matter governed entirely by the market opportunities. Nor could the single tax do anything towards abolish- ing poverty by lowering prices to the consumers. Prod- ucts would not be cheapened by the fact that the state took all the rent, because prices would still be determined by the cost of production on the dearest land, as at pres- ent. It would cost just as much to utilize the poor or badly situated land for any given purpose then as it does now. The cost of production, therefore, would be the same ; the cost of the dearest portion would be the same, and hence prices would be the same. Real wages would not be increased by the single tax. Rent would have to be paid just as now, to the state as a tax, instead of to private landlords as rent, and, as we have just seen, the tax could not force industries into existence and so increase employment for labor. The only thing that the single tax would really accomplish is to establish government ownership of land. This would be a disadvantage, because the state is never as efficient in the use of any productive instrument as is private en terprise. This would neither increase the use of land, re- l62 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS duce the price of products from the land, give a single additional laborer a day's work on land, nor do anything whatever to raise wages. The single tax is based on a false assumption. It will produce none of the results predicted for it, because it does not affect the economic conditions out of which these results arise. As a means of raising revenue, a tax on real property is far superior to any form of taxes on incomes and personal property, or any method of direct taxation, but a revenue tax should be levied only as required to meet government ex- penses or for public improvements, not for the purpose of confiscating private property regardless of the amount of revenue required. Instead of being a means of estab- lishing justice, the single tax would be nothing less than legalized robbery. As a means of abolishing poverty it is a delusion. SUGGESTED READING. In "Principles of Social Economics,'' Section IV. of Chapter IV., Part III. This section discusses the ques- tion: "Is Rent a Social Tax?" and has already been sug- gested in connection with the chapter on Rent. Additional References. In Gunton's "Wealth and Progress," Section III. of Chapter I., Part II., on "Henry George's Theory" — of wages. In Hadley's "Economics," Sections 521 to 524 inclu- sive, in Chapter XIV This chapter is on "Government Revenue," and the sections mentioned point out some of the economic and moral defects of the single-tax proposition. In Sehgman's "Essays on Taxation," Chapter III, on "The Single Tax." In Francis A. Walker's "Land and Its Rent," Chapter III., on "Recent Attacks Upon Landed Property." THE SINGLE TAX 1 63 The pamphlet, "Economic Heresies of Henry George," by George Gunton, is also recommended. For a complete statement of the single-tax doctrine see Henry George's "Progress and Poverty." EXTRACTS FROM READINGS. No Sudden Millenniuni Possible. "It is clearly impos- sible to discuss in this place the wider claim of the single- taxers, that the application of their scheme would intro- duce the social millennium. If economists thought that the distinguished single-tax leader had solved this prob- lem they would enthrone him high on their council seats ; they would reverently bend the knee and acknowledge in him a master, a prophet. But when he comes to them with a tale that is as old as the hills ; when he sets forth in his writings doctrines that have long since been re- futed ; when in his enthusiasm he seeks to impose a remedy which appears to them as unjust as it is one- sided, as inconsistent as it is inequitable, — they have a right to protest. This is not the first time that some en- thusiast has supposed that he has discovered a world- saving panacea. The remedy for social maladjustments does not lie in any such lop-sided idea; the only cure is the slow, gradual evolution of the moral conscience ot mankind. We cannot solve the labor problem by any rule of thumb. Every student of history, of political philoso- phy, of economics, will tell us that the progress of the race has been slow and painful; that the world has ad- vanced step by step ; and that each successive step, to be enduring, must be founded on justice. To suppose for a moment that the social millennium will be ushered in by any one sudden change — even were the change not so lamentably inadequate as the one above discussed — is an 164 OUTLINES OF|SOCIAL ECONOMICS evidence not of wisdom, but of short-sightedness." — From Seligman's "Essays on Taxation," Chapter III. A One-Sided Proposition. "Now it is evident, beyond challenge or question by any honest man, that in a read- justment of the relations of land, made primarily to meet the demands of political equity, the state, if it will claim the benefit of all gain resulting from general causes af- fecting the numbers and productive power of the com- munity, and thus due neither to the merits nor to the sacrifices of owners, is bound to make good all losses re- sulting from a decline of demand due to causes which are of a general nature, and are thus attributable to no fault or neglect on the part of owners. If he who remains, in name, the proprietor of land is not to be allowed to reap any gain not brought about by his own exertions, he has a good claim to be saved harmless from loss which no effort of his could have averted." — From Walker's "Land and Its Rent," Chapter III. Fallacies in Single-Tax Theory. "In contradiction, then, of Mr. George's proposition that the entire effect of an increase of production is expended in raising rents, neither wages nor the interest of capital deriving any gain whatsoever therefrom, rent indeed absorbing the entire gain, 'and more than the gain,' we have seen, — "i. That an increase of production may enhance the demand for labor equally with the demand for land. "2. That, in fact, in those forms of production which especially characterize modern society, the rate of en- hancement of the demand for labor tends to far exceed the rate of enhancement of the demand for land. "3. That an increased demand for the production of wealth may, and in a vast body of instances does, enhance the demand for labor without enhancing the demand for land in any, the slightest degree, the whole eflfect being THE SINGLE TAX 165 expended in the elaboration of the same amount of ma- terial. "4. We have now only to show, in the fourth place, that, instead of all improvements and inventions increas- ing the demand for land, as Mr. George declares, some very extensive classes of improvements and inventions ac- tually operate powerfully, directly, and exclusively in reducing the demand for land, — we have, I say, only to show this, to convict this would-be apostle of a new po- litical economy and a regenerated humanity, iof the grossest incompetence for economic reasoning. This it will be easy to do." — From Walker's "Land and Its Rent," Chapter III. QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW OR DEBATE. 1. What is the single-tax proposition? What does it promise? 2. On what theory of land value is it based? 3. How is the value of productive land really determined? 4. How is the value of land used for residence purposes de- termined? 5. What are some of the elements of cost in utilizing land? On what kind of land are these items actually, though not relatively, largest? 6. Does rent absorb all the gain in wealth production? Does it take an increasing or relatively decreasing portion? Illustrate. 7. Is all land increasing in value? Is there any permanent landlord class? Give reasons for answer. 8. What great injustice would the single tax inflict? g. Would the single tax make land "free" to all comers? If not, what system of rent charges would the state as land- lord have to adopt? 10. Could the single tax force unused la:nd into use? Give reasons for your answer. 11. What effect would it have on wages and employment? Why? 12. What effect would it have on prices of commodities? Why? CHAPTER XX. COOPERATION AND PROFIT-SHARING. 91. What Cooperation Is. Cooperation and profit- sharing are propositions for industrial reform, aiming at a better distribution of wealth. Cooperation is a form of socialism, though not of a political character. It is a voluntary effort to conduct specific industries on the strictly democratic plan. Hundreds of cooperative experiments have been made, during the last half century and more. Cooperation dif- fers from socialism in that socialism aims to have the government own and conduct all productive industry, while cooperation relies on voluntary association and divides the results according to the amount of stock held, while the management is by majority vote of the stock- holders as individuals. 92. Difference Between Cooperation and Corpora- tions. Sometimes we hear people speak of corporations as a form of cooperation. That is a distortion of the term. The difference is very great. Corporations are chartered companies in which, not only the profits are divided according to the number of shares held, but the management also goes with the ownership of the capital. If one man owns more than half he can have absolute management of the corporation, because by majority vote he can elect all the directors and dictate the entire policy. With cooperation the case is quite different. The profits, to be sure, are divided according to the capi- 166 COOPERATION AND PROFIT-SHARING 1 67 tal, whatever that may be, and the owner of the largest amount of stock in a cooperative concern will therefore get the largest share of the dividends. But when it comes to the management the case is quite different. This, under cooperation, is thoroughly democratic. It assumes that one man knows just as much as another, which of course is not true. 93. History of Productive Cooperation. Modern cooperative experiments came into existence about the middle of this century. The movement was the historic successor of the chartist movement in England. It grew out of the ruins of the Fergus O'Connor land-ownership scheme for poor people, which finally collapsed in 1848. Under the leadership of a few of the former followers of the Owenite movement and the radical chartists, co- operative experiments were made. These took two dif- ferent directions, one in productive enterprise, like manu- factures, and the other in mercantile or, as they call it, distributive enterprises. The history of these two lines of experimenting is very instructive and throws much light on the character and possibility of industrial co- operation. The first efforts were in manufacturing, and for a time they seemed very promising. The experiments were quite successful until they reached the stage of being what we may call established industries, when they came into steady competition with non-cooperative enterprises. Under the enthusiasm of the cooperative idea, the ex- periments extended through the greater part of Lan- cashire. Some of the largest cotton factories were built and equipped on the purely cooperative plan, and many people who did not believe in cooperation invested in them. But a quarter of a century saw the collapse of the entire cooperative experiment in productive industry. l68 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS Democracy of management did what it nearly always does at the convention and ballot-box in politics; it se- lected the superficial faultfinder, the popular sentimental- ist, and rejected the hard-headed and efficient business manager. The outcome was that to prevent bankruptcy and ruin one concern after another was converted into a regular joint-stock corporation. The cooperative ele- ment was dropped, and now the concerns are as success- ful as their average competitors. In other words, the experiment proved that in productive enterprise on any considerable scale, where the industry is complex and requires special skill and expert management, coopera- tion was an unqualified failure. 94. Success of Mercantile Cooperation. In mer- cantile enterprise, however, it has been a signal success. In conducting grocery and haberdashery and general sup- ply stores, the cooperative plan has worked well from the first. Starting at about the same time that productive cooperation did in England, and at the same place, while cooperative manufacture has disappeared cooperative stores have multiplied and become very large, being in many respects superior to private concerns. The local cooperative stores have established wholesale stores which they jointly own and through which they make their purchases. They have their agents in different countries purchasing, on the best terms, supplies for all their various departments. What is the reason why the one kind of cooperation failed and the other has been such a marked success? Chiefly because productive cooperation requires expert talent, quick decision, inventive genius, and constant re- sourceful adaptation to conditions, in its management, while the other does not. The purchasing of materials, choice and operation of machinery, direction of experi- COOPERATION AND PROFIT-SHARING 1 69 ments, application of inventions, are necessary in manu- facturing without much waiting. Mediocre effort and slow judgment, which the yearly or half-yearly meeting of the cooperative concerns furnished, put the manage- ment to a disadvantage. In selling its products it had to compete with concerns guided by individual enterprise and expert management. Clumsy methods, waste, and poor management could not succeed against the highest type of individual effort. When a cooperative concern failed to make profits the manager would be removed at the next annual meeting, and the man who made the strongest speech against the management would proba- bly be appointed, however little he might know about the business. In mercantile enterprises it was different. The man- agers were selected by the same method, but they sold goods to their own members. They did not have to go into competition with other firms on prices. They fixed their prices so as to cover their expenses, and coopera- tive prices were often from ten to fifteen per cent, higher than the prices of private concerns. But this secured the enterprise against loss and always insured a dividend, be- cause prices could always be put to a point where they would yield a dividend at the end of the quarter. This was a seeming net gain to the members of the coopera- tive associations. At any rate, it acted as an automatic savings institution. It was the rule of the cooperative stores to compel the members to leave their dividends until they acquired a share in the business, of a certain amount, upon which they would always receive interest. In this way the stores never failed, and they gradually grew from grocery stores into large department stores, supplying everything from bread and butter to the mi- nute furnishing of a home, and later even providing 170 OUTLINES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS houses on the installment plan. Being free from com- petition on prices their permanence was secured, and establishing their own wholesale stores yielded a great economy in business. This distributive cooperation in England also had so- cial and educational features. They erected their own buildings and in each one would usually have a lecture- hall free for all purposes of the association, a library, a well-appointed reading-room, and sometimes excellent courses of lectures. In this way they conducted, as a part of the expense of the business, an educational work which was very beneficial and has been a great factor in the intellectual and social improvement of the people. The secret of the success of this phase of cooperation is that it does not have to be on its merits as an economic proposition. The owners of each store are themselves the purchasers of its products. The stores buy their goods in open market and sell to their own members. When it has been attempted, as under productive cooperation, to produce by the members and sell in the open market it has failed. Moreover, conducting a mercantile business is a much less complex matter than operating highly-de- veloped manufacture. Being free from competition as to prices, cooperative stores succeed with mediocre tal- ent. This indicates that cooperation on a purely demo- cratic basis can succeed only in lines of industry where the methods are relatively permanent and simple, and not subject to the revolutions which invention and expert management by competitors may create. Where the undertaking is subject to competition with private con- cerns, and the methods are complex and subject to sud- den changes by the introduction of new methods, then mediocre management by popular election on the co- operative plan is in great danger of failure. COOPERATION AND PROFIT-SHARING 171 95. Prolit=Sharing. Profit-sharing is quite distinct from cooperation. It is a system of distributing a part of the profits of an industry among the employees, but l