LOCAL FINANCE IN JAPAN IN RELATION TO IMPERIAL FINANCE BY BUNSHIRO ]p[ATTORI, Ph.D. The original of tliis bool< is in tlie Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924023533080 LOCAL FINANCE IN JAPAN IN RELATION TO IMPERIAL FINANCE BY BuNSHiRO Hattoei, Ph.D. Sometime University Fellow in Social Science in Princeton University. Prinoton Fxxss. A^ ^-ofco-ji CoPYKiGHT, igo6, BY BUNSHIRO HATTORI TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE. Introduction i CHAPTER I. Administrative Organization i Section I. The Central Government i Section II. The Local Government 3 (I). Prefectures 5 (II). Counties 9 (III). Cities, towns, and villages 11 CHAPTER 11. Local Finance 18 Section I. The revenue of local government 19 (I). The revenue of prefectures 19 A. The ordinary public revenue 19 1. The subsidy from the national treasury 19 2. Pref ectural taxes 19 a. The land tax 21 b. The house tax 22 c. The surtax on the national business tax. . . 23 d. The surtax on the income tax 24 e. The prefectural business tax 25 f . The miscellaneous taxes 26 g. The special apportioned tax on cities, towns, and villages 27 h. Labour and commodities : 27 3. Fees 28 4. Fines 28 5. The quasi-private revenue 29 B. Extraordinary revenue 30 (II). The revenue of counties 32 (III). The revenue of cities, towns, and villages 33 A. The ordinary public revenue 34 1. Subsidies and grants 34 2. The taxes of cities, towns, and villages 34 a. The surtax on the national land tax 35 b. The surtax on the national income tax 35 c. The surtax on the national business tax. . . 35 d. The surtax on the indirect national taxes. . 36 3 e. The surtax on the prefectural house tax. . . 36 f. The surtax on the prefectural business tax, 36 g. The special tax 36 (i) The Janbetsu wari 37 (2) The Buichi tax 37 (3) The surtax on the national and pre- fectural taxes 37 (4) The tax on Sake 38 h. Labour and commodities 38 3- Fees 39 4. Fines 39 5. The quasi-private income 39 a. The income from the productive capital. . . 39 b. Donations 41 6. Miscellaneous income 41 B. Extraordinary revenue 41 Section II. The expenditure of local government 45 (I). The expenditure of prefectures 45 (II). The expenditure of counties 47 (III). The expenditure of cities, towns, and villages 47 Section III. Budgetary legislation and administration of local government 48 (I). Prefectures 48 A. The budget 48 B. The legislative audit 50 (II). Cities, towns, and villages 50 A. The budget 50 B. The legislative audit 51 CHAPTER III. The Problems of Local Finance in Japan and their Discussion 52 Section I. The causes of the increase in expenditure 55 (I). The increase in public functions 55 (II). Self-government 56 (III). Influence of political parties 56 (IV) . Corruption 58 (V). Inefficient administration 58 (VI). IndustriaUsm 5g Section II. How the increased expenditure is met '. 60 Section III. Reform of local finance 60 (I). Expenditure for prisons 61 (II) . Expenditure for education 63 (III). The relief fund 65 4 (IV). Expenditure for the construction of dykes and har- bours 67 (V). The land tax 69 (VI). The special tax 73 (VII). Public property (domains) 74 (VIII). The ownership of natural Monopolies ^^ (IX). Public debts (local governments) 78 (X). The abolition of counties 81 (XI). The combination of rural communities 82 (XII). Strict administrative supervision from above 83 CHAPTER IV. Conclusion 84 Appendix 86 Bibliography 89 PREFACE This monograph has been prepared in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Prince- ton University. It might seem that the study of local finance is not so important as that of national finance, and that the special difficulties involved might render its investigation un- fruitful. For the common welfare of the people, however, the study of local finance is more important than might at first sight appear, especially when the magnitude of local ex- penditure and revenue in the aggregate is considered, and when the indirect effects of local finance upon the economic and social life of the people are taken into consideration. This is especially true of Japan, where public finance so greatly affects private finance. This monograph is far from exhaustive, for I could not wholly escape from the difficulties connected with the gathering of satisfactory statistical material, which in the case of local finance is often meagre. I shall be content, how- ever, if I have shed any light upon the essentials of the matter. I am bound to record my obligations to the many persons who have cordially assisted me with material, information, and criticism ; especially are my thanks due to Professor Winthrop M. Daniels, under whose untiring encouragement and guid- ance the thesis was undertaken and completed. I have also to acknowledge my particular obligation to Mr. K. Nakajima, my former classmate in Waseda University in Tokio, for furnishing me with materials. BUNSHIRO HaTTORI. Princeton^ N. J., March 5, igo6. LOCAL FINANCE IN JAPAN IN RELATION TO IMPERIAL FINANCE. Introduction. Since the Meiji restoration in 1867, Japan has progressed wonderfully along all lines of civilized life. It will be needless to say that financiering both public and private has had a most important bearing on this progress. In the following chapters I propose to study, though it may be imperfectly, one of the branches of Japanese public finance — ^local finance — ^in relation to central finance. Being far away from my fatherland, I found it naturally very hard to get sufficient information and to collect materials, which are specially scarce and incomplete, for local finance. It seems to me, however, that the study of local finance is of prime importance, and it is very desirable to put it on a sound basis, for the tendency ^ of all modern countries is to increase the expenditure of local governments. This may, unless carefully administered, lead to financial trouble. This study in Japan has not received much attention from scholars or men of affairs until recently. This paper may be the first of the sort. CHAPTER I. Administrative Organization. Section I. The Central Government. It is difficult, though it may not be impossible, to understand any financial system, its organization, and its activity, without knowing the administrative organization which is different in each different country, and on which the financial conditions ' Leroy-Beaulieu, Science des Finance, Vol. I., p. 746. largely depend.^ It is necessary, therefore, to give the outlines of administrative organization to begin with, in order to facili- tate the understanding of the subject. But this paper being limited to the study of finance can not be enlarged more than to give the necessary outlines. Japan is a monarchy. The sovereignty rests entirely with the Emperor.' If it be looked on from the point of view as to how this sovereignty is used, that is, from the point of view of the form of government, Japan has constitutional government.* The three domains of the legislative, the judicial, and the ex- ecutive have their limited functions, and are each carried on through different organs of the state. If the government, for instance, wants to impose taxes on people, it can not determine them itself as it pleases. According to the Constitution, the bill must be first passed by the Imperial Diet, and get the Im- perial sanction; and when, after laws are carried into eflfect, the people think that officials have misunderstood or misapplied tax laws, they can appeal to the administrative courts, and the wrong will be remedied. Under the Emperor, who holds the sovereign power, there are the different state organs, such as the Cabinet, composed of a Prime Minister and nine Ministers of State, who are at the same time in charge of administrative departments; the Privy Council, other high advisory bodies to the Emperor, the Imperial Diet and the courts. These are the organs through which the sovereign power is exercised, none of them having absolute, independent, and in- herent power. They are independent only in the sense that they can act freely by the right given them by the constitution, which guarantees them not to be interfered with by any other organ of the state. It is a peculiar characteristic in the Japa- ' Adams's Public Debts, p. 375 and Seligman, Am. Statistical Associa- tion, Vol. I., p. 350, concerning the relation of law to taxes. ' The constitutional law of Japan, Article I. *Hozumi, Imperial Constitution, p. 18. nese constitution that the Imperial Diet has no share of sov- ereignty." The Central government stands first in the order of the ex- ecutive departments. The Minister of State is at the same time the head of the Department of State. Among nine departments of state, the Home and Finance Departments have chief rela- tion to this paper. Section II. The Local Government. In very ancient times, Japan was divided into twelve parts, each of which included several provinces which in turn em- braced several counties. This is the beginning at least of the local administrative system more than twenty-five hundred years ago. History tells us that the first emperor Zimmu had appointed his meritorious vassals the governors of the prov- inces.® At the time of the emperor Saga,^ the provinces were sixty-eight in number. The-local officials who were appointed by the central government were governors changing every four years, and sheriffs holding the office by heredity. The num- ber of counties depended on the number of houses, so many houses being in each county. Consequently where population was dense there the counties were more numerous and covered smaller areas than in other places. In the Kamakura era,' the country was divided into many districts which were governed by the feudal system. Since then until the Meiji restoration, local communities were gov- erned on the military basis and by the feudal system more or less combined. In the rural communities, in ancient times, there was no self- governing system at all. We can find, in the thirteenth century. " Hozumi, Imperial Constitution, p. 87. ' Ogino, History of Japan, and The History of the Empire of Japan, by Japanese commissioners to the Chicago Fair. Zimmu was the first Emperor, B. C. seventh century. ' Ninth century. 'Thirteenth century. some trace of it, but to a very limited extent. Before the resto- ration, under the Tokugawa Shogunate government, cities and counties were regulated fairly well, enjoying to some extent self-government. Cities and counties had their chief magis- trates. The chief magistrate of Tokio was appointed by the Shogunate and had the right of administration all over Tokio and also judicial power." Several officials under him were elected from among the people. All business of each street was administered by landholders who collected taxes. Villages were governed by the president of the village who held the office usually by heredity, or sometimes by rotation, or by pub- lic election. Representatives of the farmers had also shared the adipinistration. On the whole the system was based on self-government by city people and by farmers in each case." After the restoration, the government adopted a centralizing system, and divided the provinces into two kinds of districts — large and small. The latter is a combination of from five to ten villages and the former compromises several small districts. Soon after that, the system of one chief magistrate for one village was introduced. After many changes and reforms, the first pref ectural organi- zation and the city, town, and village organization were estab- lished in 1878 and 1880 respectively. The pref ectural law simply regulated how to arrange the budget of expenditure to be paid out of local taxes, and also their collection. The pre- sent city, town, and village Civic Corporation Acts date from 1888 and the prefectural and county laws from 1899. These laws were the long-desired idea of the Constitutional party, and were introduced oftentimes in the House of Representatives, and were finally passed in the thirteenth session of the Diet (1898). They made many improvements in the local regulations. " Shimada, The Outline of Self-government, p. 49. "This explanation is based on the system adopted in the direct domain of the Shogunate; the domain of the feudal lords follows the example generally. The payment of certain direct national taxes was made the principal condition of the electoral franchise. The boundaries of the present rural communities were mostly established artificially as the consequence of laws paying little attention to different local circumstances.^^ All local governments in Japan have two aspects; in one aspect they are the administrative agents of state, and in the other they are self-governing bodies. All enjoy the rights of juristic persons. There are three classes: Fu and Ken (Pre- fecture), Gun (county), and Shi, Cho, Son (city, town, and village) . The extent and limit of the power of self-government of each class are defined in detail in legal regulation. Fu and Ken are the same, and the difference is in name only, except that Fu includes each of the three largest cities. There are in Japan three Fu; namely, Tokio, Kioto, and Osaka. The coun- ties are much the same in nature as the prefecture, being more an administrative area, like prefectures, than self-governing bodies. The last class relating to municipal and rural com- munities represents the self-governing organism in its most striking form. I will review, first, prefectures, next counties. Counties being very much the same as prefectures, I need not go further than to describe the difference. .As to cities, towns and vil- lages, they all have the most characteristic points of civic cor- porations, and are the lowest administrative divisions. The cities have special concern with the modern problems of the municipality. These I will take up last. (I). Prefectures. Prefectures includes counties, cities, and islands. Those who live in a definite place in a prefecture with the intention of residing there are called citizens. Citizens in city, town, or vilage are at the same time citizens of the prefecture ; " Shimada, The Outline of Self-government, p. SO-i. for. the latter includes the former. This will be made clear when we come to the regulations concerning the citizens of the village. The Prefectural Assembly is a representative body elected by the people, the number of representatives being thirty where the prefecture has less than 70x5,000 population. Where the population is from 700,000, to 1,000,000, one member is added for every 50,000 in excess of 700,000; and where over 1,000,000 one member for every additional 70,000. The franchise is limited, and direct. Only those citizens can vote who pay more than three yen" a year in direct national taxes.^^ Only those can be elected who pay more than ten yen. Officials, civil or police magistrates, priests, and teachers of elementary schools may not be elected. The Prefectural Assembly sits once a year for thirty days, but, when it is necessary, it can have an extra session, the term of which is limited to seven days. The prin- cipal work of the Assembly is to deliberate and vote the budget of the prefecture. It has no right to assemble itself, being always summoned by the Governor. It only declares its will, and has no right to execute its en- actments. Even its legislative power is not unlimited as will be shown below. It may legislate as follows : ( i ) to determine the prefectural expenditure and revenue, to impose taxes, to dispose of public properties,, to incur financial responsibility or to waive claims to prefectural property, although these are matters lying outside the budget, to determine the way to ad- minister the public property and public establishments,^* to elect its own committees, to determine the number of members of the Assembly to be elected by the election districts, and to fix the necessary amounts to be paid to men holding official positions; (2) to sanction the financial report of the year be- " Yen = so cents in American money. "The three taxes of land, income, and business are called by that name. "The distinction between the property and establishment will be treated under the head of property. fore; (3) to elect its president, vice-president, and the lay inembers of the Prefectural Council — a standing committee, which will be explained just below; (4) to present its opinion concerning prefectural administration to the Governor or the Home Minister, and (5) to arrange the business of the Assem- bly itself." Next comes the Prefectural Council, which is composed of the Governor, two high officials, and six (in the case of Ken) or eight (in the case of Fu) honorary councillors elected by the Prefectural Assembly from its members for the term of four years. The Council stands in contrast to the City Coun- cils which are executive bodies. It is not an executive body, but auxiliary to the Assembly, and simply makes decisions on administrative matters when the Assembly can not be called together with convenience, or the decision be delayed. Its functions are : ( i ) to decide administrative matters which pri- marily belong to the Assembly, but are entrusted by the latter to the Council, or brought before the Council by the require- ment of speedy decision before the Assembly meets, to decide on administrative details of public properties and public estab- . lishments, to decide on regulations to carry on the public works to be paid for out of prefectural revenue, and to decide on judicial matters concerning the prefecture; (2) to present its opinion about prefectural administration to the Governor and the other administrative offices ; (3) to examine the actual out- lay and income of the prefecture; (4) to render decisions on appeals and petitions brought by the people aggrieved, and (5) to superintend the administration of counties, cities, towns, and villages." The Governor of the prefecture is an official of state and at the same time the head of the executive office of the prefecture. He has the right : ( i ) to govern the prefecture and represent it; (2) to formulate bills to be introduced in the Prefectural Assembly and Council; (3) to summon, open, close, and ad- " Prefectural law, articles 41, 44, 47, 64. " Prefectural law, articles 68, 69. journ the Assembly; (4) to veto the decisions or choice of officers by the Assembly and the Council, when they violate laws, or go beyond what they have a right to do; (5) when he thinks the decision contrary to public interests, or the decision of financial matters is improper, he can send the measures back again to them for further consideration, or stop said measures from going into effect; (6) when, under certain circumstances, the Assembly or Council does not give the decision, he can appeal to the Minister of the Home department, and ask of him direction; (7) when the business legally belonging to the Council should be disposed of without delay, he can give a de- cision and dispose of it himself; (8) when entrusted by the Council with any business legally belonging to the Council, he may dispose of it himself; (9) if there is any public affair to be disposed of in a hurry while the Assembly or Council does not exist legally, he can also dispose of it himself; (10) to look after the pref ectural officials ; (11) to guide and direct commit- tees, and (12) to make rules to manage the pref ectural busi- ness.^' Though the nature of the business of a self-governing body is the same as that of state, the extent of it is determined and limited by the state, and it can not go further than that. Local self-governing bodies are always concerned chiefly with finance," and have nothing to do with foreign, military, naval, and legislative affairs of the state. There are two kinds of public affairs respectively called " original " and " delegated," which give rise to much discus- sion and explanation. The former is the public business orig- inally entrusted by the state to local government at the time when each class of local self-government was established and incorporated. The latter comprises additional functions en- trusted at later times by the state to various local govern- ments.^* " Prefectural law, articles 78, 81, 82, 83, 84, 85, 86, 87. ''Bastable, Public Finance, p. 126. Nitti, Principes de Science des Finances, p. 704. "Minobe, Prefectural and County law, p. 253. The prefectures sometimes go beyond the limit of their sphere and want to do what they have no right to do, or do not do what they ought to do, so it is necessary that the higher administrative office, central in this case, shall superintend them. This is called the right of supervision, and is used more ex- tensively in the case of prefectures than in the case of any other grade of local government ; for the welfare of the state is most closely related with the prefecture! administration. This is the distinguishing mark between the sovereign state and the subordinate self-governing bodies, for at no time does the sov- ereign state receive supervision from outside. The Ministers of the Home and Finance departments have this right of super- vision and also the Emperor exercises a similar power of super- vision. The ministers can by virtue of the right of supervision force prefectural officials to make reports about administrative business, or to send to them necessary documents. They can examine the management of business and financial transactions, issue the necessary orders to superintend them and give de- cisions. They can also annul the decision of Prefectural As- semblies or Councils, when it goes beyond their rights, or violates other regulations, or they may determine themselves certain administrative business for prefectures, give permission for the exercise of certain administrative powers, interfere with the organization of prefectural administrative organs and dis- solve the Assemblies.^" Beside this, the administrative courts may take cognizance of prefectural matters involving questions of the interpretation of law. (II). Counties. Counties, like prefectures, are self-governing bodies and at the same time administrative divisions of the state. They stand between the prefecture on one hand and town and village on the other. They first became self-governing bodies, when the County law was established; while before that time pre- fectures and rural communities only were juristic persons. ' Prefectural law, articles 127, 129, 130, 131, 133, 134. counties having remained simply as administrative divisions. In 1890, the county law was first formulated and recognized counties as juristic persons giving them the right of self-gov- ernment, though it was of a very limited nature. Since then, there have been proposals to reconvert them into simple ad- ministrative divisions, depriving them of self-government, but the new law of 1900 not only did not change this, but estab- lished it more securely.^^ The system of local self-government depends largely on the history of each country. Some countries have four classes of local administration, only two exercising self-government, e. g., France and Italy f"^ while other countries have three classes of local administration and have two classes of self- governing bodies, e. g., Switzerland.^^ In Japan all three local administrative divisions are self-governing bodies, and the reason is that there are many public affairs which can not be managed advantageously by prefectures. These prefectures cover too large areas to have proper concern for the common interests of all the people; and the government by individual towns or villages is too narrow to have proper concern for what involves several towns or villages. For such cases, the inter- mediate class of local government is necessary between the pre- fecture and the rural community. Cities have direct relation with prefectures. Counties have nothing to do with cities, so there is here only a two-class system. The County Assembly has exactly the same position as the Prefectural Assembly. Before the new law was formulated, it was organized by members who partly were indirectly elected by Town or Village Assemblies, and partly by those who were directly elected by large land-holders, who had thus a direct influence over elections, simply because they were owners of ""Minobe, Prefectural and County law, p. 330. "" Lowell, Governments and Parties in Continental Europe, Vol. I., p. 36-40, 168. ''Lowell, Vol. II., p. 236. Bastable, p. 115 and Nitti, p. 706-10. Minobe, Prefectural and County law, p. 330. a large area of lands. It is now changed, and the members of the Assembly are elected by the direct vote of the people and the land-holders have no more right than others.^* It seems to me that the new law properly abrogated this privilege of the land-owners which was borrowed from the constitution of" Prussia. Japan has had a different social development and has no need to imitate this plan which simply gave power to an oligarchy. The election district is the rural community. The members of the Assembly usually number from fifteen to thirty. They can be increased until they reach forty. The electoral fran- chise is limited to the people who pay more than three yen in national direct taxes, five yen being the amount which is re- quired for those who are eligible. The County Council is composed of the Sheriff and five lay members. Other regulations are the same as in the case of the Prefectural Council with certain necessary changes. The Sheriff stands also in the county in the same position as the Governor in the Prefecture. He is one of the administra- tive officials of the state as well as the chief executive of the county. First the Governor, and secondly the Minister of the Home department have the right of supervision. ( III ) . Cities, Towns and Villages. If any society advance in civilization, the division of labour necessarily goes on to minute details. City and country life naturally show a great differentiation, and we see in contrast the busy life of cities where every kind of good is exchanged and transported ; while on the other hand we have the tranquil life of the country with the farm houses scattered around. These two different ways of living are nevertheless indispen- sable to modern life. It seems to me that it is quite foolish to disregard one for the sake of the other; for their respective interests are both of sufficient importance to be encouraged. "County law, article VI. 12 City and country have their peculiar characteristics, and ought to be governed by somewhat diflferent rules. But the fact that city, town, and village are all in the lowest adminis- trative class of communities has given rise to regulations almost the same for the government of them all. I will take up the three together and give special notice whenever I come to the different rules for the cities. These three are the lowest classes of local self-governments, and have the corporate character in its fullest extent. By cor- porate character or juristic personality, I understand the power of compelling people to obey its ordinances, and the capacity of bringing suits under the administrative law. It can also dis- pose of its business as it jileases within the limits of law and Imperial ordinance; and makes regulations in order to exer- cise its right of decree over the people. The basis of the lowest self-governing bodies are land and people. As already remarked, these communities represent, in the most striking form, the self-governing mechanism. They will be presented more carefully than others. People of these communities are divided into two classes: those who do not have the electoral franchise and those who have and who participate in the political affairs of the commu- nity. The former comprises the people who are simply resi- dents, while the latter, the voter, must meet the conditions following: (a) he must be a citizen of the Empire; (b) must have attained his majority; (c) must have lived for more than two years in the same community and bear a share of the tax burden; (d) he must have paid the land tax or other direct taxes more than two years; (e) he must ndt have received, for more than two years, any relief from the public funds. Naturally those who have been elected mayor, or chief officials of the town or village, or assistants to the chief officials, or treasurers, come to belong to the latter class during their ten- ure of office, even though they originally belonged to the former.^" "■ Civic corporation law, article 56. '3 It would not be out of place to notice here a difference of administrative organization betvveen cities on the one hand and towns and villages on the other. Any community which has more than 20,000 population can be incorporated as a city. Cities are entirely independent of the county. The election of members of the City Assembly is effected by the three-class system^* of voters, each class paying one-third of the city taxes, while that of the town and village is effected by two classes of voters similarly divided. The executive organs of the cities are boards, while the executive organ of the town and village is a single official. City Assemblies nomi- nate three candidates for mayor and the Emperor designates one of the three to the office. When cities, towns, and villages covering a large area and having a large population find it inconvenient to manage their business, they can divide themselves into more narrow districts and elect their chief officials. If they have their own proper- ties, they can have their special administrative organs enjoying, to a certain limited extent, the right of self-government. We call them self-governing districts within the city, town, or vil- lage as the case may be. They are not, ih principle, indepen- dent corporations, but belong to one of the three larger com- munities. If, on the other hand, towns or villages can not alone afford to bear the expense of certain public affairs, or if there is any necessity for joint action to secure the public wel- fare, they are allowed, or sometimes compelled to join with other towns or villages to manage all their common affairs, or some definite parts thereof such as schools, drainage, or some other public works.^' Tokio, Kioto, and Osaka were, for political reasons, once governed by special regulations different from other cities, like Paris in France and London in England. The system has been abolished now. "Loiyell, Vol, I., p. 304. " Civic corporation law, article 116. 14 The Assembly of cities, towns, and villages is the most im- portant organ of these self-governing bodies. The number of its members is from thirty to sixty in the case of cities ; from eight to thirty in the case of towns and villages ; in the case of small villages sometimes the mass meeting of the people is recognized.^' Only those who have the electoral franchise are eligible to the Assembly. Some administrative officials, public, procurators, police magistrates, priests, and teachers of ele- mentary schools are not eligible. The term of office is six years, and half of them elected anew every three years. The Assemblies simply deliberate and decide upon their pub- lic affairs, but they have no legal right to represent their com- munities in communications to the Imperial government and others, or even to execute what they decide upon. Business which ought to be disposed of by them is as follows : first, to decide on all communal affairs according to the Civic Corpora- tion Acts. These acts provide a wide sphere of activity and within limits complete self-government. Their proper business is second, to exercise those powers delegated to communities before the Civic Corporation Acts were formulated; third, to exercise those powers to be delegated later on by laws, or Im- perial ordinances; fourth, the election of officials of communi- ties ; fifth, the supervision of administration ; sixth, to give their opinions when consulted by other public officers; seventh, to give the decision upon petitions. Besides these items mentioned above, they can make for themselves their own rules of pro- cedure, and examine the credentials of their members.^* The executive department of cities is an organized body of councillors, but that of towns or villages is only one chief official. It might be said that, from its purpose, the executive department of towns or villages should be also a deliberative body. It might be argued that there is no reason why cities " See Bryce.The American Commonwealth, Vol. I., p. 6li, concern- ing the town meeting of the people in New England. "City law. Chap. II., Sect. II., Town and village law. Chap. II., Sect. II. IS should have a different system; for all are the lowest form of local community. There are, however, practical reasons for this ; towns and villages do not generally have so complicated an administration as cities, and can not usually get enough men of administrative ability to perform public services without pay. City Councils and the chief officials of towns and villages are not primarily administrative agents of the state, but only of the local communities. Cities, towns, and villages elect these coun- cillors and officials themselves in spite of the fact that they are at the same time administrative divisions of the nation and manage the public business of the state. The state has, there- fore, the right of supervision over these officials to watch its own interests. The City Council is composed of the mayor, assistant mayors, and associate councillors usually six in number. The chief officials and assistants of towns and villages are elected by their Assemblies. These executive officers are in charge of the administrative affairs of the self-governing bodies and are in charge of the general state administration also. I will treat first of the former class, i. e., of the affairs of the local govern- ments. It is very hard to define its extent ; because these local councils and officials represent the communities and perform the general administrative business of the communities. The Civic Corporation Act simply defines their powers in general terms, the principal items of which are as follows : (a) To prepare measures to be discussed in the Assemblies and to execute what the Assemblies decide upon. They, i. e., the local officials and councils, are not compelled to give effect to whatever measure the Assemblies decide upon. If the As- semblies decide on anything which does not properly belong to them, or violate laws, or go contrary to the public welfare, the officials and councils can send the decision back to the Assem- bly for further consideration giving the reason therefor. (b) The administration of public property. (c) The supervision over income and outlay. (d) Protection of the rights of communities, for instance, to bring suits before the courts. (e) The administration of the tax system. (f) The supervision and discipline of officials and em- ployees.'" The Mayor is the president of the Gty Council and represents it. The general administration is delegated by laws, imperial ordinances, and orders of high officials to these local officials and councils. In practice, however, the most of it is delegated to the mayors and chief officials. It should be noticed here that in cities, the executive is the Council, though we must be care- ful to distinguish whether administration is delegated to the mayor or Council. The general administrative business is : (a) the judicial police power (Imperial), and the local administra- tive police power, (b) the sea-coast office business which takes .care of shipwrecks, (c) the administration of general home affairs, so far as they are carried on in that administrative division, such as the census, education, industry and sanitation which primarily ought to be dealt with by the Imperial and higher local governments. Theoretically, the police power be- longs entirely to the Imperial government; and local self-gov- erning bodies exercise police powers, not of their own right, but simply because it is delegated by laws passed by the Diet and by Imperial ordinances.'^. Treasurers, clerks, employees, and permanent and temporary commissions are also employed in local governments. They have various commissions for the purpose that people may ac- quire the ability of self-government. Some might say perhaps that they might learn this in Assemblies and Councils in which they are directly concerned. Yet the number of positions is limited. The system is to give a fairly good chance to the people at large to learn the art of self-government gratui- tously.. There are two kinds of officials : those who receive salaries and those who do not. Those who perform their services gratuitously are called honorary officials. Though in principle " City law, article 64, 65. Town and village law, article 68. "City law, 74. Town and village law, 69. '7 the lowest local self-governments are to be carried on by the honorary officials, their actual necessary expenses incurred in doing the public business are paid, and sometimes they receive extra pay. The responsibility for the performance of duty is the same in the case of both kinds of officials with slight nat- ural differences. The supervision over the local administration is exercised by the higher administrative offices. The Governor and the Min- ister of the Home department have the right over cities ; and the Sheriff, Governors, and the Minister of the Home department over towns and villages. But in special cases, such as the dis- cipline of officials, the City Councils and Governors have the right of superintendence ; and Sheriffs and Governors over the chief officials of towns and villages. Only the Minister of the Home department can dissolve their Assemblies. County and Prefectural Councils, and administrative courts have also a right of supervision in some specific cases. In Hokkukaido, and Okinawa, the system of self-government is somewhat different, but the difference is not worth, special notice here. Modern public affairs are so wonderfully wide and complex that the state can not rely on itself to do all business, and thus delegates some of it which is not directly concerned with the national welfare to the local self-governing bodies. And yet, not satisfied to entrust them with full power, it establishes other special administrative organs or boards for special purposes. These organs or boards enjoying the right of control over cer- tain limited public affairs, and enjoying the rights of juristic persons are called public corporations in the administrative law. They are, in this respect, the same as the local self-governing bodies, but differ from the latter in being charged with limited functions rather than having a certain fixed territorial jurisdic- tion. Membership in such boards is limited to the organiza- tions from which they are drawn. Though in Japan at the present time the system has not yet been developed fully, and though sometimes these boards are simply recognized as ad- l8 visory bodies, the plan was devised in feudal times, and has an interesting history. Service on some of the boards is conipulsory ; such as the cor- poration for protection against flood; service sometimes is- optional, such as the corporation for common drainage or the chamber of commerce. They are given as examples existing at the present time, and deal with the business indicated by their names. They are in some respects auxiliary organs to the local governments. CHAPTER II. Local Finance. It cannot be denied that the most striking financial tendency of our day is that public affairs become more and more compli- cated and increase the amount of revenue and expenditure required. The natioiial government can not undertake tck manage all local affairs itself, and leaves some of them which, are not directly concerned with national affairs to local deter- mination. Local governments should pay the expenses for all works they have to carry on. Thus finance becomes a most important part of self-government ; its success depends largely on the financial management. Before taking up the problems and discussions about local finance, it seems to me the natural process that the regulations- concerning public properties, revenues, and expenditures of local governing bodies should be first presented. We should first see how they are defined and carried on in practice. In the preceding chapters I described the functions of local governments. They must pay all necessary local expenses, and for this purpose must have their own properties and get the additional revenue they need by means of taxation. 19 Section I. The Revenue of Local Governments. (I). The Revenue of Prefectures. A. The Ordinary Public Revenue. I. The Subsidy from the National Treasury. Theoretically it is supposed that the prefectures shall pay all necessary expenditures out of their own revenues, but, if this principle be strictly followed, the state finds itself sometimes handicapped owing to the disability on the part of prefectures to deal with public affairs properly on account of the lack of money.^ The prefectures are an integral part of the nation, and have closer relation to the welfare of the whole country than any other class of local governments. The state, there- fore, in the case of necessity grants to them for the promotion of public interests a subsidy, and lets them expend it for what is needed. The subsidy may be given as a certain percentage of the amount they spend, or in lump sums. In 1902 it reached 3,553,566 yen. It was given mostly for public works. 2. Prefectural Taxes. The relation of prefectural taxes to prefectures is quite dif- ferent from the relation of city, town, and village taxes to their respective communities. These latter local self-governing bodies have to accumulate capital, the interest of which is sup- posed to be used first to pay their current expenditures; and only when the interest is not enough to defray current expenses do they collect taxes. The prefectures, on the contrary, are not required to accumulate capital. AH their necessary ex- penditures are supposed to be paid first out of the taxes which occupy the most important place among their receipts. In 1902, the prefectural taxes yielded 46,596,332 yen, while other revenues, exclusive of debts contracted, amounted to 8,390,338 yen. ' Nitti, p. 716. The prefectures being divided simply by imaginary lines, there arise complicated inter-prefectural relations about the collection of taxes. A railroad may traverse two prefectures and be taxed by both, for emample. By tax-payer is meant here not the man who pays the taxes ultimately after the shifting of taxation, but the man who is responsible for taxes to the public office. The tax-payer may be an individual, or private corporation, and is liable to pay taxes under the following conditions : first, if he has his domi- cile in the prefecture with the intention to stay there perma- nently, or if he has remained more than three months in any part of it. Or, secondly, if he owns or uses lands or buildings or other properties in the prefecture ; or has a place of business in a definite place therein, or carries on certain specific kinds of business in any part of it. This does not mean that all peo- ple are liable who do meet these conditions, but rather that pre- fectures can not impose taxes on any person who does not fall in any of these classes. We see, however, that this includes every possible case which they can avail themselves of in levy- ing taxes. For example, the man who does not live in the prefectures, but only holds some property there must pay taxes. On the other hand, any prefecture can not tax the income derived from lands, buildings and other properties owned by its own people, but situated in another prefecture. So, also, the income of its people derived from the business which has its office in another prefecture can not be taxed. If any prefecture wants to tax the income of people who live and stay in more than one prefecture, it can not collect the tax from the entire income, but only from a part of the income. Suppose, for instance, that a man living in a prefecture stays in another prefecture more than three months, neither one of them can, tax more than one part of his income, even though the other does not tax at all. This is simply for administrative convenience.* ' Prefectural law, article 107. 21 When the national business tax is imposed upon a business which is carried on over several prefectures and has business ofiSces in them, the business is considered as a unit, and can not be divided among its different offices. Prefectures can add the additional tax to it, but the principle above mentioned can not be applied in this case ; for there is no standard available to divide the taxable proportion among the prefectures concerned. The Governors meet together in order to decide among them the shares, and impose the tax in the proportions agreed on, after the sanction of the Minister of the Home and Finance departments. If they can not agree, the two ministers divide it among the prefectures, a decision ^ from which there is no appeal. The most striking exaniple of this case is the business tax on railway companies, and it would not be too much to say that this regulation has been made specially with them in view. Banking, insurance, manufacturing, and warehouse businesses come sometimes under this rule also. The tax rate must be the same in all cases. When a tax is .collected to pay expenses which are specially beneficial to some part of the prefecture, the rate can be increased in that pro- .portion only. Or, when the prefecture which includes the city wants to raise a tax to pay the expenses of a court building and of maintaining county offices, it can not tax the city for this purpose. These are the only two exceptions to the require- ment of an identical tax rate in prefectural taxes. Cities, towns, and villages collect the prefectural taxes for the prefectures which in turn give them four per cent, of the amount collected as the expense of collection, except in the -case of the land tax. a. The land tax. This is the additional rate on the national land tax, which additional rate is imposed by local governments, and occupies the most important place among the prefectural taxes. In 1902, it yielded 25,554,209 yen against 21,042,125 yen, the sum of all other prefectural taxes put together. The 'Prefectural law, article 108. local rate can not exceed one-third of the national tax rate. I will give its details in the third chapter.* b. The house tax? There are two ways of collecting this tax. One is to impose it on the house taking into consideration the area occupied by the building, the situation of the building site, the materials used, and the rental value. The other way is to divide the tax-payers into fewer than thirty grades according to their economic status. This economic status is a very am- biguous term. In practice, it means that consideration is taken of every possible indication of an individual's means." There is a great difference between the highest and lowest grades. In the prefecture from which I received the information, the high- est pays 98.28 yen annually, while the lowest pays .04 yen only. The average is a little more than one yen a year.' The first is really a house tax. The second seems like the general property tax, but there is here one condition probably peculiar to Japan, which will explain why it is called the house tax. The man who pays the tax lives in a house owned or rented. The family or household is still the unit of society, and every independent man with his family lives in a separate house, so that it is a sort of family income tax collected from each household. This second way of collecting the tax is to impose it on the house in the sense of family or household. Where the first is used, there the second can not be applied. In reality, there are three prefectures which use the first, and they apply it only to cities : Tokio, Kioto, and Osaka. The rest of them use the second. If the first method is applied, the object of taxation is defin- ite, and the immediate burden of the tax falls on the owner of the house, while the second method is uncertain in its valuation, and discriminates unfairly often between the rich and poor. * See Chap. Ill, Sect. III., V. ° Goschen, Local Taxation, p. 205, concerning English house tax. "The Reports of Shiga Prefecture. ' Blunden, Local Taxation and Finance, p. 24, concerning the valua- tion in England. 23 The whole sum raised by the house tax was 9,318,595 yen in 1902. c. The surtax on the national business tax. Until 1896, there was in Japan no national business tax at all, and pre- fectures were quite free to tax business as they pleased. Soon after the war with China, the Imperial government, confronted by an enormous increase of expenditure, began to collect the business tax.* Besides the increase in expenditure, there were three more reasons for doing so. First, to effect a fair distri- bution of the burden of taxation among the people of different prefectures by allowing the prefectures to impose additions to the national business tax; secondly, to arrange the system of taxation by subjecting some business to the national tax ex- clusively, and giving prefectures the right to tax the rest when the expenses of collection are proportionally large; thirdly, to extend to business men the electoral franchise more widely and to secure their participation in political affairs by making the payment of the business tax (now a national direct tax) a qualification for voting. Hitherto only land and income taxes were legally called direct national taxes. The electoral fran- chise was given to people who paid more than ten yen a year in these two taxes. Naturally the agricultural interests were represented in the Diet more largely than others ; for the land tax was the most important one. Now the business tax is in- cluded in the national direct taxes, the result of which is to increase the representation of commercial and manufacturing interests in the House of Representatives.* Twenty-four of the most important businesses, such as wholesale trading, retail trading, banking, insurance, lending of money, manufacturing, transporting, warehousing, contract- ing, printing, hotel keeping, restaurant keeping, and others, mostly commercial or manufacturing or transporting are selected as the objects of taxation. The base and rate of the ' History of Finance in Japan, Vol. VI., Chap. I., Sect. V., published , by the association of the same name. •History of Finance in Japan, Vol. VI., p. 45. 24 tax are not the same with all of them. The base of wholesale and retail trading is taken from the amount sold, the rental value of the house used, and the number of employees, and the rate is five ten-thousandths of the amount sold at wholesale fifteen ten-thousandths at retail, forty thousandths of the rental value of the house, and one yen for each employee. For bank- ing, insurance, and private lending, the amount of capital is taken; the rate being two thousandths. For manufactures, the base is the capital eniployed, and the rate is one and one- half thousandths. For warehouses, the rate on rental value of houses is twenty thousandths. For restaurants and hotels* only the rental value of house and the number of employees are considered. The rate is sijrty thousandths and forty thous- andths respectively and one yen for each employee in both cases. For contractors, only the amount contracted for, and the number of employees are considered. The rate on the amount contracted for is two thousandths.^" Not even on all of these businesses is the tax imposed. Some of them are left to prefectures as a source of revenue. Th^ are as follows : wholesale and retail trading fdlling below one thousand yen 'in the amount sold a year ; loaning, below five hundred yen of capital; manufacturing, below five hundred yen of capital and less than two employees ; transporting and bank- ing employing less than two eniployees, contractors contractir^ for less than a thousand yen a year; hotels and restaurants employing less than three employees each. Local governments can not impose the business tax on those businesses which are taxed by the national government. Pre- fectures can collect additional taxes on these, but to an amount not to exceed one-fifth of the national tax. From this source, prefectures received 1,021,608 yen in 1902, while the national tax amounted to 6,777,047 yen. d. The surtax on the income tax. The national income tax^^ "The business tax law, article 12. " Dowell, History of Taxation and Taxes in England, Vol. III., Bk. II., Chap. I., Sect. IV., concerning the income tax in England. Bk. II., Chap. I., Sect. IV., concerning income tax in England. 2S was first imposed in 1887 and revised in 1899. All incomes ol people, and foreigners who live more than one year in the Empire are liable to pay the tax. The rate is progressive and as follows : ^^ The income of corporations 25 yen per 1,000 yen The interest of public debts and bonds. .25 " " " " All other incomes: Over 100,000 yen 55 " " " " 50,000 " 50 " " " " 30,000 " 45 " " " " 20,000 " 40 " " " " 15,000 " 35 " " " 10,000 " 30 " " " " S,ooo " 25 " " " 3,000 " 20 " " " 2,000 " 17 " " " 1,000 " 15 " " " " " 500 " 13 " 300 " 10 " " " Until 1895 the prefectures did not augment by prefectural rates the percentage of the income tax, though they could have done so legally. In 1902, 32,922 yen was collected for prefect- ural purposes ; while 7,460,693 yen was the whole Imperial tax. The prefectural requirements do not amount to much, but are increasing every year. They may not make an additional levy of more than one-fifth of the national income tax. e. The prefectural business tax. Prefectures can impose the business tax on any business which is not taxed by the national business tax. The present usage is to impose it on commerce and manufactures. The process of collecting the same is quite different from that of the national tax. The prefectures do not take the amount sold, or the capital invested as the base of taxation, but they divide the places in which the stores or work- shops are located into certain grades according to their pros- perity, by which the amount sold or business transacted is ' History of Finance in Japan, Vol. VI., p. 13. 26 guessed at; and then impose the same amount of tax for all business enterprises of the same grade in the place, without paying any attention to the capital invested or other elements. In the prefecture from which I received the information, for example, the business tax on commerce is divided into five grades, according to the location, and exacts 2.40 yen a year for the first grade ; 1.90 for the second ; 1.50 for the third ; 1.20 for the fourth; i.oo for the fifth. The tax on manufactures is divided also into five classes and exacts 1.60 yen a year for the first ; 1.30 for the second ; i.oo for the third ; .80 for the fourth ; .60 for the fifth.^^ Prefectures received in 1902 from this source 2,673,899 yen. f. The miscellaneous prefectural taxes. I use here the term " miscellaneous " tax according to the actual practice. There are taxes on restaurants, tea-houses, baths, hair-dressers, wrest- lers, actors, geisha girls, markets, theaters, shows, boats, car- riages, riding horses, fishermen, bicycles, and some others.^* Prefectures can tax anything they want under the name of miscellaneous taxes. The objects of taxation are, therefore, different among them. The rate of taxation varies according to the situation exactly as in the case of the business tax. Some of the taxes are divided into five, some four, and some three classes. Some of them take into consideration the age of those taxed; for in- stance, geisha girls of more than thirteen years of age in the first grade-place pay 4.50 yen a month, while those of less than thirteen years of age pay 2.25 yen in the same place. Sometimes the use is considered, for example, those jinrickshaws for one man's accommodation for the owner's private use pay 2.50 yen a year, while public jinrickshaws pay 1.80 yen. The tax on bicycles is also 3.00 yen and 2.00 yen respectively. The rev- enue from these taxes reached 6,225,909 yen in 1902. "The Budget of Shiga Prelecture of 1905. The Report of Kana- gawa Prefecture of 1903. " The Budget of Shiga Prefecture of 1905. 27 Though the tax on commerce and manufacture only is called the business tax of prefectures, there is, as can be seen in the above statement, no difference at all between the business tax and some of the miscellaneous taxes. They are business taxes even if they have a strong resemblance to a license tax ; because they are not the condition precedent, but result subsequent" to carrying on the business. Some of the miscellaneous taxes, however, such as taxes on carriages, geisha girls, and bicycles, are license taxes pure and simple. Some of them come be- tween the two and are very hard to define exactly. g. The special apportioned tax on cities, towns, and villages (Prefectural tax.) The taxes of prefectures are based pri- marily on the principle that they shall be collected directly fron^ the people. In the old law, it was strictly prohibited to leyy any tax upon rural communities, and pth^r public corpor^tign? as a unit. When, however, they want to defray small expendir tures for certain purposes, it is very troublesome to impose the tax on all people throughout the prefeqture directly and equally. The new law changed this requirement and permit? the prefectures to gather revenues from rural communities a? a unit. Cities, towns, and villages are responsible to fulfil the requirement, but they are free to determine themselves how the tax is, tQ be distributed among their people. They might be able to pay it out of the interest of public funds, or in some other way. In 1902 1,554,023 yen was the sum thus collected, way. In 1902 1,554,023 yen was the sum thus collected. h. Labour and Commodities (Taxes in kind). This is one of the ways to levy the prefectural taxes. They might be imposed directly on the people, or on cities, towns, and villages as a unit. They can also be collected from other quasi-public cor- porations. The prefecture may impose on the drainage board, for instance, covering a certain area special taxes for drain- age purposes, and even require the drainage board to furnish a supply of labour and commodities. Any prefectural tax must be imposed generally, but the exaction of labour and commodities may be imposed on some " Seligman, Essays in Taxation, p. 280. 28 specified portions of the prefecture for the public works which benefit these portions in particular. Practically, however, this prefectural tax (in kind) is hardly ever applied to individuals directly and not frequently to cities, towns, and villages. The amount levied and calculated when put in money terms does not amount to much, and is included in the figures of the apportioned tax. It is more frequently exacted of towns and villages ; so it is more convenient to explain it later when I shall come to towns, and villages.^" 3. Fees. In the law, fees are divided into two classes : one is paid for the use of public establishments, for example, for the privilege of passing over a bridge, and the other is the fee paid for the use of public establishments where the chief element fixing the fee is the service of officials.^'' The distinction is unscientific, for any public establishment involves both kinds of service which can not distinctly be separated. This division is made according to an old custom, and perhaps for administrative convenience. School tuition is a fee of the latter kind. Some of the public establishments, such as highways, some bridges, and parks are open free to all the people. Fees do not amount to much and no separate statistics are made of them. They are included in the miscellaneous rev- enue. 4. Fines. Fines are also a part of the public income, and the result of the exercise of the public power. They are generally im- posed on people and sometimes on officials.^* When the pre- fectural officials neglect their duty, they must pay fines. Both are collected by the administrative office of the prefecture. The amount is too insignificant to make a separate statement of, and is included in the miscellaneous revenue. " See page infra 38. " Prefectural Law, article 99. " Prefectural Law, article 81. 29 5- The quasi-private revenue. The most striking difference between the public and quasi- private revenues can be seen in the process of enforcing the collection of each of them, when the people neglect their pay- ment. The former is collected by distraint and forced sale; while the latter, such as donations promised by private persons, can only be collected by suit brought in the ordinary civil courts. The treasury stands in the latter instance on the same footing with private suitors.^' The Income from Public Property. According to the pre- fectural law, such properties are divided first into those whose earnings are to be used to defray certain prefectural expendi- tures (e. g., public lands rented to private persons), and second, those which are provided for the general use of the public such as parks (usually called the public estab- lishments). The former is again divided: the earnings of a part going to defray ordinary expenditures, and of the other to defray the extraordinary expenditures.^" In the old prefectural law, it was not allowed to set apart any income from public property for undefined extraordinary ex- penditures, but only for some specific purposes predetermined by the law, such as relief funds in case of bad harvests. It goes without saying that it is a very desirable thing to lay by in prosperous times some resources not only for definite ex- penditures, but also for general losses arising through emer- gencies disturbing local finance. In the new law, therefore, a clause was inserted to let prefectures provide some reserve funds largely made up of annual surpluses. These may exist in kind, or in the form of immovable property. The prefect- ures can even impose prefectural taxes on the people to make up these reserves."^ These reserve funds resemble the pro- ductive capital of cities, towns, and villages.^^ They differ. " Minobe, Prefectural and County Law, p. 295. " Prefectural Law, article 98. " Minobe, p. 262. "See infra page 39. 30 however, in this, that not only the income but, if necessary, the principal can be freely used, while the productive capital of cities, towns, and villages can be employed only by taking the income for use. The new law having been passed only six years ago, some prefectures have not yet started this method of accumulating reserve funds, artd no statistics of such properties are as yet available. Prefectures, from the time of the old law, have con- trol of the educational funds and the poor relief funds, the amount of which are, according to the latest estimate of 1902, 1,370,198 yfen and 27,2^2,6)60 yen respectively. The income from these properties, artd properties sold, with Some father minor revenues in 1902 reached 4,433,827 yen under the name of the miscellaneous income. In 1902 donations amounted to 402,945 yen. B. EXtRAORDINARY ReVENUE. The Public Debt. Prefectures, like individuals, meet with unexpected demands, and are placed at times in urgent need of unusually large sums of money. Even if the prefectures are not permanent entities like the state^ they certainly enjoy a more permanent existence than individuals, and are more fully justified than they in undertaking a permanent scheme for the future benefit of their people. These expenditures amount to so much that the ordinary revenue can not afford the needed supply. For these purposes, it is not only unobjectionable, but rather beneficial that prefectures distribute their burden over the future by means of public loans. In spite of these undoubted advantages, however, the resort to public credit is the easiest way to shift present burdens on to posterity, and may easily cause, unless carefully guarded, financial trouble in the future.^* The pre^- fectural debt is, therefore, under careful supervision and rigid limitation.^* " Adams, Public Debt, p. 25. "Bastable, p. 721, concerning the supervision of local debts in Eng- land. 31 Its purpose must be to redeem the old debts, or to pay the cost of permanent improvements, or to provide for natural calamities, or emergencies. Prefectures are not allowed to resort to borrowing, unless the expenditure can not be met by an increase of the ordinary revenues. The bill to authorize the debt must have the approval of the Prefectural Assembly which determines at the time the details of the loan subscrip- tion, the rate of interest, and the time of redemption. The project must get the sanction of the superintending adminis- trative office ^° which will give the final decision. Prefectural debt stands as follows: 1898 7,885,202 yen 1899 8,672,639 yen 1900 9,719,983 " 1901 10,379,664 " 1902 10,712,864 " 1903 12,076,497''° " The yearly amount of new debt contracted is : 1897 3,512,067 yen 1898 2,589,723 yen 1899 2,899,145 " 1900 3,078,281 " 1901 1,448,753 " 1902 2,652,711 " The redemption, the payment of interest and other expendi- tures connected with the debt each year, aggregate the follow- ing amounts: 1897 952,433 yen 1898 1,466,267 yen 1899 1,629,005 " 1900 2,786,748 " 1901 3,243,771 " 1902 3,726,142 " The average rate of interest is necessarily higher than that of the national debt and ranges somewhere about six per cent The duration of the debt can hardly be given; for it differs widely in different cases. Formerly debt had to be redeemed in thirty years. No such limit is now set, but perpetual debt is not allowed. Temporary loans (e. g., for anticipating taxes) are repaid out of ordinary revenues within the fiscal year. "Imperial government. "The figures do not include temporary loans. 32 (II). The Revenue of Counties. Counties, like other local governments, get their revenues in part from public property and in part from taxes. It seems rather surprising to find that there are no statistics of county finance. When we consider, however, that counties have no right to impose taxes directly on the people, and that their public revenues come chiefly from the apportioned tax " on towns and villages, the absence of statistics is not surprising, because the apportioned tax is one item of the expenditure of towns and villages which would be duplicated, if independent statistics of county finance were made. As ordinary public income, the counties get subsidies from the national and prefectural treasuries. The counties impose the apportioned tax as a unit on towns and villages which in turn distribute it among their people as they please, or pay it out of the interest of their capital. The rate of tax is determined by the total amount of the direct national and the prefectural taxes which were collected in the towns and villages in the previous fiscal year. The counties can require labour and com- modities exactly as in the case of prefectures. They impose fees and fines which amount practically to very little. As quasi-private income, the counties get the income from public property. What I have said about the prefectural prop- erties applies here with but slight modification. There are in Japan six hundred and thirty-eight counties in all. It is quite out of question to collect the materials from them, and make up any trustworthy statistics. The whole revenue can only be guessed at by the whole expenditure which I can fortunately give later on. The statistics of local finance are very meagre in every country in the world.^* It is surely disappointing to see no " County law, article 89. "Seligman, Finance Statistics of the American Commonwealths. American Statistical Association, Vol. I., p. 455, concerning imperfect local statistics in America. 33 statistics of county finance. It is advisable to compile such statistics if the counties are to continue' as self-governing bodies. I give here one example of county revenue from the budget for 1905 which I received from one of the counties of my native prefecture.^' The subsidy for education from the national treasury, 500 yen The subsidy for education from the prefectural treasury 500 " The apportioned tax. , 2,034 " Tuition (fees collected from pupils) 123 " Income from county property 342 " Property sold 199 " Extraordinary income will include any public debt contracted by the counties. I will not repeat here again what I have said about the prefectural debt, for the same thing applies here with only the necessary change of County Assembly in the place of the Prefectural Assembly. The amount of all debts of coun- ties stands as follows: 1898 45,729 yen 1899 62,646 yen 1900 135,613 " 1901 339,348 " , 1902 509,588 " 1903 890,045 " The rate of interest is almost the same as that of the prefect- ures. (III). The Revenue of Cities, Towns, and Villages. All people of the country belong to either one of these lowest communities, and all financial burdens of the country fall in the last resort on them. The national, prefectural, and county revenues all come from them. They at last pay the expendi- ture of their own administration both original and delegated, and their burden is increasing year after year. ' The Budget of Ika County of Shiga Prefecture, 1905. 34 A. The Ordinary Public Revenue. I. Subsidies, and Grants. These are given by the national, prefectural, and county treasuries. In the case of cities, there is no county subsidy, because they are independent of the county and have no rela- tion to it at all. The subsidies and grants are given for educa- tional, and industrial purposes, and for public works. The statistics of the national and prefectural subsidies include the grants given to the cities, towns, and villages to repay them for the expense of collection of the national and prefectural taxes, except in the case of the national land tax and the prefectural addition to the ra;te thereof. Four per cent, of the amount collected is repaid to the local .governments. The figures in 1901 stand as follows : I. Cities: From the national treasury . ., > , 546,526 y&t Prcau the prefectural treasuri^. 3iOi698 " II. Towns and villages: Ffom the national treasury 286,490 " From the prefectural treasuries 3,901,534 " From the county treasuries 324,150 " 2. The Taxes of Cities, Towns, and Villages. Whatever the actual situation may be, cities, towns, and villages are debarred from collecting any tax at all, unless the interest of their capital, their fees, fines, and toliier income are insufficient to pay their expenditures. This precaution was made so as not to disturb the common financial resources of aiH grades of governments. As I have said, just before, all national and prefectural burdens lall on the people of these communi- ties. If the cities, towns, and villages in addition to the national and prefectural governments impose as heavy taxes on their people as they please, much suffering of the people will be caused and much disturbance as regards the national and prefectural revenues. 35 The taxes are imposed on residents of the taxing communi- ties, or on those who stay there more than three months, or who own lands or buildings situated therein, or on those who have a business office situated within such communities. The most important of these local taxes is the additional rate which they add to the national or prefectural taxes. The rate must be uniform, and an addition to the direct national or prefectUral taxes, but, when sanctioned, in the case of necessity, by the superentending administrative office,'" cities, towns, and vil^ lages may also levy additional rates on the indirect taxes in force. Unless by special permission of the Ministers of the Home and Finance departments, the maximum rate of one- seventh of the national land tax, and one-half of other direct taxes can not be exceeded. a. The surtax on the national land tax.^^ This is one of the most important reventies of cities, towns, and villages. The maximum rate is one-seventh of the national land tax. In I901 cities, towns and villages received from this surtax 441,'- 985 yen and 13,252,550 yen respectively. For further consider* ations, see the third chapter .^^ b. The surtax on the national income tax,^^ In setting the rate, care is taken to avoid double taxation. Incomes derived ffom lands, buildings, and business enterprises which are out- side cities, towns, and villages in which taxpayers live must be deducted ; and incomes coming from other sources than lands, buildings and business enterprises of taxpayers who live or stay in more than one community must be equally divided among fh6 communities concerned. From this source in 1901 cities received 1,271,651 yen and towns and Villages 647,856 yen. c The surtax on the national business tax.^* The rat6 of the "Imperial government. ** Lefby-BeaulieU, Vol. I., p. 32S. 33*. Nitti, p. J?i8, coftCerning the strong resemblance of the lax to " les centimes additlohels." "* See page itiira. '69. " See page supra 24. " See page supra 23. 36 tax is set just as in prefectures. The maximum local rate is one-half of the national rate of the tax; much more than the maximum prefectural rate which is only one-fifth of the national rate of the tax. The cities in 1901 got 2,020,738 yen and the towns and villages 857,580 yen from this source. d. The surtax on the indirect national taxes. Though the local rate on the national or prefectural taxes may generally result in a fairer burden on the people than the special taxes, the local rate added to the indirect national taxes is apt to throw an unfair burden especially on the poor. This local surcharge on national indirect taxes is considered as excep- tional and is carefully guarded, and can not be collected unless the Ministers of the Home and Finance departments allow it. The objects of the tax are generally liquor, Shoyu (a kind of sauce) and sugar. Practically few of the local communities collect the tax. It does not amount to much and reached in 1898 only 274 yen for cities and 932 yen for towns and villages. The figures of the latest statistics of 1901 are 2,711 yen and 6,282 yen respectively. e. The surtax on the prefectural house tax. Cities, towns, and villages impose the additional rate on the prefectural taxes just as they do on the national taxes. The maximum rate is one-half of the prefectural rate. The revenue derived from it in 1901 is as follows : Cities (a)«= 1,336,151 yen (b) 1,160,247 " Towns and villages (b) 25,520,535 " f. The surtax on the prefectural business tax.^^ In 1901 it produced 555,985 yen for cities and 2,367,221 for towns and villages. g. The special tax. The tax revenues of cities, towns and "In explaining the pfefectural house tax, I said that there are two ways of levying the tax, and the first method is applied only in the three largest cities. The (a) supra corresponds to the first and the (b) supra to the second. See page supra 22. " See page supra 25. 37 villages come mostly from the surcharges made to national and prefectural taxes but a small part from the special tax.*' Under the name of the special tax, there are many varieties of an independent character. Any of the cities, towns, and villages, as they think necessary, may select any object and im- pose any rate of taxation on it within the community. It must be approved by the Ministers of Home and Finance depart- ments. This precaution was made not only to prevent an unfair burden on the people, but to protect the national policy of taxation. For instance, the national tax on manufactured goods will be greatly obstructed by having a special tax on the raw materials of manufacture imposed by local gov- ernments. In Japan there are 60 cities, 1,121 towns, and 12,351 villages. Many of them do not impose any special tax at all, and the rest of them have their own special taxes differing from each other according to the circumstances of their locality. Of these, there are no statistics. It is an immense task and hardly possible to systematize scientifically all these taxes, especially cvhen we consider the lack of materials. The following are the common special taxes : (i) "Tanbetsuwari" (rate per tan). It is imposed on the owner of lands, the base being the "tan" (about f of an acre). When the registered value of forests is comparatively low, it is imposed on them and called by the same name. (2) The Buichi tax (percentage tax). It is collected when the ownership of lands or buildings is transferred. If by sale, some percentage of the actual price is collected from the buyer. In other cases, cities, towns, and villages themselves value the property and collect the tax from the new owners. In some villages, it ranges as high as two per cent. (3) The surtax on the national and prefectural taxes. This is a most perplexing special tax ; for although based on a per- centage of the national and prefectural taxes, it is called a special tax. The rate, as I said before, has its maximum. " See page infra 43-44- 38 Now instead of exceeding it nominally, there is collected some percentage of the land tax, the national and prefectural busi- ness tax, and the house tax under the name of a special tax. Though legally the maximum may not be exceeded, this is practically done under the name of a special tax. (4) The tax on Sake (liquor). This resembles the octrois.^^ The local governments impose the tax both on sake when brought within the city, and when made and sold there. If re-exported out of the city, the tax is paid back. In Tokio the duty is fifty cen per koku (39.70 imp. gal.) . In the metropolis, this special tax on sake and the special tax of the (3) supra are collected for the expenses of the street improvements.^* Other special taxes are special assessments to meet the cost of improving private property ; taxes on dogs and some others. In 1901, cities received 4,135,321 yen and towns and villages 1,177,204 yen from all these special taxes. h. Labor and commodities. Taxes in every modern society are generally raised in the form of money ; nevertheless in some parts of rural communities even at the present day, their econ^ omic conditions are still backwards, and better fitted to allow taxes to be collected in the form of labour and commodities; for the people might think such forms of taxation less heavy than money payments. For this reason, the law provided that local governments may impose taxes in the form of labour and commodities in case of necessity.*" The payment in labour may seem the same in appearance as military service and the service rendered by the local government officials who hold honorary positions, but it has an essentially different character. It may be paid by any individual providing an acceptable sub- stitute and need not be paid in propria persona. Service re- quiring special training such as professional service can not be demanded, and people who are required to contribute labour may send another person as a substitute. The contribution in "^ Leroy-BeauHeu, Vol. I., p. 736. Basta,iile, p. 543- " Hosono, The Past and Future of City of Tokio, p. 78. "Civic Corporation Act. article loi. 39 kind and labour should be, unless in the time of pressing needs, calculated in money terms, and people can pay it in money, if they so choose. The purposes for which this kind of tax may he required are more clearly defined than in the case of the prefectural labour and commodity tax. The labour and com- modity tax of the lowest local governments must be to construct public works, such as roads, parks, banks, schools, hospitals, and drainage works, or to protect the public welfare against fire, flood, earthquake, and other calamities. It is different, also, from the case of the prefectural labour and commodity tax, imposed directly on individuals. Its amount must be de- termined in proportion to the sum total of all direct taxes which each person pays. When labour is valued in money terms, the day's wage prevailing in the locality is to be taken as the standard. The amount in 1901 required by towns and villages were : Labour 412,897 yen, commodities 4,006 yen. Cities do not resort to this sort of revenue. 3. Fees. For explanation, I refer to the fees of prefectures.*^ In 1901 cities received 745,305 yen and towns and villages 337,077 yen. 4. Fines. They are a source of revenues, but amount to little aud are 2S6,876 " Cash and in kind 4,274,626 " 6,787,495 " Total 10,658,063 " 39.354,532 " The towns and villages which have such capital are 11,073 *° number.** All cities have it. In 1901 cities received 861,273 yen and towns and villages 1,604,811 yen from the interest of this capital. b. Donations. In 1901, donations or gifts yielded 142,094 yen for cities and 3,428,966 yen for towns and villages. The donations are received mostly for the purposes of education, charity, and some public works. 6. Miscellaneous Income. Under this head, the grants from the Emperor, and Empress, incomes from properties sold, and some other minor incomes are included. Cities received 7,512,199 yen and towns and villages 5,639,135 yen in 1901 from these sources. B. Extraordinary Revenue. The Public Debt. Until the Civic Corporation Act was passed, cities, towns, and villages could not resort to the use of public credit. They can now do so, and are bound by the rights and duties of debtors. But if they are left entirely free to go on borrowing, there is much reason to fear that they may disorder local finances. They must, therefore, observe the limitations set "See page supra 37, concerning the total number of cities, towns and villages. 42 before them; first to redeem the old debts, and secondly to issue bonds to pay for unavoidable expenditures caused by natural calamities or emergencies, and thirdly to pay for works of permanent advantage. The improvement of lands and forests, and the construction of canals, wharves, and other means of transportation might increase the temporary burden on the people, but they will increase their productive power and strengthen the permanent economic power of the country. The immediate increase they would cause in taxes would be unsupportable by the peoule.*' The bill to authorize the loan must be made by the decision of the local Assembly which de- termines at the time the details of subscription, the time of redemption, and the rate of interest. The redemption of the debt must be begun within three years from its issue, and com- pleted entirely within thirty years.*' If the local governments can not follow these rules, they must get the permission of the Ministers of the Home and Finance departments. The rate of interest is almost the same as on the prefectural debts,*' and sometimes higher. They can borrow temporarily to pay for the expenditure included already in their budgets independently of the above provisions. Temporary loans are redeemable within £t period not exceeding three years. The outstanding debts are as follows : Towns. Villages: 147,904 yen 235,481 yen 176,776 " 315.173 " 266,624 " 562,872 " 400.514 " 1,116,940 " 521,221 " 1,463,028 " 791.515 " i,8o8,237«" " Civic Corporation Act, article 106. "Concerning repayment of local loans in England, see Blunckn, Local Taxation and Finance, p. 20. "See page supra 31. If it is issued below par, say 93 yen with face value of 100 yen, the interest is usually six per cent. If it is issued at par, the interest reaches as high as seven per cent. "The figures do not include temporary loans. 1898 Cities. 11,501,480 yen 1899, 18,276,755 " 1900 25,849,033 " I90I 29,796,663 " 1902 35,130,242 " 1903 38,463.137 " 43 The yearly amount of debt contracted was : Cities. Towns and villages^ 1897 1,103,152 yen 2,288,869 J^^ 1898 1,007,720 " 2,945,575 " 1899 2,653,695 " 3.867,647 " 1900 2,781,873 " 5,002,696 " 1901 3,878,226 " 6,223,692 " The redemption, payment of interest, and other expenditures on account of the debt amounted yearly as follows : Cities. Towns and villages. 1897 2,480,128 yen 1,693,851 yeil 1898 1,481,642 " 2,3^3,787 " 1899 1,656,745 " 2,609,806 " 1900 2,190,588 " 3,576,112 " 1901 2,880,288 " 4,876,784 " The tables sUmmaHsing the revenue of local governments: I. Prefectures. 189I 1901 ^fSS^. Local surtax on land tax 7,222,759 23,620,662 226 Local surtax on business tax . . . 946.635 Other prefectural taxes*» 7,189,327 18,541,134 157 Public debts contracted 1,448,753 Subsidies 7,937-294 2,671,030 *65 Donations 123,204 569-542 362 Miscellaneous 2,318,256 3-987-541 72 Money carried forward from previous year 1,427,085 6,918,224 384 * decrease. 26,217,933 58,721,522 123 In 1891, there was no national business tax, therefore, no local rate additional oti it, and the receipts from public debt contracted were included in the miscellaneous item. The in- crease of local public debts is treated in another place. "See page sttpra 22-27. 44 II. Cities. 1891 Local surtax on land tax 104,530 Local surtax on other national taxes 125,510 Local surtax on prefectural taxes 1,161,657 Special taxes 4S.I9I Revenue from public properties, 456,566 Public debts contracted 140,649 Fees 30,286 Subsidies 746,632 Donations 21,010 Miscellaneous 31265,391 Money carried forward from previous year 216,050 5,460,472 III. Towns and villages. 1891 Local surtax on land tax 5,913,107 Local surtax on other national taxes 3o>356 Local surtax on prefectural taxes 7,601,199 Special taxes 387,971 Labour and commodities 288,986 Revenue from public properties, 626,609 Public debts contracted 352,790 Fees 29,467 Subsidies 2,540,401 Donations 855,761 Miscellaneous 2,160,351 Money carried forward from previous year 1,067,580 21,827,578 1901 441,985 Percentage of Increase. 322 3,295,100 2,546 3,052,383 4.135,321 861,273 3,878,226 '745,305 857,224 142,094 7,512,199 162 950 88 2,657 2,360 14 576 130 3,411,334 1,478 28,332,444 400 »9oi o^Yr^ 13,252,550 124 1,511,718 4,879 27,887,756 266 1,177,204 203 416,903 44 1,604,811 156 6,223,692 1,810 337,077 1,043 4,512,174 T7 3,428,966 300 5,639,135 161 4,324,624 305 70,316,610 222 45 Section II. The Expenditure of Local Governments. Some public affairs, such as military and diplomatic admin- istration, are exclusively taken into, the charge of the Imperial government, but the character of public business becomes more complicated every year, and the expenditures of all' local governments increase accordingly. Usually the expenditures of local governments are divided into the self-determined and the obligatory.^" The former is to defray the expense of the original and the other of the dele- gated administrative functions. The distinction is specially clear in the case of cities, towns, and villages. For prefectures, it is of no practical importance at all, because the superintend- ing administrative officers have such extensive power that they can fix even the size of the self-determined expenditure so- called, when they think it necessary. (i). The Expenditure of Prefectures. Prefectures are required to pay for both self-determined and obligatory expenditures. They are fixed in part by Imperial laws, and Imperial ordinances, and in part by customs and old usages. Their administrative business has a certain limit, and it fol- lows naturally that their expenditures are correspondingly limited. Prefectures may not spend any revenue, except for strictly prefectural purposes. By a special regulation, however, they are allowed to make contributions to the state for Im- perial purposes (e. g., the sea-coast defence), and to give sub- sidies to individuals or other public corporations, which have benefited the prefecture, as by establishing an agricultural society within the prefecture." The following is the prefect- ural expenditure for 1902 : "' Minobe, p. 299. "Prefectural Law, article loi. The subsidy to an agricultural society was declared contrary to the law by an administrative court, but the decision seems by no means well grounded. 46 Prefectural Assemblies 4^1,154 yen Prefectur^l Assembly buildings , 266,8pi County office expenses 2,948,987 County pffice buildings 202,946 Police 8,997.219 Police office buildings 793,719 Public works 15,574,204 Subsidies to above. ,,..,,....,. 3,010,547 industry , : 3,464,172 Education ......,,,.... .....^ , . ^0,830,961 Subsidies to above. ,.......,..., ,,,.... 33,917 Poor Relief. ,.,.,,,, ,..,,..., 106,624 Sanitation ..,,.,.., : , . r - , 1,823,584 Subsidies to above. ■■■■■•, r 1,222,610 Election expenses of members of Die^. , 90,664 Expense of handling prefectural money 827,280 Notices and advertisements 63,010 Salaries 948,603 Public debts (interest and re4eraption) 3,726,142 Miscellaneous . .' 1,185,646 56,578,790 « The expenditure for the county offices and buildings are paid from the prefectural treasury."^ The salaries of Govern nors and other higb prefectural officials are not included under the head of salaries, for they are paid from the national treasr ury.°' The miscellaneous item includes expenses for the elec- tion of members of the Prefectural Assembly, prefectural star tistics, mmor subsidies, grants to school teachers, and some other minor expenses, "Prefectural Law, article 114. °^ See page supra 7 and also appendix page 88 about tlieir amount. 47 (II). The Expenditure of Counties. As I have said before, there are no statistics of county finance, for their revenues come partly from the prefectures and partly from towns and villages. The following statistics of 1904 were specially made for reference purposes, when the abolition of the county was discussed in the Imperial Diet in 1905: County Assembly and County Council 329,199 yen Public works 3,015,847 " Other expenses 627,668 " 3,972,714 "Other expenses" includes salaries of oificials and employees, notices and advertisements, subsidies, education, election ex- penses, and some minor expenses. The average for a county is 6,163 y^"> ^^^ highest being 21,359 yen and the lowest 1,978' yen. (III). The Expenditures of Cities, Towns, and Villages. They are for the original and delegated administrative pur- poses. The most of the latter are defined by Imperial laws and Imperial ordinances, and the former are regulated by the Civic Corporation Acts which allow the local governments discretion to make expenditures according to their own circumstances for the benefit of their people. When the obligatory expenditures are not provided for in their budget, the authority of the superintending administrative offices can force them to include such items. The election of members of the House of Repre- sentatives, census, judicial police, the higher branches of educa- tion, the collection of taxes, and conscription belong to the delegated functions, while public works, industry, sanitation, poor relief, general education and others belong to their orig- inal jurisdiction. They differ widely from each other in the amount of business and expenditure. 48 The expenditure in 1901 is as follows : Cities. Towns and villages. Assembly 90,426 yen 599.0I2 yen Public buildings and sal- aries i,787>oi4 " 13,108,601 Public works 3.477.541 " 7.3S2,5i2 Education 4,692,144 " 25,449,643 Sanitation I.355.03S " 3.901,605 Poor relief 57,876 " 39,679 Police 148.274 " 439.940 Industry 78.898 " 951.128 Public debts 2,880,288 " 4,876,784 Control of property 413.819 " ' 543,385 Taxes and other burdens, 1,397,792 " 4,858,117 Miscellaneous 5,732,972 " 3,180,324 22,112,079 " 65,300,730 " The miscellaneous item includes the light in parks, small charitable contribution, grants and some minor expenditures. Section III. The Budgetary Legislation and Adminis- tration OF Local Governments. (I). Prefectures. The financial administration and control of prefectures like those of the state comprise the budget and the audit of accounts. A. The budget. The nature of the budget has been much discussed, and it is finally settled that in Japan the budget refers not to the actual law authorizing expenditure and collection of revenue, but simply to an approximate estimate of revenue and expenditure. The prefectural budget is prepared by the Gov- ernor before the fiscal year and introduced into the Prefectural Assembly after a previous examination by the Prefectural Council. It must be made according to the model set forth by the Minister of the Home Department. The fiscal year begins April first and ends March thirty-first. The budget must be ratified by the Assembly, but the decision is not at all final, be- 49 cause if the Governor thinks it is improper, he can send it back again for further consideration. Again the Minister of the Home Department may change it, when the Governor without sending the budget back to the Assembly asks the Minister's instructions. The exclusive right of proposal rests entirely with the Governor, and the Assembly have only the right to amend it, but can not introduce any new proposal at all. So far as the revenue is concerned, it may not come exactly to the amount estimated. On the other hand, the expenditures voted must be strictly observed by the administrative officials who are charged not to spend more than definite amounts allotted to definite purposes. However carefully the expendi- ture may be estimated, it must be admitted that the actual con- dition of things does not allow every thing to be foreseen which might happen within a year. Thus to a certain extent, regu- lated by the Home Minister, the transfer of appropriations within certain limits is allowed. If there arises any need for expenditure unanticipated in the budget, or for more expendi- ture than anticipated, such expenditure must be met out of the reserve which is necessarily provided for in the budget, or by amendment to the budget by the approval of the Assembly. The reserve can in no case be used for expenditure which the Assembly has not approved.'* If there be any necessity to spend money continually for a number of years, the prefecture can, by the permission of the superintending administrative office, settle the amount of ex- penditure for certain purposes in the first year for the rest of the series of years. It need not henceforth be voted annually. Such necessity arises in building public works which take years to finish. Governors, by the approval of the local Assembly and the permission of the Minister of the Home Department can make a separate account for certain purposes such as for schools and hospitals. It is officially called the special account." Its 'Prefectural Law, article 121. 'Prefectural Law, article 123. 5P budget snd the audit of the account are prepared for the con?' venience of the prefectural administration. Some of the prefectural officials are appointed by the Gov^ ernor to manage the treasury. They are in a position entirely subordinate tp him and have no right to refuse any order signed by him which is presented to them for payment. On the othw hand, treasurers of cities, towns, and idllages have independert power °* in paying out pubhc money. If there is any surplus, it must be included in next year's budget. It can never be used gt the discretion of the treasury. Governors nominate the banks to handle the prefectural money. B. The Legislative Audit. The completed accounts are introduced into the Prefectural Assembly for ex- amination and audit two years after the budget was passed. It is important for the supervision of finance to have information how far the budget as enacted has been fol- lowed in practical administration. The completed accounts are prepared by the Governor and, after investigation by the Pre- fectural council, introduced into the Assembly. If the Assem- bly find any illegitimate expenditure made, it expresses its opinion thereupon tp the administrative officials responsible for such expenditure. This is really only the "power to scold" — an insufficient degree of legislative control. Practically all that has been said about the prefectures applies to the counties with the necessary changes in nomenclature. (II). Cities, Towns, and Villages. A. The budget. The City Councils and the chief official* of towns, and villages have to make their budgets two months before the beginning of the fiscal year, and obtain the approval of their respective Assemblies. After the decision of the Assembly they must send a copy to the superin-- ' See page infra Si. SJ tending offices, and at the same time advertise its essen- tial parts to the public according to the different local custppis of advertising. The City Councils and the chief officials of towns, and villages may not neglect to make the budget. When they neglect it, the superintending offices force them to act, or make it themselves. This power to force the local officials tp make the budget is exercised with great freedom to compel the making of provision for expenditure involved in the adminis- tration delegated to local governments. The payment of exr penditures unanticipated and those in excess of the budget: estimate, and the transfer of appropriations from one purpose to another are not allowed, unless approval is given by the Asr sembly. Reserve funds may be provided for in the budget, if the Assembly so chgoses, and will be used for unexpected outlay. All the business of the treasury is managed by the Treasurer who is elected by the Assembly. Only in a small town or vil- lage where its financial transactions do not amount to much, its chief official, or assistant may dp the work of treasurer, The treasurer is corrlmonly elected, because of the impprtancg of having a particular official responsible for ^11 financial acts. Orders for payment are drawn on the treasurer by the City Council, the chief officials of towns and village?, and somcr times by the superintending administrative offices. He cap in no case pay out money unless he receives such an order, The law also makes him responsible for examining the legitimacy of the order and thus he may refuse to honor it. B. The Lepslative audit. The treasurer has to render a completed account within three months after the fiscal year ig over and send it together with the necessary documents includ- ing receipts and vouchers to the City Council, or chief officials pf towns and villages as the case may be. They in turn rtiyst introduce it together with their opinion therepn fpr the ?ipprpval of the Assemblies, and must report the action of the Assemblies to the superintending administrative office. 52 CHAPTER III. The Problems of Local Finance in Japan and their Discussion. The increase in the expenditures and revenues of local self- governing bodies has not until recently attracted the attention of politicians, economists, and men of affairs. This tendency towards increase is not however confined to Japan only, but is discernible in almost all civilized countries where the self- governing system is adopted. There seems to exist a close rela- tion between this increase and the system of self-government. Their expenditures and revenues, if taken separately, amount to but little and look like unimportant matters. This is the reason why the important question of local public finance has been neglected for a long time, though it is now being carefully investigated. , All local expenditures and revenues taken to- gether involve a vast sum, and such sums have a weighty bear- ing upon the common welfare of the people. It need not be said that local self-governing bodies are an integral part of the state, and that their sound financiering is essential to the development and prosperity of the country. To give a con- crete idea of the rapid increase and importance of local finance, the statistics below are cited. The relative amounts of the central and local expenditures and revenues in Japan in 1901 are as follows : Local Percentage of ImperiaL Imperial. Local.* Expenditures 266,856,824 139,981,258 52 Revenues 274,359,049 159,370,576 57 'The statistics are quoted from the seventeenth and twenty-third reports of the statistical bureau. Here local includes all classes of local governments. S3 The increase in local expenditures and revenues in ten years is as follows; Percentage 189I I9OI ,^oi^^^_ Expenditures 44,734,473 139,981,258 212 Revenues 53.685,973 159.370,576 196 The following tables show the relative increase in the de- tailed expenditure of local self-governing bodies : 3,083,390 73 8,883,938 92 17,653,216 134 10,768,714 921 2,787,220 574 69.999 8 Percentage I. Prefectures. 1891 1901 in„^„ Pref ectural Assembly and build- ings 401,641 762,302 89 County office expenses and buildings 1,776,421 Police 4,610,644 Public works and subsidies. . . . 7,541,833 Education and subsidies 1,054,501 Sanitation and subsidies 413,454 Poor relief 64,565 Election expenses of members of Diet 8,418 8,461 Expenses of handling prefect- ural money 296,712 Notices and advertisements .... 48,275 Salaries Public debts Industry 168,204 Miscellaneous 1,667,838 21,245,672 ' Decrease. 772,016 160 61,459 28 904,233 3,243,771 2,599.76s 144 879.965 47== 52,478,449 147 54 The salaries and the expenditure for public debts in 1891 were included in the miscellaneous. If we take l89;7 instead of 1891, the increase is as follows : Percentage 1897 I9OI i„°Le. Salaries 254,402 904.233 255 Public debts 952,433 3-243.71 1 240 The decrease in the miscellaneous is the result of separate itemizations at the later date. Percentage II. Cities. 1891 1901 i„,°J^, Assemblies 35,838 90,426 152 Public buildings and salaries. 537,905 1,787,014 232 Public works 444,712 3,477,541 682 Education 865,083 4,692,144 447 Sanitation 99>9i5 i,3SS,03S 1.256 Poor relief 20,467 57,876 182 Police 44,749 148,274 231 Industry 5,757 78,898 1,270 Public debts 207,475 2,880,288' 1,288 Control of property 57,968 414,819 615 Taxes and other burdens 3,265 1,397,792 42,711 Miscellaneous 634,193 5,732,972 803 2,957,327 22,112,079 647 Percentage III. Towns and villages. 1891 Igoi i^alase Assemblies 315,457 599,oi2 89 Public buildings and salaries . 6,554,564 13,108,601 99 Public works 5,447,S84 7,352,5^2 34 Education 6,738,465 25,449,643 277 Sanitation 318,794 3,901,605 1,123 Pdor relief 21,672 39,679 83 Police 151,648 439,940 190 Industry 86,569 951,128 99 Public debts 242,204 4,876,784 1,938 Control of property 8,757 543,385 6,100 Taxes and other burdens 263,386 4,858,117 1,744 Miscellaneous 382,374 3,180,324 731 20,531.474 65,300,730 218 ^■5 Iii the interval of these ten years, the increase in the expendi- ture of the Imperial government was 219 per cent., almost the same as that in the local governin^nts which was 212 per cent- After the war with China (1895-1896) all attention was drawn to the enormous increase in the central expenditure which was lliought exceptional. The equally steady increase in local ex- penditure was neglected. The fact remains the same, how- ever, as indicated above, and shows the rapid increase and "he great importance of local finance. Section I. The Causes of tAe Increase in Expenditure. So far as the practical discussions of public finance are con- cerned, they must be confined to a particular country, be- cause no country has to confront exactly the same conditions as another. The administrative organization and regulations of finance depend in each country on the circumstances of that particular state. Let us now inquire how and why local Jap- anese budgets swell rapidly and steadily. (I). The Increase in Public Functions. As was already said in the previous chapter, the local gov- ernments have both original and delegated administrative func- tions. As in every civilized country, these functions increase with the growth and the development of the country.^ They may grow because of the increase of population, wealth, the progress of science, and the activity of the various depart- ments of human life altogether. These causes are almost irresistible. The national government can not of course take on all these increasing new functions and delegates some of them to the local governments. The local governments have, on the other hand, their own increasing mass of concerns to be taken care of. They manage, moreover, the delegated business of the Imperial and prefectural governments at their own ex- pense. We should remember that there are as yet untouched many local public affairs to be profitably managed, if the local ' Leroy-Beaulieu, Vol. I., p. 8. S6 financial resources suffice. Schools are crowded with children, the banks of rivers are too weak to protect lives and property against flood, and drainage works are far from satisfactory. Practically local governments in Japan now manage only such of their own affairs as are indispensably necessary. The in- crease * in the expenditure of Assemblies, buildings, and salar- ies shows the increase in the volume of public affairs. ( II ) . Self-government. If we consider self-government by itself — its own necessary tasks — ^there seems hardly any other alternative than to in- crease local expenditure. Local self-governing communities know and feel their own needs more keenly than those gov- erned from above. They control their own purse, but the in- centive is always strong at least over those men who are directly concerned with the administration to plan improve- ments of various kinds and to please the people of the district. This is the natural cause of the increase of expenditure. The system of self-government safeguards only the exorbitant ex- penditure of public money, but does not check the steady in- crease. This is another way of saying that expenditure is increased by the feeling of local pride.'' The local communi- ties think much of their independent position and try to take care of their welfare and are anxious not to be inferior in this respect to other communities. The wonderful increase in sani- tary and educational expenses reminds us how they augment their expenditure in order to facilitate the convenience of their own people. (III). Influence of Political Parties. Political parties appear necessarily, when the representative system is adopted, because there are, in every state of things, interests opposed to each other. If a government takes any * See the statistical tables quoted in page 5314. " Adams, Public Finance, p. 43-4. 57 step in administration, those who think it promotes their own interests approve and those who think their interests are dis- regarded constitute the opposition.* Some say that the system of self-government may be man- aged independent of political parties and is able to get a fair non-partisan adrhinistrationJ There is no warrant for this assertion, but on the contrary, in Japan at least, the evil of political parties is more felt in local communities than in the national administration.^ The evil can not be remedied simply by administrative organization, unless general education and the idea of civic responsibility on the part of people generally are better advanced. In the local communities of Japan, the government, as well as the people, always try to minimize the influence of political parties and to manage their public aflfairs in a fair manner with^ out giving place to partisanship. At the time of the first ses- sion of the Imperial Diet, Marquis Yamagata, then the premier, gave instruction ® to all local government officials to the effect that they should refrain from taking part in the work of political parties, because if they mingled with parties, all local communi- ties would become entangled in partisan agitation, a situation which would check the wholesome growth of ^the country. One of the important issues in the fourth session of the Diet, how- ever, was an appeal ^^ to the Emperor with reference to the interference of local officials at elections. They are said 16 have much favored the candidates of the government party. As is naturally the case with all political parties, they claim to economize expenditures and when not in power attack the policy of their opponents as wasteful and extravagant; but once in power, a party does not adhere to its program and ' Ariga, The Principle of Public Law, Vol. I., p. 346. ' Shimada, The Outline of Self-government, p. 24. ' Bastable, p. 392-3. How party spirit in a small area operates. ' Kudo, The History of Imperial Diet, Vol. I., p. 19. "Kudo, Vol. I., p. 240. S8 Spends public money to please certain portions of the people for whose benefit the expenditure is made. Party influence in Japan is always exerted through the representative assemblies in behalf of public works and education. The constructions of dykes, drainage, and other public works are generally closely associated with political corruption.^^ The estabUsh- ment of schools is the football of political parties. The final outcome is usually a compromise causing unnecessary expendi- ture. Reference to statistics given before will prove this assertion. ( IV) . Corruption. Closely related to party influence is the corruption of local governments. Fortunately in Japan we do not hear so much about administrative corruption as in other countries. It may not necessarily be that Japanese politicians have a higher moral standard than those of other countries, but it seems to me that in Japan the influence of political parties is as yet compara- tively not strong enough in local governments to entirely cor- rupt them, and the memory of feudal times still lingers in the minds of people who were educated for centuries in the pure spirit ^^ of feudal service to condemn political corruption. But in cities and prefectures where parties are becoming an influ- ence, we often see dishonest practices which must be carefully guarded against. (v.). Inefficient Administration. In rural communities it is naturally very hard to get efficient officials to manage public business. The important officials of cities, towns, and villages are elected from among the people, and the assemblies and councils are also elected bodies, though the prefectural officials and sheriffs are administrative officers properly appointed by the Imperial government. Locally ' Infra, page 78. ' See " Bushido," the famous work of Nitobe. 59 elected officials are generally inferior in their administrative abilities to those of the Imperial administration. This might account for the comparatively loose management of local ex- penditures. The easy custom of putting together all minor expenditures and revenues under "miscellaneous" seems to come from this source. It is greatly to be desired that more comprehensive and exact statistical details of local finances should be collected. ( VI ) . Industrialism. One of the most important influences in increasing local ex- penditures is undoubtedly industrialism. Since japan has opened her doors to foreign countries, modern industrialism has invaded the country. Schools have been established not only for general education, but for commercial and technical training, even in most of the rural communities. Highways have been improved and street railways and wharves have been constructed for the convenience of transportation. Subsidies have been granted by local communities to private railway companies to build stations. Experiment stations for seri- culture and agriculture have been founded. Waterways, gas and electric light plants and many other public works have all added to the aggregate of public expenditures by localities. After the war between Japan and China was over, the central government proclaimed a so-called "post-bellum programme" ^^ which gave an impetus to activity in every department of life. The example having been set by the central government, the local governments felt the impulse to a further extension of activities. The expenditures for education, public works and industry, and the increase of the public debts clearly indicate the trend. A few words will be added here to explain by far the greater increase of taxes specially in cities. Those of cities are largely the apportioned tax of prefectures which is used for various ' Kobayashi, Past and Present of Finance, Chap. IV., Sect. II. 60 city improvements under the care of the prefectural adminis- tration. It might therefore be included under this head. The taxes aiid burdens of towns and villages are larg'ely the ap- portioned tax of the counties whose statistics also iridicate the increase in this line of expendittire. City firlarice haS nothing to do with that of the counties. All thesfe causes stated above combined result in the increased expenditures. Section II. How the Increased Expenditure is Met. We next inquire, with what revenues the increased expendi- tures caused by these several influences just considered are met? They are met mostly by the revenues from the additional rates forming the surcharge on national and prefectural taxes, and by resort to public credit. The local additions to the national and prefectural taxes have their maximum limits, but the prac- tice to exceed these limits is so common that the Ministers of the Home and Finance departments regard it as the usual thing in the petitions from the local governments, and so sanc- tion this excess required to meet extra expenditure. The Im- perial revenue from the land tax in 1901 was 46,666,494 yen,^* and the additional tax levied by adding local rates thereto was altogether 37,315,970 yen. Thus the local rate amounts to 79 per cent, of the Imperial tax, while the maximum limit contettl- plated by law is 47 per cent. Resort to public credit is the common practice used extensively by local governments. The special taxes are not much used except in cities. The tables ^° already given present the situation, and I will omit further comment on them in order to proceed to consider each topic in detail. Section III. Reform of Local Finance. It is my intention to treat in this section each topic of local finance and express an opinion on each seriatim. Let me then examine in detail the problems which have been distussed and are still being discussed in this field. "Japan in the beginning of the twentieth century, p. 498. " See page supra 4314. (I). Expenditure for Prisons. It is contemplated that there shall be a sharp distinction be- tween central and local finance.i^ Certain duties being, how- ever, the province of either much complicates this division of function, and there often arises the question whether certain public business shall be managed by the Imperial government or by the local government. It would seem that any public function which is directly concerned' with the welfare of the whole country should be managed by the national govern- ment,^' and that thus a separation of local finance from the Imperial finance could be maintained. The question of ex- penditure on prisons was one of the most warmly debated issues for quite a long time in Japan. Though it may seem to have been a political question, yet it shows the difficulty of sharply drawing a distinction between the expenditures of the national and local governments. An appropriation bill providing for national expenditure upon prisons was first introduced into the House of Represen- tatives in the second session of the Diet by Count Matsukata, the Minister of the Finance department. He said, when it was introduced, that the revenues of local communities should in general be used so as to develop their productive efficiency, and that the expenditure upon prisons had formerly been paid from the central treasury and had been transferred in 1880 so as to burden local governments (prefectures) under the stress of financial necessity, but that now as Imperial finances had been put upon a sound basis; therefore it was to be regarded as a matter of course that this expenditure should be trans- ferred back to the Imperial government.^^ The government tried at this session (1891) every possible means to have the bill passed. The reasons given for it were : (a) by the very nature of the expenditure itself, it should fall ■ " Row-fugo, I^oqal Taxation in England, p. 283-5. "Row-Fugo, p. 30s. Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, Vol. II., Bk. I., Oiap. I., p. 402-3. BastaMe, p. 120. "Kudo, Vol. I., p. 102, 122. 62 on the national treasury ; (b) it was necessary in order to man- age the criminal administration impartially; and (c) to improve the prison management. It was, however, rejected by the House for the following reasons: first, that it would increase the total expenditure on prisons if paid by the central govern- ment; second, that there were more important public affairs to be taken in charge by the Imperial government, and because the time would again come soon when this item of expense would be transferred to local governments, even if it were paid for a time out of national treasury. The rejection of the bill was one of the causes of the dissolution of the Diet that year. It was rejected with an overwhelming majority in spite of the fact that the House did not deny the principle that the expenditure should be paid out of the national treasury. It would seem that this expenditure should fall naturally on the central government. As was remarked in the second chapter, the local government has no authority in connection with the judicial and police administration except to act as the auxiliary officials of the central government. Its administration further- more must be uniform throughout the country which can only be done by the central administration. It was not logical to oppose the assumption of this expenditure by the Imperial government. In principle this was recognized, but the natural inference was denied. Only the fact that it was used as a partisan issue will explain this financial anomaly. The bill was again introduced in the third session (1892) through the House of Peers which passed it with a great ma- jority, but it was rejected as before by the House of Repre- sentatives. In the fourth session (1892), it was introduced through the members of the government party in the lower house, but was once more rejected for the reason that the financial supply for it could not be found. When, in the thirteenth session (1898), the bill to increase the land tax from two and one-half per cent, of the land's value to four per cent, was introduced, the bill to transfer the prison expenditure from the local to the central government was brought in at the same time in order to decrease somewhat 63 local financial burdens. The land tax bill was amended so as to increase the rate to three and one-third per cent, and the government again could not find adequate financial supply for the prisons. The situation was entirely the outcome of polit- ical struggles. Constitutionalists who favored the increase of the land tax were very sensitive as to their own local political popularity, and tried to compensate for the increase of the tax by removing part of the burden of local governments. It is interesting to notice that the situation was so radically changed that Minister Matsukata, the original proposer of the measure, was now in opposition to it. After much discussion, the bill was sent to the House of Peers where it was this time rejected. In the next session (1899) it passed both Houses at last and was carried into effect October i, 1900.^° About four millions and a half yen is the sum total of the expenditure required and about one million of the sum is secured from the productive labour of the prisoners. However confused government functions in Japan originally were, after the recent treaties with foreign countries guaran- teeing to improve Japanese prisons through national action, it clearly indicates that after long controversy, there is now a clear distinction between national and local governmental functions.^* (II). Expenditure for Education. Colleges and universities, except private institutions, must be maintained by the central government, and so far there is no special difiiculty about them. When we come to general education, which we consider as one of the most important requirements for the citizen of constitutional governments, the question arises whether or not the expenditure shall be entirely paid by the local communities. It is equally important for every part of the country, and it seems almost self-evident that "Kudo, Vol. II., p. 238. '"Bastable, p. iii and 86. In England also, the prisons were trans- ferred from local to central management. 64 it ought to be paid by them. If, however, we adhere to the principle strictly, and do not help them at all, this important matter would be frequently neglected by reason of insvifificient ■local expenditure. It is so important that the country at large can not overlook it. Since the fifth session ( 1893) of the Diet, a bill was constantly introduced to give educational subsidies to cities, towns, and villages. It was not intended to give these subsidies for general educational purposes, but to give rewards to teachers who served more than a definite number of years. It did not of course satisfy the local needs and in the thirteenth session (1898), a system of compulsory and gratuitous in- struction giving larger subsidies to the local governments was contemplated.^^ The original measure, however, did not grant any definite sum nor indicate any available source of revenue to defray this charge, but the bill was finally changed so as to give local governments subsidies to the amount of one-tenth of the teachers' salaries, viz., 800,000 yen. It was anticipated that this would increase until the subsidy amounts to 4,000,000 yen yearly. An educational fund of 10,000,000 yen for general education was set apart from the Chinese indemnity, the interest of which, about 500,000 yen, is to be used for school expenses. The subsidy for elementary education was passed in the four- teenth session (1899), the estimate being 1,000,000 yen an- nually. A subsidy for technical schools was also advocated, and such bills have been passed several times. The annual sub- sidies for technical schools amount now to more than 250,000 yen. So far as local governments are unable to afford sufficient expenditure, the necessity for a subsidy from the central treas- ury for expenses which are of vital concern to the welfare of the country at large is not disputed.^^ The subsidy for tedir nical education is not so vital as that for elementary education, and is given chiefly through the influence of modern industriaL- 'Kudo, Vol. II., p. 124-5. ' Nitti, p. 716. 6s ism which recently swept over Japan. The grant of a subsidy has to be extremely guarded, for lavish grants have bad effects 2^ on local communities and make them dependent on the central government. (III). The Relief Fund.^'' The country is sometimes visited by extensive floods, earth- quakes, tidal waves, and other unexpected calamities. The Imperial government is ready to help people who have suffered by these calamities where their revenues from taxation have for the same cause diminished. At the time of Takugawa Shogunate, the local governors saved rice in normal years for the expected time of calamities, and the land tax was made to vary in rate according to the harvest. The law was revised in 1873 and the tax was fixed at a definite rate. This was diffi- cult to enforce, for people could not pay the whole tax in a bad year. In 1877, the regulation was made to allow people to pay the tax by installments when they suffered from calami- ties, but it could not produce satisfactory results ; because they were often driven to a worse condition by the increase of debt on the lands, and the lowered value of the lands. The first relief fund regulation was made in 1880 at the suggestion of Count Okuma. Prefectures must now save three per cent, of the land tax, that is to say, 1,200,000 yen an- nually, and the central government must give the annual sum of 1,200,000 yen, out of which 900,000 yen is distributed among prefectures and the rest kept in the central treasury. Annual prefectural incomes for the fund amounted to 2,100,000 yen, and annual payments therefrom were, supposed to be 700,000 yen, thus giving 1,400,000 yen as the net annual increase. The pne-half of the fund must be in kind and the other half in securities, These reserve funds can be used either to make good the diminished revenues, or to help the poor and the 'Row-Fogo, p. 283. ' History of Finance in Japan, Vol. X., Chap. III. 66 needy by giving them food, seedcorn, agricultural implements, and shelter. If a prefecture spends more than two-thirds of its reserve funds, it may draw the rest from the central fund. The practice was to have been continued for twenty years, but the fund so increased after ten years that the annual in- crease was suspended. Unfortunately soon after the revision of the law, there was a succession of calamities which almost depleted the fund. A new law was again passed in 1899, by which the central fund was transferred to the general account, and only pre- fectures were required to raise annual sums for this purpose, whose minimum amount was 500,000 yen by means of a rate not to exceed three per cent, of the direct national taxes. The central treasury must distribute among the prefectures 300,000 yen annually for ten years. If prefectures spend more than five per cent, of their funds, the central treasury must give one- third of excess amount. In 1887, there was a great earthquake in two prefectures, and the Imperial government drew 2,250,000 yen from the surplus of the general account to save the woe-stricken people. This action proved to be of importance from a constitutional standpoint and served as one cause for the eventual dissolution of the Diet. In 1899, 10,000,000 yen were set apart from the Chinese indemnity as the relief fund whose interest only can be used. Though the action ^° in 1887 was once looked upon as a seri- ous question, it seems to me that it was so rather in its con- stitutional or political aspect. There is no special difficulty or weighty objection against the fund itself. It is to be earnestly desired that every prefecture shall manage its affairs independ- ent of the central government. Nevertheless, the suffering of any part of the country is of direct concern to the country as a whole. To give the subsidy is one beneficient method of ''"The action strictly was unconstitutional. The Constitutional Law of Japan, article 64. 67 mutual insurance among the component parts of the nation, for the subsidy is, it can be said, subscribed from all parts of the country through the central treasury. The attempt to fix the land tax at a uniform annual rate, no matter what the condition of the harvest may be, is somewhat instructive ; because it put upon the people the responsibility of being prudent in the time of good harvests. People who have little foresight suffer always, and in this respect markedly. To give relief in kind is a good practice and avoids extrava- gant demands for aid. The physical situation of Japan has always much to do with floods and earthquakes ; and granting the subsidy is unavoidable. The law providing for relief in calamity has in view only the agricultural class, but it seems to me that there is no reason to single out this class from others for aid of this kind. We admit that they form the largest part of the population, yet the rest are no less entitled to ask the same assistance in time of similar need. {IV) . Expenditure for the Construction of Dykes and Harbors. At the second session (1891) of the Diet, Count Matsukata, then premier, said: protection from flood is very important, for it concerns the lives and property of the people. If it be delayed one year, it would inflict ten years' damage. There- fore the government increased this expenditure and investi- gated the proper amount uniformly required throughout the country to complete the works of constructing dykes. The bill as introduced gave subsidies to four prefectures. The House of Representatives approved it after cutting the appro- priation down, but the Diet was dissolved before the House of Peers had approved the measure. The government then issued an Imperial ordinance authorizing the expenditure on the chance of getting legislative sanction in the following ses- ;;ion. This again gave rise to much discussion as to its con- stitutionality. In the next session, the Diet approved this action. Since then the central government has given the sr^b- sidy every year. 68 Owing to the peculiar physical situation of Japan, the pi^viks of rivers often overflow and destroy lives and property. It is not only in the interest of the local communities, but of the country at large to construct strong dykes or banks to prevent this annual loss. At every session of the Diet, we hear much about it, and pomplaints of dishonest dealings of officials con- cerned. It is not a good plan at all to construct cheap tem- porary works. It is far more economical and important to invest once for all a sufficient sum of money to make under careful supervision strong and permanent works. The construction of harbors is more strictly a national pur- pose than any other public work. It is undertaken by a local government or a municipality; because the harbor happens to be situated in a locality which can draw great advantage from it, and can administer it carefully.^" K we consider the future development in trade specially in the trans-oceanic trade, we can not deny the justification for this subsidy. Yokohama, Nagasaki, and Osaka were given subsidies of 300,000 ; 800,000, and 4,600,000 yen respectively.^'' The mere accident that any work is situated in any particular part of the country is no weighty reason to impose the expendi- ture on the local government. There may not be the same economy as regards the whole amount of the expenditure, but this plan can prevent undue hardship which might fall other- wise on any particular locality. This plan divides the burden more fairly by distributing it over the whole country. The government has given Kobe and Hakodate subsidies for water supply works. This is entirely a local purpose having no direct concern with the state as a whole. It was a misuse of the subsidy for which no good reason whatever can be given. " Concerning the minute supervision of local govertjments see Bastable, p. 120. " These subsidies are here expressed in sum total given, 1897-1901. eg (V). The Land Tax. It may seem to go beyond the subject of local finance to dis- cuss the national land tax, for this study is intended primarily to investigate the public finance of local governments. The national land tax is so closely related, however, to the local tax that it is necessary to give here a short outline of the nature of the national land tax and an opinion about it in connection with local finance. At present, it is pne of the most important national and local sources of revenues.^* Being so important a source of revenue to the central treasury, it is almost out of question at least in our generation to think of turning it over entirely into the hands of local governments,^" however desirable it may be. From ancient times down to the present day, the tax on lands has always been the most important tax and especially so dur- ing the feudal regime (i 185-1867). All the time during the Tokugawa Shogunate, this land tax furnished the greater part of tne revenue. Since the Meiji restoration (1867), owing to the increase of expenditure, many other direct and indirect taxes were introduced, but it is still the dominant one, even though its yield has decreased proportionally compared with other taxes which have increased rapidly. An Imperial regu- lation was made in 1873 to set the rate of the tax at three per cent, of the capital value of lands estimated at the market price, and f)ayment was required in money instead of in kind. In 1875, the national and local taxes were separated, the latter levied entirely for local purposes. The national land tax rate was reduced in 1877 to two and one-half per cent., and the local rate was not to exceed one-fifth of the national rate. After the war between Japan and China, expenditure in- creased with leaps and bounds, and in consequence the tax rate was again raised to three and three-tenths per cent. City lots " See pagfe silpra 43i4- ^ Cdnderriihg PrtiSsiaH tax rfefdtffl in tHe pointy see Wagtierj Fihanz- wessenschaft. Vol. IV., 91-97- 70 were at this time first separated from other lands and taxed at the rate of five per cent.*" The new rates were to be in force for only five years beginning in 1899. The distinction between the national rate of the tax and the local rate was not clear until 1873. In 1872, three per cent, of the amount collected by local governments was given to the local governments for their expenses of collecting the national tax. There followed several changes; sometimes it was left free to local communities to add such additional rates to the tax as they pleased ; sometimes the additional local rate was limited so as not to exceed one-third or one-fifth of the national tax rate. The local land taxes are now used to pay the general expenses of local governments ; and in 1888, the prefectural rate of one- third of the national rate, and the city, town, and village rate of one-seventh of the national rate were fixed. The maximum limit, however, is constantly exceeded by local governments. The value of lands is even now based on their supposed market price in 1872. At first it was intended to adjust the value as nearly as possible to the market price and to appraise the land every five years, or at least every ten years.'^ If it had been done, the tax would have been fairer. During more than twenty years, however, the actual market value of lands has changed remarkably, some lands rising five or ten times their original value, while other lands have declined by virtue of different circumstances of social evolution. The public demand for revaluation became so loud that the government was oftentimes obliged to heed it partially. An amendment was made, however, not basing valuation on the new market price of land, but raising some valuations, lowering others and keep- ing most valuations as they were originally. A great difference between the assessed value of lands and their actual value still persists. The former assessed valuation is now nothing more than a mere nominal standard for assessment. ™ History of Finance in Japan, Vol. V., Chap. I., Sect. III. " Concerning valuation of land in France, see Leroy-Beaulieu, Vol. I., p. 344- 71 Let us pause here to inquire into the nature of the tax on the assessed value at present. The first registered value was intended to be based on the actual market price, but in reality there was a definite rule to determine this price. The orig- inal formula to compute for tax purposes the capital value of lands cultivated by their owners was as follows : < value of gross pro- _ / ^j^^ „f ^^^^^ _^ fertilizer per \ ) capital i duce per unit of land \ unit of land / ) value of Rate of national , prevailing rate of in- land per and local tax terest assumed at 6% unit, or, to put it concretely in figtires, (4-80- .72) X 100^ ^ (3 + I) + 6 The formula was a close estimate, when it was in use, of the value of average land. An average harvest of rice raised on one Tan ^^ will be one Koku ^^ and six To,^^ and the usual price of one Koku ranged about three yen. Thus one Tan would raise rice worth 4.80 yen. Fifteen per cent, of the value of the gross produce, that is, .72 yen, is always deducted as the expense for seeds and fertilizer. In the denominator of the formula 3 represents the Imperial land tax rate, i the local land tax rate and 6 the assumed prevailing rate of inter- est. This formula would make rice land have a capital value per Tan of 40.80 yen, and this is the basis for assessment. The local rate is one-third of the national rate. Four per cent, tax on 40.80 gives 1.63.2 yen, the total tax of which 1.22,4 goes to the national treasury. If the tax and the expense for seeds and fertilizer be deducted from the value of the gross produce, there remains 2.44,8 yen per Tan as income to the cultivator. This is capitalized at 6 per cent, and consequently 40.80 yen is the capital value of the land per Tan. The formula is far from accurate to-day. Anybody can see that the expense of produc- tion ought to include more than seeds and fertilizer. The government intended obviously to impose the tax on the net " Tan = about i of an acre. "Koku = 5-13 Bushels. " To = The tenth of Koku. 72 income of the land. The faet that the expense of production is always fixed at fifteen per cent, of the value of the gross produce defeated this purpose, and the tax unmistakably fell on a percentage of the value of the gross produce. The reform of this tax is one of the most important political and financial issues that must be solved ere long. A well-known economist^" attacks the tax on the ground that it is unfair when compared with the income tax. It seems to me that the tax system is so complex that it can not be easily compared with any one tax like an income tax. It is rigorously attacked by a promising young newspaper econo- mist ^° from three points of view: (i) its injustice; (2) its being a tax on capital rather than income, and (3) on account of its lack of elasticity. His proposal is to remove the national land tax entirely and to give the tax to the local governments as one of their financial resources. I dare say we can not expect that all taxes shall be in exact accordance with justice, to say nothing about the ambiguity of the term justice itself ; for there are other circumstances to take into consideration, even if justice in taxation is very desirable indeed. The tax on capital is not a bad thing, if it be paid out of income. Elasticity is desirable, but certainty in securing revenue is also desirable. If the tax can be transferred to the local governments, the great question of local finance would be solved smoothly. We are not at liberty, however, to entertain dreams, or ideal projects. It is inconceivable that so important a source of national rev- enue as the land tax can be surrendered by the central govern- ment without embarrassment. The only solution I know of is to revalue the land, reduce the rate of the national land tax, and allow an increase in the rate on it for the local governments.'^ All desirable conditions "^ The Oriental Economist, No. 92* p. 3. An article on the increase of tax rate by Prof. Amano. "Mr. Enjoji, The Abolition of Land Tax, pp. 4-15. " The Oriental Economist, No. 57, p. 8 and Discussion of Land Tax^ by Viscount Tani and Dr. Taguchi, Vol. L, p. 27^ 57. 73 will be fulfilled only in this way. The revaluation will make the tax fair. The earnest desire of the people to reduce its rate will be realized. Other national taxes, especially indirect taxes, will increase the national revenues every year and make up the deficit resulting from a decreased land tax. Thus the national government will depend more on indirect taxes and the local governments on direct taxes.^^ Finally the local gov- ernments can thus get sufficient financial resources. (VI). The Special Taxes. In a previous chapter, I explained the nature of local taxes ; and pointed out that the local tax revenues in Japan came mostly from the surtax added to taxes originally imposed by the state and sometimes by the prefectures. Some say the local and central taxes must be separated.^' It seems to me that this is almost impossible, at least in local finance in Japan. Having great difficulty in imposing local indirect taxes, the important objects of local taxation must still be lands, buildings, incomes and business, all of which are the bases of national taxes. It is, therefore, easy and safe to im- pose the local additional tax on these four bases for the reason that the expenses of collection of the local tax are less than those of special local taxes ; for there is no trouble in selecting and appraising the objects of taxation. It will also generally assure a fairer and juster burden of taxation than special local taxes ; for the national and sometimes the pref ectural taxes on which the local additional rate is imposed are usually collected after the most careful consideration.*" In spite of these disadvantages, the special local taxes have certain advantages of their own in that they can impose the tax burden on objects which escape national or sometimes the "See Leroy-Beaulieu, Vol. I., p. 710. Nitti, p. 705, concerning the same tendency in France. ■" The Oriental Economist, No. 57, p. 7- " See Bastable, p. 407, for a discussion of this point. 74 pfefectural taxes, and thus remedy the unfair distribution of taxation, without overburdening the same financial resources employed by other higher grades of government. On the other hand, the additional local rate upon national and prefectural taxes has its disadvantages. If it is superimposed on the national or sometimes on the prefectural taxes v/hich are already imposing on the people an undue pressure of taxa- tion, it will make the pressure *^ intolerable. It falls now mostly on the agricultural class, therefore, those communities whose people live from fishing and hunting have great diffi- culty in obtaining their revenues, thus imposing an undue tax burden on this small section of the people. In such cases, the special local taxes are preferable to the local additional rate on national or prefectural taxes. According to the Civic Corporation Acts, local governments in Japan may resort to both kinds of taxes, but, as has been shown, the special taxes amount to very little comparatively.*" There may be many circumstances which give rise to dififerent varieties of special taxes on account of the different economic conditions of various localities ; and there is still plenty of room for special local taxes to be opened up. (VII). Public Property (Dbmains). In the second chapter, it was said that the local governments, especially of towns and villages, are supposed to pay their ex- penditure first out of the income of their public properties. In practice, they depend, however, chiefly on the revenues coming from their different taxes and from the resort to public credit This is because they do not own properties which give them sufficient incomes. Though it is a little encouraging to see that the revenues from public properties in cities, and in towns and villages increased 88 per cent, and 156 per cent, respect- " Leroy-Beaulieu, Vol. I., p. 710. "See page supra 44. The English rate has a resemblance to our :special taxes. See Row-Fogo, Part I., Chap. II., The Poor Rate. 75 ively during the ten years from 1891 to 1901, these receipts reach only three and two per cent, respectively of their total revenues, while the revenues from the prefectural property comprise only a part of the miscellaneous receipts. We must remember, too, that the expenditures for managing these pub- lic properties are increasing rapidly. Tl;e reasons why the local governments do not have large public properties can be found in an analysis of events at the time of the restoration (1867). At that time, all domains of the feudal lords were vested in the Emperor and all titles to lands, mountains, forests, and swamps together with other property were vested in the new Meiji government. The spirit of local self-government was then not strong, and the minds of men of public affairs were absorbed in the matter of central administration. The ownership of lands except those in pri- vate possession became the state's. Proclamation No. 120 in 1874 (concerning the vesting of titles to lands) included all lands which were not private lands in the public domain of the state. It recognized to a certain extent the local communal ownership of lands occupied by schools, hospitals, public store- houses, shrines and temples, and of pastures used in common by private individuals, or by one or several communities. The area occupied by schools, hospitals, and other similar institu- tions is not at all large. Only the profitable pastures were owned by the people of the villages for their common use. When the system of local self-government was first introduced, the local communities thereupon had no public property of their own, except the common pastures which had been held by their people.*^ Not all of the villages have these common pastures, and some of the villages have pastures common to only a part of the villagers, and such partly common pastures could not be transferred to the villages as public property. If the local gov- ernments want to obtain public properties, there is no other way than to get them donated from the Imperial domain, or to buy them from private people out of the proceeds of local taxes. 'Oda, Administrative Law, p. 8S9- 76 The local governments of Japan have a different history from European countries where the local governments gener- ally possess property and resources. Thus it is not surprising at all to find that our local governments depend mostly on taxes. It is desirable, indeed, that the local governments have their own properties and put their finance on a sound basis. The Civic Corporation Acts recognized the importance of such public properties and made their management subject to care- ful supervision from above. For the purpose of permanent revenues, lands are far preferable to any other form of public property. Securities are easily transferable and may be sold by local governments to the disadvantage of the community, and their price and income are not steady as are the price and income of lands. The only way left open to local governments to augment this public property is to secure a transfer of the government for- ests to them.** The central government owns the extensive area of 13,078,505 cho *" of forests and fields whose revenues, owing to the inefficient management, are only 2,744,249 yen. If some parts of them be transferred to the local governments, the local governments will secure good financial resources, and will probably control these tracts efficiently through careful administration. These domains would not give a large profit in the near future, but will prove a lucrative source of revenue after the lapse of a certain period of time. The local govern- ments can reasonably undertake to manage them, for govern- ments live considerably longer than individuals, even though they may not enjoy perpetual existence. Forestry is not a speculative venture, and the forest properties can not easily be transferred from public ownership. It may be objected to the plan that the forests can only profit- ably be controlled by the state which has a permanent policy." Here the geographical features of the country should be con- " The Oriental Economist, No. 57, p. 10. " One cho = Ten Tan and one Tan to i of an acre. " Bastable, p. 190. 77 sidered. A country like Japan whose forests extend far and wide can safely transfer the comparatively unimportant forests to the local governments. For those communities not contiguous to tracts of public forests, there is another way to increase their public properties. It may be through the construction of profitable public works, or through the increase of securities held, but it is impossible here to give a definite plan for each one of them. (VIII.). The Ownership of Natural Monopolies. There is scarcely a question which has recently been dis- cussed so much as the ownership of natural monopolies. It falls within the scope of local finance, only when it specially concerns municipal monopolies, though it is not by itself so much a question of local finance as a question of economics and the technical management of public industries. It is not my intention to discuss this question in its entirety, but simply to consider its financial side. Cities, towns, or sometimes villages must be very careful in undertaking such public works ;" because if they fail, they will greatly hamper their finances. But there are many monopolies which are very profitable indeed. If they are certain to give fair profits, public authorities had better undertake their man- agement; because, by the public management, the unearned increment which is yielded by monopolies and which increases the income of comparatively few private people can be absorbed to the government and used for the general interest of the peo- ple. Furthermore, the actual condition in Japan favours the government work. The nature of the government is paternal, and people depend on the government, which itself always tries to guide the people. There is, therefore, scarcely any difference between government and private business in the effec- tiveness of management. It might be said that when they are managed by public authorities, they will not give the same profits as if they were in private hands ; for public authorities *' Whinery, Municipal Public Works, Chap. XIV. 78 are very slow to adopt new inventions and slow to improve the management so as to reduce operating expenses.** The ex- perience of the central government in Japan with railways and the postal service however bids fair to be successful, and there would seem to be not much fear that local authorities would not be equally successful. The rapid increase of city population will undoubtedly neces- sitate the building of different public works.** Cities must not hesitate to undertake them themselves, when the profits are certain. They will thus get increasing revenues every year. Such public works in Japan are not yet constructed extensively except in a few cities. The street cars are operated by private companies on condition that the cities may purchase them after a certain number of years.^". Japan will get in this respect information from the experi- ence of other countries, for Japan is just on the way to make a beginning here. (IX). Public Debts (Local Governments) . One of the most important topics of local finance is the in- crease of local public debts.^^ Their rapid increase is due mostly to constructing roads, dykes, wharves, waterways, and other public works.°^ Generally speaking, local public debts are raised chiefly for industrial purposes in contrast to the national debts which are largely raised for the national defence. "Daniels, Public Finance, p. 271-272. "Daniels, Public Finance, p. 267. "^ Thirty years in Tokio. " See page supra 31, 33, 42-3. ""The same thing holds true in England. See S. H. Blunden, Local Taxation and Finance, p. 19. 79 These local public debts are also due to the increase of the city population.'^ The distribution of urban and rural population of Japan in 1886, 1893,1897, and 1903 is as follows: " Year. Urban Pop. Ratio. Rural Pop. Ratio 1886 4,990,960 12.5 34,168,731 87-5 1893 6,522,994 157 34,865,319 84.3 1897 7.384,160 17.0 35,844,703 83.0 1903 9.348,616 20.0 37,384,225 80.0 increase 4,448,656 7-5 3,215,494 *7.5 * decrease. Cities must undertake various improvements to accommodate this increase. But the increasing population is largely made up of labourers who can not pay direct taxes,'*' and thus the burden of increasing expenditure falls on the well-to-do popu- lation who are also unable to bear an unlimited increase of taxes. Inventions, the progress of science, and the develop- ment of self-governing communities are other causes which combine to augment local public debts. As often remarked, the contracting of public debts ought to be carefully guarded ; because they may easily be misused and leave the burden to future generations which have their own affairs to care for. There are several methods to check the debt increase: (i) limiting the total amount of debts by law ;°' (2) limiting the debt to a percentage of the local property; " (3) limiting the pur- poses for which local debts may be contracted; (4) by requir- ing popular approval;'' (5) by providing supervision by the higher administrative offices. The third and last methods are employed in 'Japan. Formerly the term of prefectural debts " Adams, Public Debts, p. 348. " Daily Consular Report, No. 2239. '" Adams, Public Debts, p. 353. '" Adams, Public Debts, p. 378-9. " Bryce, Vol. I., p. 688-9. " Adams, p. 379- 8o was limited to thirty years, but now the superintending offices consider the different circumstances and give the final sanction to all necessary details with better results. The most desirable reform concerning local public debts in Japan would be to require the Imperial government to act as in- termediate agent"" in contracting the loan. Local governments are naturally situated in a disadvantageous position in borrow- ing; because their credit is comparatively low and the amount of the money needed is usually small, so that the interest on small blocks of local bonds is higher and the price realized lower than if the loan were contracted by the Impedial government and charged to the various localities. Local public debts can not be used as security for private loans; because banks prefer securities like Imperial bonds which are more readily saleable; but local bonds are bought only for the purpose of investment or saving ; for there is no fear of repudiation and the rate of interest is high, sometimes 2 per cent, higher than on Imperial bonds. If local bonds are to serve as security for loans, their interest should be payable everywhere throughout the country. The most important thing, however, is the lower rate of interest obtainable through central loans. The national government therefore ought, in its own name, to borrow the money required by local govern- ments. Thus the rate of interest will be lowered,"" and the debts will become universally negotiable, because they would be practically identical with national bonds. Some might advance the opinion that the central government instead of taking such measures had better prescribe for the local governments a uniform type of bond to be sold for local purposes.*^ This uniformity would make such bonds more widely negotiable. Thus when we had about 150 national banks in Japan, they issued a uniform paper currency and the 'This is English system. See Blunden, p. 19. Bastable, p. 717-8. ° See page supra 42. 'Taguchi, Public Finance and Money Market, 7th Ed., p. 152. 8i result was good. For the local debts, however, this uniform- ity would not insure as favorable terms of interest as if the central government itself undertook to place the loan. (X). The Abolition of Counties. The reason given for creating the counties that some public affairs which are too extensive for towns and villages, and too narrow for the prefecture to manage ought to be conducted by an intermediate grade of government would appear well grounded. To-day, however, we have an elaborate system of transportation and distances consequently are reduced so re- markably that there is no need to have two grades of govern- ment below the prefecture.*^ The latter together with cities, towns, and villages can manage all local public business di- rectly. Even under the present system, cities have no admin- istrative relation to counties and the chief officials of towns and villages usually go more often to the prefectural office than to the country office and conduct administrative business with the former. If any public business is too extensive for a single town or village, the Civic Corporation Acts allow the town or village to combine with others in order to conduct the business jointly. A promising young statesman recently proposed to make prefectures larger and to reduce their number.®* It will prob- ably be done eventually, if it becomes practicable. Generally people are always inclined to preserve their own prefecture and oppose the agitation for the change as likely to create much trouble and expenditure. It seems to me that it is far easier and more economical to abolish counties first than to reduce the number of prefectures. There is no public business, whether it be education, industry, or public works which can not be con- veniently administered either by prefectures, or by towns or "Rathbone Local Government and Taxation, p. loo-ioi. See in- teresting condition existed in England and author's idea to have only two classes of local administration. "Mr. Enjoji, The Reform in Finance, p. 51. 8z villages. This change would save the greater part of the annual expenditure ^* of counties, whose revenue could be used more effectively than now. If counties can not be abolished entirely, the right of self- government ought to be taken away from them, because their public affairs are not so important as to require a separate unit of self-government. The county expenditure will thus be saved and county offices will remain simply as administrative intermediaries between the prefecture and the rural communi- ties. (XI). The Combination of Rural Communities. The boundaries of rural communities were, as has been seen in the first chapter, fixed soitnewhat artificially to a certain extent as a consequence of the laws (1888-1889).^° Rural ad- ministrative divisions in Japan are in this respect somewhat different from those in European counitries where local self- government was the natural outgrowth of a local community of interests. The Civic Corporation Act (1888), therefore, provides that they may combine to manage certain public affairs jointly whenever they think it convenient.*® But it seems to me that this is not satisfactory, for each of these combining communi- tieis still keeps its own official establishment and does not lose its corporate character, with the result that the total expenditure can not thus be reduced much. There seems to be a consensus of opinion that there is not a small number of local communities which are too small and weak to keep up their corporate financial character."' These communities ought to join other communities, or be combined together to all intents and purposes. As communities become larger, the number of local self-governments will become " See page supra 47. " See page supra 5. '" See page supra 13. "Shimada, Outline of Local Self-government, p. 119. 83 smaller, and thus economy in their expenditure can be secured. By so doing, schools can be established more easily, better pub- lic works can be constructed, the means of transportation will be more systematically administered, and the spread of con- tagious diseases can be more effectually checked. People are generally conservative about the change of the local division, and often object to it. There is, however, no special legal difficulty about it, for the law authorizes the Pre- fectural Councils to effect the combination of rural communi- ties even in spite of local objection."^ (XII). Strict Administrative Supervision from Above. The last financial device to be specially recommended is strict administrative supervision °* over the local governments. Some might say that it is contrary to the idea of self-govern- ment that other higher authorities should have power over local communities. It seems to me that it is rather desirable when we keep in mind two facts. First, the higher administra- tive offices have, generally speaking, more intelligent and en- lightened officials than the lowest self-governing bodies. Sec- ondly, the local self-governing bodies are parts of state and their welfare has an important relation to the country as a whole. We may assume that they can get sound advice from the higher authorities who look at local affairs from the stand- point of the general interest. There is, threfore, no special fear of their not getting wise direction. In this respect, there is no unsurmountable objection, so far as the law is concerned, inasmuch as the right of supervision over local affairs vests in the officials of the higher grades of government.'"' " See page supra 13. ™ Concerning control in local finance in different countries, see Bastable, p. 763-4. '" See page supra 9, 11, 17. 84 CHAPTER IV. Conclusion. It seems generally the case that in Japan laws and regula- tions are made first in anticipation of circumstances to be met with subsequently. This is often for the reason that when- ever laws and regulations are going to be made, the officials first study the systems of advanced countries and adopt the best part of them in spite of the different conditions prevailing in Japan. Consequently such laws prove impracticable and are often amended or repealed. Laws and regulations concerning the local governments are no exception. Japan has now out- grown this imitative stage, and the practice would seem now to belong to the past. She must consider her circumstances her- self and make from the beginning laws and regulations which are best suitable to her conditions. The difficulty in local finance seems to be the increasing ex- penditures and the insufficient revenues. The tendency is universal and almost unavoidable. The increase of expendi- tures is not by itself a bad thing, if the money is used properly. Therefore, this thesis, keeping in view the need of checking the increase of unnecessary expenditures, has paid much more careful attention to the question how to promote eflfectively wisdom in local public outlay. A few reforms I have suggested in this paper will do some good in local finance, if they are faithfully followed. It is very satisfactory to me to learn of the strong public opinion for the abolition of counties recently expressed at home. This thesis so far has avoided a discussion of the effects of the Japanese-Russian war on public finance, because war is an abnormal condition and its eventual effects can not yet be predicted. But one noticeable effect of the war is the decrease in incurring local public debts and a lessened expenditure by the local governments. Local public debts at the end of 1904 had decreased by 2,209,239 yen since the end of 1903. This is due to economy of expenditure and the suspension of public works. Now, after the conclusion of the war, they will again 8s increase their expenditure perhaps more rapidly than ever. It is a time when care in this respect is specially needed. The best possible policy of local finance is the wisest possible use of public revenues, affording the largest possible utility to the communities concerned. 86 APPENDIX. Extracts from the " Fifth Financial and Economical Annual of Japan," which has just been received, are as follows : I. Prefectures. Revenue. Fiscal year. Taxes. Receipts from other sources. Total. Expenditure. igoo-oi 1901-02 1902-03 . ... ig03-04 1904-05 ..... Yen. 39.854.281 43.155.568 46.596.334 39.72g.2g4 32.382 021 Yen. 1g.01g.408 15.565.954 17.605.705 g.322.4gg 8.439.984 Yen. 58.873-689 58.721.522 64.202.039 49.051-793 40.822,005 Yen. 52.022.567 52.478.449 56.578.790 49.073.420 40.797.153 II. Cities. Revenue. Fiscal Year. Taxes. Receipts from other sources. Total. Exprnditure. igoo-oi 1901-02 1902-03 Yen. 9.629.522 10.924. 78g II. 371-884 Yen. 14.744.134 17.407.655 20.457.691 Yen. 24.373.656 28.332.444 31.82g.575 Yen. 19.043,701 22.112.079 25.986.669 III. Towns and Villages. Revenue. Fiscal Year. Taxes. Receipts from other sources. Total. Expenditure. igoo-oi 1901-02 1902-03 Yen. 37.845.856 44.246.131 47.230.631 Yen. ' 24.423.936 26.070.47g 26.585-533 Yen. 62.26g.792 70.316.610 73-816.164 Yen. 58,000.025 65.300.730 68.413.024 The figures for the fiscal years 1903-1904 and 1904-1905 represent the estimates in the budget, and those for all other fiscal years settled accounts. 87 IV. Amount of Local Loans. At the end of 1900 . . 1901 . 1902 . 1903 . . 1904 . - Prefectures. Counties. Gities. Towns. Villages. Yen. 9.719-983 10.379.664 10.712.864 12.076.497 11.318.655 Yen. 135 613 339-548 509.588 890.045 854.914 Yen. 25.849.033 29.796.663 35-122 817 37 934-437 39318.446 Yen. 266.624 400.514 521.221 791.515 881.999 Yen. 562.872 1.116.940 1.463.028 1.808.237 1. 811. 077 V. Local Loans Classified According to the Objects FOR which they WERE RAISED. At the •end of 1900 . 1901 . 1902 . 1903 . 1904 . Education Sanitation. Industry. Public Works. Redemption of Old 1-oans. Others Yen. 336.456 1.624.656 1.757.688 2.396,234 2.078.801 Yen. 80.740 18.144 56.585 9.787-416 10.662.220 Yen. 285.942 477-797 303.464 2.577.126 3.596.046 Yen. 36.811.443 41.365164 47-946-674 31-847-757 38,430.082 Yen. 208.892 235-045 331-447 1-973-307 2.516.735 Yen. 7. 964. 41 1 107.214 VI. Loans of Cities Issued Abroad. Cities. Name of Loans. Amount Authorized. Amount Issued. Amount not yet issued. Osaka Harbour-Works Loan. Yokohama Water- Works Loan Kob^ Do. Total Yen. 17.038.000 2.055.600 Additions! issue x.940.000 21.033.600 Yen. ( Internal Loan 13. 538. 000 ( Foreign Loan 3.5.0.000 \ Do. I-ISS.600 r 900.000 J Do 1.690.000 t 250.000 \ Do. 16-383.600 I 4 650.000 VII. Loans of Cities Issued Abroad (Continued). Internal Loans. Foreign Loans. Cities. Rate of Interest Average price offered. (Per 100 Yen of face value.) Rate of Interest Price at which the bonds were taken up by underwriters. (Per 100 Yen of face value.) Price at which the bonds were sold in the Foreign market. (Per 100 Yen of face value.) Yokohama Kobi Total 6 per ct. 6 per ct. 6 per ct. 6 per ct. Yen. 9!»-3" 93.70 90.00 92.20 6 per ct. 6 per ct. 6 per ct. 6 per ct. Yen 96.50 90.00 92.00 (average) 92-80 Yen. 99.00 98.00 Unknown (average) 98 50 88 VIII. Loans of Local Associations. At the end of Yen. At the end of Yen. At the end of Yen. igoo .... 1903 .... I.I95-345 2.S16.820 1901 . . 1904 . . 1.687.674 2.677-307 1902 . . 2.058.913 Imperial expenditures for prefectures and Okinawa and Hokkukaido were as follows: 1897 13,456,727 1898 12,524,969 1899 15-505.513 1900 12,114,407 1901 11,880,243 1902 • . . .14,079.395 These figures include the salaries and travelling expenses of the officials of Prefectures, who are appointed by the Imperial government, and also the expenses for buildings, police, and others. 89 BIBLIOGRAPHY. Only books referred to in the footnotes are mentioned here. Adams, H. C. Science of Finance. New York. 1899. Adams, H. C. Public Debts. London. 1888. Ariga, N. The Principle of Public Law. Tokio. 1902. Bastable, C. F. Public Finance. London. 1903. Blunden, G. H. Local Taxation and Finance. London. 1895. Bryce, J. The American Commonwealth. New York. 1895. Budget of Shiga Prefecture in 1905. Budget of Ika County of Shiga Prefecture in 1905. DowELL, S. History of Taxation and Taxes in England. London. 1884. Daniels, W. M. Public Finance New York. 1899. Daily Consular Report. No. 2239. 1905. DuRAND, E. D. The Finances of New York City. New York. 1898. Enjoji, K. The Abolition of Land Tax. Tokio. 1903. Enjoji, K. Reform of Finance. Tokio. 1903. Goschen, G. J. Local Taxation. London. 1872. History of Finance in Japan, published by the Association of History of Finance in Japan. Tokio. 1904-1905. History of the Empire of Japan, by Japanese Commissioners to the Chicago World's Fair. Tokio. 1893. HosoNO, L The Past and Future of City of Tokio. Tokio. 1902. HozuMi, H. Imperial Constitution. Lectures given in the Tokio Imperial University. KobayashI, U. Past and Present of Finance. Tokio. 1902. Kudo, J. The History of Imperial Diet. Tokio. 1902. Leroy-Beaulieu, p. Traite de la Science des Finance. Cinquieme Edition. Paris. 1892. Lowell, A. L. Governments and Parties in Continental Europe. Boston. 1896. MiNOBE, T. Prefectural and County Law. Tokio. 1899. NiTTi, F. S. Principes de la Science des Finances. Traduction Frangaise de J. Chamard. Paris. 1904. NiTosi, I. Bushido, the Soul of Japan. Tokio. 1900. Oda, M. Administrative Law. Tokio. 1898. Ogino, Y. The History of Japan. Tokio. 1899. Oriental Economist. Nos. 57. 92. Tokio. 1897. 1898. Publications of American Statistical Association. Vol. I. Boston. 1889. Rathbone, W. Local Government and Taxation. London. 1892. Report of Kanagawa Prefecture in 1903. Row-FoGO, J. Local Taxation in England. London. 1902. Seligman, E. R. a. Essays in Taxation. New York. 1900. so ShimadAj T. The Outline of Self-Government. Tokio. 1901. Shimamura, T. The Outline of Local Administration. Tokio. 1904. Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. Oxford. 1880. Statistical Report, published by the Statistical Bureau of Imperial Government. Nos. 17. 23. Tokio. 1898. 1904. Tajiri, I. Public Finance and Money Market. Seventh Edition. Tokio. 1903. • Tani and Taguchi. Discussion of Land Tax. Tokio. 1899, UcHiKAWA, Y. The Land Dictionary. Tokio. 1904. Wagner, A. Finanzwissenschaft. Leipzig. 1889. W^iNEEY, S. Municipal Public Works. New York. 1903. Yamawaki, H. Japan in the Beginning of the Twentieth Century. HJ 9570.H36 " """"""^ '""'"'>' """lllllilliffiiiiiliSI, ifSSIl./" relation to 3 1924 023 533 080