CORNELL UNIVERSITY LIBRARY BOUGHT WITH THE INCX>J.fE OF THE SAGE ENDOWMENT FUND GIVEN IN 1891 BY HENRY WILLIAMS SAGE Cornell University Library DG 209.G81 1906 History of Rome : 3 1924 028 284 663 The original of tliis book is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924028284663 A HISTORY OF ROME A HISTORY OF ROME FROM THE TRIBUNATE OF TIBERIUS GRACCHUS TO THE END OF THE JUGURTHINE WAR B.C. 133—104 BY A. H. J. GREENIDGE, MA., D.Litt. LATE TUTOR AND FELLOW OF HERTFORD COLLEGE AND LECTURER IN ANCIENT HISTORY AT BRASENOSE COLLEGE, OXFORD With two maps METHUEN & CO. 36 ESSEX STREET W.C. LONDON Mrst Published in 1904 TO B. G. AND T. G. PREFACE This work will be comprised in six volumes. According to the plan ifhich I have provisionally laid down, the second volume will cover he period from 104< to 70 b.c, ending with the first consulship of *ompeius and Crassus ; the third, the period from 70 to 44 b.c, losing with the death of Caesar ; the fourth volume will probably )e occupied by the Third Civil War and the rule of Augustus, while he fifth and sixth will cover the reigns of the Emperors to the iccession of Vespasian. The original sources, on which the greater part of the contents if the present volume is based, have been collected during the last ew years by Miss Clay and myself, and have already been published n an abbreviated form. Some idea of the debt which I owe to Qodem authors may be gathered from the references in the foot- lotes. As I have often, for the sake of brevity, cited the works of hese authors by shortened and incomplete titles, I have thought it .dvisable to add to the volume a list of the full titles of the works eferred to. But the list makes no pretence to be a full biblio- ;raphy of the period of history with which this volume deals. The oap of the Wad Mellag and its surrounding territory, which I have riserted to illustrate the probable site of the battle of the Muthul, 3 taken from the map of the " Medjerda superieure " which appears a M. Salomon Reinach's Atlas de la Province Romaine d^Afrique. I am very much indebted to my friend and former pupil, Mr. 5. J. Harding, of Hertford College, for the ungrudging labour which e has bestowed on the proofs of the whole of this volume. Many nprovements in the form of the work are due to his perspicacity nd judgment. viii PREFACE A problem which confronts an author who plunges into thi midst of the history of a nation (however complete may be th( unity of the period with which he deals) is that of the amount o introductory information which he feels bound to supply to hii readers. In this case, I have felt neither obligation nor inclinatior to supply a sketch of the development of Rome or her constitutior up to the period of the Gracchi. The amount of information or the general and political history of Rome which the average studeni must have acquired from any of the excellent text-books now ir use, is quite sufficient to enable him to understand the technicalities of the politics of the period with which I deal ; and I was ver} unwilling to burden the volume with a prdcis of a subject which 1 had already treated in another work. On the other hand, it is nol so easy to acquire information on the social and economic historj of Rome, and consequently I have devoted the first hundred pages of this book to a detailed exposition of the conditions preceding and determining the gi-eat conflict of interests with which oui story opens. A. H. J. G. Oxford, August, 1904 NOTE This volume, intended as the first of a series, is now left by the lamented death of its Author as an isolated unit. Dr. Greenidge has not left behind him sufficient material to justify the continuance of the work by the hand of an Editor. Notwithstanding this un- happy curtailment of the original scheme, the Publishers believe that this volume, comprising as it does a strongly marked epoch of Roman History, is well able to stand alone, and to serve as a valu- able contribution to the story of the later Republic. August, 1906 CONTENTS {The references are to the pages) CHAPTER I Characteristics of the period, i. Recent changes in the conditions of Roman life, 2. Close of the period of expansion by means of colonies or land assignments, 3. Reasons for social discontent, 10. The life of the wealthier classes, 11. The expenses of political life, 23. Attempts to check luxury, 27. Motives for gain amongst the upper classes, 31. Means of acquiring wealth open to members of the nobility, 32 ; those open to members of the com- mercial class, 41. The political influence of the Equites, 47. The business life of Rome ; finance and banking, 49. Foreign trade, 53. The condition of the small traders, 55. Agriculture, 58. Diminution in the numbers of peasant pro- prietors, 59. The Latifundium and the new agricultural ideal, 64. Growth of pasturage, 66. Causes of the changes in the tenure of land, 6g. The system of possession, 73. Future prospects of agriculture, 78. Slave labour, 81 ; dangers attending its employment ; revolts of slaves in Italy, 86. The servile war in Sicily (circa 140-131 B.C.), 8g. The need for reform, gg. CHAPTER n The sources from which reform might have come, 100. Attitude of Scipio Aemilianus, 102. Tiberius Gracchus; his youth and early career, 103. The affair of the Numantine Treaty, 108. Motives that urged Tiberius Gracchus to reform, log. His tribunate (b.c. 133), no. Terms of the agrarian meastue which he introduced, in. Creation of a special agrarian commission, 116. Opposition to the bill, 117. Veto pronounced by Marcus Octavius, 120. Tiberius Gracchus declares a Justitium, 121. Fruitless reference to the senate, 122. Deposition of Octavius, 125, Passing of the agrarian law ; appointment of the commissioners ; judicial power given to the commissioners, 127. Em- ployment of the bequest of Attalus, I2g. Attacks on Tiberius Gracchus, 130. His defence of the deposition of Octavius, 132. New programme of Tiberius Gracchus ; suggestion of measures dealing with the army, the law-courts and the Italians, 134. Tiberius Gracchus's attempt at re-election to the tribunate, 137. Riot at the election and death of Tiberius Gracchus, 139. Consequences of his fall, 143. Does the Eagle know what is in the pit ? Or wilt thou go ask the Mole ? Can Wisdom be put in a silver rod ? Or Love in a golden bowl ? Blake A HISTORY OF ROME CHAPTER I THE period of lioman history on which we now enter is, like so many that had preceded it, a period of revolt, directly aimed against the existing conditions of society and, through the neans taken to satisfy the fresh wants and to alleviate the suddenly •ealised, if not suddenly created, miseries of the time, indirectly iffecting the structure of the body politic. The difference between ;he social movement of the present and that of the past may be ustly described as one of degree, in so far as there was not a single ilement of discontent visible in the revolution commencing with ;he Gracchi and ending with Caesar that had not been present in ;he earlier epochs of social and political agitation. \The burden )f military service, the curse of debt, the poverty of an agrarian proletariate, the hunger for land, the striving of the artisan and ;he merchant after better conditions of labour and of trade — the ;eparate cries of discontent that find their unison in a protest igainst the monopoly of office and the narrow or selfish rule of a lominant class, and thus gain a significance as much political as locial — 9,11 these plaints had filled the air at the time when Caius Licinius near the middle of the fourth century, and Appius Claudius it its close, evolved their projects of reform. The cycle of a lation's history can indeed never be broken as long as the character )f the nation remains the same. And the average Roman of the niddle of the second century before our era ^ was in all essential parti- ;ulars the Roman of the times of Appius and of Licinius, or even of ;he epoch when the ten commissioners had published the Tables vhich were to stamp its perpetual character on Roman law. He vas in his business relations either oppressor or oppressed, either lammer or anvil. In his private life he was an individualist whose ' The average, or at least the most powerful, type of a race is stamped on its listory. It is perliaps needless to say that no generalisations on character apply o all its individual members. 1 X CONTENTS CHAPTER III Attitude of the senate after the fall of Tiberius Gracchus, 145. Special commisi appointed for the trial of his adherents (b.c. 132), 146. Fate of Scipio Nas 147. Permanence of the land commission and thoroughness of its work, Difficulties connected with jurisdiction on disputed claims, 150. The Itali appeal to Scipio Aemilianus, 154. His intervention ; judicial power taken f the commissioners (b.c. 129), 157. Death of Scipio Aemilianus, 159. Tribui of Carbo (B.C. 131) ; ballot law and attempt to make the tribune immedia re-eligible, 163. The Italian claims; negotiations for the extension of franchise, 165. Alien act of Pennus (b.c. 126), 166. Proposal made by Flac to extend the franchise (b.c. 125), 167. Revolt of Fregellae, 170. Foundat of Fabrateria (b.c. 124), 171. Foreign events during this period ; the kingc of Pergamon, 172. Bequest of Attalus the Third (e.g. 133), 175. Revolt Aristonicus (b.c. 132-130), 177. Organisation of the province of Asia (b.c. i 126), 183. Sardinian War (b.c 126-125), 188. Conquest and annexation of Balearic Islands (b.c 123-122), 188. CHAPTER IV The political situation at the time of the appearance of Caius Gracchus a candidate for the tribunate (e.g. 124), igo. Early career of Caius Grace! igi. First tribunate of Caius Gracchus (e.g. 123), 199. Laws passed or ] posed during this tribunate ; law protecting the Caput of a Roman citizen, i Impeachment of Popillius, 201. Law concerning magistrates who had b deposed by the people, 202. Social reforms, 203. Law providing for cheapened sale of corn, 205. Law mitigating the conditions of military serv 208. Agrarian law, 209. Judiciary law, 210. Law permitting a crim: prosecution for corrupt judgments, 216. Law concerning the province of A 218. The new balance of power created by these laws in favour of the Equi 221. Law about the consular provinces, 222. Colonial schemes of Ci Gracchus, 224. The Rubrian law for the renewal of Carthage, 227. Law the making of roads, 228. Election of Fannius to the consulship and of d Gracchus and Flaccus to the tribunate, 230. Activity of Caius Grace during his second tribunate (e.g. 122), 231. The franchise bill, 233. Opposit to the bill, 235. Exclusion of Italians from Rome ; threat of the veto, suspension of the measure, 236. Proposal for a change in the order of vol in the Coraitia Centuriata, 237. New policy of the senate ; counter-legislal of Drusus, 238. Colonial proposals of Drusus, 240. His measure for the ] tection of the Latins, 242. The close of Caius Gracchus's second tribun 243. His failure to be elected tribune for the third time, 247. Proposal for repeal of the Rubrian law, 248. The meeting on the Capitol and its c sequences (e.g. izi), 249. Declaration of a state of siege, 251. The seizun the Aventine ; defeat of the Gracchans ; death of Caius Gracchus and Flaci 253. Judicial prosecution of the adherents of Caius Gracchus, 257. Ful judgments on the Gracchi, 259. The closing years of Cornelia, 260. Estin of the character and consequences of the Gracchan reforms, 261. CONTENTS xi CHAPTER V The political situation after the fall of Caius Gracchus, 277. Prosecution and acquittal of Opimius (b.c. 120), 278. Publius Lentulus dies in exile, 280. Pro- secution and condemnation of Carbo (b.c. ng), 281. Lucius Crassus, 282. Policy of the senate towards the late schemes of reform, 283. Two new land laws {circa 121-119 B.C.), 285. The settlement of the land question with respect to Ager Publicus in Italy (b.c. hi), 288. Limitations on the power of the nobility; the Equestrian courts; trials of Scaevola (b.c. 120) and Cato (e.g. 113), 295. Consulship of Scaurus (b.c. 115) ; law concerning the voting power of freedmen, 296. Sumptuary law; activity of the censors Metellus and Domitius (e.g. 115), 297. Triumphs of Domitius, Fabius (b.c. 120) and Scaurus (e.g. 115), for military successes, 298. Confidence of the electors in the ancient houses, 298. Recognition of talent by the nobility; career of Scaurus (b.g. 163-115), 298. The rise of Marius; his early career (b.c 157-119), 301. Tribunate of Marius (b.c. 119), 303. His law about the method of voting in the Comitia carried in spite of the opposition of the senate, 304. He opposes a measure for the distribution of corn, 306. Marius elected praetor ; accused and acquitted of Ambitus (e.g. 116), 306. His praetorship (b.g. 115), and pro- praetorship in Spain (b.c 114), 304. Further opposition to the senate ; founda- tion of Narbo Martins (b.c 118), 308. Glaucia; his tribunate and his law of extortion (ceVco III B.C.), 309. The spirit of unrest; religious fears at Rome (b.g. 114), 311. First trial of the vestals (b.g. 114), 312. Second trial of the vestals (e.g. 113), 313. Human sacrifice, 314. Great fire at Rome (b.g. hi), 314. CHAPTER VI The kingdom of Numidia, 315. The races of North Africa, 317. The Numidians, 318. The Numidian monarchy, 320. Reign of Micipsa (b.c 148-118), 323. Early years of Jugurtha, 323. Jugurtha at Numantia (b.c 134-133), 324. Joint rule of Jugurtha, Adherbal and Hiempsal (b.c 118), 326. Murder of Hiempsal {circa 116 b.c) ; war between Jugurtha and Adherbal, 328. Both kings send envoys to Rome; the appeal of Adherbal, 329. Decision of the senate, 331. Numidia divided between the claimants, 333. Renewal of the war between Jugurtha and Adherbal {circa 114 b.c), 334. Siege of Cirta (b.c 112), 335. Embassy firom Rome neglected by Jugurtha, 337. Renewed appeal of Adherbal, 339. Another commission sent by Rome, 340. Surrender of Cirta and murder of Adherbal, 343. Massacre of Italian traders, 343. Its influence on the commercial classes at Rome ; protest by Memmius, 344. Declaration of war against Jugurtha, 345, Command of Bestia in Numidia (b.c hi), 347. Attitude of Bocchus of Mauretania, 349. Negotiations of Bestia with Jugurtha ; conclusion of peace, 351. Excitement in Rome on the news of the agreement with Jugurtha, 353. Activity of Memmius, 355. Jugurtha induced to come to Rome (e.g. iio), 358. Jugurtha at Rome; the scene at the Contio, 361. Murder of Massiva, 363. Jugurtha leaves Rome and the war is renewed, 365. Spurius Albinus in Numidia, 367. He returns to Rome leaving Aulus AI- binus in command, 369. Enterprise of Aulus Albinus ; his defeat and compact with Jugurtha (e.g. 109), 370. Reception of the news at Rome ; the senate invalidates the treaty, 372. Return of Spurius Albinus to Africa, 374. The Mamilian Commission (b.g. no), 375. Metellus appointed to Numidia (b.c log), 380. Does the Eagle know what is in the pit ? Or wilt thou go ask the Mole ? Can Wisdom be put in a silver rod ? Or Love in a golden bowl ? Blake A HISTORY OF ROME CHAPTER I THE period of Roman history on which we now enter is, like so many that had preceded it, a period of revolt, directly aimed against the existing conditions of society and, through the neans taken to satisfy the fresh wants and to alleviate the suddenly ealised, if not suddenly created, miseries of the time, indirectly ifFecting the structui-e of the body politic. The difference between he social movement of the present and that of the past may be ustly described as one of degree, in so far as there was not a single ilement of discontent visible in the revolution commencing with he Gracchi and ending with Caesar that had not been present in he earlier epochs of social and political agitation. iThe burden »f military service, the curse of debt, the poverty of an agrarian )roletariate, the hunger for land, the striving of the artisan and ;he merchant after better conditions of labour and of trade — the eparate cries of discontent that find their unison in a protest igainst the monopoly of office and the narrow or selfish rule of a lominant class, and thus gain a significance as much political as ocial-^%11 these plaints had filled the air at the time when Caius jicinius near the middle of the fourth century, and Appius Claudius it its close, evolved their projects of reform. The cycle of a lation's history can indeed never be broken as long as the character if the nation remains the same. And the average Roman of the aiddle of the second century before our era ^ was in all essential parti- ulars the Roman of the times of Appius and of Licinius, or even of he epoch when the ten commissioners had published the Tables irhich were to stamp its perpetual character on Roman law. He 7as in his business relations either oppressor or oppressed, either tammer or anvil. In his private life he was an individualist whose ' The average, or at least the most powerful, type of a race is stamped on its istory. It is perhaps needless to say that no generalisations on character apply D all its individual members. 1 2 A HISTORY OF ROME sympathies were limited to the narrow circle of his dependants ; he was a trader and a financier whose humanitarian instincts were subordinated to a code of purely commercial morality, and who valued equity chiefly because it presented the line of least resistance and facilitated the conduct of his industrial operations. Like all individualists, he was something of an anarchist, fi;lled with the idea, which appeared on every page of the record of his ancestors and the history of his State, that self-help was the divinely given means of securing right, that true social order was the issue of conflicting claims pushed to their breaking point until a temporary compromise was agreed on by the weary combatants ; but he was hampered in his democratic leanings by the knowledge that demo- cracy is the fruit of individual self-restraint and subordination to the common will — qualities of which he could not boast and symbols of a prize which he would not have cared to attain at the expense of his peculiar ideas of personal freedom — and he was forced, in consequence of this abnegation, to submit to an executive govern- ment as strong, one might almost say as tyrannous, as any which a Republic has ever displayed — a government which was a product of the restless spirit of self-assertion and self-aggrandisement which the Roman felt in himself, and therefore had sufficient reason to suspect in others. The Roman was the same; but his environment had changed more startlingly during the last fifty or sixty years than in all the centuries that had preceded them in the history of the Republic. The conquest of Italy had, it is true, given to his city much that was new and fruitful in the domains of religion, of art, of commerce and of law. But these accretions merely entailed the fuller realisa- tion of a tendency which had been marked from the earliest stage of Republican history — the tendency to fit isolated elements in the marvellous discoveries made by the heaven-gifted race of the Greeks into a framework that was thoroughly national and Roman. Ideas had been borrowed, and these ideas certainly resulted in increased efficiency and therefore in increased wealth. But the gross material of Hellenism, whether as realised in intellectual ideas or (the prize that appealed more immediately to the practical Roman with his concrete mind) in tangible things, had not been seized as a whole as the reward of victory : and no great attempt had been made in former ages to assimilate the one or to enjoy the other. The nature of the material rewards which had been secured by the epochs of CLOSE OF THE PERIOD OF EXPANSION 3 Italian conquest had indeed made such assimilation or enjoyment impossible. They would have been practicable only in a state which possessed a fairly complete urban life ; and the effect of the wars which Rome waged with her neighbours in the peninsula had been to make the life of the average citizen more purely agricultural than it had been in the early Republic, perhaps even in the epoch of the Kings. The course of a nation's political, social and intel- lectual history is determined very largely by the methods which it adopts for its own expansion at the inevitable moment when its original limits are found to be too narrow to satisfy even the most modest needs of a growing population. The method chosen will depend chiefly on geographical circumstances and on the military characteristics of the people which are indissolubly connected with these. When the city of Old Greece began to feel the strength of its' growing manhood, and the developing hunger which was both the sign and the source of that strength, it looked askance at the mountain line which cut it off from the inland regions, it turned hopeful eyes on the sea that sparkled along its coasts ; it manned its ships and sent its restless youth to a new and distant home which was but a replica of the old. The results of this maritime adventure were the glories of urban life and the all-embracing sweep of Hellenism. The progress of Roman enterprise had been very different. Following the example of all conquering Itahan peoples,^ and especially of the Sabellian invaders whose movements immediately preceded their own, the Romans adopted the course of inland expansion, and such urban unity as they had possessed was dissipated over the vast tract of territory on which the legions were settled, or to which the noble sent his armed retainers, nominally to keep the land as the public domain of Rome, in reality to hold it for himself and his descendants. At a given moment (which is as clearly marked in Roman as in Hellenic history) the possibility of such expansion ceased, and the necessity for its cessation was as fully exhibited in the policy of the government as in the tastes of the people. No Latin colony had been planted later than the year 181, no Roman colony later than 157,^ and the senate showed no inclination to renew schemes for the further assignment of territory ' Even the Hellenes of the West are only a partial exception. It is true that their cities clung to the coast ; but the vast inland possessions of states like Sybaris are scarcely paralleled elsewhere in the history of Greek colonisation. "The Latin colony of Aquileia was settled in the former year (Liv. xl. 34 Vellei. i. 15), the Roman colony of Auximum in the latter (Vellei. I.e.). 4 A HISTORY OF ROME amongst the people. There were many reasons for this indifference to colonial enterprise. In the first place, although colonisation had always been a relief to the proletariate and one of the means regularly' adopted by those in power for assuaging its dangerous discontent, yet the government had always regarded the social aspect of this method of expansion as subservient to the strategic.^ This strategic motive no longer existed, and a short-sighted policy, which looked to the present, not to the future, to men of the exist- ing generation and not to their sons, may easily have held that a colony, which was not needed for the protection of the district in which it was settled, injuriously affected the fighting-strength of Rome. The maritime colonies which had been established from the end of the great Latin war down to the close of the second struggle with Carthage claimed, at least in many cases, exemption from military service,^ and a tradition of this kind tends to linger when its justification is a thing of the past. But, even if such a view could be repudiated by the government, it was certain that the levy became a more serious business the greater the number of communities on which the recruiting commander had to call, and it was equally manifest that the veteran who had just been given an allotment on which to establish his household gods might be inclined to give a tardy response to the call to arms. The Latin colony seemed a still greater anachronism than the military colony of citizens. The member of such a community, although the state which he entered enjoyed large privileges of autonomy, ceased to be a Roman citizen in respect to political rights, and even at a time when self-government had been valued almost more than citizen- ship, the government had only been able to carry out its project of pushing these half-independent settlements into the heart of Italy by threatening with a pecuniary penalty the soldier who preferred his rights as a citizen to the benefits which he might receive as an emigrant.^ Now that the great wars had brought their dubious ^Cic. de Leg. Agr. ii. 27. 73 Est operae pretium diligentiam majorum recordari, qui colonias sic idoneis in locis contra suspicionem periculi collocarunt, ut esse non oppida Italiae, sed propugnacula imperii viderentur. ^ Liv. xxvii. 38 ; xxxvi. 3 ; cf. Marquardt Staatsverwaltung i. p. 51. ^The Roman citizen, who entered his name for a Latin colony, suffered the de- rogation of caput which was known to the later jurists as capitis deminutio minor andxxpressed the loss oi civitas (Gaius i. 161 ; iii. 56). That a fine was the alterna- tive of enrolment, hence conceived as voluntary, we are told by Cicero {pro Caec. 33. 98 Aut sua voluntate aut legis multa profecti sunt : quam multam si sufferre voluissent, manere in civitate potuissent. Cf. pro Domo 30. 78 Qui cives Romani in colonias Latinas proficiscebantur, fieri non poterant Latini, nisi erant auctores acti nomenque dederant). DECLINE OF COLONISATION IN ITALY 5 but at least potential profits to every member of the Roman com- munity, and the gulf between the full citizens and the members of the allied communities was ever widening, it was more than doubt- ful whether a member of the former class, however desperate his plight, would readily condescend to enroll himself amongst the latter. But, even apart from these considerations, it must have seemed very questionable to any one, who held the traditional view that colonisation should subserve the purposes of the State, whether the landless citizen of the time could be trusted to fulfil his duties as an emigrant. As early as the year 186 the consul Spurius Postumius, while making a judicial tour in Italy, had found to his surprise that colonies on both the Italian coasts, Sipontum on the Upper, and Buxentum on the Lower Sea, had been abandoned by their inhabitants : and a new levy had to be set on foot to replace the faithless emigrants who had vanished into space.^ As time went on the risk of such desertion became greater, partly from the growing difliculty of maintaining an adequate living on the land, partly from the fact that the more energetic spirits, on whom alone the hopes of permanent settlement could depend, found a readier avenue to wealth and a more tempting sphere for the exercise of manly qualities in the attractions of a campaign that seemed to promise plunder and glory, especially when these prizes were accom- panied by no exorbitant amount of suffering or toil. Thus when it had become known that Scipio Africanus would accompany his brother in the expedition against Antiochus, five thousand veterans, both citizens and allies, who had served their full time under the command of the former, offered their voluntary services to the de- parting consul,^ and nineteen years later the experience which had been gained of the wealth that might be reaped from a campaign in Macedonia and Asia drew many willing recruits to the legions which were to be engaged in the struggle with Perseus.^ The semi-professional soldier was in fact springing up, the man of a spirit adventurous and restless such as did not promise contentment with the small interests and small rewards of life in an Italian outpost. But, if the days of formal colonisation were over, why might not the concurrent system be adopted of dividing conquered lands amongst poorer citizens without the establishment of a new political ' Liv. xxxix. 23. ^ Liv. xxxvii. 4. s Liv. xlii. 32 Multi voluntate nomina dabant, quia locupletes videbant, qui priore Macedonico bello, aut adversus Antiochum in Asia, stipendia fecerant. 6 A HISTORY OF ROME settlement or any strict limitation of the number of the recipients ? This 'viritane' assignation had always run parallel to that which assumed the form of colonisation ; it merely required the existence of land capable of distribution, and the allotments granted might be considered merely a means of affording relief to the poorer members of existing municipalities. The system was supposed to have existed from the times of the Kings ; it was believed to have formed the basis of the first agrarian law, that of Spurius Cassius in 486 ; ^ it had been employed after the conquest of the Volscians in the fourth century and that of the Sabines in the third ; ^ it had animated the agrarian legislation of Flaminius when in 232 he romanised the ager Gallicus south of Ariminum without planting a single colony in this region ; ^ and a date preceding the Gracchan legislation by only forty years had seen the resumption of the method, when some Gallic and Ligurian land, held to be the spoil of war and declared to be unoccupied, had been parcelled out into allotments, of ten jugera to Roman citizens and of three to members of the Latin name.* But to the government of the period with which we are concerned the continued pursuance of such a course, if it suggested itself at all, appealed in the light of a policy that was unfamiliar, difficult and objectionable. It is probable that this method of assignment, even in its later phases, had been tinctured with the belief that, like the colony, it secured a system of military control over the occupied district : and that the purely social object of land-distribution, if it had been advanced at all, was considered to be characteristic rather of the demagogue than the statesman. From a strategic point of view such a measure was unnecessary; from an economic, it assumed, not only a craving for allotments amongst the poorer class, of which there was perhaps little evidence, but a belief, which must have been held to be sanguine in the extreme, that these paupers, when provided for, would prove to be 1 For the assignations viritim in the times of the Kings see Varro R. R. i. lo (Romulus) ; Cic. de Rep. ii. 14. 26 (Numa) ; Liv. i. 46 (Servius TuUius). That the Cassian distribution was to be kbt" &ySpa is stated by Dionysius (viii 72 73) On the whole subject see Mommsen in C. I. L. i. p. 75. He has made out a'good case tor the land thus assigned being known by the technical name of mritanus ager. See Festus p. 373 ; Siculus Flaccus p. 154 Lachm. We shall find that this was the form of distribution effected by the Gracchi. HT . 1^°^ *^ settlement in the land of the Volsci see Liv. v. 24 ; for that made by M. Cunus in the Sabine territory, Colum. i. praef. 14; [Victor] de Vir. III. 33. Cato ap. Varr. R. R. i, 2. 7 Ager Gallicus Romanus vocatur, qui viritim cis Ariminum datus est ultra agrum Picentium ; cf. Cic. Brut. 14. 57 ; de Senect. 4. 11; Val. Max. v. 4. 5. ■ .<» > -r * Liv. xlii. 4 (173 B.C.) ; cf. xli. 16. DIFFICULTY OF LAND-ASSIGNMENT 7 efficient farmers capable of maintaining a position which many of them had already lost. Again, if such an assignment was to be made, it should be made on land immediately after it had passed from the possession of the enemy to that of Rome ; if time had elapsed since the date of annexation, it was almost certain that claims of some kind had been asserted over the territory, and shadowy as these claims might be, the Roman law had, in the interest of the State itself, always tended to recognise a de facto as a de jure right. The claims of the allies and the municipalities had also to be considered ; for assignments to Roman citizens on an extensive scale would inevitably lead to difficult questions about the rights which many of these townships actually possessed to much of the territory whose revenue they enjoyed. If the allies and the municipal towns did not suffer, the loss must fall on the Roman State itself, which derived one of its chief sources of stable and permanent revenue — the source which was supposed to meet the claims for Italian administration ^ — from its domains in Italy, on the contractors who collected this revenue, and on the enter- prising capitalists who had put their wealth and energy into the waste places to which they had been invited by the government, and who had given these devastated territories much of the value which they now possessed. Lastly, these enterprising possessors were strongly represented in the senate ; the leading members of the nobility had embarked on a new system of agriculture, the results of which were inimical to the interest of the small farmer, and the conditions of which would be undermined by a vast system of distribution such as could alone suffice to satisfy the pauper pro- letariate. The feeling that a future agrarian law was useless from an economic and dangerous from a political point of view, was strengthened by the conviction that its proposal would initiate a war amongst classes, that its failure would exasperate the commons and that its success would inflict heavy pecuniary damage on the guardians of the State. Thus the simple system of territorial expansion, which had con- tinued in an unintei-rupted course from the earliest days of conquest, might be now held to be closed for ever. From the point of view ^ The other sources were the fortoria and the vicesima Ubertatis. Even at a period when the revenues from the provinces were infinitely larger than they were at the present time Cicero could write, with reference to Caesar's proposal for dis- tributing the Campanian land, Portoriis Italiae sublatis, agro Campano diviso, quod vectigal superest domesticum praeter vicensimam ? (Cic. ad AH. ii. i6. i). 8 A HISTORY OF ROME of the Italian neighbours of Rome it was indeed ample time that such a closing period should be reached. If we possessed a map of Italy which showed the relative proportions of land in Italy and Cisalpine Gaul which had been seized by Rome or left to the native cities or tribes, we should probably find that the possessions of the conquering State, whether occupied by colonies, absorbed by the gift of citizenship, or held as public domain, amounted to nearly one half of the territory of the whole peninsula.^ The extension of such progress was clearly impossible unless war were to be provoked with the Confederacy which furnished so large a proportion of the fighting strength of Rome ; but, if it was confessed that extension on the old lines was now beyond reach of attainment and yet it was agreed that the existing resources of Italy did not furnish an adequate hvelihood to the majority of the citizens of Rome, but two methods of expansion could be thought of as practicable in the future. One was agrarian assignation at the expense either of the State or of the richer classes or of both ;_ the other was enterprise beyond the sea. But neither of these seemed to deserve govern- ment intervention, or regulation by a scheme which would satisfy either immediate or future wants. The one was repudiated, as we have already shown, on account of its novelty, its danger and its inconvenience ; the other seemed emphatically a matter for private enterprise and above all for private capital. It could never be available for the very poor unless it assumed the form of colonisa- tion, and the senate looked on transmarine colonisation with the eye of prejudice.^ It took a different view of the enterprise of the foreign speculator and merchant ; this it regarded with an air of easy indifference. Their wealth was a pillar on which the State might lean in times of emergency, but, until the disastrous effects of commercial enterprise on foreign policy were more clearly seen, it was considered to be no business of the government either to help or to hinder the wealthy and enterprising Roman in his dealings with the peoples of the subject or protected lands. Rome, if by this name we mean the great majority of Roman citizens, was for the first time for centuries in a situation in which all movement and all progress seemed to be denied. The force of ' See the map attempted by Beloch in his work Der Italische Bund unter Roms Hegemonie. 2 Vellei. ii. 7. See ch. iv., where the attitude of the senate towards the pro- posals for transmarine settlement made by Caius Gracchus is described. THE CLOSE OF THE LONG WARS 9 the community seemed to have spent itself for the time ; as a force proceeding from the whole community it had perhaps spent itself for ever. A section of the nominally sovereign people might yet be welded into a mighty instrument that would carry victoiy to the ends of the earth, and open new channels of enterprise both for the men who guided their movements and for themselves. But for the moment the State was thrown back upon itself; it held that an end had been attained, and the attainment naturally suggested a pause, a long survey of the results which had been reached by these long years of struggle with the hydra-headed enemy abroad. The close of the third Macedonian war is said by a contemporary to have brought with it a restful sense of security such as Rome could not have felt for centuries.^ Such a security gave scope to the rich to enjoy 'the material advantages which their power had acquired ; but it also gave scope to the poor to reflect on the strange harvest which the conquest of the great powers of the world had brought to the men whose stubborn patience had secured the peace which they were given neither the means nor the leisure to enjoy. The men who evaded or had completed their service in the legions lacked the means, although they had the leisure ; the men who still obeyed the summons to arms lacked both, unless the respite between pro- longed campaigns could be called leisure, or the booty, hardly won and quickly squandered, could be described as means. Even after Carthage had been destroyed Rome, though doubly safe, was still busy enough with her legions ; the government of Spain was one protracted war, and proconsuls were still striving to win triumphs for themselves by improving on their predecessors' work.^ But such war could not absorb the energy or stimulate the interest of the people as a whole. The reaction which had so often followed a successful campaign, when the discipline of the camp had been shaken off and the duties of the soldier were replaced by the wants of the citizen, was renewed on a scale infinitely larger than before — a scale proportioned to the magnitude of the strain which had been removed and the greatness of the wants which had been revived. The cries for reform may have been of the old familiar type ^ but ' Polyb. xxxii. ii. 2 Besides the continued war in Spain from 145 to 133 there were troubles in Macedonia (in 142) and in Sicily during this period of comparative peace. Circa 140-135 commences the great slave rising in that island, and in the latter year the long series of campaigns against the free Illyrian and Thracian peoples begins. 3 P. I. 10 A HISTORY OF ROME their increased intensity and variety may almost be held to hav| given them a difference of quality. There is a stage at which a difference of degree seems to amount to one of kind : and this stage seems certainly to have been reached in the social problems pre- sented by the times. In the old days of the struggle between the orders the question of privilege had sometimes overshadowed the purely economic issue, and although a close scrutiny of those days of turmoil shows that the dominant note in the conflict was often a mere pretext meant to serve the personal ambition of the champions of the Plebs, yet the appearance rather than the reality of an issue imposes on the imagination of the mob, and political emancipatio:^ had been thought a boon even when hard facts had shown that its greater prizes had fallen to a small and selfish minority. Now,- however, there could be no illusion. There was nothing but material wants on one side, there was nothing but material power on the other. The intellectual claims which might be advance|| to justify a monopoly of office and of wealth, could be met by an intellectual superiority on the part of a demagogue clamouring for confiscation. The ultimate basis of the life of the State was for the first time to be laid bare and subjected to a merciless scrutiny; it remained to be seen which of the two great forces of society would prevail ; the force of habit which had so often blinded the Roman to his real needs ; or the force of want which, because it so seldom won a victory over his innate conservatism, was wont, when that victory had been won, to sweep him farther on the path of reckless, and inconsistent reform than it would have carried a race bett^ endowed with the gift of testing at every stage of progress the ends and needs of the social organism considered as a whole.. An analysis of social discontent at any period of history must take the form of an examination of the wants engendered by the age, and of the adequacy or inadequacy of their means of satisfac- tion. If we turn our attention first to the forces of society which: were in possession of the fortress and were to be the object of attack, we shall find that the ruling desires which animated these men of wealth and influence were chiefly the product of the new cosmopolitan culture which the victorious city had begun to absorb in the days when conquest and diplomacy had first been carried across the seas. To this she fell a willing victim when the conquered peoples, bending before the rude force which had but substituted a new suzerainty for an old and had scarcely NEW INFLUENCES ON LIFE 11 •touched their inner life, began to display before the eyes of their Wonished conquerors the material comfort and the spiritual charm Vhich, in the case of the contact of a potent but narrow civilisation .with one that is superbly elastic and strong in the very elegance of 'its physical debility, can always turn defeat into victory. But the 'student who begins his investigation of the new Roman life with the 'study of Roman society as it existed in the latter half of the second ''century before our era, cannot venture to gather up the threads p of the purely intellectual and moral influences which were created sby the new Hellenistic civilisation. He feels that he is only at the 'beginning of a process, that he lacks material for his picture, that ithe illustrative matter which he might employ is to be found ' mainly in the literary records of a later age, and that his use of this matter would but involve him in the historical sins of anticipation '?and anachronism. Of some phases of the war between the old I spirit and the new we shall find occasion to speak ; but the cul- minating point attained by the blend of Greek with Roman ; elements is the only one which is clearly visible to modern eyes. This point, however, was reached at the earliest only in the second half of the next century. It was only then that the fusion of the i seemingly discordant elements gave birth to the new " Romanism," ! which was to be the ruling civilisation of Italy and the Western provinces and, in virtue of the completeness of the amalgamation ; and the novelty of the product, was itself to be contrasted and to [ Hve for centuries in friendly rivalry with the more uncompromising ; Hellenism of Eastern lands. But some of the economic effects of ; the new influences claim our immediate attention, for we are en- gaged in the study of the beginnings of an economic revolution, and ; an analysis must therefore be attempted of some of the most press- : ing needs and some of the keenest desires which were awakened i by Hellenism, either in the purer dress which old Greece had ; given it or in the more gorgeous raiment which it had assumed dining its sojourn in the East. A tendency to treat the city as the home, the country only as ! a means of refreshment and a sphere of elegant retirement during that portion of the year when the excitement of the urban season, I its business and its pleasure, were suspended, began to be a marked feature of the life of the upper classes. The man of afiairs and the man of high finance were both compelled to have their domicile in the town, and, if agriculture was still the staple or the supplement 12 A HISTORY OF EOME of their wealth, the needs of the estate had to be left to the super- vision of the resident bailiff.^ This concentration of the upp^ classes in the city necessarily entailed a great advance m the price and rental of house property within the walls. It is true that the reckless prices paid for houses, especially for country villas, bj the grandees and millionaires of the next generation,^ had not yet been reached ; but the indications with which we are furnished of the general rise of prices for everything in Rome that could be deemed desirable by a cultivated taste,^ show that the better class of house property must already have yielded large returns, whether it were sold or let, and we know that poor scions of the nobihty, if business or pleasure induced them to spend a portion of the year in Rome, had soon to climb the stairs of flats or lodgings.* The pressure for room led to the piling of storey on storey. On tlft roof of old houses new chambers were raised, which could be reached by an outside stair, and either served to accommodate the increased retinue of the town establishment or were let to strangers who possessed no dwelling of their own ; * the still larger lodging-houses or " islands," which derived their name from their lofty isolation from neighbouring buildings,* continued to spring up, and even private houses soon came to attain a height which had to be re- strained by the intervention of the law. An ex-consul and augui was called on by the censors of 125 to explain the magnitude of a villa which he had raised, and the altitude of the structure exposed him not only to the strictures of the guardians of morals but to a fine imposed by a public court.'' Great changes were effected 1 The officia of the villicus have become very extensive even in Cato's time (Cato R. R. 5). Their extent implies the assumption of very prolonged absences on the part of the master. 2 Lucullus paid 500,200 drachmae for the house at Misenum which had once be- longed to Cornelia. She had purchased it for 75,000 (Plut. Afar. 34). Marius had been its intermediate owner. Even during his occupancy it is described as uoXvnKkii o'tKta Tpui^cts ex"""'" ""^ Siairas Bri\vTepas ^ kot liySpa TTO\ifUin' TOtroiruv ko! ffTparfm aiiTovpy6v. " Diod. xxxvii. 3. ■* Sulla rented one of the lower floors for 3000 sesterces (Plut. Sulla i). ^ The coenaculum is mentioned by Livy (xxxix. 14) in connection with the year 186 B.C. It is known both to Ennius (ap. TertuU. adv. Valent. 7) and to Plautus {Amph. iii. i. 3). ° Festus p. III. The insula resembled a large hotel, with one or more courts, and bounded on all sides by streets. See Smith Diet, of Antiq. (3rd ed.) i. p. 665. 'Val. Max. viii. i. damn. 7 Admodum severae notae et illud populi judiciumi cum M. Aemilium Porcinam (consul 137 B.C.) a L. Cassio (censor 125 B.C.) accusa- tum crimine nimis sublime extructae villae in Alsiensi agro gravi multa affecit. The author does not sufficiently distinguish between the censorian initiative and the operation of the law. The passage is important as showing the existence of an CHANGES IN DOMESTIC LIFE 13 jin the interior structure of the houses of the wealthy — changes excused I by a pardonable desire for greater comfort and rendered necessary .both by the growing formality of life and the large increase in the .numbers of the resident household, but tending, when once adopted, to draw the father of the family into that most useless type of J extravagance which takes the form of a craze for building. The , Hall or Atrium had once been practically the house. It opened I on the street. It contained the family bed and the kitchen fire. I The smoke passed through a hole in the I'oof and begrimed the , family portraits that looked down on the members of the household , gathered round the hearth for their common meal. The Hall was the chief bedroom, the kitchen, the dining-room and the reception room, and it was also the only avenue from the street to the small courtyard at the back. The houses of the great had hitherto differed from those of the poor chiefly in dimensions and but very slightly in structure. The home of the wealthy patrician had simply been on a larger scale of primitive discomfort ; and if his large parlour built of timber could accommodate a vast host of clients, the bed and the cooking pots were still visible to every visitor. The chief of the early innovations had been merely a low portico, borrowed from the Greeks by the Etruscans and transmitted by them to Rome, which ran round the courtyard, was divided into little cells and chambers, and served to accommodate the servants of the house. ^ But now fashion dictated that the doorway should not front the street but should be parted from it by a vestibule, in which the early callers gathered before they were admitted to the hall of audience. The floor of the Atrium was no longer the common passage to the regions at the back, but a special corridor lying either on one or on both sides of the HalP led past the Study or Tablinum, immediately behind it, to the inner court beyond. Even the sanctity of the nuptial couch could not con- tinue to give it the publicity which was irksome to the taste of an age which had acquired notions of the dignity of seclusion, of enactment on the height of buildings. See Voigt in Iwan-Miiller's Handbuch iv. 2, p. 394, and cf. Vellei. ii. 10. Augustus limited the height of houses to 70 feet (Strabo v. p. 235). ' Diodor. v. 40 (The Etruscans) in . • • rais olxlais ra irepiarcfa irphs t&j tSiv BepairevivTav Kx^o"' rapax^s ^{tupoc euxpio'Ttai'. See Krause Deinokrates p. 528. ' In spite of the plural form fauces (Vitruv. vi, 3. 6) may denote only a single passage. See Marquardt Privatl. p. 240 ; Smith and Middleton in Smith Diet, of Antiq. i. p. 671. 14 A HISTORY OF ROME the comfort that was to be found in retirement, and of the con- venience of separating the chambers that were used for public from those which were employed for merely private purposes. The chief bedrooms were shifted to the back, and the sides of the court- yard were no longer the exclusive abode of the dependants of the household. The common hearth could no longer serve as the sphere of the cuhnary operations of an expensive cook with his retinue of menials ; the cooking fire was removed tq one of the rooms near the back-gate of the house, which finally became an ample kitchen repletfe with all the imported means of satisfying the growing luxury of the table ; and the member of the family loitering in the hall, or the visitor admitted through its portals, was spared the annoyances of strong smells and pungent smoke. The Roman family also discovered the discomfort of dining in a large and scantily furnished room, not too well lit and accessible to the intrusions of the chance domestic and the caller. It was deemed preferable to take the common meal in a light and airy upper chamber, and the new type of Coenaculum satisfied at once the desire for personal comfort and for that spe- cialisation in the use of apartments which is one of the chief signs of an advancing material civilisation. The great hall had become the show-room of the house, but even for this purpose its dimensions proved too small. Such was the quantity of curios and works of art collected by the conquering or travelled Roman that greater space was needed for the exhibition of their rarity or splendour. This space was gained by the removal from the Atrium of all the domestic obstacles with which it had once been cumbered. It might now be made slightly smaller in its proportion to the rest of the house and yet appear far more ample than before. The space by which its sides were diminished could now be utilised for the build- ing of two wings or Alae, which served the threefold purpose of lighting the hall from the sides, of displaying to better advantage, as an oblong chamber always does, the works of art which the lord of the mansion or his butler ^ displayed to visitor or client, and lastly of serving as a gallery for the family portraits, which were finally! removed from the Atrium, to be seen to greater advantage and in a better light on the walls of the wings. These now displayed the family tree through painted lines which connected the little shrines ' For this atriensis, the English butler, the continental porter, see the frequent references in Plautus (e.g., Asin. ii. 2. 80 and loi ; Pseud, ii. 2. 15), Krause Deitw- krates p. 534 and Marquardt Privatl. p. 140. CHANGES IN DOMESTIC LIFE 15 holding the inscribed imagines of the great ancestors of the house.^ It is also possible that the Alae served as rooms for more private audiences than were possible in the Atrium.^ From the early morning crowd which thronged the hall individuals or groups might have been detached by the butler, and led to the presence of the great statesman or pleader who paced the floor in the retirement of one of these long side-galleries.' Business of a yet more private kind was transacted in the still greater security of the Tablinum, the archive room and study of the house. Here were kept, not only the family records and the family accounts, but such of the official registers and papers as a magistrate needed to have at hand during his year of office.* The domestic transaction of official business was very large at Rome, for the State had given its administrators not even the skeleton of a civil service, and it was in this room that the consul locked himself up with his quaestor and his scribes, as it was here that, as a good head of the family and a careful business man, he carefully perused the record of income and expenditure, of gains and losses, with his skilled Greek accountant. The whole tendency of the reforms in domestic architecture was to differentiate between the public and private life of the man of business or affairs. His public activity was confined to the fore- part of the house ; his repose, his domestic joys, and his private pleasures were indulged in the buildings which lay behind the Atrium and its wings. As each of the departments of life became more ambitious, the sphere for the exercise of the one became more magnificent, and that which fostered the other the scene of a more perfect, because more quiet, luxury. The Atrium was soon to be- come a palatial hall adorned with marble colonnades ; ' the small ' Plin. H. N. XXXV. 6 Stemmata vero lineis discurrebant ad imagines pictas. It is not known at what period the imagines were transferred from the Atrium to the Alae. ^ Overbeck Pompeii p. 192 ; Krause Deinohrates p. 539. ^ For the practice started, or developed, by Caius Gracchus of receiving visitors, some singly, others in smaller or larger groups, see Seneca de Ben. vi. 34. 2 and the description of Gracchus' tribunate in chapter iv. * Festus p. 357 (according to Mommsen, Abh. der Berl. Akad. Phil.-hist. Classe, 1864 p. 68) Tablinum proxime atrium locus dicitur, quod antiqui magistratus in suo imperio tabulis rationum ibi habebant publicarum rationum causa factum locum ; Plin. H. N. XXXV. 7 Tabulina codicibus implebantur et monimentis rerum in magis- tratu gestarum. Marquardt, however (Privatl. p. 215) thinks that the name tablinum is derived from the fact that this chamber was originally made of planks (tablinum from tabula ss figUnum from figulus). ° The earliest instances of extreme extravagance in the use of building material —of the use, for instance, of Hymettian and Numidian marble — are furnished by 16 A HISTORY OF ROME yard with its humble portico at the back was to be transformed ini the Greek Peristyle, a court open to the sky and surrounded by columns, which enclosed a greenery of shrubs and trees and an atmosphere cooled and freshened by the constant play of fountai: The final form of the Roman house was an admirable type of the new civilisation. It was Roman and yet Greek ^ — Roman in the grand front that it presented to the world, Greek in the quiet background of thought and sentiment. The growing splendour of the house demanded a number and variety in its human servitors that had not been dreamed of in a simpler age. The slave of the farm, with his hard hands and weather-beaten visage, could no longer be brought by his elegaii master to the town and exhibited to a fastidious society as the type of servant that ministered to his daily needs. The urban and rustic family were now kept wholly distinct ; it was only when some child of marked grace and beauty was born on the farm, that it was transferred to the mansion as containing a promise that would be wasted on rustic toil.^ In every part of the establish- ment the taste and wealth of the owner might be tested by the courtliness and beauty of its living instruments. The chained dog at the gate had been replaced by a human janitor, often himself in chains.^ The visitor, when he had passed the porter, was received by the butler in the hall, and admitted to the master's presence by a series of footmen and ushers, the show servants of the fore-part of the house, men of the impassive dignity and obsequious repose that servitude but strengthens in the Oriental mind.* In the penetralia of the household each need created by the growing ideal of comfort and refinement required its separate band of ministers, the houses of the orator Lucius Licinius Crassus (built about ga B.C.) and of Marcus Aemilius Lepidus, consul in 78 B.C. This growth of luxury will be treated when we come to deal with the civilisation of the Ciceronian period. 1 As Krause expresses it (DeinokraUs p. 542), at the final stage we find a Greek " Hinterhaus" standing behind an old Italian " Vorderhaus ". ^The case mentioned by Juvenal (xi. 151) Pastoris duri hie est filius, ille bubulci. Suspirat longo non visam tempore matrem, Et casulam, et notos tristis desiderat haedos, must have been of frequent occurrence as soon as the urban and ru&tic familiae had been kept distinct. ' Suetonius says (de Rhet. 3) of L. Voltacilius Pilutus, one of the teachers J Pompeius, Servisse dicitur atque etiam ostiarius vetere more in catena fuisse. ^For these atrienses, atriarii, admissionales, velarii see Wallon Hist, dt I'Esclavage ii. p. 108. GROWTH OF LUXURY 17 The body of the bather was rubbed and perfumed by experts in the art ; the service of the table was in the hands of men who had made catering and the preparation of delicate viands the sole business of their lives. The possession of a cook, who could answer to the highest expectations of the age, was a prize beyond the reach of all but the most wealthy ; for such an expert the sum of four talents had to be paid ; ^ he was the prize of the million- aire, and families of more moderate means, if they wished a banquet to be elegantly served, were forced to hire the temporary services of an accomplished artist.^ The housekeeper,^ who supervised the resources of the pantry, guided the destinies of the dinner in con- cert with the chef ; and each had under him a crowd of assistants of varied names and carefully differentiated functions.* The busi- ness of the outer world demanded another class of servitors. There were special valets charged with the functions of taking notes and invitations to their masters' friends ; there was the valued attendant of quick eye and ready memory, an incredibly rich store-house of names and gossip, an impartial observer of the ways and weak- nesses of every class, who could inform his master of the name and attributes of the approaching stranger. There were the lackeys who formed the nucleus of the attendant retinue of clients for the man when he walked abroad, the boys of exquisite form with slender limbs and innocent faces, who were the attendant spirits of the lady as she passed in her litter down the street. The muscles of the stouter slaves now offered facilities for easy journey- , ing that had been before unknown. The Roman official need not sit his horse during the hot hours of the day as he passed through the hamlets of Italy, and the grinning rustic could ask, as he watched the solemn and noiseless transit of the bearers, whether the carefully drawn curtains did not conceal a corpse.* The internal luxury of the household was as fully exhibited in lifeless objects as in living things. Rooms were scented with fragrant perfumes and hung with tapestries of great price and 1 Diod. xxxvii. 3 ; Sallust (yug. 85) makes Marius say (107 b.c) Neque pluris pretii coquum quain villicum habeo. Livy (xxxix. 6) remarks with reference to the consequences of the return of Manlius' army from Asia in 187 B.C. Tum coquus, vilissimum antiquis mancipium et aestimatione et usu,^ in pretio esse ; et, quod ministerium fiierat, ars haberi coepta. * Plin. H. N. xviii. 108 Nee coquos vero habebant in servitiis eosque ex macello conducebant. The practice is mentioned by Plautus (Aul. ii. 4. i ; iii. 2. 15). ^ Condus promus (Plaut. Pseud, ii. 2. 14). * Wallon op. cit. ii. p. iii. " C. Gracchus ap. Gell. x. 3. 5. 2 18 A HISTORY OF ROME varied bloom. //Tables were set with works of silver, ivory and other precious material, wrought with the most delicate skill. Wine of moderate flavour was despised ; Falernian and Chian were the only brands that the true connoisseur would deem worthy of his taste. A nice discrimination was made in the qualities of the rarer kinds of fish, and other delicacies of the table were sought in proportion to the difficulty of their attainment. The fashions of dress followed the tendency of the age ; the rarity of the material, its fineness of texture, the ease which it gave to the body, were the objects chiefly sought. Young men were seen in the Forum in robes of a material as soft as that worn by women and almost transparent in its thinness. Since all these instruments of plea- sure, and the luxury that appealed to ambition even more keenly than to taste, were pursued with a ruinous competition, prices were forced up to an incredible degree. An amphora of Falernian wine cost one hundred denarii, a jar of Pontic salt -fish four hundred ; a young Roman would often give a talent for a favourite, and boys who ranked in the highest class for beauty of face and elegance of form fetched even a higher price than this.^ Few could have been inclined to contradict Cato when he said in the senate-house that Rome was the only city in the world where a jar of preserved fish from the Black Sea cost more than a yoke of oxen, and a boy- favourite fetched a higher price than a yeoman's farm.^ One of the great objects of social ambition was to have a heavier service of silver-plate than was possessed by any of one's neighbours. In the good old days, — ^days not so long past, but severed from the pre- sent by a gulf that circumstances had made deeper than the years — the Roman had had an official rather than a personal pride in the silver which he could display before the respectful eyes of the distinguished foreigner who was the guest of the State ; and the Carthaginian envoys had been struck by the similarity between the silver services which appeared at the tables of their various hosts. The experience led them to a higher estimate of Roman brother- hood than of Roman wealth, and the silver-plate that had done such varied duty was at least responsible for a moral triumph.* Only a few years before the commencement of the first war with Carthage 1 Polyb. xxxii. ii ; Diodor. xxxvii. 3. ^ Diod. I.e. "Plin. H. N. xxxiii. 143 Invenimus legates Carthaginiensium dixisse nuUos hominum inter se benignius vivere quam Romanes. Eodem enim argento apud omnes cenitavisse ipsos. COLLECTION OF WORKS OF ART 19 Rufinus^a consular had been expelled from the senate for having ten pounds of the wrought metal in his keeping/ and Scipio Aemi- lianus, a man of the present age, but an adherent of the older school, left but thirty-two pounds' weight to his heir. Less than forty years later the younger Livius Drusus was known to be in possession of plate that weighed ten thousand pounds,^ and the accretions to the primitive hoard which must have been made by but two or three members of this family may serve as an index of the extent to which this particular form of the passion for display had influenced the minds and practice of the better-class Romans of the day. There were other objects, valued for their intrinsic worth as much as for the distinction conveyed by their possession, which attracted the ambition and strained the revenues of the fashionable man. Works of art must once have been cheap on the Roman market ; for, even if we refuse to credit the story of Mummius' estimate of the prize which fallen Corinth had delivered into his hands,' yet the transhipment of cargoes of the priceless treasures to Rome is at least an historic fact, and the Gracchi must themselves have seen the trains of wagons bearing their precious freight along the Via Sacra to the Capitol. The spoils of the generous conqueror were lent to adorn the triumphs, the public buildings and even the private houses, of others ; but much that had been yielded by Corinth had become the property neither of the general nor of the State. Polybius had seen the Roman legionaries playing at draughts on the Dionysus of Aristeides and many another famous canvas which had been torn from its place and thrown as a carpet upon the ground ; * but many a camp follower must have had a better estimate of the material value of the paintings of the Hellenic masters, and the cupidity of the Roman collector must often have been satisfied at no great cost to his resources. The extent to which a returning army could disseminate its acquired tastes and distribute its captured goods had been shown some forty years before the fall of Corinth when Manlius brought his legions back from the first exploration of the rich cities of Asia. Things and names, of which the Roman had never dreamed, soon gratified the eye and struck the ear with a familiar sound. He learnt to love the bronze couches meant for the dining hall, the slender side tables with the strange foreign name, the delicate tissues woven to ' Val. Max. ii. 9, 3. ' Plin. H. N. xxxiii. 141. »Vellei. i. 13. < Polyb. xl. 7. 20 A HISTORY OF ROME form the hangings of the bed or litter, the notes struck from the psalter and the harp by the fingers of the dancing-women of the East.i This was the first iiTuption of the efflorescent luxury of Eastern Hellenism ; but some five-and-twenty years before this date Rome had received her first experience of the purer taste of the Greek genius in the West. The whole series of the acts of artistic vandalism which marked the footsteps of the conquering state could be traced back to the measures taken by Claudius Marcellus after the fall of Syracuse. The systematic plunder of works of art was for the first time given an official sanction, and the public edifices of Rome were by no means the sole beneficiaries of this new interpretation of the rights of war. Much of the valuable plunder had found its way into private houses,^ to stimulate the envious cupidity of many a future governor who, cursed with the taste of a collector and unblessed by the opportunity of a war, would make subtle raids on the artistic treasures of his province a secret article of his administration. When the ruling classes of a nation have been famiharised for the larger part of a century with the easy acquisition of the best material treasures of the world, things that have once seemed luxuries come to fill an easy place in the category of accepted wants. But the sudden supply has stopped ; the market value, which plunder has destroyed or lessened, has risen to its normal level; another burden has been added to life, there is one further stimulus to wealth and, so press- ing is the social need, that the means to its satisfaction are not likely to be too diligently scrutinised before they are adopted. More pardonable were the tastes that were associated with the more purely intellectual elements in Hellenic culture — with the in- fluence which the Greek rhetor or philosopher exercised in his converse with the stern but receptive minds of Rome, the love of books, the new lessons which were to be taught as to the rhythmic flow of language and the rhythmic movement of the limbs. The Greek adventurer was one of the most striking features of the epoch which immediately followed the close of the great wars. ' Liv. xxxix. 6 Lectos aeratos . . . plagulas . . . monopodia et abacos Romam advexerunt. Tunc psaltriae sambucistriaeque et convivalia ludionum oblectamenta addita epulis. C/. Plin. H. N. xxxiv. 14. 2 Polyb. ix. 10 'Vufiaioi S^ fisTOKOfiiffavres tcl -Trpoeiprifisya rais fiev ISioyrtiaus KaTaffK^vais tovs auruv 4K6s> Another great raid was that made by Fulvius Nobilior in 189 B.C. on the art treasures of the Ambraciots (Signa aenea marmoreaque et tabulae pictae, Liv. xxxviii. 9). REVERENCE FOR GREEK CULTURE 21 ater thinkers, generally of the resentfully national, academic and ieudo-historical type, who repudiated the amenities of life which ley continued to enjoy, and cherished the pleasing fiction of the iiempiary mores of the ancient times, could see little in him but a lurce of unmixed evil ; i and indeed the Oriental Greek of the com- oner type, let loose upon the society of the poorer quarters, or orming his way into the confidence of some rich but uneducated laster, must often have been the vehicle of lessons that would stter have been unlearnt. But Italy also saw the advent of the 3st professors of the age, golden-mouthed men who spoke in the mguage of poetry, rhetoric and philosophy, and who turned from le wearisome competition of their own circles and the barren fields r their former labours to find a flattering attention, a pleasing ignity, and the means of enjoying a full, peaceful and leisured life 1 the homes of Roman aristocrats, thirsting for knowledge and lirsting still more for the mastery of the unrivalled forms in which leir own deeds might be preserved and through which their own olitical and forensic triumphs might be won. Soon towns of Italy -especially those of the Hellenic South — would be vying with each bher to grant the freedom of their cities and other honours in their ift to a young emigrant poet who hailed from Antioch, and mem- ers of the noblest houses would be competing for the honour of his iendship and for the privilege of receiving him under their roof.^ 'he stream of Greek learning was broad and strong ; ^ it bore on its osom every man and woman who aimed at a reputation for legance, for wit or for the deadly thrust in verbal fence which layed so large a part in the game of politics ; every one that re- ised to float was either an outcast from the best society, or was living to win an eccentric reputation for national obscurantism ad its imaginary accompaniment of honest rustic strength. Acquaintance with professors and poets led to a knowledge of ooks ; and it was as necessary to store the latter as the former * PUn. H. N. XV. 19 Graeci vitiorum omnium genitores. 2 Cic. pro Arch. 3. 5 Erat Italia turn plena Graecarum artium ac disciplinarum . . Itaque hunc (Archiam) et Tarentini et Regini et Neapolitani civitate ceterisque raemiis donarunt : et omnes, qui aliquid de ingeniis poterant judicare, cognitione que hospitio dignum existimarunt. ^ Cic. de Rep. ii. ig. 34 Videtur insitiva quadam disciplina doctior facta esse vitas. Influxit enim non tenuis quidam e Graecia rivulus in hanc urbem, sed mndantissimus amnis illarum disciplinarum et artium. Cicero is speaking of the :ry earliest Hellenic influences on Rome, but his description is just as appropriate the period which we are considering. 22 A HISTORY OF ROME under the fashionable roof. The first private library in Rome was established by Aemilius Paulus, when he brought home the books that had belonged to the vanquished Perseus ; ^ and it became as much a feature of conquest amongst the highly cultured to bring home a goodly store of literature as to gather objects of art which might merely please the sensuous taste and touch only the outer surface of the mind.^ But it was deemed by no means desirable to limit the influences of the new culture to the minds of the mature. There was, indeed, a school of cautious Hellenists that might have preferred this view, and would at any rate have exercised a careful discrimination be- tween those elements of the Greek training which would strengthen the young mind by giving it a wider range of vision and a new gallery of noble lives and those which would lead to mere display, to effeminacy, nay (who could tell ?) to positive depravity. But this could not be the point of view of society as a whole. If the elegant Roman was to be half a Greek, he must learn during the tender and impressionable age to move his limbs and modulate his voice in true Hellenic wise. Hence the picture which Scipio Aemilianus, sane Hellenist and stout P^oman, gazed at with astonished eyes and described in the vigorous and uncompromising language suited to a former censor. " I was told," he said, " that free-born boys and girls went to a dancing school and moved amidst disreputable professors of the art. I could not bring my mind to believe it ; but I was taken to such a school myself, and Good Heavens ! What did I see there ! More than fifty boys and girls, one of them, I am ashamed to say, the son of a candidate for office, a boy wearing the golden boss, a lad not less than twelve years of age. He was jingling a pair of castanets and dancing a step which an immodest slave could not dance with decency."' Such might have been the reflections of a puritan had he entered a modern dancing-academy. We may be permitted to question the immorality of the exhibition thus displayed, but there can be no doubt as to the social ambition which it reveals — an ambition 1 Plut. Paul. 28. 2 Sulla brought back the library of Apellicon of Teos, LucuUus the very large one of the kings of Pontus (Plut. Sulla 26 ; Luc. 42 ; Isid. Orig. vi. 5). LucuUus allowed free access to his books. Here we get the germ of the public library. The first that was genuinely public belongs to the close of the Republican era. It was founded by Asinius PoUio in the Atrium Libertatis on the Aventine (Plin. H. N. vii. 45 ; Isid. Orig. vi. 5). ' Macrob. Sat. iii. 14. 7. THE COST OF POLITICAL LIFE 23 which would be perpetuated throughout the whole of the life of the boy with the castanets, which would lead him to set a high value on the polish of everything he called his own — a polish determined by certain rigid external standards and to be attained at any hazard, whether by the ruinous concealment of honest poverty, or the struggle for affluence even by the most questionable means. But the burdens on the wealth of the great were by no means limited to those imposed by merely social canons. Political life at Rome had always been expensive in so far as office was unpaid and its tenure implied leisure and a considerable degree of neglect of his own domestic concerns in the patriot who was willing to accept it. But the State had lately taken on itself to increase the financial expenditure which was due to the people without pro- fessing to meet the bill from the public funds. The 'State' at Rome did not mean what it would have meant in such a context amongst the peoples of the Hellenic world. It did not mean that the masses were preying on the richer classes, but that the richer classes were preying on themselves; and this particular form of voluntary self-sacrifice amongst the influential families in the senate was equivalent to the confession that Rome was ceasing to be an Aristocracy and becoming an OUgarchy, was voluntarily placing the claims of wealth on a par with those of birth and merit, or rather was insisting that the latter should not be valid unless they were accompanied by the former. The chief sign of the confession that pohtical advancement might be purchased from the people in a legitimate way, was the adoption of a rule, which was established about the time of the First Punic War, that the cost of the public games should not be defrayed exclusively by the trea- sury.i It was seldom that the people could be brought to contri- bute to the expenses of the exhibitor by subscriptions collected from amongst themselves ; ^ they were the recipients, not the givers of the feast, and the actual donors knew that the exhibition was a contest for favour, that reputations were being won or lost on the merits of the show, and that the successful competitor was laying up a store-house of gratitude which would materially aid his ascent to the highest prizes in the State. The personal cost, if it 1 Dionys. vii. 71. ^ , <• c ■ ■ "They had made contributions in 186 B.C. towards the games ot bcipio Asiaticus (Plin. H. N. xxxiii. 138). 24 A HISTORY OF ROME could not be wholly realised on the existing patrimony of the magistrate, must be assisted by gifts from friends, by loans from money-lenders at exorbitant rates of interest and, worst but readiest of all methods, by contributions, nominally voluntary but really I enforced, from the Itahan allies and the provincials. As early as ' the year 180 the senate had been forced to frame a strong resolution against the extravagance that implied oppression ; ^ but the resolu- tion was really a criticism of the new methods of government ; the roots of the evil (the burden on the magistracy, the increase in the number of the regularly recurring festivals) they neither cared nor ventured to remove. The aedileship was the particular magistracy which was saddled with this expenditui-e on account of its traditional connection with the conduct of the public games ; and although it was neither in its curule nor plebeian form an obligatory step in the scale of the magistracies, yet, as it was held before the praetor- ship and the consulship, it was manifest that the brilliant display given to the people by the occupant of this office might render fruitless the efforts of a less wealthy competitor who had shunned its burdens.^ The games were given jointly by the respective pairs of colleagues,^ the Ludi Romani being under the guidance of the curule,* the Ludi Plebeii under that of the plebeian aediles.^ Had these remained the only annual shows, the cost to the exhibitor, although great, would have been limited. But other festivals, which had once been occasional, had lately been made permanent. The games to Ceres (Cerialia), the remote origins of which may have dated back to the time of the monarchy, first appear as fully established in the year 202 ; ^ the festival to Flora (Floralia) dates from but 238 b.c.,^ but probably did not become annual until 173 ; * while the games to the Great Mother(Jlfegiaiesia)followed by thirteen years the invitation and hospitable reception of that Phrygian god- ^ Livy (xl. 44) after describing the senatus consultum, in which occur the words Neve quid ad eos ludos arcesseret, cogeret, acciperet, faceret adversus id senatus :onsultum, quod L. Aemilio Cn. Baebio consulibus de ludis factum esset, adds Decreverat id senatus propter effusos sumptus, factos in ludos Ti. Sempronii aedilis, jui graves non modo Italiae ac sociis Latini nominis sed etiam provinciis externis "uerant, ^ The effect was still worse when a rich man avoided it. Cic. de Off, ii. 17. 58 i^'itanda tamen suspicio est avaritiae. Mamerco, homini divitissimo, praetermissio ledilitatis consulatus repulsam attulit. Sulla said that the people would not give lira the praetorship because they wished him to be aedile first. They knew that he ;ould obtain African animals for exhibition ( Plut. Sulla 5). ^ Cic. in Verr. v. 14. 36. •• Liv. x. 47 ; xxvii. 6. ^ Liv. xxiii. 30. 6 Liv. xxx. 39. ' Plin. H. N. xviii. 286. s Mommsen Rom. Munzw. p. 645. POPULAR SPECTACLES 25 dess by the Romans, and became a regular feature in their calendar in 191.1 This increase in the amenities of the people, every item of which falls within a term of fifty years, is a remarkable feature of the age which followed Rome's assumption of imperial power. It proved that the Roman was willing to bend his austere religion to the purposes of gratification, when he could afford the luxury, that the enjoyment of this luxury was considered a happy means of keeping the people in good temper with itself and its rulers, and that the cost of providing it was considered, not merely as com- patible with the traditions of the existing regime, but as a means of strengthening those traditions by closing the gates of office to the poor. The types of spectacle, in which the masses took most delight, were also new and expensive creations. These types were chiefly furnished by the gladiatorial shows and the hunting of wild beasts. Even the former and earlier amusement had had a history of little more than a hundred years. It was believed to be a relic of that realistic view of the after life which lingered in Italy long after it had passed from the more spiritual civilisation of the Greeks. The men who put each other to the sword before the eyes of the sorrow- ing crowd were held to be the retinue which passed with the dead chieftain beyond the grave, and it was from the sombre rites of the Etruscans that this custom of ceremonial slaying was be- lieved to have been transferred to Rome. The first year of the First Punic War witnessed the earliest combat that accompanied a Roman funeral,^ and, although secular enjoyment rapidly took the place of grim funereal appreciation, and the religious belief that underlay the spectacle may soon have passed away, neither the State nor the relatives were supposed to have done due honour to the illustrious dead if his own decease were not followed by the death-struggle of champions from the rival gladiatorial schools, and men who aspired to a decent funeral made due provision for such combats in their wills. The Roman magistrate bowed to the prevalent taste, and displays of gladiators became one of the most familiar features of the aediles' shows. Mihtary sentiment was in its favour, for it was beheved to harden the nerves of the race that had sprung from the 1 Liv. xxxvi. 36. On these festivals see Warde Fowler The Roman Festivals pp. 72. 91. 70. The Megalesia seem to have fallen to the lot of the curule aediles (Dio. Cass, xliii. 48), the others to have been given indifferently by either pair. ' Val. Max. ii. 4. 7 ; Liv. Ep. xvi. It was exhibited in the Forum Boarium by Marcus and Decimus Brutus at the funeral of their father. 26 A HISTORY OF ROME loins of the god of war,i and humane sentiment has never in any age been shocked at the contemporary barbarities which it toler- ates or enjoys. But a certain element of coarseness in the sport, and perhaps the very fact that it was of native Italian growth, might have given it a short shrift, had the cultured classes really possessed the power of regulating the amusements of the public. Leaders of society would have preferred the Greek Agon with its graceful wrestling and its contests in the finer arts. But the Roman public would not be hellenised in this particular, and showed their mood when a musical exhibition was attempted at the triumph of Lucius Anicius Gallus in 167. The audience insisted that the performers should drop their instruments and box with one another.^ This, although not the best, was yet a more tolerable type of what a con- test of skill should be. It was natural, therefore, that the pro- fessional fighting man should become a far more inevitable condition of social and political success than the hunter or the race-horse has ever been with us. Some enterprising members of the nobility soon came to prefer ownership to the hire system and started schools of their own in which the lanista was merely the trainer. A stranger element was soon added to the possessions of a Roman noble by the growing craze for the combats of wild beasts. The first recorded " hunt " of the kind was that given in 186 by Marcus Fulvius at the close of the Aetolian war when lions and panthers were exhibited to the wondering gaze of the people.' Seventeen years later two curule aediles furnished sixty-three African lions and forty bears and elephants for the Circensian games.* These menageries eventually became a public danger and the curule aedile (himself one of the chief offenders) was forced to frame an edict specifying the com- pensation for damage that might be committed by wild beasts in their transit through Italy or their residence within the towns.' The obligation of wealth to supply luxuries for the poor — a splendid feature of ancient civilisation in which it has ever taken precedence of that of the modern world — was recognised with the utmost frank- ness in the Rome of the day ; but it was an obligation that had passed the limits at which it could be cheerfully performed as the ' Compare Livy's description (xli. 2o) of the adoption of Roman gladiatorial shows by Antiochus Epiphanes — Armorum studium plerisque juvenum accendit. ' Polyb. XXX. 13. * Liv. xxxix. 22. * Liv. xliv. 18. " Dig. 21. i. 40-42 (from the edict of the curule aediles) Ne quis canem, verrem vel minorem aprum, lupum, ursum, pantheram, leonem . . . qua vulgo iter fiet, ita habuisse velit, ut cuiquam nocere damnumve dare possit. ATTEMPTS TO CHECK LUXURY 27 duty of the patriot or the patron ; it had reached a stage when its demoralising effects, both to giver and to receiver, were patent to every seeing eye, but when criticism of its vices could be met by the conclusive rejoinder that it was a vital necessity of the existing poli- tical situation. 1 \The review which we have given of the enormous expenditure created by the social and political appetites of the day leads up to the consideration of two questions which, though seldom formulated or faced in their naked form, were ever present in the minds of the classes who were forced to deem themselves either the most re- sponsible authors, or the most illustrious victims, of the .existing standards both of politics and society. Thes^uestions weref'Coulo^ the exhausting drain be stopped?" and ''If it could not, how was^ it to be supplied ? " A city in a state of high fever will always , produce the would-be doctor; but the curious fact about the RomeV of this and other days is that the doctor was so often the patienti in another form. Just as in the government of the provinces the)* scandals of individual rule were often met by the severest legislation^ proceeding from the very body which had produced the evil-doers,\ so when remedies were suggested for the social evils of the city, the/ Vfeenate, in spite of its tendency to individual transgression, generally^ displayed the possession of a collective conscience. The men who formulated the standard of purity and self-restraint might be jgw in number ; but, except they displayed the irritating activity and the uncompromising methods of a Cato, they generally secured the s upport o f their peers, and the sterner the censor, the mo re glad ly was he hailea aslin ornament to the order. This guardian of morals still issued his edicts against delicacies of the table, foreign perfumes and expensive houses ; ^ as late as the year 169 people would hastily put out their lights when it was reported that Tiberius Sempronius Graccus was coming up the street on his return from supper, lest they should fall under the suspicion of untimely revelry,' and the sporadic activity of the censorship will find ample illustra- tion in the future chapters of our work. Degradation from the various orders of the State was still a consequence of its animad- 1 Cic. de Off. ii. 17. 60 Tota igitur ratio talium largitionum genere vitiosa est, temporibus necessaria. He adds the pious but unattainable wish Tamen ipsa et ad facultates accomodanda et mediocritate moderanda est. Compare the remarks of Pohlmann on the subject in his Geschichtt des antiken Communismus und Sozialismus ii. 2. p. 471. "Mommsen Staatsr. ii., p. 382. ' Plut. Ti. Gracch. 14. 28 A HISTORY OF ROME versions; but a milder, more universal and probably far more eificacious check on luxuryA;^system, pursued by Cato, of adopt- ing an excessive rating for articBs of value ^ and thus of shifting the incidence of taxation from the artisan and farmer to the shoulders of the r jfhpat. rla ss^ — had been taken out of its hands by the complete cessation of direct imposts after the Third Macedonian War.3 Meanwhile sumptuary laws continued to be promulgated from the Rostra and accepted by the people. All that are known to have been initiated or to have been considered valid after the close of the great wars have but one object — an attack on the expenses of the table, a form of sensuous enjoyment which, on account of the ease and barbaric abundance with which wealth may vaunt itself in this domain, was particularly in vogue amongst the upper classes in Rome. Other forms of extravagance seem for the time to have been left untouched by legislation, for the Oppian law which had been due to the strain of the Second Punic War had been repealed after a jfierce struggle in 195, and the Roman ladies might now adorn themselves with more than half an ounce of gold, wear robes of divers colours and ride in their carriages through any street they pleased.* The first enactment which attempted to control the wastefulness of the table was an Orchian law of 181, limiting the number of guests that might be invited to entertain- ments. Cato was consistent in opposing the passing of the measure and in resisting its repeal. He recognised a futile law when he saw it, but he did not wish this futility to be admitted.* Twenty years later ^ a Fannian law grew out of a decree of the senate which had enjoined that the chief men (principes) of the State should take an oath before the consuls not to exceed a certain limit of expense in the banquets given at the Megalesian Games. Strengthened by this expression of opinion the consuls then went to the people ' Liv. xxxix. 44 ; Plut. Cat. Maj. i8. ^ Nitzsch Die Gracchen, p. 128. ' Cic. de Off. ii. 22. 76 (Paullus) tantum in aerarium pecuniae invexit, ut unius imperatoris praeda finem attulerit tributorum. A deterrent to luxury could still have been created by imposing heavy harbour-dues on articles of value ; but this would have required legislation. Nothingjis known about the Republican tariff at Italian ports. The percentage may have been uniform for all articles. * Liv. xxxiv. cc. 1-8 ; Val. Max. ix. i. 3 ; Tac. Ann. iii. 33. ''Macrob. Sat. iii. 17; Festus pp. 201, 242; Schol. Bob. p. 310; Meyer Orat. Rom. Fragm. p. gi. " This date (161) is given by Pliny (H. N. a. 139) ; Macrobius (Sat. iii. 17. 3) places the law in 159. SUMPTUARY LAWS 29 with a measure which prescribed more harrassing details than the Orchian law. The new enactment actually determined the value and nature of the eatables whose consumption was allowed. It permitted one hundred asses to be spent on the days of the Roman Games, the Plebeian Games and the SaturnaUa, thirty asses on certain other festival occasions, and but ten asses (less than twice the daily pay of a Roman soldier) on every other meal throughout the year ; it forbade the serving of any fowl but a single hen, and that not fattened; it enjoined the exclusive consumption of native wine.^ This enactment was strengthened eighteen years later by a Didian law, which included in the threatened penalties not only the giver of the feast which violated the prescribed limits, but also the guests who were present at such a banquet. It also compelled or induced the Italian allies to accept the provisions of the Fannian law 2 — an unusual step which may show the belief that a luxury similar to that of Rome was weakening the resources of the con- federacy, on whose strength the leading state was so dependent, or which may have been induced by the knowledge that members of the Roman nobility were taking holiday trips to country towns, to enjoy the delights which were prohibited at home and to waste their money on Italian caterers.^ The frequency of such legislation, which we shall find renewed once again before the epoch of the reforms of Sulla * seems to prove its ineffectiveness,* and indeed the standard of comfort which it desired to enjoin was wholly incompatible with the circumstances of the age. The desire to produce uniformity* of standard had always been an end of Roman as of Greek sumptuary regulation, but what type of uniformity could be looked for in a community where the ' Gell. ii. 24 ; Macrob. Sat. iii. 17 ; Plin. H. N. x. 139 ; Tertull. AJ>ol. vi. The ten asses of this law are the Fanni centussis misellus of Lucilius. ' It seems that we must assume formal acceptance on the part of the allies in accordance with the principle that Rome could not legislate for her confederacy, a principle analogous to that which forbade her to force her franchise on its members (Cic. pro Balbo 8. 20 and 21). ^ We may compare the enactment of 193 B.C., which was produced by the dis- covery that Roman creditors escaped the usury laws by using Italians as their agents (Liv. xxxv. 7 M. Sempronius tribunus plebis . . . plebem rogavit plebesque scivit ut cum sociis ac nomine Latino creditae pecuniae jus idem quod cum civibus Romanis esset). * The Lex Licinia, which is attributed by Macrobius (l.c.) to P. Licinius Crassus Dives, perhaps belongs either to his praetorship (104 B.C.) or to his consulship (97 B.C.). " Gellius (ii. 24), in speaking of Sulla's experiments, says of the older laws Legibus istis situ atque senio obliteratis. ' Exaequatio (Liv. xxxiv. 4). 30 A HISTORY OF ROME extremes of wealth and poverty were beginning to be so strongly marked, wh ere capital w as accumulating in the hands of the great noble and the great trader and being wholly withdrawn from those of the free-bom peasant and artisan ? The restriction of useless con- sumption was indeed favourable to the more productive employment of capital ; but we shall soon see that this productive use, which had as its object the deterioration of land by pasturage and the purchase of servile labour, was as detrimental to the free citizen as the most reckless extravagance could have been. There is no ques- tion, however, that both the sumptuary laws and the censorian ordin- ances of the period did attempt to attain an economic as well as a social end ; and, however mistaken their methods may have been, they showed some appreciation of the industrial evils of the time. The provision of the Fannian law in favour of native wines ^ suggests the desire to help the small cultivator who had substituted vine- growing for the cultivation of cereals, and foreshadows the protective legislation of the Ciceronian period.^ Much of this legislation, too, was animated by the "mercantile" theory that a State is im- poverished by the export of the precious metals to foreign lands ' — a view which found expression in a definite enactment of an earlier period which had forbidden gold or silver to be paid to the Celtic tribes in the north of Italy in exchange for the wares or slaves which they sold to Roman merchants.* ^Another series of laws aimed at securing the purity of an electo- rate exposed to the danger of corruption by the overwhelming in- fluence of wealth. "~feaws against bribery, unknown in an earlier period,^ become painfully frequent from the date at which Rome came into contact with the riches of the East. Six years after the close of the great Asiatic campaign the people were asked, on the authority of the senate, to sanction more than one act which was directed ' P. 2g. * Cic. de Rep. iii. g. i6 ; see p. 80. ' Compare Tac. Ann. iii. 53. The Emperor Tiberius here speaks of Ilia femin- arum propria, quis lapidum causa pecuniae nostrae ad externas aut hostilis gentes transferuntur. * The prohibition belongs to the year 229 B.C. (Zonar. viii. 19). For other prohibitions of the same kind dating from a period later than that which we are considering see Voigt in Iwan-Miiller's Handbuch iv. 2, p. 376 n. 95. ' Earlier enactments had been directed against canvassing, but not against bribery. The simplicity of the fifth century E.c. was illustrated by the law 5iat a candidate should not whiten his toga with chalk (Liv. iv. 25 ; 433 B.C.). The Lex Poetelia of 358 B.C. (Liv. vii. 16) vi^as directed against personal solicitation by novi homines. Some law of ambitus is known to Plautus (Amph. prol. 73 ; cf. Trinumm. iv. 3. 26). See Rein Criminalrecht p. 706. THE MOTIVE FOR GAIN 31 against the undue influence exercised at elections ; i in 166 fresh scandals called for the consideration of the Council of State ; ^ and the year 159 saw the birth of another enactment.' Yet the capital penalty, which seems to have been the consequence of the transgres- sion of at least one of these laws,* did not deter candidates from stak- ing their citizenship on their success. The still-surviving custom of clientship made the object of largesses difficult to establish, and the secrecy of the ballot, which had been irttfoduced for elections in 139, made it impossible to prove that the suspicious gift had been effective and thus to construct a convincing case against the donor. The moral control exercised by the magistrate and the sumptu- ary or criminal ordinances expressed in acts of Parhament might serve as temporary palliatives to certain pronounced evils of the moment ; but they were powerless to check the extravagance of an expenditure which was sanctioned by custom and in some respects actually enforced by law.* One of the greatest of the practical needs of the new Roman was to increase his income in every way that might be deemed legitimate by a society which, even in its best days, had never been overscrupulous in its exploitation of the poor and had been wont to illustrate the sanctity of contract by visible examples of grinding oppression. The nature and intensity of the race for wealth differed with the needs of the anxious spend- thrift ; and in respect both to needs and to means of satisfaction the upper middle class was in a far more favourable position than its noble governors. It could spend its unfettered energies in the pursuit of the profits which might be derived from public contracts, trade, banking and money-lending, while it was not forced to submit to the drain created by the canvass for office and the exorbitant de- mands made by the electorate on the pecuniary resources of the can- didate. The brilliancy of the life of the mercantile class, with its :;areless luxury and easy indifference to expenditure, set a standard For the nobility which was at once galling and degrading. They were induced to apply the measure of wealth even to members of their own order, and regarded it as inevitable that any one of their 'Liv. xl. 19 Leges de ambitu consules ex auctoritate senatus ad populum ulerunt. This was the lex Cornelia Baebia and that it referred to pecuniary cor- uption is known from a fragment of Cato (ap. Non. vii. 19, s.v. largi, Cato lege Baebia : pecuniam inlargibo tibi). 2 Obsequens Ixxi. ' Liv. Ep. xlvii. * Polyb. vi. 56 irapic fiiv Kapxri^oy^o^' SSpo y, u EXTORTION IN THE PROVINCES 39 he expenses that had been arbitrarily impbsed on the unhappy natives of Sardinia,^ but seems to have been the author of a definite law which fixed a limit to such requisitions in the future.^ But it was easier to fi'ame an ordinance than to guarantee its observation, and, at a time when the surrounding world was seething with war, the regulations made for a peaceful province could not touch the actions of a victorious commander who was following up the results of conquest. Complaints began to pour in on every hand — from the Ambraciots of Greece, the Cenomani of Gaul ' — and the senate did its best, either by its own cognisance or by the creation of a commission of investigation, to meet the claims of the dependent peoples. A kind of rude justice was the result, but it was much too rude to meet an evil which was soon seen to be developing into a trade of systematic oppression. A novel step was taken when in 171 delegates from the two Spains appeared in the Curia to complain of the avarice and insolence of their Roman governors. A praetor was commissioned to choose from the senatorial order five of such judges as were wont to be selected for the settlement of in- ternational disputes (recuperatvres), to sit in judgment on each of the indicted governors,* and the germ of a regular court for what had now become a regular offence was thus developed. The further and more shameful confession, that the court should be permanent and interpret a definite statute, was soon made, and the Calpurnian law of 1^9^ was the first of that long series of enactments for extortion which mark the futility of corrective measures in the face of a weak system of legal, and a still weaker system of moral, control. Trials for extortion soon became the plaything of politics, the favourite arena for the exercise of the energies of a young and rising poli- tician, the favourite weapon with which old family feuds might be at once revenged and perpetuated. They were soon destined to gain a still greater significance as furnishing the criteria of the methods of administration which the State was expected to employ, as determining the respective rights of the administrator and the ^Liv. xxxii. 27 Sumptus, quos in cultum praetorum socii facere soliti erant, circumcisi aut sublati (ig8 BX.). 2 The Lex de Termessibus (a charter of freedom given to Termessus in Pisidia in 71 B.C.) enjoins (ii. 1. 15) Nei . . . quis magistratus . . . inperato, quo quid magis iei dent praebeant ab ieisve auferatur nisei quod eos ex lege Porcia dare praebere oportet oportebit. This Porcian law was probably the work of Cato (Rein Criminalr. P- 607). s Liv. xxxviii. 43 ; xxxix. 3 ; Rein, I.e. " Liv. xlui. 2. = Cic. Brut. 27. 106 ; de Off. ii. 21. 75 ; cf. in Verr. iii. 84. 195 ; iv. 25. 56. 40 A HISTORY OF ROME capitalist to guide the destinies of the inhabitants of a dependent district. Their manifold political significance destroys our con- fidence in their judgments, and we can seldom tell whether the acquittal or the condemnation which these courts pronounced was justified on the evidence adduced. But there can be no question of the evil that lay behind this legislative and judicial activity. The motive which led men to assume administrative posts abroad was in many cases thoroughly selfish and mean, — the desire to acquire wealth as rapidly as was consistent with keeping on the safe side of a not very exacting law. No motive of this kind can ever be universal in a political society, and in Rome we cannot even pronounce it to be general. Power and distinction attracted the Roman as much as wealth, and some governors were saved from temptation by the colossal fortunes which they already possessed. But how early it had begun to operate in the minds of many is shown by the eager- ness which, as we shall see, was soon to be displayed by rival con- suls for the conduct of a war that might give the victor a prolonged control over the rich cities which had belonged to the kingdom of Pergamon, if it is not proved by the strange unwilling- ness which magistrates had long before exhibited to assume some commands which had been entrusted to their charge.^ A suspicion of another type of abuse of power, more degrading though not necessarily more harmful than the plunder of subjects, had begun to be raised in the minds of the people and the govern- ment. It was held that a Roman might be found who would sell the supposed interests of his country to a foreign potentate, or at any rate accept a present which might or might not influence his judgment. A commissioner to Illyria had been suspected of pocket- ing money offered him by the potentates of that district in 171,^ and the first hint was given of that shattering of public confidence in the integrity of diplomatists which wrought such havoc in the foreign pohtics of the period which forms the immediate subject ^ Liy. xli. 15. (176 B.C.) Duo (praetores) deprecati sunt ne in provincias irent, M. Popillius in Sardinian! : Gracchum earn provinciam pacare &c. . . . Probata Popillii excusatio est. P. Licinius Crassus sacrificiis se impediri soUemnibus ex- cusabat, ne in provinciam iret. Citerior Hispania obvenerat. Ceterum aut ire jussus aut jurare pro contione soUemni sacrificio se prohiberi . . . Praetores ambo in eadem verba jurarunt. I have seen the passage cited as a proof that governors would not go to unproductive provinces ; but Sardinia was a fruitful sphere for plunder, and the excuses may have been genuine. That of Popillius seems to have been positively patriotic. ^ Liv. xlii. 45 Decimius unus sine uUo effectu, captarum etiam pecuniarum ab regibus Illynorum suspicione infamis, Romam rediit. THE KNIGHTS 41 of our; work. The system of the Protectorate, which Rome had so widely adopted, with its secret diplomatic dealings and its hidden conferences with kings, offered greater facilities for secret enrich- ment, and greater security for the enjoyment of the acquired wealth, even than the plunder of a province. The proof of the committal of the act was difficult, in most cases impossible. We must be con- tent to chronicle the suspicion of its growing frequency, and the suspicion is terrible enough. If the custom of wringing wealth from subjects and selling support to potentates continued to prevail, the stage might soon be reached at which it could be said, with that element of exaggeration which lends emphasis to a truth, that a small group of men were drawing revenues from every nation in the world .^ Such were the sources of wealth that lay open to men, to whom commerce was officially barred and who were supposed to have no direct interest in financial operations. Far ampler spheres of pecuniary enrichment, more uniformly legal if sometimes as op- pressive, were open to the class of men who by this time had been recognised as forming a kind of second order in the State. The citizens who had been proved by the returns at the census to l\ave a certain amount of realisable capital at their disposal — a class of citizens that ranged from the possessors of a moderate patrimony, such as society might employ as a line of demarcation between an upper and a lower middle class, to the controllers of the most gigantic fortunes — had been welded into a body possessing consider- able social and political solidarity. This soUdarity had been attained chiefly through the community of interest derived from the similar methods of pecuniary investment which they employed, but also through the circumstance (slight in itself but significant in an ancient society which ever tended to fall into grades) that all the members of this class could describe themselves by the courtesy title of "Knights" — a description justified by the right which they pos- sessed of serving on their own horses with the Roman cavalry instead of sharing the foot-service of the legionary. A common designation was not inappropriate to men who were in a certain sense public servants and formed in a very real sense a branch of the administra- tion. The knight might have many avocations ; he might be a money-lender, a banker, a large importer ; but he was pre- ' Cic. in Verr. v. 48. 126 (70 B.C.) Patimur . . . multos jam annos et silemus cum videamus ad paucos homines omnes omnium nationum pecunias pervenisse. 42 A HISTORY OF ROME eminently a farmer of the taxes. His position in the former cases was simply that of an individual, who might or might not be temporarily associated with others; his position in the latter case meant that he was a member of a powerful and permanent corpora- tion, one which served a government from which it might wring great profits or at whose hands it might suifer heavy loss — a government to be helped in its distress, to be fought when its demands were overbearing, to be encouraged when its measures seemed progressive, to be hindered when they seemed reaction- ary from a commercial point of view. A group of individuals or private firms could never have attained the consistency of organisation, or maintained the uniformity of policy, which was displayed by these societies of revenue-collectors ; even a company must have a long life before it can attain strength and confidence sufficient to act in a spirited manner in opposition to the State; and it seems certain that these societies were wholly exempted from the paralysing principle which the Roman law applied to partner- ship — a principle which dictated that every partnership should be dissolved by the death or retirement of one of the associates.^ The State, which possessed no civil service of its own worthy of the name, had taken pains to secure permanent organisations of private share-holders which should satisfy its needs, to give them something of an official character, and to secure to each one of them as a result of its permanence an individual strength which, in spite of the theory that the taxes and the public works were put up to auction, may have secured to some of these companies a practical monopoly of a definite sphere of operations. But a company, at Rome as elsewhere, is powerful in proportion to the breadth of its basis. A small ring of capitalists may tyrannise over society as long as they confine themselves to securing a monopoly over private enterprises, and as long as the law permits them to exercise this autocratic power without control ; but such a ring is far less capable of meeting the arbitrary dictation of an aristocratic body of land- holders, such as the senate, or of encountering the resentful opposi- tion of a nominally all-powerful body of consumers, such as the Comitia, than a corporation which has struck its roots deeply in society by the wide distribution of its shares. We know from the positive assurance of a skilled observer of Roman life that the ' For the principle see Gaius iii. 151-153. THE PUBLIC COMPANIES 43 number of citizens who had an interest in these companies was particularly large.^ This observer emphasises the fact in order to illustrate the dependence of a large section of society on the will of the senate, which possessed the power of controlling the terms of the agreements both for the public works which it placed in the hands of contractors and for the sources of production which it put out to lease ; ^ but it is equally obvious that the large size of the number of shareholders must have exercised a profoundly modifying influence on the arbitrary authority of a body such as the senate which governed chiefly through deference to public opinion ; and we know that, in the last resort, an appeal could be made to the sovereign assembly, if a magistrate could be found bold enough to carry to that quarter a proposal that had been discountenanced by the senate.^ In such crises the strength of the companies depended mainly on the number of individual interests that were at stake ; the shareholder is more likely to appear at such gatherings than the man who is not profoundly affected by the issue, and it is very seldom that the average consumer has insight enough to see, or energy enough to resist, the sufferings and inconveniences which spring from the machinations of capital. It may have been possible at times to pack a legislative assembly with men who had some financial interest, however slight, in a dispute arising from a con- tract caUing for decision ; and the time was soon to come when such questions of detail would give place to far larger questions of policy, when the issues springing from a line of foreign activity which had been taken by the government might be debated in the cold and glittering Ught of the golden stakes the loss or gain of which depended upon the policy pursued. Nor could it have been easy even for the experienced eye to see from the survey of such a gathering that it represented the army of capital. Research has ' Polybius (vi. 17), after speaking of various kinds of property belonging to the state, adds itcJvto xc'P^fe"'*'" irvn^alvei. rk irpoeipriiifva Sii tov ttK^Bovs, koI crxeShv iis (itos flireiv Trivras ivSei4iw,Tos ytvonivov Kovipicrat koI t)> irapA'Trav oJwoTOu Tivhs a-v/ifidvTos oiroAucroi Trjs ipyavias. Thus the senate invalidated the locationes of the censors of 184 B.C. (Liv. xxxix. 44 Locationes cum senatus precibus et lacrimis publicanorum victus induci et de integro locari jussisset.) ' In i6g B. c. it was the people that released from an oppressive regulation (Liv. xliii. 16). In this case a tribune answered the censor's intimation, that none of the former state-contractors should appear at the auction, by promulgating the resolution Quae publica vectigalia, ultro tributa C. Claudius et Ti. Sempronius locassent, ea rata locatio ne esaet. Ab integro locarentur, et ut omnibus redimendi et conducendi promiscue jus esset. 44 A HISTORY OF ROME rendered it probable that the companies of the time were composed of an outer as well as of an inner circle ; that the mass of share- holders differed from those who were the promoters, managers and active agents in the concern, that the liability of the former at least was limited and that their shares, whether small or great, were transmissible and subject to the fluctuations of the market.* But, even if we do not believe that this distinction between socii and participes was legally elaborated, yet there were probably means by which members of the outside public could enter into business relations with the recognised partners in one of these concerns to share its profits and its losses.^ The freedman, who had invested his small savings in the business of an enterprising patron, would attach the same mercantile value to his own vote in the assembly as would be given to his suffi-age in the senate by some noble peer, who had bartered the independence of his judgment for the acquisition of more rapid profits than could be drawn from land. The farmers of the revenue fell into three broad classes.V First there were the contractors for the creation, maintenance and repair of the public works possessed or projected by the State, such as roads, aqueducts, bridges, temples and other public buildings. Gigantic profits were not possible in such an enterprise, if the censors and their advisers acted with knowledge, impartiality and discretion ; for the lowest possible tender was obtained for such contracts and the results might be repudiated if inspection proved them to be unsatisfactory. 'Secondly there were the companies which leased sources of production that were owned by the State such as fisheries, salt-works, mines and forest land. In some par- ticular cases even arable land had been dealt with in this way, ^ Deloume op. cit. pp. iig ff. Polybius (vi. 17) has been quoted as an authority for the distinction between these two classes. He says 01 ixev yhip a-yopdiovffi jropit Twy Tifi7]Twv avTol rits eKSdaets, ot 5e Kotvwvovo't to6toiSj ot S* iyyvuvrat robs 7iyopaK6TaSt ol Si Tcts obffias SiS6airi irepL toiStoiv els rh Sn/idffioi/. The first three classes are the mancipes, socii and praedes. In the fourth the shareholders (participes or perhaps adfines, cf. Liv. xliii. 16) are found by Deloume (p. 120) ; but the identification is very uncertain. The words may denote either real as opposed to formal security or the final payment of the vectigal into the treasury. A better evidence for the distinction between socii and shareholders is found in the Pseudo-Asconius (in Cic. in Verr. p. 197 Or.) Aliud enim socius, aliud particeps qui certam habet partem et non iwdivise agit ut socius. The magnas partes (Cic. pro Rab. Post. 2. 4) and the particulam (Val. Max. vi. g. 7) of a publicum, need only denote large or small shares held by the socii. Dare partes (Cic. I.e.) is to "allot shares," but not necessarily to outside members. Apart from the testimony of the Pseudo-Asconius and the mention of adfines in Livy the evidence for the ordinary shareholder is slight but by no means fatal to his existence. ''■ E.g. by loan to a socius at a rate of interest dependent on his returns, perhaps with a. pactum de non petendo in certain contingencies. OPERATIONS IN STATE CONTRACTS 45 and the confiscated territories of Capua and Corinth were let on long leases to publicani. Thirdly there were the societies, which did not themselves acquire leases but acted as true intermediaries between the State and individuals ^ who paid it revenue whether as occupants of its territory, or as making use of sites which it claimed to control, or as owing dues which had been prescribed by agree- ment or by law. These classes of debtors to the State with whom the middlemen came into contact may be illustrated respectively by the occupants of the domain land of Italy, the ship-masters who touched at ports, and the provincials such as those of Sicily or Sardinia who were burdened with the payment of a tithe of the produce of their lands.^. If we consider separately the characteristics of the three classes of state-farmers, we find that the first and the second are both direct employers of labour, the third reaping only indirect profits from the production controlled by others. It was in this respect, as employers of labour, that the societies of the time were free from the anxieties and restrictions that beset the modem employment of capital. Except in the rare case where the contractors had leased arable land and sublet it to its original occupants, — the treatment which seems to have been adopted for the Campanian territory ^ — there can be no question that the work which they controlled was done mainly by the hands of slaves. They were therefore exempt from the annoyance and expense which might be caused by the competition and the organised resistance of free labour. The slaves employed in many of these industries must have been highly skilled ; for many of these spheres of wealth which the State had delegated to contractors required peculiar industrial appliances and unusual knowledge in the foremen ana leading artificers. The weakness of slave-labour, — its lack of intelH- gence and spirit — could not have been so keenly felt as it was on the great agricultural estates, which ofiered employment chiefly for the unskilled ; and the difficulties that might arise from the lack ^ These are, in strict legal language, the true publicani ; the lessees of state property are publicanorum loco (Dig. 39. 4. 12 and 13). 2 Later legal theory-assimilated the third with the first class. Gams says (u. 7) In eo (provinciali) solo dominium populi Romani est vel Caesaris, nos autem possessionem tantum vel usumfructum habere videmur. But the theory is not ancient— perhaps not older than the Gracchan period. See Greenidge Roman Pubhc Life p. 320. From a broad standpoint the first and second classes may be assimi- lated, since the payment of harbour dues (portoria) is based on the idea of the use of public ground by a private occupant. 'Cic. de Leg. Agr. ii. 31. 84. 46 A HISTORY OF ROME of strength or interest, from the possession of hands that were either feeble or inert, were probably overcome in the same uncom- promising manner in the workshop of the contractor and on the domains of the landed gentry. The maxim that an aged slave should be sold could not have been peculiar to tlie dabbler in agriculture, and the ergastulum with its chained gangs must have been as familiar to the manufacturer as to the landed proprietor.^ As to the promoters and the shareholders of these companies, it could not be expected that they should trace in imagination, or tremble as they traced, the heartless, perhaps inhuman, means by which the regular returns on their capital were secured.* Nor is it probable that the government of this period took any great care to supervise the conditions of the work or the lot of the workman. The partner desired quick and great returns, the State large rents and small tenders. The remorseless drain on human energy, the waste of human life, and the practical abeyance of free labour which was flooding the towns with idlers, were ideas which, if they ever arose, were probably kept in the background by a government which was generally in financial difficulties, and by individuals animated by all the fierce commercial competition of the age. The desire of contractors and lessees for larger profits naturally took the form of an eagerness to extend their sphere of operations. Every advance in the Roman sphere of military occupation implied the making of new roads, bridges and aqueducts ; every extension of this sphere was likely to be followed by the confiscation of certain territories, which the State would declare to be public domains and hand over to the company that would guarantee the payment of the largest revenue. But the sordid imperialism which animated the contractor and lessee must have been as nothing to that which fed the dreams of the true state-middleman, the individual who intervened between the taxpayer and the State, the producer and the consumer. Conquest would mean fresh lines of coast and frontier, on which would be set the toll-houses of the collectors with their local directors and their active " families " of freedmen and slaves. It might even mean that a more prolific source of revenue would be handed over to the care of the publican. The spectacle of the method in which the land-tax was assessed and collected in Sicily 1 Thedenat in Daremberg-Saglio Diet, des Antiq. s.t. Ergastulum. ''Compare Cunningham Western Civilisation in its Economic Aspects vol. i. p. 162. COMMERCE AND IMPERIALISM 47 and Sardinia may have already inspired the hope that the next instance of provincial organisation might see greater justice done to the capitalists of Rome. When Sicily had been brought under Roman sway, the aloofness of the government from financial in- terests, as well as its innate conservatism, justified by the success of Italian organisation, which dictated the view that local institutions should not be lightly changed, had led it to accept the methods for the taxation of land which it found prevalent in the island at the time of its annexation. The methods implied assessment by local officials and collection by local companies or states.' It is true that neither consequence entirely excluded the enterprise of the Roman capitalists ; they had crossed the Straits of Messina on many a private enterprise and had settled in such large numbers in the business centres of the island that the charter given to the Sicilian cities after the first servile war made detailed provision for the settlement of suits between Romans and natives.^ It was not to be expected that they should refrain from joining in, or competing with, the local companies who bid for the Sicilian tithes, nor was such association or competition forbidden by the law. But the scattered groups of capitalists who came into contact with the Sicilian yeomen did not possess the official character and the official influence of the great companies of Italy. No association, how- ever powerful, could boast a monopoly of the main source of revenue in the island. But what they had done was an index of what they might do, if another opportunity and a more complaisant govern- ment could be found. Any individual or any party which could promise the knights the unquestioned control of the revenues of a new province would be sure of their heartiest sympathy and sup- port. And it would be worth the while of any individual or party which ventured to frame a programme traversing the lines of poli- tical orthodoxy, to bid for the co-operation of this class. For recent history had shown that the thorough organisation of capital, en- couraged by the State to rid itself of a tiresome burden in times of peace and to secure itself a support in times of need, might become, as it pleased, a bulwark or a menace to the government which had created it. The useful monster had begun to develop a self-con- sciousness of his own. He had his amiable, even his patriotic 1 Cic. in Verr. ii. 55. 137 ; iii. 33. 77 ; ii. 13. 32 ; 26. 63. 2 Ibid. ii. 13. 32. 48 A HISTORY OF ROME moments ; but his activity might be accompanied by the grim de- mand for a price which his nominal master was not prepared to pay. The darkest and the brightest aspects of the commercial spirit had been in turn exhibited during the Second Punic War.-^On the one hand we find an organised band of publicans attempting to break up an assembly before which a fraudulent contractor and wrecker was to be tried ; ' on the other, we find them meeting the shock of Cannae with the offer of a large loan to the beggared treasury, lent without guarantee and on the bare word of a ruined government that it should be met when there was money to meet it.^ Other companies came forward to put their hands to the public works, even the most necessary of which had been suspended by the misery of the war, and told the bankrupt State that they would ask for their payment when the struggle had completely closed.' A noble spectacle ! and if the positions of employer and employed had been reversed only in such crises and in such a way, no harm could come of the memory either of the obligation or the service. But the strength shown by this beneficence sometimes exhibited itself in un- pleasant forms and led to unpleasant consequences. The censorships of Cato and of Gracchus had been fierce struggles of conservative officialdom against the growing influence and (as these magistrates held) the swelling insolence of the public companies ; and in both cases the associations had sought and i found assistance, either from a sympathetic party within the senate, or from the people. Cato's regulations had been reversed and their vigorous author had been threatened with a tribunician prosecution before the Comitia;* while Gracchus and his colleague had actually been impeached be- fore a popular court.* The reckless employment of servile labour by the companies that farmed the property of the State had already proved a danger to public security. The society which had pur- chased from the censors the right of gathering pitch from the Bruttian forest of Sila had filled the neighbourhood with bands of fierce and uncontrolled dependants, chiefly slaves, but partly men of free birth who may have been drawn from the desperate Bruttians whom Rome had driven from their homes. The con- sequences were deeds of violence and murder, which called for the intervention of the senate, and the consuls had been appointed 1 Liv. XXV. 3. 2 Liv. xxiii. 49. ' Liv. xxiv. 18 ; Val. Max. v. 6. 8. * Plut. Cato Maj. ig. B Ljy xliii. 16. THE FINANCIER 49 as a special commission to inquire into the outrages.^ NOr were complaints limited to Italy ; provincial abuses had already called for drastic remedies. A pfoof that this was the case is to be found in the striking fact that on the renewed settlement of Macedonia in 167 it was actually decreed that the working of the mines in that country, at least on the extended scale which would have required a system of contract, should be given up. It was considered dangerous to entrust it to native companies, and as to the Roman — their mere presence in the country would mean the surrender of all guarantees of the rule of public law or of the enjoyment of liberty by the provincials.^ The State still preferred the embarrass- ments of poverty to those of overbearing wealth ; its choice proved its weakness; but even the element of strength displayed in the surrender might soon be missed, if capital obtained a wider influ- ence and a more definite political recognition. As things were, these organisations of capital were but just becoming conscious of their strength and had by no means reached even the prime of their vigour. The opening up of the riches of the East were re- quired to develop the gigantic manhood which should dwarf the petty figure of the agricultural wealth of Italy. Had the state-contractors stood alone, or had not they engaged in varied enterprises for which their official character offered a favourable point of vantage, the numbers and influence of the individuals who had embarked their capital in commercial enter- prise would have been far smaller than they actually were. But, in addition to the publican, we must take account of the business man (negotiator) who lent money on interest or exercised the profession of a banker. Such men had pecuniary interests which Icnew no geographical limits, and in all broad questions of policy were hkely to side with the state-contractor.^ The money-lender ' Cic. Brut. 22. 85 Cum in silva Sila facta caedes esset notique homines inter- fecti insimulareturque familia, partim etiam liberi, societatis ejus, quae picarias de P. Cornelio, L. Mummio censoribus redemisset, decrevisse senatum ut de ea re cognoscerent et statuerent consules. For the value of the pine-woods of Sila see Strabo vi. i. 9. , , . 2 Liv. xlv. 18 Metalli quoque Macedonici, quod ingens vectigal erat, locationesque praediorum rusticorum toUi placebat. Nam neque sine publicano exerceri posse, et, ubi publicanus esset, ibi aut jus publicum vanum aut libertatem sociis nullam esse. The praedia rusHca were probably public domains, that might have formed part of the crovifn lands of the Macedonian Kings and would now, in the natural course of events, have been leased to publicani. 3 It might happen that the interest of the negotiator was opposed to that of the publicanus. The former, for instance, might wish portoria to be lessened, the latter to be increased (Cic. ad Att. ii. 16. 4). But such a conflict was unusual. 4 50 A HISTORY OF ROME (fenerator) represented one of the earliest, most familiar and most courted forms of Roman enterprise — one whose intrinsic attractions for the grasping Roman mind had resisted every effort of the legisr lature by engaging in its support the wealthiest landowner as well as the smallest usurer. It is true that a taint clung to the trade — a taint which was not merely a product of the mistaken economic conception of the nature of the profits made by the lender, but was the more immediate outcome of social misery and the fulminations of the legislature. Cato points to the fact that the Roman law had stamped the usurer as a greater curse to society than the common thief, and makes the dishonesty of loans on interest a sufficient ground for declining a form of investment that was at once safe and profitable.^ Usury, he had also maintained, was a form of homicide.^ But to the majority of minds this feeling of dishonour had always been purely external and superficial. The proceedings were not repugnant to the finer sense if they were not made the object of a life-long profession and not blatantly exhibited to the eyes of the public. A taint clung to the money-lender who sat in an office in the Forum, and handed his loans or received his interest over the counter ; ^ it was not felt by the capitalist who stood behind this small dealer, by the nobleman whose agent lent seed-corn to the neighbouring yeomen, by the inrestor in the state- contracts who perhaps hardly realised that his profits represented but an indirect form of usury. But, whatever restrictions public opinion may have imposed on the money-lender as a dealer in Rome and with Romans, such restrictions were not likely to be felt by the man who had the capital and the enterprise to carry Ms financial operations beyond the sea. Not only was he dealing with provincials or foreigners, but he was dealing on a scale so grand that the magnitude of the business almost concealed its shame. Cities and kings were now to be the recipients of loans and, if the lender occupied a political position that seemed inconsistent with the profession of a usurer, his personality might be successfully ^ Cato R. R, pr. i Est interdum praestare mercaturis rem quaerere, nisi tam periculosum sit, et item fenerari, si tam lionestum sit. Majores nostri sic habuerunt et ita in legibus posiverunt, farem dupli condemnari, feneratorem quadrupli. Quanto pejorem civem existimarint feneratorem quam furem, hinc licet existimare. C/. Cic. de Off. i. 42. 150 Improbantur ii quaestus, qui in odia hominum incurrunt, ut porti- torum, ut feneratorum. 'J Cic. de Off. ii. 25. 89 Cum ille . . . dixisset "Quid fenerari?" turn Cato "Quid hominem," inquit, " occidere ? " ' For such professional money-lenders see Plaut. Most. iii. i.iS.; Cure. iv. 1. 19. BANKING 51 concealed under the name of some local agent, who was adequately rewarded for the obloquy which he incurred in the eyes of the native populations, and the embarrassing conflicts with the Roman government which were sometimes entailed by an excess of zeal. Cato had swept both principals and agents out of his province of Sardinia ; ^ but he was a man who courted hostility, and he lived before the age when the enmity of capital would prove the certain ruin of the governor and a source of probable danger to the senate. In the operations of the money-lender we find the most universal link between the Forum and the provinces. There was no country so poor that it might not be successfully exploited, and indeed exploitation was often conditioned by simplicity of character, lack of familiarity with the developed systems of finance, and the lack of thrift which amongst peoples of low culture is the source of their constant need. The employment of capital for this purpose was always far in advance of the limits of Roman dominion. A pro- tectorate might be in the grasp of a group of private individuals long before it was absorbed into the empire, the extension of the frontiers was conditioned by considerations of pecuniary, not of political safety, and the government might at any moment be forced into a war to protect the interests of capitahsts whom, in its collective capacity as a government, it regarded as the greatest foes of its dominion. A more beneficent employment of capital was illustrated by the profession of banking which, like most of the arts which exhibit the highest refinement of the practical intellect, had been given to the Romans by the Greeks.^ It had penetrated from Magna Graecia to Latium and from Latium to Rome, and had been fully estab- lished in the city by the time of the Second Punic War.^ The strangers, who had introduced an art which so greatly facilitated the conduct of business transactions, had been welcomed by the government, and were encouraged to ply their calling in the shops rented from the State on the north and south sides of the Forum. These argentarii satisfied the two needs of the exchange of foreign money, and of advances in cash on easier terms than could be gained ' Liv. xxxii. 27. ^ On the history and functions of the bankers see Voigt Ueber die Bankiers, die Buchfuhrung und die Litteralobligation der Romer (Abh. d. Konigl. Sachs. Gesell. d. Wissench. ; Phil. hist. Classe, Bd. x) ; Marquardt Staatsverw. ii. pp. 64 ff. ; Deloume Les manieurs d'argent d Rome, pp. 146 ff. 3 Plin. H. N. xxi. 3. 8. 52 A HISTORY OF ROME from the professional or secret usurer, to citizens of every grade ^ who did not wish, or found it difficult, to turn theu- real property into gold. Similar functions were at a somewhat later period usurped by the money-testers (nummularii), who perhaps entered Rome shortly after the issue of the first native silver coinage, and competed with the earlier-established bankers in most of the branches of their trade.^ Ultimately there was no department of business connected with the transference and circulation of money which the joint profession did not embrace. Its representatives were concerned with the purchase and sale of coin, and the equalisation of home with foreign rates of exchange ; they lent on credit, gave security for others' loans, and received money on deposit ; they acted as intermediaries between creditors and debtors in the most distant places and gave their travelling customers circular notes on associated houses in foreign lands ; they were equally ready to dissipate by auction an estate that had become the property of a congress of creditors or a number of legatees. Their carefully kept books improved even the methodical habits of the Romans in the matter of business entries, and introduced the form of " contract by ledger" {litterarum obligatio), which greatly facilitated business operations on an extended scale by substituting the written record of obligation for other bonds more difficult to conclude and more easy to evade. The business life of Rome was in every way worthy of her posi- tion as an imperial city, and her business centre was becoming the greatest exchange of the commercial world of the day. The forum still drew its largest crowds to listen to the voice of the lawyer or the orator ; but these attractions were occasional and the constant throng that any day might witness was drawn thither by the entice- ments supplied by the spirit of adventure, the thirst for news and the strain of business life. The comic poet has drawn for us a picture of the shifting crowd and its chief elements, good and bad, honest and dishonest. He has shown us the man who mingles pleasure with his business, lingering under the Basilica in extremely doubtful company ; there too is a certain class of business men ^ C/. Cic. de Off. iii. 14. 58 Pythius, qui esset ut argentarius apud omnes ordines gratiosus. . . . ^ Yet the two never became thoroughly assimilated. The argentarius, for in- stance, was not an official tester of money, and the nummularii appear not to have performed certain functions usual to the banker, e.g. sales by auction. See Voigt of. cit. pp. 521. 522. BUSINESS LIFE AT ROME 53 giving or accepting verbal bonds. In the lower part of the Forum stroll the lords of the exchange, rich and of high repute ; under the old shops on the north sit the bankers, giving and receiving loans on interest.^ The Forum has become in common language the symbol of all the ups and downs of business life,^ and the moralist of later times could refer all students, who wish to master the lore of the quest and investment of money, to the excellent men who have their station by the temple of Janus.^ The aspect of the market place had altered greatly to meet the growing needs. Great BasUicae — sheltered promenades which probably derived their names from the Royal Courts of the Hellenic East — had lately been erected. Two of the earliest, the Porcian and Sempronian, had been raised on the site of business premises which had been bought up for the purpose,* and were meant to serve the purposes of a mai'ket and an exchange.^ Their sheltering roofs were soon employed to accommodate the courts of justice, but it was the business not the legal life of Rome that called these grand edifices into existence. The financial activity which centred in the Forum was a con- sequence, not merely of the contract-system encouraged by the State and of the business of the banker and the money-lender, but of the great foreign trade which supplied the wants and luxuries of Italy and Rome. This was an import trade concerned partly with the supply of corn for a nation that could no longer feed itself, partly with the supply of luxuries from the East and of more necessary products, including instruments of production, from the West. Tte Eastern trade touched the Euxine Sea at Dioscurias, 1 Plaut. Cure. iv. i. 6 ff. Commonstrabo, quo in quemque hominem facile inveniatis loco. Ditis damnosos maritos sub basilica quaerito. Ibidem erunt scorta exoleta, quique stipulari solent. In foro infumo boni homines, atque dites ambulant. Sub veteribus, ibi sunt qui dant quique accipiunt faenore. ' To be bankrupt is foro mergi (Plaut. Ep. i. 2. i6), « foro fugere, abire (Plaut. Pen. iii. 3. 31 and 38). 'Cic. de Off. ii. 24. 87 Toto hoc de genere, de quaerenda, de collocanda pecunia, vellem etiam de utenda, commodius a quibusdam optumis viris ad Janum medium sedentibus . . . disputatur. For Janus medius and the question whether it means an arch or a street see Richter Topogr. dtr Stadt Rom. pp. 106. 107. * Liv. xxxix. 44 ; xliv. 16. The Porcian was followed by the Fulvian Basilica (Liv. xl. 51). The dates of the three were 184, 179, i6g B.C. respectively. ^ Delpume op. cit. pp. 320 ff. ; Guadet in Daremberg-Saglio Diet, dts Antiq. s.v. Basilicae. 64 A HISTORY OF ROME Asia Minor chiefly at Ephesus and Apamea, and Egypt at Alexan- dria. It brought Pontic fish, Hellenic wines, the spices and medicaments of Asia and of the Eastern coast of Africa, and count- less other articles, chiefly of the type which creates the need to which it ministers. More robust products were supplied by the West through the trade-routes which came down to Gades, Genua and Aquileia. Hither were brought slaves, cattle, horses and dogs ; linen, canvas and wool; timber for ships and houses, and raw metal for the manufacture of implements and works of art. Neither in East nor West was the product brought by the producer to the consumer. In accordance with the more recent tendencies of Hellenistic trade, great emporia had grown up in which the goods were stored, until they were exported by the local dealers or sought by the wholesale merchant from an Italian port. As the Tyrrhenian Sea became the radius of the trade of the world, Puteoli became the greatest staple, to which this commerce centred ; thence the goods which were destined for Rome were*conveyed to Ostia by water or by land, and taken by ships which drew no depth of water up the Tiber to the city.^ But it must not be supposed that this trade was first controlled by Romans and Italians when it touched the shores of Italy. Groups of citizens and allies were to be found in the great staples of the world, receiving the products as they were brought down from the interior and supplying the shipping by which they were transferred to Rome.^ They were not manu- facturers, but intermediaries who reaped a larger profit from the carrying trade than could be gained by any form of production in their native land. The Roman and Italian trader was to be inferior only to the money-lender as a stimulus and a stumbling- block to the imperial government ; he was, like the latter, to be a cause of annexation and a fire-brand of war, and serves as an almost equal illustration of the truth that a government which does not control the operations of capital is likely to become their instrument.' ' Large transport ships could themselves come to Rome if their build was suited to river navigation. In 167 B.C. Aemilius Paulus astonished the city with the size of a ship (once belonging to the Macedonian King) on which he arrived (Liv. xlv. 35). On the whole question of this foreign trade see Voigt in Iwan-MuUer's Handbuch iv. 2, pp. 373-378. 2 Voigt op. cit. p. 377 n. gg. ' Compare Cunningham Western Civilisation in its Economic Aspects vol. i. p. 165, " It is only under very special conditions, including the existence of a strong government to exercise a constant control, that free play for the formation of THE SMALL TRADER 55 If we descend from the aristocracy of trade to its poorer re- presentatives, we find that time had wrought great changes in the lot of the smaller manufacturer and artisan. It is true that the old trade-gilds of Rome, which tradition carried back to the days of Numa, still maintained their existence. The goldsmiths, copper- smiths, builders, dyers, leather-workers, tanners and potters i still held their regular meetings and celebrated their regular games. But it is questionable whether even at this period their collegiate life was not rather concerned with ceremonial than with business, whether they did not gather more frequently to discuss the prospects of their social and religious functions than to consider the rules and methods of their trades. We shall soon see these gilds of artificers a great political power in the State — one that often alarmed the government and sometimes paralysed its control of the streets of Rome. But their political activity was connected with ceremonial rather than with trade ; it was as religious associations that bhey supported the demagogue of the moment and disturbed the peace of the city. They made war against any aristocratic abuse that was dangled for the moment before their eyes ; but they undertook no consistent campaign against the dominance of capital. / Their activity was th at of the radical caucus, not of the trade-union.' But, if even their industrial character had been fully maintained and trade interests had occupied more of their attention than street processions and political agitation, they could never have posed as the representatives of the interests of the free-born sons of Rome. The class of freedmen was freely admitted to their ranks, and the freedman was from an economic point of view the greatest enemy of the pure-blooded Italian. We shall also see that the freedman was usually not an independent agent in the conduct of the trade which he professed. He owed duties to his patron which limited his industrial activity and rendered a whole-hearted co-operation with his brother-workers impossible. It is questionable whether any gild organisation could have stood the shock of the immense development of industrial activity associations of capitalists bent on securing profit, is anything but a public danger. The landed interest in England has hitherto been strong enough to bring legislative control to bear on the moneyed men from time to time. . . . The problem of leaving sufficient liberty for the formation of capital and for enterprise in the use of it, without allowing it licence to exhaust the national resources, has not been solved." ^ Plut. Numa 17. On the history of these gilds see Waltzing Corporations pro- fessionelles chez Us Romains pp. 61-78. 56 A HISTORY OF ROME of which the more fortunate classes at Rome were now reaping the fruits. The trades represented by Numa's colleges would at best have formed a mere framework for a maze of instruments which formed the complex mechanism needed to satisfy the voracious wants of the new society. The gold-smithery of early times was now complicated by the arts of chasing and engraving on precious stones ; the primitive builder, if he were still to ply his trade with profit, must associate it with the skill of the men who made the stuccoed ceilings, the mosaic pavements, the painted walls. The leather-worker must have learnt to make many a kind of fashionable shoe, and the dyer to work in violet, scarlet or saflron, in any shade or colour to which fashion had given a temporary vogue. Tailoring had become a fine art, and the movable decora- tions of houses demanded a host of skilled workmen, each of whom was devoted to the speciality which he professed. It would seem as though the very weaknesses of society might have benefited the lower middle class, and the siftings of the harvest given by the spoils of empire might have more than supplied the needs of a parasitic proletariate. It is an unquestioned fact that the growing luxury of the times did benefit trade with that doubtful benefit which accompanies the diversion of capital from purposes of per- manent utility to objects of aesthetic admiration or temporary display; but it is an equally unquestioned fact that this un- healthy nutriment did not strengthen to any appreciable extent such of the lower classes as could boast pure Roman blood. The military conscription, to which the more prosperous of these classes were exposed, was inimical to the constant pursuit of that technical skill which alone could enable its possessor to hold the market against freer competitors. Such of the freedmen and the slaves as were trained to these pursuits — men who would not have been so trained had they not possessed higher artistic perception and greater deftness in execution than their fellows — were wholly freed from the military burden which absorbed much of the leisure, and blunted much of the skill, possessed by their free-born rivals. The competition of slaves must have been still more cruel in the country districts and near the smaller country towns than in the capital itself. At Rome the limitations of space must have hindered the development of home-industries in the houses of the nobles, and, although it is probable that much that was manu- factured by the slaves of the country estate was regularly supplied COMPETITION OF FREEDMEN 57 to the urban villa, yet for the purchase of articles of immediate use or of goods which showed the highest qualities of workmanship the aristocratic proprietor must have been dependent on the com- petition of the Roman market. But the rustic villa might be perfectly self-supporting, and the village artificer must have looked in vain for orders from the spacious mansion, which, once a dwelling- house or faxm, had become a factory as well. Both in town and country the practice of manumission was paralysing the energies of the free-born man who attempted to follow a profitable pro- fession. The frequency of the gift of liberty to slaves is one of the brightest aspects of the system of servitude as practised by the Romans ; but its very beneficence is an illustration of the aristocrat's contempt for the proletariate ; for, where the ideal of citizenship is high, manumission — at least of such a kind as shall give political rights, or any trading privileges, equivalent to those of the free citizen — is infrequent. In the Rome of this period, however, the liberation of a slave showed something more than a mere negative neglect of the interests of the citizen. The gift of freedom was often granted by the master in an interested, if not in a wholly selfish, spirit. He was freed from the duty of supporting his slave while he retained his services as a freed man. The performance of these services was, it is true, not a legal condition of manu- mission ; but it was the result of the agreement between master and slave on which the latter had attained his freedom. The nobleman who had granted liberty to his son's tutor, his own doctor or his barber, might still bargain to be healed, shaved or have his children instructed free of expense. The bargain was just in so far as the master was losing services for which he had origin- ally paid, and juster still when the freedman set up business on the peculium which his master had allowed him to acquire during the days of his servitude. But the contracting parties were on an unequal footing, and the burden enforced by the manumittor was at times so intolerable that towards the close of the second century the praetor was forced to intervene and set limits to the personal service which might be expected from the gratitude of the liberated slave.i The performance of such gratuitous services necessarily 1 The praetor was Rutilius (Ulpian in Dig. 38. 2. i. i), perhaps P. Rutilius Rufus, the consul of 105 B.C. (Mommsen Staatsr. iii. p. 433). See the last chapter of this volume. For the principle on which such operae were exacted from freedmen see Mommsen I.e. 58 A HISTORY OF ROME diminished the demand for the labour of the free man who at- tempted to practise the pursuit of an art which required skill and was dependent for its returns on the custom of the wealthier classes; and even such needs as could not be met by the gratuitous services of freedmen or the purchased labour of slaves, were often supplied, not by the labour of the free-born Roman, but by that of the immigrant peregrinus. The foreigner naturally reproduced the arts of his own country in a form more perfect than could be ac- quired by the Roman or Italian, and as Rome had acquired foreign wants it was inevitable that they should be mainly supplied by foreign hands. We cannot say that most of the new developments in trade and manufacture had slipped from the hands of the free citizens ; it would be truer to maintain that they had never been grasped by them at all. And, worse than this, we must admit that there was little effort to attain them. Both the cause and the consequence of the monopoly of trade and manufacture of a petty kind by freedmen and foreigners is to be found in the con- tempt felt by the free-bom Roman for the "sordid and illiberal sources of livelihood "} This prejudice was reflected in public law, for any one who exercised a trade or profession was debarred from office at Rome.^ As the magistracy had become the monopoly of a class, the prejudice might have been little more than one of the working principles of an aristocratic government, had not the arts which supplied the amenities of life actually tended to drift into the hands of the non-citizen or the man of defective citizenship. The most abject Roman could in his misery console himself with the thought that the hands, which should only touch the plough and the sword, had never been stained by trade. His ideal was that of the nobleman in his palace. It differed in degree but not in kind. It centred round the Forum, the battlefield and the farm. For even the most lofty aristocrat would have exempted agri- culture from the ban of labour ; ^ and, if the man of free birth could still have toiled productively on his holding, his contempt for the rabble which supplied the wants of his richer fellow-citizens in the towns would have been justified on material, if not on moral, • Inliberales ac sordid! quaestus (Cic. de Off. i. 42. 150). " Gell. yii. (vi.) g ; Liv. ix. 46 ; Mommsen Staatsr. i. p. 497. ' C/. Cic. de off. i. 42. 151 Omnium autem rerum, ex quibus aliquid adquiritur, nihil est agricultura melius, nihil uberius, nihil dulcius, nihil homine libero dignius. , CONDITION OF AGRICULTURE 59 grounds. He would have held the real sources of wealth which had made the empire possible and still maintained the actual rulers of that empire. (^Italian agriculture was still the basis of the brilliant life of RomeV Had it not been so, the epoch of revolu- tion could not have been ushered in by an agrarian law. Had the interest in the land been small, no fierce attack would have been made and no encroachment stoutly resisted. We are at the com- mencement of the epoch of the dominance of trade, but we have not quitted the epoch of the supremacy of the landed interest. ^^he vital question connected with agriculture was not that of its failure or success, but that of the individuals who did the work and shared the profits. The labourer, the soil, the market stand in such close relations to one another that it is possible for older types of cultivation and tenure to be a failure while newer types are a brilliant success. But an economic success may be a social failure. Thus it was with the greater part of the Italian soil of the day which had passed into Roman hands. Efficiency was secured by accumulation and the smaller holdings were falling into decay. A problem so complex as that of a change in tenure and in the type of productive activity employed on the soil is not likely to yield to the analysis of any modern historian who deals with the events of the ancient world. He is often uncertain whether he is describing causes or symptoms, whether the primary evil was purely economic or mainly social, whether diminished activity was the result of poverty and decreasing numbers, or whether pauperism and diminu- tion of population were the effects of a weakened nerve for labour and of a standard of comfort so feverishly high that it declined the hard life of the fields and induced its possessors to refuse to propa- gate their kind. But social and economic evils react so constantly on one another that the question of the priority of the one to the other is not always of primary importance. A picture has been conjured up by the slight sketches of ancient historians and the more prolonged laments of ancient writers on agriculture, which gives us broad outlines that we must accept as true, although we may refuse to join in the belief that these outlines repre- sent an unmixed and almost incurable evil. These writers even attempt to assign causes, which convince by their probability, although there is often a suspicion that the ultimate and elusive truth has not been grasped. 60 A HISTORY OF ROME The two great symptoms which immediately impress our im- agination are a decline, real or apparent, in the numbers of the free population of Rome, and the introduction of new methods of agriculture which entailed a diminution in the class of freehold proprietors who had held estates of small or moderate size. The evidence for an actual decline of the population must be gathered exclusively from the Roman census hsts.^ At first sight these seem to tell a startling tale. At the date of the outbreak of the First Punic War (265 B.C.) the roll of Roman citizens had been given as 382,234,2 at a census held but three years before the tribunate of Tiberius Gracchus (136 B.C.) the numbers presented by the list were 307,833.^ In 129 years the burgess roll had shrunk by nearly 75,000 heads of the population. The shrinkage had not always been steadily progressive ; sometimes there is a sudden drop which tells of the terrible ravages of war. But the return of peace brought no upward movement that was long maintained. In the interval of comparative rest which followed the Third Macedonian War the census rolls showed a decrease of about 13,000 in ten years.* Seven years later 2,000 more have disappeared,* and a slight increase at the next lustrum is followed by another drop of about 14,000.® The needs of Rome had increased, and the means for meeting them were dwindling year by year. This must be admitted, however we interpret the meaning of these returns. A hasty generalisation might lead us to infer that a wholesale diminution was taking place in the population of Rome and Italy. The returns may add weight to other evidence which points this way ; but, taken by themselves, they afford no warrant for such a conclusion. The census lists were concerned, not only purely with Roman citizens, but purely with Roman citizens of a certain type. It is practically certain that they reproduce only the effective fighting strength of Rome,'^ and take no account of those citizens whose property did not entitle them to be placed amongst the 1 See de Boor Fasti Censorii. A disturbing element in this enumeration is the uncertainty of numerals in ancient manuscripts. But the fact of the progressive decline is beyond all question. No accidental errors of transcription could have produced this result in the text of Liyy's epitome. « Liv. Ep. xvi. ' Ibid. Ivi. * Ibid. xlvi. xlviii. ^ Euseb. Arm. a. Abr. 1870 01. 158.3 (Hieron. 01. 158.2 = 608 A.u.c). «Liv. fi^. Ivi. ' Eorum qui arma ferre possent (Liv. i. 44) ; tUv ix^"'''"'" t^'' (rrpoTeiiiri/tov fiKixlay (Dionys. xi. 63) ; tuv 4v tois vKixlais (Polyb. ii. 23). DECLINE OF THE WEALTHIER CLASSES 61 ^ But, if it is not necessary to believe that an actual diminution of population is attested by these declining numbers, the conclusion which they do exhibit is hardly less serious from an economic and political point of view. They show that portions of the well-to-do classes were ceasing to possess the property which entitled them to entrance into the regulai* army, and that the ranks of the poorer proletariate were being swelled by their impoverish- ment. It is possible that such impoverishment may have been welcomed as a boon by the wearied veterans of Rome and their descendants. It meant exemption from the heavier burdens of military service, and, if it went further still, it implied immunity from the tribute as long as direct taxes were collected from Roman citizens.^ As long as service remained a burden on wealth, how- ever moderate, there could have been little inducement to the man of small means to struggle up to a standard of moderately increased pecuniary comfort, which would certainly be marred and might be lost by the personal inconvenience of the levy. The decline in the numbers of the wealthier classes is thus at- tested by the census rolls. But indications can also be given which afford a slight probability that there was a positive diminution in the free population of Rome and perhaps of Italy. The carnage of the Hannibalic war may easily be overemphasised as a source of positive decline. Such losses are rapidly made good when war is followed by the normal industrial conditions which success, or even failure, may bring. But, as we shall soon see reason for believing that these industrial conditions were not wholly resumed in Italy, the Second Punic War may be regarded as having produced a gap in the population which was never entirely refilled. We find evidences of tracts of country which were not annexed by the rich but could not be repeopled by the poor. The pohcy pursued by the decaying Empire of settHng foreign colonists on Italian soil had already occurred to the statesmen of Rome in the infancy of her imperial expansion. In 180 b.c. 40,000 Ligurians belonging to the Apuanian people were dragged from their homes with their wives ' Besides the proletarii all under military age would be excluded firom these lists. Mommsen (Staatsr. ii. p. 411) goes further and thinks that the seniores are not included in our lists. ''The limit to the incidence of taxation was a property of 1500 asses {Cic.de Rep. ii. 22. 40), the limit of census for military service was by the time of Polybius reduced to 4000 asses (Polyb. vi. 19). Gellius (xvi. 10. 10) gives a reduction to 375 asses at a date unknown but preceding the Marian reform. Perhaps the numerals are incorrect and should be 3,750. 62 A HISTORY OF ROME and children and settled on some public land of Rome which lay in the territory of the Samnites. The consuls were commissioned to divide up the land in allotments, and money was voted to the colonists to defray the expense of stocking their new farms.^ Al- though the leading motive for this transference was the preserva- tion of peace amongst the Ligurian tribes, yet it is improbable that the senate would have preferred the stranger to its kindred had there been an outcry from the landless proletariate to be allowed to occupy and retain the devastated property of the State. But moral motives are stronger even than physical forces in check- ing the numerical progress of a race. Amongst backward peoples unusual indulgence and consequent disease may lead to the diminu- tion or even extinction of the stock ; amongst civilised peoples the motives which attain this result are rather prudential, and are con- cerned with an ideal of life which perhaps increases the efficiency of the individual, but builds up his healthy and pleasurable environ- ment at the expense of the perpetuity of the race. The fact that the Roman and Italian physique was not degenerating is abundantly proved by the military history of the last hundred years of the Re- public. This is one of the greatest periods of conquest in the history of the world. The Italy, whom we are often inclined to think of as exhausted, could still pour forth her myriads of valiant sons to the confines marked by the Rhine, the Euphrates and the Sahara ; and the struggle of the civil wars,- which followed this ex- pansion, was the clash of giants. But this vigour was accompanied by an ideal, whether of irresponsibility or of comfort, which gave rise to the growing habit of celibacy — a habit which was to stir the eloquence of many a patriotic statesman and finally lead to the intervention of the law. When the censor of 131 uttered the memorable exhortation " Since nature has so ordained that we can- not live comfortably with a wife nor live at all without one, you should hold the eternal safety of the State more dear than your own brief pleasure," ^ it is improbable that he was indulging in conscious cynicism, although there may have been a trace of conscious humour in his words. He was simply bending to the ideal of the people whom he saw, or imagined to be, before him. The ideal was not necessarily bad, as one that was concerned with individual life. It implied thrift, forethought, comfort— even efficiency of a kind, for the unmarried man was a more likely 1 Liv. xl. 38. 2 Gell. i. 6. C/. Liv. Ef. lix. INCREASE OF CELIBACY 63 recruit than the father of a family. But it sacrificed too much — the future to the present ; it ignored the undemonstrable duty which a man owes to the permanent idea of the State through working for a future which he shall never see. It rested partly on a conviction of security ; but that feeling of security was the most perilous sign of all. The practice of celibacy generally leads to irregular attach- ments between the sexes. In a society ignorant of slavery, such attachments, as giving rise to social inconveniences far greater than those of marriage, are usually shunned on prudential grounds even where moral motives are of no avail. But the existence in Italy of a large class of female dependants, absolutely outside the social circle of the citizen body, rendered the attachment of the master to his slave girl or to his freedwoman fatally easy and un- embarrassing. It was unfortunately as attractive as it was easy. Amidst the mass of servile humanity that had drifted to Italy from most of the queirters of the world there was scarcely a type that might not reproduce some strange and wonderful beauty. And the charm of manner might be secured as readily as that of face and form. The Hellenic East must often have exhibited in its women that union of wit, grace and supple tact which made even its men so irresistible to their Roman masters. The courtesans of the capital, whether of high or low estate,^ are from the point of view which we are considering not nearly so important as the permanent mistress or "concubine" of the man who might dwell in any part of Italy. It was the latter, not the former, that was the true substitute for the wife. There is reason to believe that it was about this period that " concubinage " became an institution which was more than tolerated by society.^ The relation which it implied between the man and his companion, who was generally one of his freedwomen, was sufficiently honourable. It excluded the idea of union with any other woman, whether by marriage or temporary association ; it might be more durable than actual wed- lock, for facilities for divorce were rapidly breaking the permanence ' See Wallon Hist, de I'Esclavage ii. p. 276. 2 Concuhinatus could not, by the nature of the case, become a legal conception until the Emperor Augustus had devised penalties for stuprum. It was theii necessary to determine what kind of stuprum was not punishable. But the social institution and its ethical characteristics, although they may have been made more definite by legal regulations, could not have originated in the time of the Principate. For the meaning oipaelex in Republican times see Meyer Der romische Konkubmat and a notice of that work in the English Historical Review for July 1896. 64 A HISTORY OF ROME of the latter bond; it might satisfy the juristic condition of " marital affection " quite as fully as the type of union to which law or religion gave its blessing. But it differed from marriage in one point of vital importance for the welfare of the State. Children might be the issue of concubinatus, but they were not looked on as its end. Such unions were not formed liber'Am quaerendorvm causa. The decline, or at least the stationary character, of the popula- tion may thus be shown to be partly the result of a cause at once social and economic ; for this particular social evil was the result of the economic experiment of the extended use of slavery as a means of production. This extension was itself partly the result of the accidents of war and conquest, and in fact, throughout this picture of the change which was passing over Italy, we can never free ourselves from the spectres of militarism and hegemony. But an investigation of the more purely economic aspects of the indus- trial life of the period affords a clear revelation of the fact that the effects of war and conquest were merely the foundation, accident- ally presented, of a new method of production, which was the result of deliberate design and to some extent of a conscious imitation of systems which had in turn built up the colossal wealth, and assisted the political decay, of older civilisations with which Rome was now brought into contact. The new ideal was that of the large planta- tion or latifundium supervised by skilled overseers, worked by gangs of slaves with carefully differentiated duties, guided by scien- tific rules which the hoary experience of Asia and Carthage had devised, but, in unskilled Roman hands, perhaps directed with a reckless energy that, keeping in view the vast and speedy returns which could only be given by richer soils than that of Italy, was as exhaustive of the capacities of the land as it was prodigal of the human energy that was so cheaply acquu-ed and so wastefully employed. The East, Carthage and Sicily had been the successive homes of this system, and the Punic ideal reached Rome just at the moment when the tendency of the free peasantry to quit their hold- ings as unprofitable, or to sell them to pay their debts, opened the way for the organisation of husbandry on the grand Carthaginian model.i The opportunity was naturally seized with the utmost eagerness by men whose wants were increasing, whose incomes must ' Cunningham Western Civilisation p. 156. Cf. Soltau in Kulturgesch. des klass. Altertums p. 318. GROWTH OF LARGE ESTATES 66 be made to keep pace with these wants, and whose wealth must inevitably be dependent mainly on the produce of the soil. Yet we have no warrant for accusing the members of the Roman nobility of a deliberate plan of campaign stimulated by conscious greed and selfishness. For a time they may not have known what they were doing. Land was falling in and they bought it up ; domains be- longing to the State were so unworked as to be falling into the condition of rank jungle and pestilent morass. They cleared and improved this land with a view to their own profit and the profit of the State. Free labour was unattainable or, when attained, em- barrassing. They therefore bought their labour in the cheapest market, this market being the product of the wars and slave-raids of the time. They acted, in fact, as every enlightened capitalist would act under similar circumstances. It seemed an age of the revival of agriculture, not of its decay. The official class was filled with a positive enthusiasm for new and improved agricultural methods. The great work of the Carthaginian Mago was trans- lated by order of the senate.^ Few of the members of that body would have cared to follow the opening maxim of the great expert, that if a man meant to settle in the country he should begin by selling his house in town ; ^ the men of affairs did not mean to be- come gentlemen farmers, and it was the hope of profitable invest- ment for the purpose of maintaining their dignity in the capital, not the rustic ideal of the primitive Roman, that appealed to their souls. But they might have hoped that most of the golden pre- cepts of the twenty-eight books, which unfolded every aspect of the science of the management of land, would be assimilated by the intelligent baUiff", and they may even have been influenced by a patriotic desire to reveal to the small holder scientific methods of tillage, which might stave off the ruin that they deplored as statesmen and exploited as individuals. But the lessons were thrown away on the small cultivator ; they probably presupposed the possession of capital and labour which were far beyond his reach; and science may have played but little part even in the accumulations of the rich, although the remarkable spectacle of ' Plin. H. N, xviii. 3. 22 ; Varro R. R. i. i. 10. 'Colum. I. I. 18. The Latin translation was probably made shortly after the destruction of Carthage, circa 140 B.C. (Mahaffy The Work of Mago on Agriculture in Hermathena vol. vii. i8go). Mahaffy believes that the Greek translation by Cassius Dionysius (Varro R. R. i. i. 10) was later, and he associates it with the colonies planted by C. Gracchus in Southern Italy. 5 66 A HISTORY OF ROME small holdings, under the personal supervision of peasant proprietors, being unable to hold their own against plantations and ranches managed by bailiffs and worked by slaves, does suggest that some improved methods of cultivation were adopted on the larger estates. The rapidity with which the plantation system spread must have excited the astonishment even of its promoters. Etruria, in spite of the fact that three colonies of Roman citizens had lately been founded within its borders,^ soon showed one continuous series of great domains stretching from town to town, with scarcely a village to break the monotonous expanse of its self-tilled plains. Little more than forty years had elapsed since the final settlement of the last Roman colony of Luna when a young Roman noble, travelling along the Etruscan roads, strained his eyes in vain to find a free labourer, whether cultivator or shepherd.^ In this part of Italy it is probable that Roman enterprise was not the sole, or even the main, cause of the wreckage of the country folk. The territory had always been subject to local influences of an aristocratic kind ; but the Etruscan nobles had stayed their hand as long as a free people might help them to regain their independence.^ Now sub- jection had crushed all other ambition but that of gain and personal splendour, while the ravages of the Hannibalic war had made the peasantry an easy victim of the wholesale purchaser. Farther south, in Bruttii and Apulia, the hand of Rome had co-operated with the scourge of war to produce a like result. The confiscations effected in the former district as a punishment for its treasonable relations with Hannibal,* the suitability of the latter for grazing purposes, which had early made it the largest tract of land in Italy patrolled by the shepherd slave,^ had swept village and cultivator away, and left through whole day's journeys but vast stretches of pasture be- tween the decaying towns. For barrenness and desolation were often the results of the new and improved system of management. There were tracts of country which could not produce cereals of an abundance and quality cap- able of competing with the com imported from the provinces ; but ' Saturnia in 183 (Liv. xxxix. 55), Graviscae in 181 (Liv. xl. 29), Luna in 180 and again in 177 (Liv. xli. 13 ; Mommsen in C. I. L. i. n. 539). See Marquardt Staatsverw. i. p. 39. 2 Plut. Ti. Gracch. 8 ; Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 198. * Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 198. * P. 68. " Liv. xxxix. 29. For the slave revolt of 185 B.C., whigh is here described, see p. 88, GROWTH OF PASTURAGE 67 even on territories where crops could be reared productively, it was tempting to substitute for the arduous processes of sowing and reap- ing the cheaper and easier industry of the pasturage of flocks. We do not know the extent to which arable land in fair condition was deliberately turned into pasturage ; but we can imagine many cases in which the land recently acquired by capitalists, whether from the State or from smaller holders, was in such a condition, either from an initial lack of cultivation or from neglect or from the ravages of war, that the new propietor may well have shrunk from the doubtful enterprise of sinking his capital in the soil, for the purpose of testing its productive qualities. In such cases it was tempting to treat the great domain as a sheep-walk or cattle-ranch. The initial expenses of preparation were small, the labour to be employed was reduced to a minimum, the returns in proportion to the expenses were probably far larger than could be gained from corn, even when grown under the most favourable conditions. The great diiBculty in the way of cattle-rearing on a large scale in earlier times had been the treatment of the flocks and herds dm'ing the winter months. The necessity for providing stalls and fodder for this period must have caused the proprietor to limit the heads of cattle which he cared to possess. But this constraint had vanished at once when a stretch of warm coast-line could be found, on which the flocks could pasture without feeling the rigour of the winter season. Conversely, the cattle-rearer who possessed the advantage of such a line of coast would feel his difficulties beginning when the summer months approached. The plains of the Campagna and Apulia could have been good neither for man nor beast during the torrid season. The full condition which freed a grazier from all embarrassment and rendered him careless of limiting the size of his flocks, was the combined possession of pastures by the sea for winter use, and of glades in the hills for pasturage in summer.^ Neither the men of the hills nor the men of the plains, as long as they formed independent communities, could become graziers on an extensive scale, and it has been pointed out that even a Greek settlement of the extent of Sybaris had been forced to import its wool from the Black Sea through Miletus.^ But when Rome had 'Varro R. R. ii. S- " Pascuntur armenta commodissime in nemoribus, ubi virgulta et frons multa. Hieme secundum mare, aestu abiguntur in montes frondosos. ^ Nltzsch Die Gracchen p. i6. 68 A HISTORY OF ROME won the Apennines and extended her influence over the coast, there were no limits to the extent to which cattle rearing could be carried.' It became perhaps the most gigantic enterprise connected with the soil of Italy. Its cheapness and efficiency appealed to every practical mind. Cato, who had a sentimental attachment to agriculture, was bound in honesty to reply to the question " What is the best manner of investment .? " by the words " Good pasturage". To the question as to the second-best means he answered "Tolerable pasturage". When asked to declare the third, he replied "Bad pasturage". To ploughing he would assign only the fourth place in the descend- ing scale.^ Bruttii and Apulia were the chief homes of the ranch and the fold. The Lucanian conquest of the former country must, even at a time preceding the Roman domination, have formed a connection between the mountains and the plains, and pasturage on a large scale in the mountain glades of the Bruttian territory may have been an inheritance rather than a creation of the Romans ; hut the ruin caused in this district by the Second Punic War, the an- nexation to the State of large tracts of rebel land,* and the reduction of large portions of the population to the miserable serf -like con- dition of dediticii,* must have offered the capitalists opportunities which they could not otherwise have secured ; and both here and in Apulia the tendency to extend the grazing system to its utmost limits must have advanced with terrible rapidity since the close of the Hannibalic war. It was the East coast of Southern Italy that was chiefly surrendered to this new form of industry, and we may observe a somewhat sharp distinction between the pastoral activity of these regions and the agricultural life which still con- tinued, although on a diminished scale, in the Western districts.* ■^ We have already made occasional reference to the accidents on which the new industrial methods that created the latifundia were designedly based. It is now necessary to examine these accidents 1 Nitzsch op. cit. p. 17. ^ Cic. de Off. ii. 25. 89. So in Cato's more reasoned estimate (/?. R. i. 7) of the relative degrees of productivity, although vinea comes first (cf. p. 80) yet pratum precedes campus frumentarius. ^ App. Hannib. 61. ■* App. I.e. ; Gell. x. 3. 19. ' Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 193 So zerfiel denn Mittelitalien in zwei scharf- getheilte Half ten, den ackerbauenden Westen und den viehzuchttreibenden Osten; jener reich an Hafen, von Landstrassen durchschnitten, in einer menge von Colonien Oder einzelnen Gehoften von Romischen Ackerbiirgern bewohnt ; dieser fast ohne Hafen, nur von einer Kustenstrasse durchschnitten, fiir den grossen Romer der rechte Sitz seiner Sclaven und Heerden. Cf. p. 21. For the pasturage in Calabria and Apulia see op. cit. pp. 13 and 193. CHANGES IN LAND TENURE 69 in greater detail, if only for the purpose of preparing the ground for a future estimate of the efficacy of the remedies suggested by statesmen for a condition of things which, however naturally and even honestly created, was deplorable both on social and political grounds. The causes which had led to the change from one form of tenure and cultivation to another of a widely different kind required to be carefully probed, if the Herculean task of a reversion to the earlier system was to be attempted. The men who essayed the task had unquestionably a more perfect knowledge of the causes of the change than can ever be possessed by the student of to-day ; but criticism is easier than action, and if it is hot to become shamelessly facile, every constraining element in the complicated problem which is at all recoverable (all those elements so clearly seen by the hard-headed and honest Roman reformers, but known by them to possess an invulnerability that we have forgotten) must be examined by the historian in the blundering analysis which is all that is permitted by his imperfect information, and still more imperfect realisation, of the temporary forces that are the mill- stones of a scheme of reform. The havoc wrought by the Hannibalic invasion ^ had caused even greater damage to the land than to the people. The latter had been thinned but the former had been wasted, and in some cases wasted, as events proved, almost beyond repair. The devas- tation had been especially great in Southern Italy, the nations of which had clung to the Punic invader to the end. But such results of war are transitory in the extreme, if the numbers and energy of the people who resume possession of their wrecked homes are not exhausted, and if the conditions of production and sale are as favourable after the calamity as they were before. The amount of wealth which an enemy can injure, lies on the mere surface of the soil, and is an insignificant fraction of that which is stored in the bosom of the earth, or guaranteed by a favourable commercial situation and access to the sea. Carthage could pay her war indemnity and, in the course of half a century, afiright Cato by her teeming wealth and fertility. Her people had resumed their old habits, bent whole- heartedly to the only life they loved, and the prizes of a crowded haven and bursting granaries were the result. If a nation does not recover from such a blow, there must be some permanent defect in its economic life or some fatal flaw in its administrative system. 1 Liv. xxviii. ii ; cf. Luc. Phars. i. 30. 10 A HISTORY OF ROME The devastation caused by war merely accelerates the process of decay by creating a temporary impoverishment, which reveals the severity of the preceding struggle for existence and renders hopeless its resumption. Certainly the great war of which Italy had been the theatre did mark such an epoch in the history of its agricultural life. A lack of productivity began to be manifested, for which, T however, subsequent economic causes were mainly responsible. The lack of intensity, which is a characteristic of slave labour, lessened the returns, while the secondary importance attached to the manuring of the fields was a vicious principle inherent in the agri- cultural precepts of the time.^ But it is probable that from this epoch there were large tracts of land the renewed cultivation of which was never attempted ; and these were soon increased by domains which yielded insufficient returns and were gradually abandoned. The Italian peasant had ever had a hard fight with the insalubrity of his soil. Fever has always been the dreaded goddess of the environs of Rome. But constant labour and effective drainage had kept the scourge at bay, until the evil moment came when the time of the peasant was absorbed, and his energy spent, in the toils of constant war, when his land was swallowed up in the vast estates that had rapid profits as their end and careless slaves as their cultivators. Then the moist fields gave out their native pesti- lence, and malaria reigned unchecked over the fairest portion of the Italian plain.^ One of the leading economic causes, which had led to the failure of a certain class of the Italian peasant-proprietors, was the competition to which they were exposed from the provinces. Borne herself had begun to rely for the subsistence of her increasing population on com imported from abroad, and many of the large coast-towns may have been forced to follow her example. The corn-producing powers of the MediteiTanean lands had now de- finitely shifted from the regions of the East and North to those of > Dureau de la Malle (Economic Politique ii. p. 58) compares the precept of the Roman "Quid est agrum bene colere ? bene arare. Quid secundum? arare. Tertio stercorare " with the adage of the French farmer " Fumez bien, lahourez mal, vous recueillerez plus qu'en fumant mal et en labourant bien ". ^ See Dreyfus Les lots agraires p. 97. Varro (R. R. i. 12. 2) is singularly correct in his account of the nature of the disease that arose from the loca palustria ;— Crescunt animalia quaedam minuta, quae non possunt oculi consequi, et per aera intus in corpus per os ac nares perveniunt atque efficiunt difficilis morbos. The passage is cited by Voigt (Iwan-Miiller's Handbuch iv. 2. p. 358) who gives a good sketch of the evils consequent on neglect of drainage. IMPORTATION OF CORN 71 the South.^ Greece, which had been barely able to feed itself during the most flourishing period of its history, could not under any circumstances have possessed an importance as a country of export for Italy ; but the economic evils which had fallen on this unhappy land are worthy of observation, as presenting a forecast of the fate which was in store for Rome. The decline in population, which could be attributed neither to war nor pestilence, the grow- ing celibacy and childlessness of its sparse inhabitants,^ must have been due to an agricultural revolution similar to that which was gradually being effected on Italian soil. The plantation system and the wholesale employment of slave labour must have swept across the Aegean from their homes in Asia Minor. Here their existence is sufficiently attested by the servile rising which was to assume, shortly after the tribunate of Tiberius Gracchus, the pre- tended form of a dynastic war; and the troubles which always attended the collection of the Asiatic tithes, in the days when a Roman province had been established in those regions, give no favourable impression of the agricultural prosperity of the countries which lay between the Taurus and the sea. As far south as Sicily there was evidence of exhaustion of the land, and of unnatural condi- tions of production, which excluded the mass of the free inhabitants from participation both in labour and profits. But even Sicily had learned from Carthage the evil lesson that Greece had acquired from Asia; the plantation system had made vast strides in the island, and the condition of the aratores, whether free-holders or lessees, was not what it had been in the days of Diodes and Timoleon. The growing economic dependence of Rome on Sicily was by no means wholly due to any exceptional productive capaci- ties in the latter, but was mainly the result of proximity, and of administrative relations which enabled the government and the speculator in com to draw definite and certain supplies of grain from the Sicilian cultivators. This was true also, although to a smaller degree, of Sardinia. But Sicily and Sardinia do mark the beginning of the Southern zone of lands which were capable of filling the markets of the Western world. It was the Northern coast of Africa which rose supreme as the grain-producer of the time. In the Carthaginian territory the natural absence of an agricultural peasantry amidst a commercial folk, and the elaboration of a de- ^ Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 228. '^ Polyb. xxxvii. 4. 72 A HISTORY OF ROME finite science of agriculture, had neutralised the ill effects which accompanied the plantation system amongst other peoples less business-like and scientific ; the cultivators had shown no signs of unrest and the soil no traces of exhaustion. It has been inferred with some probabihty that the hostility of Cato, the friend of agriculture and of the Italian yeoman, to the flourishing Punic state was directed to some extent by the fear that the grain of Africa might one day drive from the market the produce of the Italian fields ; ^ and, if this view entered into the calculations which produced the final Punic War, the very short-sightedness of the policy which destroyed a state only to give its lands to African cities and potentates or to Roman speculators, who might continue the methods of the extinct community, is only too characteristic of that t3rpe of economic jealousy which destroys an accidental pro- duct and leaves the true cause of offence unassailed. The destruc- tion of Carthage had, as a matter of fact, aggravated the danger ; for the first use which Masinissa of Numidia made of the vast power with which Rome had entrusted him, was an attempt to civilise his people by turning them into cultivators ; ^ and the virgin soil of the great country which stretched from the new boundaries of Carthage to the confines of the Moors, was soon reckoned amongst the competing elements which the Roman agriculturist had to fear. But the force of circumstances caused the Sicilian and Sardinian cultivator to be the most formidable of his immediate competitors. The facility of transport from Sicily to Rome rendered that island superior as a granary to even the more productive portions of the Italian mainland. Sicily could never have revealed the marvellous fertility of the valley of the Po, where a bushel and a half of wheat could be purchased for five pence half-penny, and the same quantity of barley was sold for half this price ; ^ but it was easier to get Sicilian com to Rome by sea than to get Gallic com to Rome by land ; and the system of taxation and requisitions which had grown out of the provincial organisation of the island, rendered it pecu- liarly easy to place great masses of corn on the Roman market at very short notice. Occasionally the Roman government enforced a sale of com from the province {frv/mentum emptuTn),* a reason- able price being paid for the grain thus demanded for the city 1 Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 237. 2 Polyb. xxxvii. 3. ^ Polyb. ii. 15. * For such purchases from Sardinia see Liv. xxxvi. 2, from Sicily (at a period later than that which we are considering) Cic. in Verr. iii. 70. 163. THE SYSTEM OF POSSESSION 7S or the army ; but this was almost the only case in which the govern- ment intervened to regulate supplies. In the ordinary course of things the right to collect the tithes of the province was purchased by public companies, who paid money, not grain, into the Roman treasury, and these companies placed their corn on the market as best they could. The operations of the speculators in grain doubtless disturbed the price at times. But yet the certainty, the abundance and the facilities for transport of this supply were such as practically to shut out from competition in the Roman market all but the most favourably situated districts of Italy. Their chance of competition depended mainly on their accidental possession of a good road, or their neighbourhood to the sea or to a navigable river.^ The larger proprietors in any part of Italy must have possessed gi-eater facilities for carrying their grain to a good market than were enjoyed by the smaller holders. The Clodian law on trade permitted senators to own sea-going ships of a certain ton- nage;^ they could, therefore, export their own produce without any dependence on the middle-man, while the smaller cultivators would have been obliged to pay freight, or could only have avoided such payment by forming shipping-companies amongst themselves. But such combination was not to be looked for amongst a peasant class, barely conscious even of the external symptoms of the great revolution which was dragging them to ruin, and perhaps almost wholly oblivious of its cause. It required less penetration to fathom the second of the great reasons for the accumulation of landed property in the hands of the few; for this cause had been before the eyes of the Roman world, and had been expounded by the lips of Roman statesmen, for generations or, if we credit a certain class of traditions,^ even for centuries. This cause of the growing monopoly of the land by the few was the system of possession which the State had encouraged, for the purpose of securing the use and cultivation of its public domain. The policy of the State seems to have changed from time to time with reference to its treatment of this particular portion of its property, which it valued as the most secure of its assets 1 C/. Cato R. R.i.3 (In choosing the situation of one's estate) oppidum validum prope siet aut mare aut amnis, qua naves ambulant, aut via bona celebrisque. 2 P. 33. 8 For the traditions which assign a very early date for laws dealing with the agerpublicus see the following chapter, which treats of the legislation of Tiberius Gracchus. 74 A HISTORY OF ROME and one that served, besides its financial end, the desirable purpose of assisting it to maintain the influence of Rome throughout almost every part of Italy. When conquered domain had first been declared "public," the government had been indifferent to the type of occupier which served it by squatting on this territory and reclaiming land that had not been divided or sold chiefly because its condition was too unattractive to invite either of these processes.^ It had probably extended its invitation even to Latin allies,^ and looked with approval on any member of the burgess body who showed his enterprise and patriotism by the performance of this great public service. If the State had a partiality, it was probably for the richer and more powerful classes of its citizens. They could embrace a greater quantity of land in their grasp, and so save the trouble which attended an estimate of the returns of a great number of small holdings; they possessed more effective means of reclaiming waste or devastated land, for they had a greater control of capital and labour ; lastly, through their large bands of clients and slaves, they had the means of efficiently pro- tecting the land which they had occupied, and this must have been an important consideration at a time when large tracts of the ager publicus lay amidst foreign territories which were barely pacified, and were owned by communities that often wavered in their allegiance to Rome. But, whatever the views of the government, it is tolerably clear that the original occupiers must have chiefly represented men of this stamp. These were the days when the urban and the rustic tribes were sharply divided, as containing respectively the men of the town and the men of the country, and when there were comparatively few of the latter folk that did not possess some holding of their own. It was improbable that a townsman would often venture on the unfamiliar task of taking up waste land ; it was almost as improbable that a small yeoman would find leisure to add to the unaided labour on his own holding the toil of working on new and unpromising soil, except in the cases where some unclaimed portion of the public domain was in close proximity to his estate. 'App. Bell. Civ. i. 7 rrjs Si yris ttjs SopiicrlfTOv ep6vttoy ras fiL 161). Frontinus p. 53 Per longum enim tempus attigui possessores vacantia loca quasi invitante otiosi soli opportunitate invaserunt, et per longum tempus in- pune commalleaverunt. For the invasion of pasturage see Frontinus p. 48 Haec fere pascua certis personis data sunt depascenda tunc cum agri adsignati sunt. Haec pascua multi per inpotentiam invaserunt et colunt. ^In spite of the fertility of the land, the native Gallic population had vanished from most of the districts of this region as early as Polybius' time (Polyb. ii. 35). Cf. Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 60. THE CONSCRIPTION 77 could only be rehabilitated by a loan of seed or money. The lot of the warrior of moderate means was illustrated by the legend of Regulus. He was believed to have written home to the consuls asking to be relieved of his command in Africa. The bailiff whom he had left on his estate of seven jugera was dead, the hired man had stolen the implements of agriculture and run away ; the farm lay desolate and, were its master not permitted to return, his wife and children would lack the barest necessaries of existence.^ The struggle to maintain a household in the absence of its head was becoming more acute now that corn-land was ceasing to pay, except under the most favourable conditions, and now that the demand for conscripts was sometimes heavier and always more continuous than it had ever been before. Perhaps one-tenth of the adult male population of Rome was always in the field ; ^ the units came and went, but the men who bore the brunt of the long campaigns and of garrison duty in the provinces were those to whom leisure meant life — the yeomen who maintained their place in the census lists by hardy toil, and who risked their whole subsistence through the service that had been wrested from them as a reward for a laborious career. When they ceased to be owners of their land, they found it difficult to secure places even as labourers on some rich man's property. The landholder preferred the services of slaves which could not be inter- rupted by the call of military duty.^ The economic evils consequent on the conscription must have been felt with hardly less severity by such of the Italian allies as lived in the regions within which the latifundia were growing up. To these were added the pecuniary burdens which Rome had been forced to impose during the Second Punic War. These burdens were for the most part indirect, for Rome did not tax her Italian socii, but they were none the less severe. Every contingent supplied from an allied community had its expenses, except that of food during service, defrayed from the treasury of its own state,* and ten con- tinuous years of conscription and requisition had finally exhausted the loyalty even of Rome's Latin kindred.' It is true that the Italians were partially, although not wholly, free from the economic ' Val. Max. iv. 4. 6. ^ Steinwender Die romische Burgerschaft in ihrem Verhdltnis zum Heere p. 28. ' App. Bell. Civ. i. 7. '' Polyb. vi. 39. 'Liv. xxvii. 9 (209 B.C.) Fremitus enim inter Latinos sociosque in conciliis ortus:— Decimum annum dilectibus, stipendiis se exhaustos esse . . . Duodecim (coloniae) . . . negaverunt consulibus esse unde milites pecuniamque darent. 78 A HISTORY OF ROME struggle between the possessors of the public land and the small freeholders ; but there is no reason for supposing that those of Western Italy were exempt from the consequences of the reduc- tion in price that followed the import of corn from abroad, and the drain on their incomes and services which had been caused by war could scarcely have fitted them to stand this unexpected trial. Rome's harsh dealings with the treasonable South, although adopted for political motives, was almost unquestionably a political blunder. She confiscated devastated lands, and so perpetuated their devasta- tion. She left ruined harbours and cities in decay. She crippled her own resources to add to the pastoral wealth of a handful of her citizens. In the East of Italy there was a far greater vitality than elsewhere in agriculture of the older type. The Samnites in their mountains, the Peligni, Marrucini, Frentani and Vestini between the Apennines and the sea still kept to the system of small freeholds. Their peasantry had perhaps always cultivated for consumption rather than for sale ; then- inhabitants were rather beyond the reach of the ample supply from the South ; and for these reasons the competition of Sicilian and African corn did not lead them to desert their fields. They were also less exposed than the Romans and Latins to the aggressions of the great possessor ; for, since they possessed no coTnmercium with Rome, the annexation of their pro- perty by legal means was beyond the reach even of the ingenious cupidity of the times.^ The proof of the existence of the yeoman in these regions is the danger which he caused to Rome. The spirit which had maintained his economic independence was to aim at a higher goal, and the struggle for equality of political rights was to prove to the exclusive city the prowess of that class of peasant proprietors which she had sacrificed in her own domains. But, although this sacrifice had been great, we must not be led into the belief that there was no hope for the agriculturist of moderate means either in the present or in the future. Even in the present there were clear indications that estates of moderate size could under careful cultivation hold their own. The estate of Lucius Manlius, which Cato sketches in his work on agriculture,^ was far from rivalling the great demesnes of the princes of the land. It consisted of 240 jugera devoted to the olive and of 100 jugera reserved for the vine. Provision was made for a moderate supply of 1 Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 194. 2 Cato R. R. 144 etc. PROSPECTS OF AGRICULTURE 79 corn and for pasturage for the cattle that worked upon the fields. But the farm was on the whole a representative of the new spirit, which saw in the vine and the olive a paying substitute for the decadent culture of grain. Even on an estate of this size we note as significant that the permanent and even the higher personnel of the household (the latter being represented by the villici and the villicae) was composed of slaves ; yet hirelings were needed for the harvest and the corn was grown by cottagers who held their land on a metayer tenure. But such an estate demanded unusual capital as well as unusual care. On the tiny holdings, which were all that the poorest could afford, the scanty retiu-ns might be eked out by labour on the fields of others, for the small allotment did not demand the undivided energies of its holder.^ There was besides a class of politores ^ similar to that figured as cultivating the corn- land on the estate of Manlius, who received in kind a wage on which they could at least exist. They were nominally TnMayer tenants who were provided with the implements of husbandry by their landlord ; but the quantity of grain which they could reserve to their own use was so small, varying as it did from a ninth to a fifth of the whole of the crop which they had reaped,* that their position was little better than that of the poorest labourer by the day.* The humblest class of freemen might still make a living in districts where pasturage did not reign supreme. But it was a living that involved a sacrifice of independence and a submission to sordid needs that were unworthy of the past ideal of Roman citizen- ship. It was a living too that conferred little benefit on the State ; for the day-labourers and the politores could scarcely have been in the position on the census list which rendered them liable to the conscription. If it were possible to lessen the incidence of military service and to secure land and a small amount of capital for the dispossessed, the prospects for the future were by no means hopeless. The smaller culture, especially the cultivation of the vine and the olive, is that to which portions of Italy are eminently suited. This is especially true of the great volcanic plain of the West extending 1 Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 187. " Cato R. R. 5, 136. ^Cato R. R. 136 Politionem quo pacto partiario dari oporteat. In agro Casinate et Vena&o in loco bono parti octava corbi dividat, satis bono septima, tertio loco sexta ; si granum modio dividet, parti quinta. In Venafro ager optimus jiona parti corbi dividat . . . Hordeum quiiita modio, fabam quinta modio dividat, * Nitzsch Die Gracchen p. 188, 80 A HISTORY OF ROME from the north of Etruria to the south of Campania and com- prising, besides these territories, the countries of the Latins, the Sabines, the Volsci and the Hernici. The lightness and richness of the alluvion of this volcanic soil is almost as suited to the production of cereals as to that of the vine and the olive or the growth of vegetables.^ But, even on the assumption that corn-growing would not pay, there was nothing to prevent, and everything to encourage the development of the olive plantation, the vineyard and the market garden throughout this region. It was a country sown with towns, and the vast throat of Rome alone would cry for the products of endless labour. Even Cato can place the vine and the olive before grazing land and forest trees in the order of produc- tivity,^ and before the close of the Republic the government had learnt the lesson that the salvation of the Italian peasantry depended on the cultivation of products like these. The con- viction is attested by the protective edict that the culture of neither the vine nor the olive was to be extended in Transalpine Gaul.^ Market gardening was also to have a considerable future, wherever the neighbourhood of the larger towns created a demand for such supplies.* A new method of tenure also gave opportuni- ties to those whose capital or circumstances did not enable them to purchase a sufficient quantity of land of their own. Leaseholds became more frequent, and the coloni thus created ^ began to take an active share in the agricultural life of Italy. Like the villici, they were a product of the tendency to live away from the estate ; but they gained ground at the expense of the servile bailiffs, prob- ably in consequence of their greater trustworthiness and keener interest in the soil. But time was needed to effect these changes. For the present the reign of the capitalist was supreme, and the plantation system was dominant throughout the greater part of Italy. The most essential ' Dureau de la Malle &conomie Politique ii. pp. 225, 226. ' Cato R. R. i. 7 Vinea est prima, . . . secundo loco hortus inriguus, tertio salictum, quarto oletum, quinto pratum, sexto campus frumentarius, septimo silva caedua, octavo arbustum, nono glandaria silva. ' Cic. de Rep. iii. 9. 16 Nos vero justissimi homines, qui Transalpinas gentis oleam et vitem serere non sinimus, quo pluris sint nostra oliveta nostraeque vineae. Cf. Colum. iii. 3. 11. * See Cato R. R. 7. 8 for the produce of the/wKdMs suburbanits. Cf. c. i (note 2) for the value of the hortus inriguus. " See the citations in Voigt (Iwan-Muller's Handbuch iv. 2 p. 370). Communities and corporations employed coloni on their agri vectigales (Cic. ad Fam. xiii. 11. i ; Hygin. de Cond. Agr. p. 117. 11; Voigt. I.e.), SLAVE LABOUR 81 ingredient in this system was the slave, — an alien and a chattel, indi- vidually a thing of little account, but reckoned in his myriads the most powerful factor in the economic, and therefore in the political, life of the times, the gravest of the problems that startled the reformer. The soil of Italy was now peopled with widely varied types, and echoes of strange tongues from West and East could be heard on every hand. Italy seemed a newly discovered country, on which the refuse of all lands had been thrown to become a people that could never be a nation. The home supply of slaves, so familiar as to seem a product of the land, was becoming a mere trifle in comparison with the vast masses that were being thrust amongst the peasantry by war and piracy. At the time of the protest of Tiberius Gracchus against the dominance of slave labour in the fields scarcely two generations had elapsed since the great influx had begun. The Second Punic War had spread to every quarter of the West ; Sicily, Sardinia, Cisalpine Gaul and Spain all yielded their tribute in the form of human souls that had passed from the victor to the dealer, from the dealer to the country and the town. Only one generation had passed since a great wave had swept from Epirus and Northern Greece over the shores of Italy. In Epirus alone one hundred and fifty thousand prisoners had been sold.^ Later still the destruction of Carthage must have cast vast quantities of agricultural slaves upon the market.^ Asia too had yielded up her captives as the result of Roman victories ; but the Oriental visages that might be seen in the streets of Rome or the plains of Sicily, were less often the gift of regular war than of the piracy and the systematised slave-hunting of the Eastern Mediterranean. Rome, who had crushed the rival maritime powers that had attempted, however imperfectly, to police the sea, had been content with the work of destruction, and seemed to care nothing for the enterprising buccan- eers who sailed with impunity as far west as Sicily. The pirates had also made themselves useful to the Oriental powers which still retedned their independence ; they had been tolerated, if they had not been employed, by Cyprus and Egypt when these states were struggl- ing against the Empire of the Seleucids.^ But another reason for their immunity was the view held in the ancient world that slave- ' Liv. xlv. 34. ' Mahaffy (" The Slave Wars against Rome " in Hermathena no. xvi. i8go) believes that the majority of these were shipped to Sicily. ' Strabo xiv. 5. 2. 6 8^ A HISTORY OF ROME hunting was in itself a legitimate form of enterprise.'^ The pirate might easily be regarded as a mere trader in human merchandise. As such, he had perhaps been useful to Carthage ; ^ and, as long as he abstained from attacking ports or nationalities under the pro- tectorate of Rome, there was no reason why the capitalists in power should frown on the trade by which they prospered. For the pirates could probably bring better material to the slave market than was usually won in war.^ A superior elegance and culture must often have been found in the helpless victims on whom they pounced ; beauty and education were qualities that had a high marketable value, and by seizing on people of the better class they were sure of one of two advantages — either of a ransom furnished by the friends of the captives, or of a better price paid by the dealer. There was scarcely a pretence that the traders were mere intermediaries who bought in a cheap market and sold in a dear. They were known to be raiders as well, and numbers of the captives exhibited in the mart at Side in Pamphylia were known to have been freemen up to the moment of the auction.* The facility for cap- ture and the proximity of Delos, the greatest of the slave markets which connected the East with the West, rendered the supply enormous ; but it was equalled by the demand, and myriads of captives are said to have been shipped to the island and to have quitted it in a single day. The ease and rapidity of the business transacted by the master of a slave-ship became a proverb ; * and honest mercantile undertakings with their tardy gains must have seemed contemptible in comparison with this facile source of wealth. An abundant supply and quick returns imply reasonable prices ; and the cheapness of the labour supplied by the slave-trade, whether as a consequence of war or piracy, was at once a necessary condition of the vitality of the plantation system and a cause of the reckless- ' C/. Arist. Pol. i. 8. 12 t) woKefuxii (picrei KTHiTixfi rus earat. ri y&p BripevTixii /iepos auTrjs, p Sei xP?"'^'" ^P^^ '''^ ''^ ftijpio Kul ray avBpdiruv iaoi ire