HCr £051 US Hfe^ CORNELL UNIVERSITY LIBRARY BUSINESS 62d Congress, ) HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, j Document 8d Session. J i n ggi ■^i^ AGRICULTURAL CRED Cornell University Library HG2051.U5H68 Agricultural credit banks. 3 1924 019 326 622 AN ARTICLE BY O. R.HftBSON, M. A., ENTITLED "AGRICULTURAL ^" " >l " 1 ! CREDIT BANKS," PUBLISHED IN THE JOURNAL OF THE INSTI- TUTE OF BANKERS, LONDON. July 27, 1912.— Ordered to be' printed. An agricultural credit bank, as its name implies, is a bank the main object of whose existence is to grant credit to those engaged in agriculture. It is, in fact, the function of the agricultural Dank to finance agriculture in just the same way as the ordinary joint stock bank considers it at any rate part of its business to finance industry. The large joint stock bank is chiefly the product of tbe industrial revolution which, consequent upon the invention of machinery and the discovery of steam power, largely increased the importance of capital as a factor of production at the expense of labor, thus replacing the small producer by the wealthy capitalist and the joint stock company. Of the agricultural credit bank, on the other hand, it would be more true to say that it was the cause than the effect of an agricultural revolution; for its growth was due rather to the wisdom oi those who saw that the methods of financing industry might with advantegs be applied to agriculture than to any demand on the part of agriculture itself for credit as a means to increasing the produc- tivity of the soil. But though it is true that capital can be used in agriculture as well as in industry, the evolution of the agricultural credit bank has not been, and can not be, similar to that of industrial credit banks. In the first place, the industrial credit bank can with advantage do business with a large number of different industries, while the agricultural credit bank must, in the probable absence of any other form of business, confine itself almost exclusively to agriculture. Secondly, while industrial production has fallen chiefly into the hands of the large capitalist, agriculture has, to a very large extent, whether for social or economic reasons, continued to be carried on by small men, and it is thus chiefly with the small and poor man that the agricultural credit bank has to deal. Agricultural credit banks may plainly be organized on three differ- ent principles, namely, (1) as State controlled institutions, (2) as joint stock, or private profit-earning companies, (3) cooperatively, as cooperative societies. " As this essay will be concerned mainly with the discussion of banks included in the third category it will not be out of place to indicate l7o "Business ■■^ q Fj I 1 2 AGBICULTTJBAL CBEDIT BANKS. U5l"\£$ at the outset the general grounds for rejecting those of the first two classes as unsuitable, amplifying and illustrating them later from the experience of countries in which such institutions exist and flourish. (1) The objections to the management or control by ^the State of agricultural credit banks are in the main those which apply to all State enterprise of a commercial character. Institutions managed by the State are liable, owing to the absence of competition and the lack of incentive on the part of its employees, to be conducted without that regard for efficiency and economy which is essential to the success of private industrial undertakings. This is a defect which is prob- ably inseparable from State trading; and though there may in many cases be countervailing reasons which will justify the State in under- taking for itself, to the exclusion of private firms or persons, the production of certain commodities or the supplying of certain wants, it will scarcely be maintained that agricultural banking is one of these. For the agricultural credit bank Is concerned, as we have seen, with the granting of credit to men of little substance engaged in a notoriously uncertain occupation, and for this reason extreme vigi- lance and economy of management are above all things essential for \\a success. The State may, indeed, carry on the business at a loss, but such protection granted to one industry at the expense of the others is scarcely likely to conduce to its real benefit, but is calculated rather to lead it to rely more and more on artificial support till it becomes finally incapable of existing without it. This criticism will apply also to State doles and bounty feeding, even though the channels through which they are dispensed are not controlled by the State. Credit can be as usefully employed by the agriculturist as by the industrialist, but only if it be obtained in the way of business at its market value. A farmer who pays the market rate for his loans will consider carefully and think long whether the result is likely to justify the outlay — whether, for example, the fertilizer which a loan will enable him to put in is likely by the increased crop of next year to yield him a margin of profit after he has paid the interest. If, however, a bountiful but misguided government literally thrusts upon him any sum he may choose to name at an absurdly low rate of interest, a very small knowledge of human nature will show that it is more than probable that he will evolve his schemes for improve- ment with a hght heart and end them with a lighter purse. Assistance of this kind merely puts a premium on incompetence. It is fairly claimed that facilities for credit will, in addition to the material profit they afford, have the moral effect of stimulating con- fidence and independence, but this result will only follow if such credit is demanded and given as a matter of business on business terms. This does not mean that the State can not do much to facilitate the establishment of a system of agricultural credit banks, but it is sub- mitted that the true criterion of any measure of assistance is this: Is the proposed aid a temporary expedient for the purpose of tiding the system over the critical period of youth, to be dispensed with as soon as it reaches a more mature age ? Or, is it calculated rather to reduce it to a permanent condition of weakliness and dependence ? (2) It may appear surprising, at first sight, that the joint stock banking system which, in the course of the last eighty years, has established itself so impregnably throughout the civilized world, AGEIOULTUBAL CREDIT BANKS. 3 should be deemed incapable of adapting itself to the needs of the small agriculturist. That it has not succeeded in doing so adequately will probably be admitted. This fact is itself prima facie evidence that it is not fitted for such a task; for, with the ever-increasing pres- sure of competition, so obvious a development of banking business would assuredly not have escaped notice had it been capable of suc- cessful exploitation. There is no need, however, fo strain the point, since the reason for this failing on the part of the 'joint-stock bank is not far to seek. In point of fact the agricultural credit bank does not pay, in the ordinary commercial sense of the word. The banking transactions of the class of men with whom it deals are on so small a scale that in any case it would be a matter of difficulty for a com- mercial enterprise to undertake them with success. But the crux of the situation lies in the fact that these small agriculturists have for the most part no security of the kind acceptable to a banker to offer as cover for their loans. In the case of the small proprietor a mort- gage of his farm may, of course, be available, though such a proceeding is m many cases too expensive and cumbersome; but the tenant farmer has usually no collateral whatever to offer, save possibly the hypothecation of future crops or of cattle or plant. Neither expedient, though useful on occasion, is very desirable, nor likely to find favor in the eyes of a banker. In the majority of cases, in fact, the lender will have little more substantial to rely on than the personal security of the borrower, supplemented, perhaps, by the guaranty of a friend or two not much better, off financially than himself. It is evident, therefore, that the professional banker will be unable to any large extent to accommodate this class of customer. His existing branches in the smaller towns are not so remunerative that he will easily be induced to establish numerous further offices in country villages; while the supervision of loans, covered by the type of security we have described, is a task which would severely tax the powers of the most vigilant and capable of managers. Further, the periods for which loans will frequently be required are much longer than that for which the joint-stock bank cares to part with its funds. Agricultural credit must in general be long-term credit. The farmer does not, as a rule, turn his money over nearly so rapidly as the manufacturer or tradesman. For few agricultural purposes is a loan for less than six months of much use; and where it is required for the purchase of a fertilizer or the erection of buildings the necessary period may run into years. We may conclude then that the joint stock banking system, through no fault of its own, but owing to the inherent difficulties which the task involves, can not hope to succeed in adapting itself to the needs of the small agriculturist. (3) The Cooperative Society is defined by Mr. Fay as "an associa- tion for the purposes of joint trading originating among the weak and conducted always in an unselfish spirit, on such terms that all who are prepared to assume the duties of membership may share in its rewards, in proportion to the degree in which they make use of their association." 1 The cooperative bank is a cooperative society for the purpose of carrying on the- trade of banking. It is, in fact, a bank in which the proprietors and the customers are one and the same body i "Cooperation at Home and Abroad," p. 5. 4 AGBICTJLTTJBAL CREDIT BANKS. of people. The qualification for membership of a credit society is the subscription of one or more shares of small amounts which are not transferable, 1 but may be refunded when membership ceases. The liability of a member for the debts of the society may be limited to the amount of the paid-up share or to a multiple of it, or, as is more usual, may be without limit. Subject to the payment of this share, with possibly a small entrance fee, anyone who can give proof of satis- factory personal character is freely admitted. What grounds have we for supposing that such an association of men of small means, utterly without training in the business they are to conduct, will succeed, where the State with its unlimited finan- cial resources and the professional banker with his expert knowledge are, as we have suggested, doomed to failure? What qualifications for the task do these pigmies possess which the giants of the finan- cial and political worlds can not claim with a hundred times more plausibility ? These are questions which a statement of claim on behalf of cooperation wul at once call forth. They are questions to which a, priori reasoning can supply no answer half so convincing as the actual history of the movement. Before passing, however, to the consideration of the systems themselves from the dynamic point of view, we may indicate briefly wherein it is that the strength of the cooperative rural credit society lies. We shall find that it lies mainly in two directions, the one peculiar to itself, the other shared with other forms of cooperation. « It has already been pointed out that the small agriculturist, while he needs credit, and can put it to good use, suffers from the great disadvantage that he has no adequate security of the type usually required to offer. Now, the place of material security can only be taken by personal security, by a system, in fact, by which the bor- rower will borrow on the security of his own character, together with that of a number of his friends who may be willing to back their good opinion of him by guaranteeing the payment of his loan. For the success of this plan it is manifestly essential for the members of the society in general, and the guarantors of a loan in particular, to keep a sharp watch on the borrowing member, to see that the loan is duly applied to the purpose for which it was granted, and that its repayment is not jeopardized by the folly or incompetence of the borrower. The situation is summed up with characteristic Gallic felicity by M. DScharme, of the French Ministere d'Agriculture, when he describes credit banks of his country as being "in communities where every- body knows everybody else, and they always ask what the man wants to borrow for, and if he says he wants 400 francs to buy a cow, they watch him, and if, four or five days afterwards, he has no cow, thev know it." ' _ J The system is, in fact, an extension of the cash credit system of Scotland, to which, in the words of Macleod, "the marvelous progress and prosperity of that country is mainly due." Its fundamental characteristic is that the supervision of loans is conducted without expense, and conducted efficiently, because it is to the' interest not only of guarantors but of all the members 'of a society to exercise the strictest vigilance. i " Cooperation at Home and Abroad." Appendix. » Interviews on the Banking and Currency Systems of England, Scotland, eto. (U. S. Monetary Com- mission.) J AGBICULTUBAL CEEDIT BANKS. 5 The second important asset of the cooperative bank — that which it possesses in common with cooperative supply and sale societies — is the power of collective bargaining. As the cooperative supply- society can buy at wholesale rates and sell to its members at less than retail prices, owing to the elimination of middlemen's profits, so the cooperative credit society is able to command loans and deposits at moderate rates on the joint security of its members, relending to the latter at lower interest than they can individually obtain. The combined effect of these two factors, inexpensiveness of man- agement and collective bargaining, is that the cooperative bank can grant credit on cheaper terms than the joint stock bank, while making the business pay where the latter can not. With this brief preliminary indication of the nature and methods of the agricultural credit society, we must proceed to consider the actual systems in existence, beginning with those of Germany, the pioneer of the movement. Germany. It was in 1848, the year in which the acute distress of the poor at last found vent in revolutions and uprisings throughout Europe, that the seeds were first sown of that great system of cooperative credit, whose influence on the agricultural world it would be difficult to over- estimate. The movement in Germany, in contrast with the pretentious but ill-fated scheme of Proudhon in France, started unostentatiously enough. Its pioneers were two, Schulze and Raiffeisen, burgomasters respectively of Delitzsch in Saxony and the district round Neuwied on the Rhine. The circumstances which called forth their energies were the same in each case, namely, the helpless distress of the poor. They saw, as others did, that it was the economic waste caused by want of capital which lay at the root of the evil. But they alone were able,, in the face of general incredulity, to devise a remedy. The first efforts of both were of the nature of individual attempts to relieve distress in their districts. And when experience taught them that permanent amelio- ration could only come through self-help, it was in the direction rather of cooperative supply than of cooperative credit that. they v set out. They organized small cooperative societies for the purchase of necessi- ties of fife and raw materials. Thia, however, they soon saw was not sufficient, because the poor were already deeply in debt to money- lenders. It was the presence of the moneylender in their midst that led the way to cooperative credit. Relief measures were of little avail while the hurden of debt remained. Their efforts were thus directed toward the establishment of credit societies; and as the out- come we have two distinct systems, differing, if not essentially as the more fanatical adherents of either would have us believe, yet in details sufficiently important to justify a brief examination of each. The points of difference will be found to be due mainly to the slightly different functions which the two systems perform, but partly, also, to the different spirit which animated their founders. The Raiffeisen banks are purely agricultural banks, drawing their members very largely from the class of small farmers and agricultural laborers. Each bank serves a very small area, an area limited hVf act by the practical requirement that all the mem- bers should know each other. The Schulze banks on the other 6 AGBICULTUBAL CEEDIT BANKS. hand are situated chiefly in urban districts, their business lies among small men of every class, industrialists and shopkeepers as well as farmers, and the area from which their members are drawn is far less restricted than under the Raiffeisen system. In fact the Schulze- Delitzsch banks are commonly called town banks, 1 and in so far as that is the case they are outside the scope of our survey. The de? scription, however, would seem to be hardly quite accurate, since of their members the largest class, about 27 per cent of the whole, is classified as "independent agriculturists." 2 In view of this and the further fact that they have always regarded the Raiffeisen banks as competitors, we should not be justified in excluding them from consideration. Membership and organization. (1) Schulze-Delitzsch banks. — The gover ning idea in Schulze's mind was that his banks should be quite above suspicion of any connection with charity and still more with religion. They were to be self-sufficient, independent, profit- making concerns, only differing from joint stock banks in that the members alone were to have an interest in profits earned. Acc&rd- ingly admission to membership must not be made too easy. The amount of the share was therefore fixed at a comparatively high figure, the minimum being about £6, while the average is no less than £17. 3 Payment by installments within a reasonable time is allowed. Over and above this there remains the unlimited liability of each member, limited liability, first allowed by the law of 1868, being a feature of only few societies. Thus no effort was spared to secure members of thrifty and industrious character, and also to establish the societies from the first on a sound basis. For this lat- ter purpose, also, strict rules were laid dwn as to the building up and administration of the reserve fund. For the first year or two all profits are allocated to reserve, and thereafter 15 to 20 per cent. The administration of the banks is closely analogous to that of the ordinary joint stock company. It consists of (1) the Aufsichtsrat or directorate, elected by the general meeting of members, and (2) the Vorstand, or management committee, three in number, appointed by the Aufsichtsrat. The managers, in strict accordance with Schulze's theory of the noncharitable, businesslike nature of his banks, ape paid officials, a weak feature of the scheme being the commission ailowed to them on business transacted. The Vor- stand, " of course, superintends the actual working of the bank, and also deals with the applications for advances, subject to the possible intervention of the Aufsichtsrat in special cases. The Aufsichtsrat determine questions of policy, and act also as an audit and inspection committee. (2) Raiffeisen banks. — The Raiffeisen banks were organized to supply the needs of a far poorer class of people than those of the Schulze-Delitzsch system — a class to which the subscription of even a moderate share was an utter impossibility. Accordingly Raiffeisen laid even more stress than Schulze on the necessity of temperance and good character as qualifications for membership, while he dispensed with such material evidence of their presence as ability to subscribe a share, by having neither shares nor entrance fee. The subscription of shares and the payment of dividends were » Pay, op. cit., p. 19. « ibid., p. 42. » Ibid., p. 22: Wolfl, " People's Banks," p. 87. AGBICTTLTtTBAL CBEDIT BANKS. 7 indeed made compulsory by the law of 1889, but the Raiffeisen societies continued to observe the spirit of their founder's teaching by making the shares as_ small as possible, 10 marks being a usual figure, and by voting their dividends once for all to a second reserve or " Stiftungsfond. " The ordinary indivisible reserve fund is admin- istered on the same lines as in the Schulze banks, though it is as a rule smaller even in proportion to the size of the banks, as it has been the custom to apply part of the profits of working to the reduc- tion of the rate of interest on loans, which, for this reason, stands, on an average, about 1 per cent less in the country than in the towns. 1 Unlike Schulze, Raiffeisen laid much stress on the moral and religious character of his banks. Owing to this and to the smaller business transacted the administration is almost entirely unpaid. The management rests in the hands of a committee of five, while to a council of inspection is intrusted the duty of auditing accounts and supervising the committee. Both bodies are elected for a period of years by the members, and on both the richer members, on whom in case of failure would fall the chief burden of the liability, are allowed by tacit consent to take the leading part. The services of the members of both committee and council are given without remuneration of any kind, the only paid official being the "rechner, " or accountant, a nonmember appointed by the committee. Funds and advances. — The funds with which both systems of banks carry on their business consist of (1) share capital and reserve funds, (2) deposits, (3) loans from central banks. As regards the first item, the proportion derived from this source is, of course, far larger in the case of the Schulze than the Raiffeisen banks. Deposits, which are received both from members and non- members, may be either small savings accounts, deposits proper ("Depositen"), or drawing accounts. The first type form a steady and comparatively cheap source of working capital. 2 The rate of interest allowed averages about 3 to 3^ per cent, varying with the length and notice of withdrawal. This is usually considerable, and rightly so, as the class from which these deposits are drawn is one that is peculiarly prone to panic. Their great merit is that being largely the savings of nonborrowers they are not so likely to be withdrawn just when they are most required. Deposits proper differ from savings deposits in being usually of larger amount and subject to shorter notice of withdrawal. The current account is increasingly used in the Schulze banks, but, as might be supposed, is of very small importance in the country banks. Deposits are the mainstay of the German cooperative banks, and the ability to attract them is generally regarded as the surest sign of the stability and efficiency of a bank. But it is not to be expected that purely local banks, as both Schulze and Raiffeisen societies are, can always command deposits sufficient to satisfy the demand for credit, or, again, can always find among their members an outlet for all the funds at their disposal. They are thus constrained in the one case to borrow from outside, and in the other to lend their surplus funds where money is required. For these purposes a system of central banks has been evolved, whose business lies almost entirely • In 1904 popular savings deposited in cooperative banks were computed at no less than US millions sterling out ofa total of 961 millions. Wolff, "Cooperative Banking," p. 135. 8 AGRICULTURAL CREDIT BANKS. among cooperative banks. These are a very important feature of the cooperative banking system and will be considered further presently. The need for them, it may be noted, is more felt by Raiffeisen than by Schulze banks, because the former, drawing their deposits, as they do, very largely from a single class, and doing their loan business with the same class, are liable to greater fluctuations in the demand for credit than the latter, which deal with a variety of different industries and can thus hope to play off a boom in one against a slump in another. Loans are principally granted against the personal pledge of one or two friends of the applicant. The successful manipulation of this form of security is the greatest achievement, as it is the sine qua non of cooperative banking. It is only possible when the bank's operations extend over only a small area, where the character and business trans- actions of the parties concerned are common knowledge; and its suc- cess is greatly facilitated where the area in question is served by but one bank, .in which case the danger of "cross-firing" by mutual guarantee is easily avoided. In cases where this form of security is not available owing to the applicant being a newcomer in tbe district, or for any other sufficient reason, loans against negotiable securities or land mortgage may be resorted to. The Schulze banks also grant occasionally blank credits, where -the stability of the borrower is beyond question. The form of the loan is either the promissory note of the borrower or else simply a bond or undertaking to repay. The former plan is often preferred, as, in case of failure to repay, the legal process of recovery is simpler, while the note, being negotiable, can, if necessary, be rediscounted with the central bank. The Schulze banks also dis- count trade bills and grant cash credits on current account, but such forms of advance are of course little required in purely agricultural districts. The normal term for loans in the Schulze banks is three months; renewals being, however, frequently allowed. In the Raiffeisen banks, for reasons which have already been considered, the periods are much longer, the minimum being about a year, while loans for as long as 10 years are not unknown. An important feature of the Raiff- eisen system, however, is that loans can always be called at four weeks' notice, though this right is never enforced, except when repayment is seriously endangered by gross extravagance on the part of the bor- rower or misapplication of the money lent. Members of the Raiffeisen banks, when applying for loans, are always required to state the pur- pose for which the money is wanted, and if th$ application is granted, it is so on the distinct understanding that the money is used for the purpose stated and for no other. Loans are commonly repaid by installments, covering both principal and interest on a plan of amor- tization. 1 Central hanks. — The functions of central banks have already been touched upon. Their establishment was found necessary both for the Eurpose of balancing the resources of the banks of the system, at the ead of which they stand, lending to those which require money and borrowing from those which have it to spare, and also, as the business of the local banks developed, to act as clearing and collecting agents. iFay, op. cit., p. 48. AGBICULTUBAL OEEDIT BANKS. 9 Raiffeisen instituted the first central bank, 1 the Rheinische land- wirtschaf tliche Genossenschaf ts-bank, as a registered association with unlimited liability, like the individual societies, in 1872. This bank was, at the instigation of Schulze-Delitzsch, dissolved by the courts. Schulze opposed the foundation of central banks both generally on the f round that cooperative societies should be self-sufficient, autonomous odies, and in particular because it was undesirable that cooperative societies should themselves become members of other cooperative societies organized likewise on the basis of unlimited liability. Raiff- eisen, accordingly, in 1876, founded the Landwirtschaftliche Central- darlehenskasse fur Deutschland at Neuwied as a limited liability com- pany. His action was indorsed by the law of 1889, which specifically allowed cooperative associations to become members of similar societies provided the latter were organized on the basis of limited liability. In addition to the Centraldarlehenskasse and its branches, a number of provincial central bank's (Provinzialkassen) have since come into existence. The Centraldarlehenskasse does no other busi- ness beyond that with the local societies-, and its expenses are defrayed out of the margin between the 3J per cent charged for loans and the 3i per cent 3 allowed on deposits. In 1895 a State central bank, the Preussische Central Genos- senschaftskasse, was established for cooperative societies — produc- tive as well as credit societies — in the Kingdom of Prussia. Its [mrpose- was to become the head of the existing "thus far head- ess organization, for besides the Central Loan Bank there were a number of other central banks for different groups of Raiffeisen banks. 3 The Central Genossenschaftskasse does business not with individual societies, but only with Provinzialkassen. The Schulze-Delitzsch banks have never developed an elaborate centralizing organization such as that of the Raiffeisen system, but do business individually with the Dresdner Bank, which has absorbed their earlier central bank, the Deutsche Genossenschaftsbank. The relations of the individual societies to the Dresdner Bank, are, how- ever, far looser than those of the Raiffeisen societies to the Prussian Central Bank. The Dresdner Bank does not insist that societies should deal with it exclusively, though it prefers that they should. 4 The Prussian Bank, on the other hand, makes it a condition that banks dealing with it should deal with no other independent bank. An interesting feature of the higher organization of the Raiffeisen societies is the close connection between the banks and noncredit societies. The credit society is, in fact, used as the channel for the supply and sale of agricultural commodities, though in the case of larger districts, where business is on a sufficiently large scale, the departments are often kept separate. Cooperative dairies, however, and other productive societies are kept distinct. The great advan- tage of this interconnection of credit and noncredit cooperative associations is, of course, the economizing of expenditure. But where the two forms of activity can profitably be worked separately, this would seem the better course, on the general principle of "ne i Bulletin of the Bureau of Economic and Social Intelligence, July, 1911, Article on Central Banks. sWolfl," People's Banks," p. 143. „.*..„. u * . , .. u , .„. t, ■» ■ • The term "Raiffeisen banks" is used here, and Indeed throughout, to Include banks of the Raiffeisen type, such as the Haas banks, not actually adhering to the Raiffeisen organization. • U. S. Monetary Commission, Volume of Interviews. 10 AGBIOULTUBAL OEBDIT BANKS. sutor ultra crepidam," and also for the economic reason that while the operation of the banks must be confined to a single parish, that of supply, or sale societies, may more profitably embrace a larger area. Finally the questions arise: How far have the German credit banks succeeded? How far have- they justified the hopes of their founders that through them credit would become accessible to the poor man as to the millionaire ? In the first place, as regards mere material success, there can not be two opinions. Out of the few small banks which Raiffeisen and Schulze started midway through the nineteenth century, there has grown up a vast system of more than 15,000 separate offices of which over 13,000 are of the Raiffeisen type. The ordinary commercial standards of prosperity hardly apply, but as a whole the manage- ment has been efficient, and most of the banks are on a sound financial footing, while it is claimed that, there has not in either system been a single failure — a truly remarkable achievement in view of the diffi- culties which they have had to contend with. In the case of the Raiffeisen banks, however, it must be admitted that the policy of the management has not always been free from blemish, the mistakes which have occurred being chiefly due to. unwisdom of the very kind of which mention has just been made, namely, that of combining cooperative purchase with credit. The question as to how far the banks have succeeded in keeping themselves accessible to the poor man is more controversial. The Schulze banks have, in particular, been charged with falling away from the ideals of their founder in this respect. There would seem to be some justice in this accusation, for the banks have come to fill in some degree the place occupied in English provincial towns by the branches of joint stock banks. Perhaps, too, it would have been wiser had the banks passed a self-denying ordinance limiting divi- dends to, say, 5 per cent, though it can not be said that dividend hunting has been the practice, still less that it has been pursued at the expense, of reserve funds. The fact, however, remains that these banks lend at a rate nearly 1 per cent higher than that charged by the Raiffeisen banks. To the strong religious spirit with which Raiffeisen inspired his organization this tribute at least must be paid, that his societies have never turned to profit seeking at the expense of their poorer members, while the Haas societies, which seceded on the religious question, have in this respect remained faithful to the teaching of their founder. France. Unlike the agricultural credit-society system of Germany which, as we have seen, grew up gradually by natural evolution from small beginnings, to develop finally into a complex organism of societies, provincial unions, and central banks, the French Crfidit Agricole was the creation of a moment, issuing, Minerva-like, fully-equipped from the brain of the statesman. The Credit Agricole was not, indeed, by any means the first attempt which had been made in France to solve the problem of agricultural credit. Numerous schemes had been evolved, all to be overtaken by failure, except perhaps the least ambitious, that of M. Durand l i Wolfl, "People's Banks," p. 429, soq. AGBICGXTTTBAL CBEDIT BANKS. 11 •which therefore deserves passing notice. M. Durand's system of credit societies is a close imitation of the Raiffeisen system, and, like it, is permeated with religion. M. Durand is a pronounced Roman Catholic, and it is, according to Mr. Wolff, the well-known attitude of the State toward Romanism in France which has impeded the growth of the system. However that may be, it seems to have reached the limit of its expansion, though it has reached a position of not incon- siderable importance and continues to prosper. 1 The State-endowed Credit Agricole Mutuel was founded as recently as 1899, and while it is thus impossible to estimate its results with any finality, its unique constitution renders it of great importance to the student of agricultural credit. The groundwork of the system consists of a number of individual societies organized on the principle of Raiffeisenism. In the large majority of cases the liability of mem- bers is unlimited, though limited liability is allowed. Each member takes up one or more shares of 20 francs, on which only 5 francs need be paid up at the start. The sphere of operation of these societies or 'caisses locales" is a commune. Each society when it is founded makes over the whole of its capital to the central bank or "caisse r6gionale" of the department in which it is situated. These caisses r6gionales are, unlike the individual societies, actually established by the State. They are under the control of the Credit Agricole, which appoints officials to inspect them and to which they send their accounts and copies of the minutes of their boards. The funds for the financing of the scheme are largely supplied by the State, which, as a condition of the renewal of the charter of the Bancpie de France in 1897, enacted that the bank should lend, with- out interest, a sum of 40 millions of francs for the purposes of agri- culture, and should in addition furnish a further annual sum by way of tax for the same purpose. The amount of this latter contribution, which depends on the average bank rate for the year, amounts usually to about 5 millions of francs. These funds are dispensed through the channel of the regional banks. The latter, as we have seen, receive their capital from the local banks, and as soon as this is made over to them they are entitled to a loan free of interest from the State of four times the amount subscribed. From these funds the regional banks lend to the local offices at 3 per cent, and the local offices in their turn lend to their members at 3£ to 4 per cent. The process by which this is done is as follows: An application for a loan is considered in the first instance by the "conseil" or administrative committee of the local office, which is elected by the members. If ap- proved, the application is then submitted to the committee of the regional bank, which is elected by the representatives of the local banks in its district. If the latter finally pass the loan, the applicant draws a bill on himself for the amount sanctioned. This bill is then indorsed on behalf of the local office and discounted by the regional office. Should the latter, however, not have sufficient funds for the purpose, it may again indorse the bill, which will now have three names, and can therefore be rediscounted with the Bank of France. Thus the funds at the disposal of the regional office are not limited to the amount furnished by the Government. It should be noticed, however, that the process of discounting with the bank leaves no i Wolff (loo. cit.) gives the number of banks as about 800, with an average membership of about 40. 12 AGRICULTURAL CREDIT BANKS. margin of profit to the regional office. These bills usually run for three months, but may be renewed for further periods of three months, provided the total period of the loan does not exceed two years, and that one-half is paid off at the end of the first year. It will be apparent from this sketch of its machinery that the Credit Agricole is a highly centralized State-endowed institution, and, sldllfully though it has been managed, it does not escape from the defects natural to such a system.'. In its desire to force the pace the Government has been compelled to rely as little as possible on the inexperience of the farmers, and has therefore formulated stringent rules governing the granting of credit. Loans are granted solely for agricultural purposes, which are set forth in elaborate schedules, together with the amounts appropriate to each. Little encouragement is thus given to the members of the societies to appre- ciate the true value of money or to acquire experience in the manage- ment of the bank. Again the finance of the scheme leaves something to be desired. The caisses regionales" are intrusted not merely with a State contribution of four times the amount of their capital. They may increase their liabilities almost indefinitely by discounting with, the Bank of France. M. Decharme himself gives an instructive example of this l when he describes how, during a recent crisis in the wine-growing district of Montpellier, the regional bank, with a capital of a million francs, lent, in all, sixteen millions, being eleven millions over and above its own capital and the proportion lent by the State. M. Decharme quotes this incident with evident approval, but what- ever be the merits of the particular case, it is difficult to believe that such a policy might not lead to a dangerous collapse. It is true that the "conseil" of the regional office watches over the local banks, and that the regional office itself is subject to the supervision and inspection of the department, but it is doubtful whether such sur- veillance from a distance is as effective as the interested vigilance of the Aufsichtsrat of the Raiffeisen society. It would seem, however, that the authorities are not insensible to the dangers of State endowment, for the hope is expressed that the bank's loan of forty millions, though not the yearly contribu- tion, will ultimately be repaid. To do this a large increase in the deposits, which at present are small, is essential, and this in view of the well-known thrift of the peasantry should not be impossible, if the inveterate habit of hoarding can gradually be broken. In spite, however, of the defects of the system the results are not discouraging. There are now regional banks in every department, and the local offices number nearly 3,000^ with an average member- ship of between 40 and 50. The average credit per member per annum is about 500 francs, but the whole amount placed at the dis- posal of the Credit Agricole by the State has not been required, and it has been necessary to find other outlets for it. Other Countries. We have considered the German and French svstems in some detail — the former not only because it was the first" in the field and has reached a higher pitch of development than that of any other country, but also because every other system of agricultural banks i Loo. olt., p. 613. A.GBICULTTJBAL CBEDIT BANKS. 13 has been to a large extent consciously modeled upon it and derived from it, the latter because it is the example par excellence of a State- controlled system. Several other European countries, however, notably Italy, Belgium, and Austria-Hungary, are provided with more or less efficient, if as yet inadequate, systems of credit societies. These all follow the Raiffeisen type closely and can only be briefly alluded to here. The experience of Italy is interesting, because in no other country, probably, has Raiffeisenism had such overwhelming difficulties and obstacles to contend against. The poverty and ignorance of the 1>easantry were, and still are, almost incredible, while everywhere the and was in the grip of the usurer. In spite of this, however, the system has won its way with notable success. It was in 1883 that Wollemborg, the Raiffeisen of Italy, started the first "cassa rurale" with 32 members at Loreggia. Since then great progress has been made, and there were in 1908 at least 1,500 banks, 1 a large propor- tion of them of Catholic foundation, having loans outstanding of over a million and a half sterling, and deposits of no less than two mil- lions. Each member subscribes a share of one or two lire, and pays also a small entrance fee, this latter feature being a departure from strict Raiffeisenism. The total share capital amounted in 1908 to nearly £20,000 and the indivisible reserve funds to more than twice as much. In Belgium, too, Raiffeisenism has been finally adopted as the solu- tion of the agricultural credit question. An earlier attempt was made, somewhat after the fashion of the French Credit Agricole, to pump down credit by means of the Comptoirs Agricoles, which are agricultural commissions, acting as intermediaries between the National Savings Bank, which provides the funds, and the small farmer who is to be thus tempted to borrow. This institution, how- ever, has failed altogether to reach the small man, and its business now consists in providing mortgage credit for well-to-do landowners. The first Raiffeisen bank was founded in 1892 by the Abb6 Mel'laerts, and the system has rapidly spread since then. In 1908 there were 2 584 "caisses locales," mostly, as in Italy, of Catholic complexion, with an average membership of between 40 and 50. There are also seven "caisses centrales," or central banks, which perform the two functions of inspecting the local banks affiliated to them, and acting as agents between the latter and the Caisse generale d'Epargne, which lends to them on bills indorsed by the "caisse centrale." Only the largest of these central banks, the "Boerenbond," has become a Centralkasse, in the German sense, receiving deposits from, and making advances to, the local banks without the aid of the savings bank. It may be remarked that the State makes a grant of 100 francs to each bank, toward its foundation expenses, besides contributing annually 25 francs to pay for inspection and audit. We have now completed our brief survey of the systems of rural credit existing in the chief European countries. We find that in every case the basis of the system is the Raiffeisen credit society, but that the superstructure, the organization by which the individual societies are coordinated, differs considerably in the various instances, both in point of development and in the degree of control exercised by the State. i W olfl, "People's Banks," p. 331. * Ibid., p. 382. 14 agbicultubal cbedit banks. The Case of England. We come now to the case of England. In England there is as yet nothing which can be dignified with the name of a system of agricultural credit banks. The few societies," says Conrad, "exist really only on paper."* The same remark applies also to noncredit agricultural societies. The state of affairs is not that of Denmark, where cooperative societies for supply and for sale of produce abound, but banks are unknown. In England, the country of Robert Owen and Holyoake, the birthplace of urban cooperative societies, strange as it may seem, agricultural cooperation has hitherto been a, failure. We are thus faced with the question, Why is it that in England alone of the important countries of Europe rural cooperation has not succeeded ? The answer to this question will carry us some distance at least toward the solution of the further questions with which we are most concerned, namely: Do the conditions which have hitherto prevented the establishment of an agricultural credit system still prevail? And, if not, what kind of system is most suited to the present conditions ? The most important circumstance which has militated against the development of agricultural cooperation in England is the system of land tenure which prevailed throughout the nineteenth century. England is a country of large properties and of large holdings. During the first half of the last century, when corn growing was the most profitable form of agriculture in western Europe, large holdings were economically most suitable, and England was consequently looked upon as the model agricultural country. With the opening up of the trans-Atlantic markets, however, the competition of the United States, Canada, and the Argentine cut severely into the profits to be derived from the growing of cereal crops in Europe. Hence, in England large tracts of arable land were converted into pasture. The quantity of live stock and the output of dairy and market-garden produce has increased during the period, but even here in consequence of improved methods of transport and storage the effects of competi- tion are severely felt. The conversion of arable land is, in the opinion of competent authorities, not likely to go much further, owing to the curtailment of the proportion of gram available for export from North America; but it is becoming increasingly apparent that the English farmer "has his only assured market in products like milk and high-class fresh fruits and vegetables which must be supplied close to the place of consumption. a Now, it is in the producing of just this class of commodity that the small holding has economic advantages over the large holding. In the normal case the large farmer can produce more profitably than the small farmer for just the same reasons that the large manu- facturer can produce more profitably than the small manufacturer, namely, because he has a larger command of capital, because he can effect economies in working, and because he is in a better position for bargaining. But where the individual care of plants is such that it can not well be left to subordinates, or where the operations can not i Conrad, "HandwBrterbuoh dcr Staatswlssenschaften" sab. tit., Darlehnskassenvereine » "Quarterly Journal of Economics," May, 1010, article by C. E. Fay on "Small Holdings and Aerlcul. tural Cooperation In England." ^^ ~6'«"" AGRICTTLTUBAL CBEDIT BANKS. 15 be reduced to rule, the economic positions may be reversed. It is generally held by agricultural economists that this argument applies to the case in question. So cautious a thinker as Prof. Marshall, for instance, says: "Very small holdings have great advantages whenever so much care has to be given to individual plants that machinery is out of place ; and there is reason for hoping that they will continue to hold their own in raising vegetables, flowers, and fruit." 1 That this analysis of the economic forces is substantially correct is borne out by the fact that the large farms of 300 acres and over are giving place, particularly in the eastern counties, to a smaller type of from 50 to 300 acres, chiefly devoted to cattle raising and dairy farming, while the still smaller class" of 5 to 50 acres has at any rate ceased to diminish. Further, this change in the agricultural conditions has found expression in the increasing demand for small holdings, to which legislative effect has recently been given by the small holdings and allotments act of 1907. This act empowers the county councils to acquire, compulsorily if necessary, land suitable for small holdings (5 to 50 acres) and allotments (under 1 acre), which the applicants hold as tenants of the county council. It is impossible to say at present to what extent the act will be successful, but numerous applications have been approved and not inconsiderable areas acquired. Thus the case of England, as regards land tenure, stands in sharp contrast to that of the chief continental countries, where, in the face of adverse economic conditions, small proprietorship was kept alive by the legislature for social reasons, while with the opening up of the New World it has been favored by the circumstances we have just mentioned. It is obvious that in a country of large holdings cooperative credit banks are not likely to succeed. Well-to-do farmers have no need of special facilities for obtaining credit; they are strong enough to make use of the town banks, and, as experience has proved, they are averse to cooperative methods. 2 We have thus one very cogent reason why cooperation, so successful under continental conditions, has failed in the past in England. Our reasoning also gives us prima facie ground for supposing that with the changing conditions in the latter country the impediments to cooperation are passing away. An6ther point, however, remains for consideration. The. small tenant farmers of England are not in the same position as the small proprietors of the Continent. The former are normally without security of tenure. Their tenancy is liable to be ended at short notice. In many cases, no doubt, this possibility is remote, and a tenant may in practice have reasonable fixity of tenure together with, perhaps, actual advantages over the small proprietor. In other cases, however, the possibility is much less remote, and the effect of its existence is to deter tenants from spending that amount of labor and of capital, whether borrowed or otherwise, on their holdings which they would spend were the conditions of tenure otherwise. But here, again, the recent course of events has introduced changes. In the first Elace, tenants of the county councils under the small holdings act are kely to have considerable security of tenure, as the land they occupy has been acquired and must be used solely for the purpose of small l "Economics of Industry," Book VI, en. 10. » Sea Fay, "Cooperation," p. 206. 16 AGBICTJLTUBAL CEEDIT BANKS. holdings. Secondly, recent legislation has instituted compensation for improvements. A tenant who improves the value of his holding by his own care and at his own expense is no longer faced with the risk, perhaps varying in the direct ratio of his efficiency, of losing his holding and with it the capital sunk in it, or, in the alternative, of paying rent upon his own improvements. It would appear, therefore, that the agricultural conditions m England are becoming very much more suited to the growth of a system of cooperative banks than they were in the past. Indeed, it is urged with much plausibility that without cooperation, both for credit and other purposes, JJie small-holdings movement is doomed to failure; for it is only by noncredit cooperation that the small holder can profitably convey his produce to the markets and secure a fair price for it on its arrival, and it is only by cooperative credit. that he can find adequate capital to develop his land and can withhold his goods from the market during a period of temporary depression. It is very possible, however, that agricultural credit banks will not reach the pitch of importance which they have attained in Germany and elsewhere, and it is certain that their progress, if healthy, can only be slow. Experience has shown that the chief difficulty which those who have attempted to establish such banks have had to contend against is the suspicion with which they are regarded by those who have most to gain from them. The average farmer does not like his business dealings or his financial position to be known by his fellows, and the better class man has a rooted and very intelligible objection to borrowing. A writer with a wide experience of these matters writes of one particular attempt. "The usual difficulty is, however, encountered; the tenants dislike having to find sureties and the publicity involved in an application for a loan to a com- mittee." 1 Conrad goes so far as to suggest that the English charac- ter (Volkscharakter) is unfavorable. 2 This, however, is a dangerous line of argument. Little progress of any kind would be possible were natural conservatism always magnified into an insurmountable obstacle. Probably educational work would do much to smooth over these difficulties. There is no reason why the small farmer should not learn — as the small business man has long since learned — the difference between borrowing for productive purposes and borrow- ing for consumption. And as to the publicity involved it can only be urged that its unpleasantness, which should not be so very great in a properly conducted society, is far outweighed by the advantages of the system. Still, the difficulties must not be underrated, especially as in England to-day the driving force of necessity will render less aid than it did to Raiffeisenism in its early days. We come now to the practical question — granting the desirability of providing credit facilities for agriculture, what type of bank is best suited to English conditions ? _ A complete answer to this ques- tion is from the nature of the case impossible, for a social institution of organic character can only grow up gradually, advancing along tb,e line of least resistance. Little, therefore, can be said of the higher organization of the system, which should come into being, as in Germany, by a natural process of evolution as the need for it is felt, not, as in France, on a predetermined plan to which the societies ' Miss L. Jobb, " Small Holdings," p. 227. i Loe. eit, AGBICULTUBAL CEEDIT BANKS. 17 must learn to adapt themselves. Possibly a modus vivendi with, the joint stock banks may be established by which needless competition and duplication of machinery may be avoided to the mutual benefit of both parties. As regards the societies themselves, it would seem fairly plain that they must approximate closely to the Raiffeisen type. As we have seen, this type of society has been universally adopted on the Continent, and in every case it has succeeded, while attempts on different lines have always sooner or later met with failure. In fact, the experience of other countries has no alternative model to offer. The Schulze-Delitzsch type of bank, though many of its members are agriculturists, does not really meet the case. It is only suited to more or less populous urban districts and for success requires a strong industrial element among its members. Nor does it satisfy the needs of the really "small" man, with whom we are here most concerned, while in England it would stand no chance in face of the competition of the already established joint stock banks. The Raiffeisen system has this further advantage ' that it has in recent years been tried with success in Ireland, while in England too such banks as exist are based upon this model. The experience of Ireland is in some respects more valuable for England than that of continental countries, for in spite of differences of racial character and land tenure, the general conditions obtaining in the two countries are not dissimilar, while the legislation governing cooperative societies is identical. The Irish societies are organized closely on Raiffeisen lines. Applicants are admitted to membership if they are known to be sober, honest, and industrious. Poverty, Erovided it is not the result of the absence of these qualities, is no ar. The members are jointly and severally liable for all the debts of the society and liability continues for a year after cessation of membership in respect of debts incurred before that event. 1 Bor- rowers must be members of the society and must state the purpose for which the loan is required. The usual security required is the bond of two sureties guaranteeing the repayment of the loan with interest at maturity or immediately in the event of its misapplication. The funds of the societies are derived from three sources: Firstly, deposits of members and others which receive interest usually at 3 \ per cent; secondly, from joint-stock banks which have advanced money at 4 per cent irrespective of bank-rate fluctuations; thirdly, from the department of agriculture and the congested districts board. 2 In 1908 the sums received by the banks from these sources were £20,000 from depositors, £15,000 from joint-stock banks, £1,000 from the department, and £6,000 from the board. 3 The societies in that year numbered 268, with an aggregate membership of 17,400. The English societies were, at the end of 1910, 40 in number. They are nearly all affiliated to the Agricultural Organization Society, and the rules by which they are governed are much the same as those of the Irish societies. The Journal of the Board of Agriculture for December, 1911, gives figures relating to 31 of these societies. The aggregate membership of these was 663 in 1910, an average of 21 as compared with the Irish figure of 65 for 1908 and the German figure of "88 for 1905. The average amount of credit per member granted i Beport of select committee of H. L., 1910, p. 12. * Ibid., pp. 22, 27. » Debate In House of Commons, July 7, 1910, Speech of Mr. Hugh Barrie. H. Doc. 891, 62-2 2 18 AGBICULTTJKAL CREDIT BANKS. during the year was little more than £2, comparing with about £25 for the Raiffeisen banks in Germany. Two or three of the older socie- ties appear to be in a nourishing condition, and have accumulated considerable reserves, but in the large majority of cases the results are as yet very meager. It is, however, only fair to point out that all except 6 of the societies have been founded since 1904, while the three years 1908-1910 have seen the birth of 27 societies. On the other hand, the report referred to deals only with existing societies, and gives no indication of the number of those which have failed to survive their infancy. The funds of the societies are derived almost wholly from deposits of members and others and from advances by the joint-stock banks, the proportions for 1910 being £1,089 from depositors and £488 from the banks. In England no funds have as yet been received from Government sources, though to judge from a recent speech of Lord Carrington l large amounts are likely to be placed at the disposal of cooperative societies from the development fund. This policy is also foreshadowed by the agricultural credit and insurance societies bill introduced during the past session in the House of Lords, which provides that the board of agriculture may out of the small holdings account "make grants upon such terms as the board may determine toward the cost of formation of the society or the payment of the expenses of management of any recently formed society." 2 This proposal has been strongly opposed by Mr. Wolff and the other leaders of the movement, and, if a permanent subsidy is intended, it would seem, in accordance with the opinion already expressed in this essay; to merit their condemnation. The section of the agricultural credit societies bill just quoted, however, certainly implies that the grant is intended merely to encourage the formation of societies without holding before them the prospect of any further assistance when once they are in full working order. If this principle be rigidly adhered to, we may, perhaps, on the analogy of the "infant industry" argument, regard such aid as free from objection. Probably there would be less risk of abuses in this con- nection were the concluding words of the section omitted and the proposed: assistance granted only "toward the cost of formation of the society." As a further safeguard the grant might be withheld till the end of the first year's working of the society, being then allowed, conditionally upon efficient management and promise of success, as a contribution toward the extinction of the probable initial deficit. A more satisfactory feature of Lord Carrington's speech was his announcement that he had been assured by the representatives of the principal joint-stock banks that they would be prepared to lend money to the credit societies. It would undoubtedly be better from the point of view of the ultimate good of the societies themselves were they to supplement the deposits intrusted to them from this source rather than by means of State loans carrying a low rate of interest. No doubt the English banks would make the same con- cession as the Irish banks, of lending at a fixed rate independent of market fluctuations; and under the overdraft system the societies would be able to satisfy their requirements without keeping any con- siderable sum lying idle, which, of course, they could not afford to do. • At Crystal Palace, Oot. 18, 19U. « Sep. 2 (1). AGBICULTUBAL CREDIT BANKS. 19 It is. significant that in Ireland the board of agriculture has in several instances failed to secure the repayment of its advances, while no such difficulty has been experienced by the joint-stock banks. It is suggested that Irish agriculturists are disposed to regard a Govern- ment loan as a Government grant, and possibly this sentiment might be found not to be confined to Irishmen. Be that as it may, it can not be too strongly urged that it is only if they are regarded as busi- nesses and not as charitable institutions that cooperative credit banks can hope to achieve lasting success. Accordingly, let the Govern- ment promote their success as far as it can by the establishment of technical colleges, by the demonstration of scientific methods and model holdings, and by educational work in general, but as little as possible by the promise of financial support. As has already been pointed out, both the Irish and the English credit societies — excluding those which add to their main non- credit business that of granting credit to members — are organized in accordance with strict Raiffeisenism on the basis of unlimited liability. Raiffeisen laid great stress on this for two reasons — first, because the peasants with whom he had to deal were so poor that, they were unable to subscribe even small shares, and their liability to the extent of their property, representing in most cases little more than the "equity of redemption" of their heavily mort- gaged farms, was therefore the only asset on which to raise the necessary capital; and, secondly, because by this means he hoped to instill into them a fit sense of responsibility and caution. Undoubt- edly in the circumstances in which he found himself Raiffeisen was right. But it is by no means so certain that the English cooperators are right in following him in this respect. The German farmers, among whom Raiffeisen worked, were so deeply involved in debt already that they had no hesitation in pledging the little that was left to them in return for the chance of freeing themselves from the clutches of the money lender. The English farmer, on the other hand, is comparatively unversed in credit dealings, and for that reason the more afraid of unlimited liability. Evidence is not lacking to support the view that men who have kept free from debt are apt, however poor they are, to shrink from making themselves liable without limit, however dazzling the prospect of gain may be. For instance, in the case of the Italian and Belgian "banques popu- lates," which are banks of the Schulze-IJelitzsch type, the attempt to introduce unlimited liability proved a failure; 1 while in France, as we have mentioned, the caisses locales of the Credit Agricole may be of limited liability. Nor does the fact that the unlimited liability type of bank has succeeded in Ireland prove anything to the contrary, for there the usury of the "gombeen" man was widespread, and the conditions in that respect more akin to those with which Raiffeisen had to deal. It would therefore seem not improbable that a system of limited liability banks with partly paid-up shares would have the best chance of success in England. This arrangement would have the advantage of giving the bank a small capital to begin with, while there is no reason why the uncalled portion of the capital should not be sufficient security upon which to borrow. Indeed, there is an » Wolff, "People's Banks," pp. 258, 361. 20 AGRICULTURAL CREDIT BANKS. instance upon record in which, a large provincial bank offered to advance money to a cooperative society l on the condition that the latter should issue £1 shares with two shillings paid up, the number of shares taken up by each member to vary according to the acreage of his holding. If, then, the joint stock banks are content to follow this example and lend to this type of society, we may rightfully claim to have disposed of one of the two main arguments of the strict Kaiffeisenist in favor of unlimited liability, namely, that it is essential for the raising of funds. The other argument is that without unlimited liability the members of a society might become careless as to whom they elected as members or selected to serve on the committee or inspection council. 2 As against the system of limited liability with fully paid shares this argument is no doubt valid, but in view of the very considerable, though strictly limited, lia- bility to which every member Would be exposed under the system mentioned it will hardly apply to that case. It may be pointed out here that if, on experiment, this type of society proved more congenial to the English farmer, as we have suggested it may do, the need for legislation in the direction suggested by the committee of the House of Lords would no longer exist. A credit society which desires to combine the business of supply or sale with its banking business can not register itself as a "specially authorized society" under the friendly societies act, under which act all existing societies are registered. It may, however, register under the industrial and provident societies act, but in that case it must be a limited liability society. The committee came to the Conclusion that it was desirable that small societies should have this power of combining banking with trading, and in order to give effect to their decision were forced to recommend the amendment of the law in the direction either of granting trading powers to specially authorized societies under the friendly societies act, or of permitting unlimited liability societies to register under the industrial and provident societies act. They chose the former alternative, but the provisions of the agricultural credit societies bill indicate that the latter was preferred by the Government. It will be seen that there is nothing to prevent limited liability credit societies from carrying on a trading business at present, and were they to displace the unlimited liability societies the proposed amendment of the law would be unnecessary. Its adoption, however, would have the advantage of allowing the two types to exist side by side under the same act until the "fitter" of the two ousted the other by a process of natural selection. Within the limits of this essay it has been, of course, impossible to deal even cursorily with all the details connected with the organi- zation of a system of agricultural credit banks, which deserve dis- cussion. The question of the relative merits of the limited and the unlimited liability society has been treated at some length because it is not impossible that a modification of strict Raiffeisenism in this respect would be justified in England, though such modi- fication would in no way amount to the invention of a new sys- tem. One further point, however, seems to deserve passing mention i Soham Small Holders, Ltd., see "Quarterly Journal of Economics," Mav. 1910 loo clt * Eoport of select committee of H. L., p. 11. ' ' AGRICULTTJBAL CEEDIT BANKS. 21 because of its paramount importance. This is the question of the proper inspection and audit of accounts. It has been found difficult to impress upon the small agriculturist the neces- sity for the punctual and accurate keeping of accounts, particu- larly in the case of the smaller societies in which transactions are not of very frequent occurrence. A considerable number of the Irish societies were reported to the department of agriculture as unsatisfactory on this very ground. 1 The dangers of carelessness of this kind would be still greater in societies which combined a trading business with banking, and as it is only the smaller societies which are likely to carry on this combined business, it is evident that the need for proper inspection is very great. The Raiffeisen machinery for the performance of this office has already been described, but in IrelancLthe necessity for the committee of inspec- tion has not been duly appreciated, while the Raiffeisen system of a union of societies for mutual inspection has not been adopted. 2 The experience of Ireland, therefore, would tend to show that inde- pendent inspection by a Government official is the most satis- factory way of dealing with the question, at any rate until the societies are numerous enough and strong enough to combine for this purpose. Finally, we may sum up once again the chief reasons for regard- ing Raiffeisenism as the only possible solution of the problem of agricultural credit. The Raiffeisen system alone has been able to utilize satisfactorily the only security which the small agricul- turist has to offer, namely, his personal pledge to repay, supported by the guaranty of men of his own class and standing. It alone has been able to perform all that is demanded of an agricultural credit bank without subsidy from charity or the State; not, indeed, with- out the assistance of the man of education and the philanthropist, but at least without his financial assistance, which alone could deprive it of that spirit of robust independence in which lies half its value. And this it has done, not in one country alone, or even in Europe alone, but throughout the civilized world wherever it has been tried, with a success that is beyond question and has all but silenced criticism. In this essay we have been concerned only with Europe, but we may conclude with the advice of one 3 — a civil serv- ant of repute, be it noted, and no fanatic or blind reformer — who has spent years in establishing the same system among the ryots of India, "Find Raiffeisen! " i Report of Select Committee. > Ibid., p. 14. » F. A. Nicholson, "Report regarding the possibility of introducing land and agricultural banks into the Madras Presidency.': o