CORNELL UNIVERSITY LIBRARY BUSINESS Cornell University Library HJ 2379.N27 Taxation and national Income ... 3 1924 018 164 743 Cornell University Library The original of tiiis book is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924018164743 TAXATION AND NATIONAL INCOME Research Report Number 55 October, 1922 National Industrial Conference Board THE CENTURY CO. NEW YORK PUBLISHERS Copyright, 1922 National Industrial Conference Board Foreword This study of important aspects of taxation in the United States and in other leading industrial nations is presented by the Conference Board in pursuance of the fundamental pur- pose of its work — "to secure, analyze and disseminate informa- tion concerning industrial problems and experience in the United States and other countries" and "in general, to encour- age and promote the sound development of American industry." It cannot be gainsaid that taxation has become an industrial problem of the first importance. The larger part of the taxes raised in the United States and other industrial nations fall upon productive industry, and the sound development of in- dustry is directly affected by the questions touching the equit- able distribution of the tax burden and its reduction through governmental economy and efficiency. In these senses the facts regarding the growth of government expenditures and the accompanying increase of taxation, and the relation of these to national income, merit the close attention of industry no less than they do that of the general public. This report, presenting these significant facts in compact form, is oifered as a timely contribution to the better understanding of this important question. CONTENTS PAGE Introduction 1 Development of Taxation 2 Taxation and National Income 5 Character of Taxation Included in Report 6 Purpose of the Report. .'. 7 I. The Growth of Public Expenditures 9 Expansion of Government Activities 9 Increase in National Wealth 11 Growth of Public Expenditures 11 Effects of the Waf 12 ■ II. The Growth of Taxation in the United States AND Abroad 22 Pre- War Growth of Taxation 23 Public Monopolies 23 War Taxation 24 Relation to National Income 25 III. The Burden of Taxation in the United States. .39 Summary of Tax Systems in the United States. . .39 Local Taxation 39 Federal Taxation 40 Sources and Character of Data 41 (a) Financial Data of the Federal Government.. . .44 (b) Financial Data of States 45 (c) Financial Data of Local Governments 46 Taxation by States 46 IV. The Present Problem of Taxation in the United States 72 Growth of State and Local Taxation 72 Taxation and National Income 74 Productivity of Government Expenditures 78 Local Financial Economy 80 Distribution of Taxation 81 Taxation and Citizenship 82 V. General Summary 84 T LIST OF TABLES AND CHARTS TABLES PAGE Table 1 : Total Governmental Expenditures in the United States ^^ Table 2: Total Governmental Expenditures in the United Kingdom 15 Table 3: Total Governmental Expenditures in France. . . 16 Table 4: Total Governmental Expenditures in Italy 17 Table 5: Total Governmental Expenditures in Germany. 18 Table 6: Total Governmental Expenditures in Japan 19 Table 7: Per Capita Total Expenditures of Governments on the Pre- War Purchasing Power Basis 20 Table 8: Total Receipts from Taxation in the United States 28 Table 9: Total Receipts from Taxation in the United Kingdom 29 Table 10: Total Receipts from Taxation in France 30 Table 11 : Total Receipts from Taxation in Italy 31 Table 12: Total Receipts from Taxation in Germany 32 Table 13: Total Receipts from Taxation in Japan 33 Table 14: Per Capita Total Taxation on the Pre-War Pur- chasing Power Basis 34 Table 15: Per Capita Total Taxation on the Pre-War Pur- chasing Power Basis as Percentage of Pre-War National Income 36 Table 16: Ratio of Total Taxation to National Income — United States 38 Table 17: Taxes Related to Income, by States, 1919 50 Table 18: Federal Taxation, by States, 1919 56 Table 19: General Property Tax Levies of Local Govern- ments 58 vi PAGE Table 20: Per Capita Local Levies of the General Property Tax 63 Table 21: Per Capita Receipts from Taxation of State Governments 65 Table 22: Per Capita Receipts from Taxes and Licenses of Principal Cities of the United States 67 Table 23 : Taxation and National Income — United States . 77 Table 24: National Income and Savings 77 CHARTS Chart 1 : Per Capita Total Expenditures of Governments On the Pre-War Purchasing Power Basis 21 Chart 2: Per Capita Total Taxation of Governments on the Pre-War Purchasing Power Basis 35 Chart 3: Total Taxation and National Income, United States 37 Chart 4: Distribution of Total Taxation by States, United States 49 Chart 5: Growth of Federal, State and Local Taxation, United States 75 Taxation and National Income INTRODUCTION The growing burden of taxation has perhaps never before in history been so forcefully impressed on our minds as in recent years. Fiscal efforts during the course of the war and there- after were of tremendous and unprecedented proportions, and the prodigious costs entailed in waging wars on a modern scale have resulted in constantly increasing demands upon the tax- payers of the nations. Present and future generations are confronted with huge gov- ernment budgets which have their origin mainly in circum- stances arising from the war. In proportion as nations have financed the war by means of bonds they have thrown on pos- terity a recurring burden in the shape of added taxes to meet the annual interest charges on the public debt. So far as governments have issued more or less inconvertible currency, either directly, as in Italy, or indirectly through the medium of central banks, as in Germany, no interest charges accrue or else the costs in connection with rediscount are insignificant be- side the huge amounts involved. But these issues of currency have contributed and still continue to contribute to inflation. In the case of Germany and Austria, this inflation has largely disposed of the problem of debts and annual debt burdens, by reducing the annual carrying charges of these debts to a mere fraction of the principal of the obligation incurred, in terms of actual purchasing power. The embarkation by governments on social policies of a pressing character created an ever- widening disparity between income and outgo, and issuance of inconvertible currency commended itself to the governments in power as the only course. The inevitable result has been a form of repudiation. Savings of large groups in society have been almost completely wiped out and a redistribution of wealth has ensued, the burden of which has fallen primarily on the middle classes that form the nucleus of the intellectual life of these countries. Aside from the chaos and disorganiza- tion that have followed in the wake of inflation, the morale and efficiency of the masses have been seriously undermined. 1 To countries that are actually on a gold basis or that have a semblance of this standard, however, the annual debt charge presents problems that in some instances challenge solution. The situation of France is a case in point. Her debt has been increasing continually, primarily because of outlays in connec- tion with reconstruction of devastated areas. These sums are theoretically recoverable from Germany; but only a fraction toward their payment has been received to date. On December 31, 1918 the public debt of France stood at 171 billion francs; from the latter date to the end of the year 1922, an additional 145 billions will have been borrowed. About 91 billions have thus far been spent on reconstruction, and completion of the full program will require a further expenditure of 55 billions, exclusive of 36 billions yet to be paid in war pensions. By the end of 1925, the annual debt charge will have increased to 19 billion francs, or more than the revenue from normal sources in the 1923 budget, exclusive of the requirements of the army, navy and civil departments. The huge growth in the burden of taxation cannot, however, be attributed to the war alone. Since the successful prosecu- tion of the war required that monetary and other consider- ations be subordinated to the needs of the hour, namely, the victory of Allied arms, it is clear that the military branch of the government had to be given a free rein in expending public funds in such manner and in such amounts as exigencies dic- tated; but these abnormal expenditures did not end as soon as the combatants laid down their arms. It is true that the con- version of military activities from a war to a peace footing caused a heavy reduction in the outlays of national govern- ments, but this reduction was partly offset by a sharp spurt in state and local government expenditures and in their result- ing tax burdens. Even before the war, it had been discernible that the tendency was for state and local governmental expendi- tures to increase rather materially from year to year. During the war, public policy made it advisable to curb the activities of these disbursing authorities, but it was after the war that the latter increased their demands and raised the burden of tax- ation to an unprecedented level. Development of Taxation Taxation in its broadest sense is as old as the record of man himself. Closely interwoven with economic life, its develop- 2 ment is a true reflection of the vast political and social changes that^have taken place throughout history. Appearing first in the guise of voluntary contributions in Iprimitive society, taxation later assumed a compulsory character when royalty began to extend its influence and commerce developed. What was initially merely a periodic and compulsory contribution for a particular or personal service, soon became a means of promoting common well-being. Revenues flowing into the public coflFers were utilized at first for the promotion of national security and defense and later for the regulative and cultural activities of government, and these in most cases form the bulk of the functions of government today. It is here that we have the beginnings of the problem of taxation with its modern ramifications. Indirect taxation antedates direct taxation. The latter form of compulsory contribution did not meet with popular favor in the early days. Its existence would have presupposed a strong monarch or leader who could defy public sentiment. Only as democracy develops and public morality and civic responsibility grow is it found possible to introduce direct taxation. Recognition of social duty opens the way for a system of taxation primarily based on one's property. At first levied in the form of poll or capitation tax, direct contributions were later exacted based on land, gross produce, and net produce. Finally, as modern economy emerges and the principle of ability is accepted as the best criterion, a system of taxation develops founded on the income of individuals or legal entities. The latter stage is only a recent phenomenon and marks the acceptance of those principles of fiscal justice and equity of which civilization boasts today. Amid the clash and din of opposing political forces during the past centuries there has gradually developed in modern communities a system of taxation which fundamentally rests on the theory of ability. Historically, taxes were at first a badge of dishonor; a social stigma was attached to the term because the ruling classes within a given nation enjoyed com- plete exemption from taxation. This principle was extended to the field of international relations, when victorious nations practiced a policy of pecuniary exploitation of subject coun- tries and provinces.^ In the Middle Ages, tax exemption was 'Cohn, Gustav, "Sciance of Finance," translated by T. B. Veblen, University of Chicago Press, 1899, pp. 301 flf. 3 a coveted honor and was synonymous with princely authority and prestige, but as the tempo of democratic progress began to grow more rapid, the underlying philosophy underwent a complete transformation and universality of taxation became the battle cry of the majorities in each country. Contemplating recorded history as a unit we find that there have been five distinct stages in the development of taxation. The first manifestation is the poll or capitation tax, levied on all alike because the interests of all citizens are supposedly identical. It does not take a long time, however, for in- equalities to begin to creep in; differences in mental and physical characteristics of individuals lead to disparities in the amount of possessions. Tangible property then becomes the basis of taxation, but the introduction of this new method must needs be slow for it presupposes a ruler whose power is secure enough to exact tribute from the wealthier classes by direct means. It assumes the form of a groping opportunism and is circumscribed more or less by expediency. Ere long the de- fects of property taxation manifest themselves. There is a divergence between property and product; the non-propertied classes escape the burden altogether; and as industry and com- merce expand there is a growing variety in the forms of wealth which vie in importance with tangible property. The lack of universality inherent in the property tax causes a reaction and expenditure becomes the standard. A tax on articles of consumption touches every class in society, and the tentacles of the exchequer therefore reach into everyone's pocket. The fundamental defect of this method is, however, that it casts a heavier burden on the lower classes as com- pared with the upper. Expenditures for consumption com- prise a much larger percentage of the total budget among the poor than among the rich. These shortcomings soon disclose themselves and then comes the movement toward the taxa- tion of gross produce and later of net produce. The former is a tax on the thing — on the land — and not on the person. In- dividual ability constitutes no criterion; the costs of indebted- ness are, therefore, not deductible. The dissatisfaction that this norm entails finally leads to the taxation of income, which has become the standard upon which modern economists and 4 statesmen now rely to a material extent.* Although income is generally recognized as the best single criterion of ability to pay, a judicious combination of income and property taxes is, how- ever, widely accepted as a good measurement of ability. A glance at tax systems in vogue today will reveal the fact that the stages above described were not separately developed nor were they synchronous in their origin. They grew up side by side, but over a long period of time there is discernible the fact that emphasis has gradually been shifting to ability-to- pay as the norm of equitable taxation. The fundamental public activities determine the existence of the individual and govern his total personal and economic strength, and the principle of ability has, therefore, won wide acceptahce. Taxation and National Income Just as it is true of the individual, so the principle applies to an aggregation of individuals or to the State, that the source of all taxation is income.* The State raises certain amounts from its citizens which it disburses in wages, salaries, pensions, materials and equipment, maintenance of hospitals, arsenals, etc. The individual merely hands over to the State a portion of the income that he would have spent or saved. In return he receives protection and services which comprise the intangible items in his budget. No matter how the tax is levied, whether on property or expenditure, whether on income or capital, it is paid out of the individual's income. Even an estate tax, while sometimes derived from the sale of capital assets, is nevertheless a tax on the income of the recipient, for the be- quest or inheritance minus the tax is nothing other than current income to its possessor. Taxation is the transfer of part of a citizen's spending or saving power to the govern- ment,' and the burden of its weight varies in the last analysis with the income, either accumulated or current, of the individual or of the nation as a whole. Hence, in this study of federal, state and local taxes it was considered essential that the relationship be drawn between these two factors. iSeligman, E. R. A. "Essays on Taxation," Ninth Edition, The Macmillan Co., New Yoric, 1921, p. 18, and "Income Tax," Fourth Edition, The Macmillan Co., New York, 1914, Introduction. 'Wagner, Adolph. "Finanzwissenschaft," Zweiter Theil, "Theorie der Besteuerung, Ge- bllhrenlehre und allgemeine Steuerlehre", Zweite Auflage, Leipzig, 1890, pp. 315 ff. 'Hobson, J. A., "Taxation in the New State," Harcourt, Brace and Howe, New York, 1920, pp. 9-14. Character of Taxation Included in Report In connection with the classification of general revenue re- ceipts falling under the title "tax," it must be borne in mind that a tax in its broadest sense is a compulsory contribution levied upon the inhabitants of the state or any subdivision to which it relegates authority by virtue of its sovereign power. The purpose is to defray the costs of government and to meet the general public needs. The consideration may involve the transfer of money, of other forms of wealth or of services. The first is the usual medium through which the obligations to the state are liquidated, but it is not uncommon nowadays to make payments of taxes in government securities in accord- ance with legal provisions expressly made therefor, as for example, in the case of the excess profits taxes in the United States, estate duties in the United Kingdom and federal property taxes in Germany. The requirement that citizens of the state contribute a specified number of days of labor toward the building of roads and the construction of other public works, was not infrequent in past centuries, but such services have in the course of time been converted into money equivalents and have now assumed as a rule the form of a poll or capitation tax. It is not unusual to find in the tax laws of many of our states today a provision requiring able-bodied adults to contribute their labor on public improvements for specified periods, and only in default of labor to pay a certain money equivalent for each day of required service. The most extreme case of compulsory service at the present time which assumes the form of a tax is to be found in Bulgaria, where a recent enactment makes both sexes (upward of 20 and 16 years for males and females respectively) liable to obligatory community labor, with no substitutions and with exemptions limited only to the physically unfit, the military and a few other groups.* Taxes are levied on persons, both natural and corporate, or physical and juridical. Furthermore, the international movement of capital in recent decades has been rendered so easy and secure that a large revenue is now being derived by citizens of one country from investments in foreign countries. The property thus invested becomes subject to multiple tax- ation which is borne by a non-citizen or foreigner, although 'Compulsory Labor Service Act, dated June S, 1920, as published by the International Labor Office, Legislative Series, 1920, Bulgaria, No. 1. 6 this happens to be amenable to taxation originally in the country of residence of its recipient. Under the head of taxes, it has been deemed advisable in this report to include what are commonly known as licenses or license taxes. These are compulsory contributions exacted in connection with the issuance of written documents which authorize the licensee to engage in specific lines of business activity. Fees, which represent compensation for special services rendered by the government, inuring to the benefit of the individual, and covering the costs of the service, are excluded. In some instances, government accounting designates as a fee what is essentially a license or license tax and hence official designations could not always be used as a criterion of proper classification. Purpose of the Report It is for the purpose of bringing out the facts with regard to taxation and its relation to national income, and of calling public attention to its possible effect on national well-being, that the National Industrial Conference Board has undertaken to make a study of the problem in its broadest aspects. Here- tofore in discussions of problems of public finance emphasis has usually been placed on expenditures and taxation of national governments, and because of the paucity of collected data and lack of knowledge of its importance, local finance has been relegated to the background. This report makes available in a new form information which gives a comprehensive picture of the total burden of public expenditures and taxation in the six principal manufacturing countries of the world, viz., the United States, the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Germany and Japan. In some cases, figures for local government ex- penditures and taxation represent estimates, based, however, on sufficiently reliable data to render the margin of possible error fairly small. The basis of these estimates is discussed in connection with them. The first chapter of the report gives a brief survey of the growth of governmental expenditures in recent years; the second summarizes the facts regarding the increase of taxation in the United States and abroad; the third presents an analysis of the federal, state and local tax burdens in the United States; and the fourth discusses the problems raised in this country by the increase of taxation in relation to income. 7 Detailed examination of the facts and figures brought out in the report will no doubt help to throw some interesting side- lights on the status of American public finance. While the Board has been interested primarily in the extent of tax burdens and their relation to national welfare, it has not lost sight of the fact that there are questions relating to equitable distribu- tion of our total national taxation which have not been treated with sufficient detail and which might become the subject of special studies. It is hoped, however, that this report will stimulate thought on the vital problems connected with taxa- tion and increase interest in the activities of the government. I THE GROWTH OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES With the gradual displacement of absolutism in the political systems of Europe early in the nineteenth century, the hope was entertained that demands on the public purse would begin to diminish and a new era of economic management of the State would be ushered in. This view is exemplified in the remarks of Villfele, the French Minister, of Finance who, in introducing the first billion-franc budget after the Napoleonic Wars, is said to have exclaimed, "Gentlemen, salute these figures; you will never have an opportunity to contemplate them again."* It was destined that this sanguine forecast should not be realized in the succeeding century for any country, and so far as the next few decades are concerned, there is no hope of even approximating it. An outstanding phenomenon of the past two centuries was the tremendous growth of public expenditures. The increase went far beyond the imagination of the most astute observer before the industrial revolution. The environment and forms of economy existing at the time could not warrant any opti- mistic expectations in regard to the income of governments. Agriculture was practically the mainstay of economic life, and the tax yield from this source was naturally very limited. Under such circumstances it was inevitable that one's outlook as to the public finances of the future should be tempered by economic considerations that then confronted the observer. Expansion of Government Activities Late in the eighteenth century, however, a revolution took place which was fated to bring in its train a long series of social, economic and political changes of far-reaching importance. The factory economy began slowly to replace the individual system of work, and with it there came unexampled expansion of wealth and enhancement of public welfare. Population grew rapidly, national rcspurces were exploited on an ever- widening scale, and prosperity became more widespread. 'Quoted in Adams, H. C. "Science of Finance," Henry Holt & Co., New York, 1912, p. 84. It is interesting to note in this connection tliat in 1913 tlie national government expenditures of France amounted to more than 5 billion francs. In private economy it is a well-known and readily accepted principle that standards of living keep pace with income, and the same applies also to public economy. The physiocrats, a group of economic theorists who held that land is the ultimate source of wealth, had recognized the relationship between pub- lic and private finance in Quesnay's celebrated maxim, "Pauvres pay sans, pauvre royaume; pauvre royaume, pauvre roi,"^ although the doctrine as thus phrased was tinged somewhat with the flavor of their peculiar philosophy. As industry developed and trade began to flourish on a scale theretofore unknown, the State assumed more and more functions, at first meeting the problems growing out of a new economic status, and later, with the rise and spread of the democratic movement, entering into the field of public welfare. The sphere of State activity was enlarged to embrace not only protection from internal disorder and foreign aggression but also public education and health, public works, provision for spiritual as well as physical advance- ment and other related activities. The collective wants of society kept abreast of economic progress and whenever indus- try and trade were confronted with new dangers and complexi- ties, the aid of the State was enlisted to an increasing extent. Meanwhile, the costs of military preparation in the feudal and early monarchical period were dwarfed by the huge outlays appropriated in the past century as the spirit of nationalism grew. The beginnings of political democracy were attained after a protracted struggle, at great cost in human sacri- fice and material goods, but democracy did not do away with militarism and its great cost of maintenance. In place of the heavy expenditures for luxurious court requirements still greater sums were raised to meet the needs of highly indus- trialized communities, and armament construction was even accelerated. Thus, public finance has always been, as it is now, at the mercy of the political, social and economic factors operating in society. The steady increase in population and the slow but insidious effect of the changing price level, consequent upon the increase in supplies of specie and credit media, are additional factors that have often been disregarded as partly explaining the in- crease in monetary outlays. In the two decades prior to the outbreak of the World War, although the alterations in •"Poor peasantry, poor kingdom; poor kingdom, poor king." 10 prices from year to year were hardly perceptible, the trend was definitely upward. During the war, the huge credit oper- ations on government and private account gave impetus to the inflationary movement, and in certain countries pushed it to unprecedented heights long after the din of battle had ceased. Increase in National Wealth It must not be inferred from the above account, however, that the burden of public expenditure before the war became so heavy as to interfere with progress, for the contrary was true. Along with the enlarged duties of the State, there was a more than proportionate increase in national wealth and income which tended to ofi^set the growing demands on the public purse. In the United States, expenditures of the national govern- ment showed a sixteenfold rise in the period between 1850 and 1912, but national wealth grew to twenty-seven times its earlier proportions during the same interval. The same phenomenon is observed in other countries of the world, although not to the same degree. Growth of Public Expenditures A glance at Tables 1 to 7 and Chart 1 will show the growth of public expenditures in the past two decades for national, state, provincial and local purposes in the United States, the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Germany and Japan. In the fiscal year 1903 or thereabouts the total per capita costs of government were approximately |22 in the United States, as compared with $40 in the United Kingdom, $24 in France, $14 in Italy, $44 in Germany and $5 in Japan. In the year immediately preceding the outbreak of the World War the per capita costs had risen to $35 in the United States, $42 in the United Kingdom, $33 in France, $22 in Italy, $69 in Germany and $8 in Japan. These figures include duplications such as revenue collected by the central government and turned over to the minor civil divisions. They also embrace extensions on account of com- mercial and industrial undertakings, including monopolies,* of national, state and local governments. The latter circum- stance, in all probability, accounts for the large per capita government outlays of Germany, for example, as compared iSuch as, for example, that of the manufacture and sale of tobacco in France, and the operation of telephones and telegraphs in Italy. 11 with other countries, since in Germany state and municipal operation of utilities and industrial undertakings was more greatly developed than elsewhere. Effects of the War The World War upset human calculations and proved far more costly, directly and indirectly, than even the keenest and most far-sighted militarist could have contemplated. Its effects were felt throughout the entire economic system and the decades to come will continue to reflect the consequences of the world's greatest upheaval. The destruction of capital and wealth has been far larger than the annual increments due to saving, and although the world is poorer today than it was before the war, the yearly costs of government are bound to remain at a level twice or three times as high as in 1914, and in some cases still higher. This is the sum and substance of the economic situation as it confronts us today. During the war, local governments tacitly submitted to numerous restrictions in their expenditure policies in order to grant the central or national authoriti,bs complete freedom in shaping their fiscal systems to meet the extraordinary demands occasioned by the conflict. This procedure was, however, equivalent to putting one coin into one pocket and removing many more from the other. Per capita costs of national, state, provincial and local governments in the last fiscal year of the war period rose to |179 in the United States, as compared with J294 in the United Kingdom, ?285 in France, $176 in Italy, $245 in Germany and $13 in Japan (foreign currencies being converted at pre-war mint parity). A large part of this in- crease was, however, due to inflation and the changing price level. Reducing these per capita outlays to the pre-war pur- chasing power basis,' the figures were substantially $88 for the United States, $130 for the United Kingdom, $84 for France, $46 for Italy, $114 for Germany and $6 for Japan. In the post-armistice period, national expenditures, meas- ured in terms of the respective currencies, have declined con- siderably in the United States and the United Kingdom. In France the reduction has been small, largely owing to heavy disbursements on account of reconstruction of devastated areas, which in major part are theoretically recoverable from 'Derived by dividing current figures by the index number of wholesale prices on the pre- war base. 12 Germany under the Treaty of Versailles. In Japan and Italy, demands on the national purse were increased almost to the maximum war levels, due in the one case to an enlarged naval program and in the other to the sale of necessities by the State, from which large deficits have resulted, though offset some- what by receipts. In Germany, the enormous inflation of the currency, combined with heavy subsidies on account of public provisioning and of public undertakings, and the re- curring burdens of reparations, have raised national expendi- tures to dizzy heights when expressed in terms of the mark. One of the outstanding features of post-armistice finance is the huge growth in expenditures of state subdivisions of the federal governments and of provincial and local bodies. This is particularly true of the United States, the United King- dom, France and Italy. Public improvements long postponed because of the war's exigencies have now been undertaken, and there has been a special incentive for communities to take advantage of the falling rate of interest and the lower costs of construction. These pent-up demands have been let loose with a consequent severe drain on the already impoverished economic resources of the countries. Per capita expenditures in the fiscal year 1920-1921, with foreign currencies converted at par of exchange, were $87 in the United States, ?164 in the United Kingdom, ?266 in France, $162 in Italy and $18 in Japan. An attempt has also been made to arrive at totals for Germany in later years, but because of the paucity of data for local governments, the highly erratic state of the currency which renders all comparisons futile, and because of the rearrangement of the whole fiscal system, a multiplicity of complexities injected themselves. Computed on the pre-war purchasing power basis, per capita expenditures during the fiscal year 1920-1921 were $45 for the United States, $61 for the United Kingdom, $77 for France (calendar year 1921), $26 for Italy, $56 for Germany and $7 for Japan. 13 h Q M h 5 M K h H 3 H Q, X w «! oi w > o O <: h .O H M rt eg ^1 rHONQOOOmO^iOO SI C Ih to •-t O C/-* -c o« og-Qg ° S -so C » >0 0*0 " •- 3 § sal 'g!j 2a S ^1" •sli vOO\ Tj 00 NOO\ ^^-H»- OOOSPO'-lO'».'» IOCS 00 00 T-lpo ON O^H \OPO ON^HOi'SiOP<»0\'»-«fOQO cOO'5s ?8 S8 S n. "S p^ is-g «a ";?• s ■3 I" ".s s-s « i Ss pg -gs s 5 E2 -gi gg 5 •o ■§£ "S g.S 5 S "2 s'-- o.'s B 6" 2" °''S dS 5 d l^ -^^ -^^ S 5! 2-S 2| ."S ^ o!2 B2 8., g M o>2 -2 .S^ H| ■* aj "O Br ?- So 2 •S S° s° i^ '° S .23 ;8-S Og fe rt 3^ js'S SS B o o,.g Sa « ., -o i £g I- IS I .S rtS teg -^^ o • - B2 V .sO« I4 ■? S2 IBS 5^ g S K.S Or; gS ". i S.O |3 I- 8 g B" I2 as ♦• I— I *»aU Wo dJ*B S • 203 „•= ss £ •o •o I 3 S V %E-5 o 415 S y.^-o-" " a a •*"! il^S-o^foSa S'S 'SqISS'S-b BSW 14 o a o iz; Q M a M P« IH Q S5 M 0. .J I? fei Pi! M O o o H n l3 P ill •a-, H 2 o 3 "5 a ^•go .a" lilt CSO0000O\v0Osv0^'O'O ^fO^'^OOoOiOOO\ONO *-i eg ro CN cs th OoOPOPorO'^fOcgoo^-i^ vH 1-H i-H v-i ro 00 i-T^ ro 0\ r* '^vOt^t^vO'-iOpOOOiO tH CSCS C^ ^ i-H OMO 00 lO lO to 0\ On t^ " ■« OO to VO "O to CO *^ VO 00 ^O00tO0N0000»HC0 ^O VO'OO 00 00 00 00 o\ o 0\ ■^ O -^ PC 00 O ' to CS "O »0 \0 00 tH so <-( to O 00 ■^ fO Q0^t>-00TfO\00^« ^VO'HOONO'-fO ^H CO 00 On to lO**^ CO CsjcsiOsOt-»vO\Oi>- *Oi-iesiro^oOcO^»-itOOO fOtOC^ONi^tO'-HCMOt^CN to rJH cct^ O On 00 \0 0\ to to OOsoOO\NOtOONONJ>-NOON CST-t^H.^-ltOtO'-H'OtO'O*-! ^e^esc^*-!^ Mf0r0^tov0t^00OvO'-< OO^H»-(»-4rHtHi-l*-tCNCS OnQsOnOnOnOnOnOnOsOsOn ^1 -a aft 9J lie * - fl P Hit .S.S|-3t.'' •d'O CO L.'S 0) C e 0) oj w 9 n O O Ih Is ga p _ — 1-1 ^ 15 u M H Oi & h Q £; M B. X W 1-9 <: !5 M Is M O O o Pi 5^ 00lOP00^1-^CN00rt^P00^t^O csioiroco»n^HOO.OOOOQOOO COOO^fO'-HrO»-iiO»OlO 00 i>- c^i t*» o^* I f^Tt^^0V0c«^c*:)00^pC0^0O'^ Is og .a •2g * : 3 CN 00" OO^OO^ O O '-H \o ■^oTirTcr th ir> th CO \0 io>o*o OOOOOi-hOOOOOOOO cncs»opooooooooo 0\t^csvO^-(OoO'-tONro rfTtrT sOiOt^OfO^-HOOvO^C'Ji-iO T-iCSf0^iO»OlOlO csr5esf0'(* o O >4 is ^ M CO lO so -^ ^O lOrooOvppOOOt^OsO « ^ « « IB O\00 \0 Ov'^ ^ O t-». 00 ON CN 0\ ON lO \0 fO ^ »o cs^^ CS lO O i>' "^ cs ■rH i-H (N C*5 VOOO ro*0^»0'Ot*000\0»-« 0\0^0^0\0^0\0\0^0^0^ S o ^ s •o 2 ?i i IS 3 .S 1 : •1 « %l y 4 •* '-•■S ^ » -: o i a a (1 •^fW 2.S„- 8{ •S1;', S"^ M 8^ "■^d 1 » d 1 §2 •d MO ¥1 2 S3 -■2 S-o'S g 0.° SS-d So, iS:2S ;oo J;52<"S£ >■ S'Om'CS « *rt o .Sh .S o c as Soy -y S2q S c.2 o a -Wji « « s M s .0 cj= «a Mrt 17 < M Q 12; M O. > o O I i h m •Si's sis -5 .SP-g ^51 OO\N0i0v000v0tO*HS0 00 00 ^' t^ '^' »0 O *-! VOOO'^tOlO'^OpO »H T-( C4 CN| ^t** ^« CO ^rfTesTp^'^io'oo'o'o OOOplO*HO\**5»-4fOOO c^ ^ ^ ^"oTo't^-^vo oCm •H *H »H es ^ rooo O " ^0 i^CS c*> to es P^ O Q O" iocOiOvO'^00O\^Sq oq^o^u^c^^^^^o '^C>_0 o ▼HT-t^-lOl^'^t^SOMOO ggggggg- « M ^W «t M «t ^•^ O »0 1** CO re 10 rfroo'oo''oO*oo'*or^ gggggggg' ^ »-i O to O PO •-< vO cs»-(Oooro*>-f»3to 00^ii^u^0(^C)^O\^iO^\O rOOOQOC OfOOOC CO PC& 00^ ISI 1© IS tti-C .a f U] ■&s ■a as a V S.2 !;! S ■" S 1 P?S *» •0 ss ^ B-n ^U, o ■ss 2 ■• 2 £2 » c f S ta « 3«S2 S|2* 2j .«♦-<« C3 .K *2 "O •g a 3 m »> . Is N o» N T-i "^ ,2 tC js .^S .0.5 H OEc] -a a> 0.13 elo-a-gjit; •sl-sia-s-sS •s, a n 18 !2i, < o O o H n e5 ?f5 C''^ ^ uu OS CO m iai M O ■2 eg ■y C S '^odododooodocoiood ON^^t^O\ ^-( O Os ^ ro f*5 iri^ T^ 00 ^ 00 ro cTin*^ ■^ ON 00 0\ 00 On ^-J^tJh^Jt^ O ro>OvOfO^OrovOiO'OOs ■^lO^-tiOfOOvOopfC^ •^^H^lr^oo^t^^vO^'^O O ooospOOOes5Qioi>-. 10*10 fo'c^Tvo cro(roo"»o'or C^O0^00^-0^<-l^0^0TJ< w Tt< ■»-i PO 00 '-' O lO »■ • ^ ■**< ■^ -^ o M m ; ^oo^t^NO^po^o^oo^ ■ o o\ o"o"o c-T-^ 0\O^V010 0COOO»OCS t^^O'^OO»O'^v000»O C^OsrOMt^O\CSf*5CSvO OOONt^'^OOONPO^Ht^C?) P2r0'«*»O\0t^00O\O»H O^O^O^O^O^O^O^O^O^0^ •o la I ° 3 I CO •§ I § •a ""> "^ -«-< 2 S s C CO .as.s S3 O V "■a 5£ 19 O Oh O Oi ■< K o A D Oi I M 0$ CM M S O > o O Ex o M U. U 1-1 Q !<5 M O, X w «<: H o H h hH 0. «>! u U n \0ro00'^0\000-* O0^v0^C(i000^*»O»OO I OOsONOO\oO"^Ot^O O^O^O^O^O^O^O^OvO\0^ SSI'S caSS - was *^ o^ o a 2? ° to S'O'*- £^ OJ (d D) a a t«^_ ,« 35C.S S-S^ s ° jg > g,2 - ■" S"u .53 •0!>.feS-3 •si§ss.s aS Mb"-" Jj rj— * ** S +J - « *3 M CI •Oc QJJ3!:. g sSs-"g^ Si s'Si. . 3.S !s as " °"3 20 Chart 1: Per Capita Total Expenditures of Govern- ments ON THE Pre-War Purchasing Power Basis (National Industrial Conference Board) I9IS-I3 1913-14 1914-15 1915-IB I9IB-I7 1917-IB I9IQ-I3 I3)9-EQ ISED-El I9EI-EE 21 II THE GROWTH OF TAXATION IN THE UNITED STATES AND ABROAD In the preceding chapter the development of total govern- mental expenditures in the six major countries of the world was traced. Were this growth merely the outcome of enlarged industrial and commercial activities of the State, which would yield sufficient net revenues to cover the requirements of the budget for purely governmental administration, no prob- lem would have ensued and no popular dissatisfaction would have arisen. But the accompaniment of this rising movement of government outlays was the increase of tax burdens and the exaction of ever larger contributions from the citizens of the State as the years rolled on. That the burden of taxation was growing rapidly even before the recent World War is a fact that is borne out by abundant statistical data of official and unofficial nature and is further corroborated by popular testimony. In fact, in pre-war days it was a fairly common expression of opinion that taxation was rapidly approaching a point that threatened to court popular disfavor and breed general discontent with government. If this is true of the period prior to 1914, how much more true is it today when the war, with its enormous destruction of capital, with its impoverishment of the whole human race and its weakening of its moral stamina, has left as heritage for the next generations, debts which bid fair to establish, for a gen- eration or two at least, an annual carrying charge beside which pre-war figures pale. In the last analysis all taxes — whether direct or indirect, whether borne by those who pay at first or later shifted to the shoulders of others — ^must come out of the excess of income over consumption or out of the national surplus of either past or current origin. Since the latter has appreciably diminished as a result of the war and since national productiveness has been impaired, especially in the older countries that participated in the conflict, the seriousness of the situation is multiplied many fold in view of the piling up of tax burdens. Furthermore, 22 although a decrease has taken place in the national surplus and tax burdens have been increased far beyond normal pro- portions, the requirements for additions to and betterments of industrial and commercial capital are heavier now than they were during the recent war. Repairs and substitutions had been at a low ebb during the war period, primarily be- cause governments had a prior lien on all available capital and this was in greater part diverted into channels that served purely war purposes. High rates of interest and high con- struction costs in themselves discouraged extensions and additions that might have been contemplated, and kept re- pairs at a minimum. If industry and commerce are to re- cover, it is clear that the demands for additions and better- ments will have to grow faster than the net increase of the national income in the coming years and the encroachments on the national surplus by virtue of high taxation will prove to be more burdensome and disproportionate. Tables 8 to 16 and Chart 2 present a comparative summary of tax burdens in the six major countries. Pre-War Growth of Taxation In 1903 or thereabouts, the per capita taxation of national, state, provincial and local governments amounted to J18 in the United States, %2\ in the United Kingdom, %\1 in France, $10 in Italy, %\2 in Germany and $3 in Japan. By 1913-1914 the annual tax burden had grown to $23 in the United States, %T1 in the United Kingdom, $22 in France, $12 in Italy, $19 in Germany and $6 in Japan. Thus the percentage increase during the ten-year period in question was largest for Japan, with 95%, and lowest for the United Kingdom, with 15%. Germany showed an increase of 62%, followed by France with 36%, the United States with 31% and Italy with 27%. That the population changes did not materially influence the se- quence may be gleaned from the fact that the increase in the total amount of taxes actually raised was 124% in Japan, 100% in Germany, 60% in the United States, 38% in France, 38% in Italy and 26% in the United Kingdom. Public Monopolies It should be borne in mind in connection with the tax status that in some states public monopolies and undertakings have been conducted along purely business lines, yielding surpluses 23 wherewith to reduce the national tax bill,* other things being considered equal. This was particularly true in France, Ger- many and Italy before the war and, to a less extent, in Japan. In 1903 the net profit from the French state monopolies, from the postal system, telephone, telegraph, railroads, etc., exclusive of domains, totaled 453 million francs, or $2.24 per capita; in 1913 it was 574 million francs or $2,19 per capita. In Italy the net profits from these sources amounted to 346 million lire or $1.71 per capita in 1902-1903, and in 1913-1914 to 404 million lire or $2.19 per capita. In Germany the operation of railroads, public utilities, etc., by the separate states and municipalities yielded financial results which were highly satisfactory. In 1913- 1914, commercial enterprises of the national and state govern- ments of the German Empire alone yielded a net revenue of 1,258 million marks or $4.42 per capita, and this figure is exclusive of municipal activities of a lucrative nature. The postal administration of the United States, however, has frequently reported a deficit and the effect of the government conduct of the business has been to increase the burden of taxation. During the war, because of the desirability of pursuing certain social policies, profit-making features of government undertakings were temporarily submerged under the pressure of political considerations, and losses became the rule prac- tically everywhere, so far as commercial and industrial under- takings were concerned. The productivity of monopolies has fallen off generally, even in France, as is evidenced occasionally in the debates of the Chamber of Deputies (official figures are not available), but monopolies in Italy have been growing more and more lucrative in a cumulative fashion. In 1918-1919 the yield of Italian state monopolies was 1,142 million lire or $5.88 per capita, and in the subsequent years the net yield will probably be still higher. fVar Taxation In the conduct of the war, so far as the six nations under review are concerned, credit was primarily the means by which the costs of the war were met. Although the fiscal policies 'It was deemed advisable not to consider such profits as additional taxation, on the ground that they do not conform to the accepted definition of a "tax." Furthermore, were the attempt otherwise justifiable, their inclusion would have led to many difficulties because of the differences in fiscal theories followed by various governments and because of the paucity of data bearing on the net results obtained during the war and post-war periods. 24 pursued by the various belligerents may thus be characterized in a general way, there was wide difference in actual practice from country to country. At one extreme there are to be found Japan, the United States and the United Kingdom, who made immediate readjustments in their fiscal systems in an attempt to defray a goodly portion of the total expenditures by means of taxation. At the other extreme are to be found France and Germany, whose management of the war from a fiscal standpoint is exposed to the charge of laxity and short- sightedness. Italy also made a poor showing, but this is largely due to her impoverished state rather than to inertia or negligence. Japan's record represented no great fiscal effort in view of her limited participation in the conflict. The per capita of taxation of national, state and local govern- ments in the fiscal year 1918-1919, with foreign currencies com- puted at par, reached $65 in the United States, $94 in the United Kingdom, $30 in France, $30 in Italy, $44 in Germany and $9 in Japan, but reduced to a comparable (pre-war) purchasing power basis, i.e., with inflation eliminated, these figures would be about $32 for the United States, $42 for the United Kingdom, $9 for France, $8 for Italy, $20 for Germany and $4 for Japan. With the close of the war, taxation receipts of national govern- ments continued to rise, with the exception of the United States and Japan, where there has been some recession. In addition, the burdens imposed by local governments have been increasing very rapidly in the past year or two, and this cir- cumstance has in some cases offset the amelioration in national taxation that has resulted in the interim in the case of some countries. The total per capita taxation in the fiscal year 1920- 1921, computed on the basis of pre-war purchasing power, was about $41 for the United States, $46 for the United Kingdom, $15 for France ($25 in the calendar year 1921), $8 for Italy, $19 for Germany and $5 for Japan. Relation to National Income Inasmuch as taxation must ultimately come out of the na- tional surplus, as stated above, it is important to indicate the relation between national income and taxation. Unfortunately figures of national income of foreign countries are not available for recent years; they all relate to pre-war conditions. Since 25 1914, national incomes have undergone considerable changes, in some cases resulting in improvement and in others in retro- gression. Germany's national income has been considerably reduced owing to transfer to neighboring nations of territories formerly under her control, and also to decreased efficiency. The reduction by virtue of these conditions is estimated to be 1S% to 20% of the national income. The national income of the countries benefited by this distribution was therefore enhanced, other things being considered equal. There has also been in the interim an upheaval in the normal channels of trade. In the absence of any satisfactory alternative with regard to post-war estimates of foreign countries, comparison is made in Table 15 between the tax burden per capita (for national, state and local purposes combined) on the pre-war purchasing power basis as compared with the pre-war national income. This study discloses the startling fact that in the fiscal year 1920-1921 about one-eighth of the pre-war national income of the United States was diverted into tax channels, one-fifth in the United Kingdom, one-twelfth in France (one-eighth in 1921), one-sixteenth in Italy, one-eighth in Germany, and slightly less than one-fifth in Japan, when due recognition is given to the changed price levels and the factor of population. The per- centage of the pre-war national income represented by taxes has been growing throughout the war period to date in most countries, the full significance of which fact has been barely appreciated as yet. Estimates of the national income for the United States have been made by other authorities' for the years 1909-1919. It is therefore possible, after readjusting the figures to make the tax year dovetail with the calendar year to which the esti- mates of income apply, to compare our tax burden from year to year without being required to reduce our taxes to a pre- war purchasing power basis. Table 16 and Chart 3 show that our total tax burden has grown from 6.4% of our national income in 1912-1913 to 14.3% of our national income in 1920-1921. The full import of this condition has barely been recognized as yet in this country, although the general aspects have been covered from time to time in various financial dis- 'Natlonal Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., "Income in the United States, Its Amount and Distribution, 1909-1919," Harcourt, Brace and Company, New York, 1921. 26 cussions. If in a country like the United States, rich in natural resources and abounding in productive capacity, tax burdens threaten to represent so high a percentage of the current national income, how much more true is it of the poorer countries of the world and how much more handicapped are these countries in their attempts to reconstruct their industrial and commercial systems? 27 i Q U in o S o M U H n^ ?1 ■SS|§ ss •sSlf r \ lu a o V 5 If ^^ 0\C0 ■*>• 00 C*3 *-H ' roc* ^-1 CO »0 CO 0\ o^^^ CS CS CN Th UT* io'cfTtCc^ pot^oocoro^esocoo CA « •* •» •s^** t2rO'^»OvO*^QOO\0'-H ^ s '^ If ^ h ^- .3*3 K - S2 I Sb-sS " ll ll .as ■g-5 •S>. :S ^s^d " H '5 5 ° OTJ3 --T d *» 3 ii c ^.^ •- a V Si S I t-m § I -:§ ^" "lis ,5 I S| ^ ^1 Hi i ll ^ _o3S*^ C on oj o 2-a"Jd-"3 u o£ S "^ S . St! M rf: ,a 2 --BD .°E - *>5 ■" SB •» 3 •« . B-B •- .2 m ?? rt O TO « g H ■" «<-:<» J*-- OS'S sl2«~- 111! " |iiil= JiH-l 28 o Q o I-I !^ Q a m M Eh O s o 01 a. iH H U u o H 0\ M M e5 III IP H o o fin "8 — ■§s? c S " W to a S-a^ ■ssS III ?^ cd THiOO'-i^rtiOsOOiOOO T-((N^OlO'-0000iO'<^*H00ro '-icsc^icscsircvOt^oo^-ics ^ CO r^ i^ t- ^-4 PO '-I ro ■« "> ■^ lO fO 0\ ■«-i O Ir^ l>- *H fOCOPOPOcO^Tf<'*>0 O\tO^vO»OiO00** *- w *o O OQ ■»-< th O ^H \p »o'*\o'oo'orororor 5 vO PO t^ es *H ^ *-H ►- « W ft lO lO PO CO OO 00 Tt* • ' VO'Or-(fOrO'0»000'OlOlO C^lOON'HOOOTt■ rt 9 TV dj . g 00 ? > (3 •« o r0r^''os''o''sooo"oocM'* cocOOOO-'-hOs^hcmoOt** ^ CMCMCMCOCOCMCOCOCO-^ §g o * ^ o ^o'o^ 00 ^H o *^ OtM ^**^ •H » B-o OOI-OOOOOOvO-"'* •- S-§ c cscscsesrocsiCNrororo U tt 11 Q0VOO\»O00O\CMt^00«-O\ »0 !2 29 '~ f^ O 0\ T* \o 0\ -H o cs "b •n vo„t»J,>o ON,t~.io >0,« -H^ c^ Ov :? -9 3 1 cSNmfONNrOTit lOOO ■* irT *H -.^ bl 1 ^ « ^> f»5 ■<1' lO VO J^ 00 Ov O « 1 s § o •- o «« s £ 2 2 s 1 .*■ OJ.O S » bo d S 3 ■§ « 3 « « S^ if C4 = I i ft ^ .i g«J5 S ado ■fi 52« O &VJS 3 5 ^ ■ill S « o .Ss- oO ._ CS ^0, T^ 30 12! O o H 0. u u M o H Ri a P §1 II •a " 2 « Ho;:? J3 I B s o 5 OJ3 ^co^'O^^n CO "^O "j^ oo t-^ (r3-«*H-^Tt^inr^c>i-Hcooo bD ^ o o o o o o o ^ OCr\-«*^^HOOOOO'-n i-T cT circs' cm" c^ rt^>j^viroC (3 5 ».£ Sag- ^•^ » « "„ • CT\ ■^ oo • en 9 : : : : : ClOTiivOoorOOO'OCOrO'pH OfO'Oi>-oOrorO'-it^iO O\v0r0^i^f0^ro»0t^ rOPO^iOvO*--OOOsO^ ■si Ssin --- SSI ^ . rH s « •S.9 5fe.s Ji M V 2-3 =^3 •I? Si 5S !i 5S-3 °S3 M -. o •^ c .5 3^ .■9 **> ap^ 3 • So* m - W'rt 2| i^S =S^o. ft "■ »HO> On ^00 . w o . S "^ IH f»i ^ I? o Saaaog "3' .3 I B O " « t^ 1-^ -ri »H ,d d oi 5 M.S.- -r-^ b*j.2*3 d'd Qj-a rS2 g .5 "' 31 s M o ;z; o XI S o «! H CLi M U M O H w e2 S3 o a o S-o >B => l3 O0\0 0soo^*^iovoe*^ *HCOO\THOOOfOT}<\OPO I Op0o«00'-i0s00 0^00^-l^0'-l^0OOO r*- CN 00 CO ^co*^^^ »-H OMOOrOCNVOOOOOstO OO ■H00\*H»OP0r0OO o > ■3S'l2|S|2.2a"-o •sis S" S-gll^o 3 u (<-u 3 in aoi 3-««,B 0) ^ 7i o vB 32 «lOOrOOOlOO\ sq^T-j^-^dH^O^cs) ^^ Os On O O C0CSlOt^QOiC^CS*^O POO'-'OOCSt^vOOOiOO On On O^ On On On On On On On 0*3 o ^ C iS S Pi Qi R fl o s u - % ":« ^ fl ft) d'** ♦* a-S^a Si § &&<=■ g _- m QJ rt «*i C u+j lo M Jg 4> 33 < a o P-, a CO < a u p4 & PL, a «•" O^ ° u. *"S CSS 'a s it V o. V .s o u g '1 El 2 SI'S .s-S s SS s« _^ P -~ « s^ si 5 BU Kg o ■S o h "2 k ^s I •a d «j ji s Jo 5« p at: Ob u ■=■0 O.S S •* 34 Chart 2: Per Capita Total Taxation of Governments ON the Pre-War Purchasing Power Basis (National Industrial Conference Board) lai^tij 1913-14 ISI4-I5 ISI5-IB I9IB-I7 I3I7-IB ISIfl-IS 1913-60 I3E0-EI I92I-EE 35 O o H la M o a PQ W o Ph o iz: n m CM 00 !>. ^_ 0\0\ONONOO\OTt<"^»0 00 1 ^ «© C4 00• OO 0\ CO 00 ^* -csoooot^r»^H^O ONO'^'^CSiO'^t^OOON (0 'S CI ON 00 !>. Cr>ododoi-H S Ih i c -« 1 B IH ^ s ::::::■•:: : 2 >^ .■..::::: : t; s ::;:::::: : S."". : ■.::::::•■ • °'o .::.::::: : we.. Per capita taxation a war national incon 1902-1903 1912-1913 1913-1914 1914-191S 1915-1916 1916-1917 1917-1918 1918-1919 1919-1920 1920-1921 36 Chart 3: Total Taxation and National Income, United States (National Industrial Conference Board) °°7D m° GROWTH DF TAXES AND NATIONAL INCa ME PER CAPITA SOD 5D0 400 i S5SS.BI j^ S3B0.BI H ■ I 1 I m •73.IS vv^Sn lOQ I9IE-I3 1SI3-I4 I3I4-IS I9I5-IB I9IB-I7 I9i7-IB 1916-19 igi9-2D 1920-21 1921-22 RATIO OF TAXES TD NATIONAL INCOME PER CAPITA PE'' nnjll NATIDNAI. INCDME' PER CAPITA - 100 V. 1312-13 I9I3-I.4 1914-15 I9I5-1G I91B-17 I9I7-1B I3IB-I9 1919-2n 1920-21 1921^2. 37 Table 16: Ratio of Total Taxation to National Income — United States National Income Total Taxation Ratio of Taxation to Fiscal Year Per Capita' Per Capita' National Income 1912-1913... $360.81 $22.95 6.36% 1913-1914... 357.52 22.93 6.41% 1914-1915... 351.66 23.28 6.62% 1915-1916. . . 402.77 24.54 6.09% 1916-1917... 482.75 28.81 5.97% 1917-1918... 546.83 57.59 10.53% 1918-1919. . . 612.83 64.66 10.55% 1919-1920. . . 648.94 84.37 13.00% 1920-1921... 552.91 79.15 14.32% ^Arrived at by taking the average of two years' national income (figures of the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., in "Income in the United States, Its Amount and Distribution, 1909-1919," Harcourt, Brace and Company, New York, 1921) and dividing the resultant fi^re by the estimated population at the middle of the fiscal year. Fo r the calendar years 1920 and 1921. the national income was independently estimated at f 72 billions and $50 billions, respectively. ^Federal, state and local combined. 38 Ill THE BURDEN OF TAXATION IN THE UNITED STATES Summary of Tax Systems in the United States Before describing in detail the sources from which the tax data of this report are derived, it will be advantageous to view the whole fiscal structure as it exists today in order to under- stand better the complexities involved. The outstanding observation is that the present fiscal system in the United States has grown up around the political structure. This is, of course, an inevitable consequence of the manner in which the State has grown, and its development presents no fresh aspects whose counterparts cannot be found in every civilized region of the world where centralized authority exists. Local needs asserted themselves first, and as relations between localities became stronger and unification resulted, further burdens were superimposed on those designed to meet local requirements. The tax system as constituted today recognizes three distinct tax-levying authorities, viz., federal, state and the civil divisions of the latter, and contributions must be paid, either directly or indirectly, to each of the three. Local Taxation Local taxation in the United States is almost wholly grounded on property. The general property tax, or as it is sometimes called, the ad valorem tax, constitutes the pillar of local finance. As a general proposition, it is safe to main- tain that over 90% of all local tax revenues are derived from this single source. The more backward or undeveloped a community is, the greater is its dependence on the general property tax, and the more closely does the percentage ap- proach 100. In the more industrialized centers, considerable revenues are drawn from license taxes and from participation in state business and income taxes, but even in such localities, reliance on property taxes is pronounced and the latter consti- tute by far the largest single item of local government income. Just what falls under the title "property taxes" varies from state to state. Property taxes as administered in the United 39 States usually assume the form of a proportional tax on the value of real estate, both land and improvements, and on personalty of every character and description. Exceptions may be found in the taxation of natural resources, such as in the case of the net output of mines or the net yield of forests, and qualifications may be discovered even in the methods of assessing value, as for example, taxes upon ships at a specific amount per registered ton or taxes upon grain at a specific amount per bushel. In the tax systems of a few state governments, property taxes have been assigned to a subordinate position, but this situation does not obtain in a majority of the commonwealths. Originally, the general property tax served the double purpose of being the principal source of revenue for both the state and local governments, but as local needs grew, and as other bases of taxes sprang up, states have gradually begun to re- linquish the general property tax. In the finances of the majority of states, the general property tax still holds first place, but there is an unmistakable tendency on the part of the more developed commonwealths to place greater and greater reliance on business and income taxes than heretofore. In three states, viz., California, Pennsylvania and Delaware, the general property tax is reserved entirely to the local govern- ments; in others, as in New York, this source is tapped inter- mittently or irregularly by the state government. The bulk of the revenue of the more prosperous states is derived from taxes on capital stock, incomes, inheritances, corporations, banks and miscellaneous businesses and also from licenses for hunting and fishing, on motor vehicles, etc. Federal Taxation Federal revenues within recent years have acquired an en- tirely different complexion; an almost complete transformation has taken place in the relationship of the various sources. Before the entrance into the World War, the mainstays of federal finances were customs duties and internal revenue taxes on tobacco and liquors. Taxation of corporate and individual in- comes had begun only in 1909 and 1913, respectively, but tested by its lucrativeness it played a secondary r61e. As soon, how- ever, as the necessity for expanding the fiscal program became manifest early in the war, as a result of the prodigious increase 40 in government outlays, attention became focused on the in- come tax and its ally, the excess profits tax, and both became by far the principal revenue producers of the nation. From ^71 millions in 1913-1914, their combined yield grew to ^3,957 millions in 1919-1920, and along with them there developed a system of miscellaneous taxes and licenses to which the emer- gency gave birth. While before the war federal taxes consti- tuted but 30.6% of all taxes combined, during the war the former increased to such an extent as actually to exceed the state and local taxes by a wide margin. Sources and Character of Data One of the popularly recognized distinctions between public and private finance relates to the method employed in raising and expending the revenues. In private finance, income governs outgo; in public finance, expenditures shape and mould the revenue policy. In the individual economy, expenditures are usually circumscribed by the amount of current receipts, although at times the expected but still un- realized income enters into the calculations. In public economy, however, the reverse is usually true. The legis- lative bodies first fix the amounts which they undertake to appropriate, and this done, attention is then directed to securing ways and means to meet the obligations incurred. To contend that the legislator pays no heed to the credit side of his revenue accounts but merely visualizes the debits and determines their proportions, would, however, be a far- fetched and inaccurate notion of actual parliamentary pro- cedure. There is always a limit to taxation, and political ex- pediency very often dictates that even an approach to this condition must be avoided. Nevertheless, it should be recog- nized that as a general rule the expenditure policy is, within reasonable limits, mapped out long before consideration is given to the revenue aspects. Not infrequently a balance becomes impossible and deficit financiering results. This is particularly true in times of war, when loans of all sorts are made to fill the void, with government fiat money sometimes issued when other recourses are considered inadvisable or less attractive; but even in periods of international tranquility, nations have repeatedly failed to meet their current expenses 41 out of revenue for long intervals at a time, as is evidenced by some of the South American countries. This general situation has its reflection in the manner in which public accounts are kept. Where no budgets exist, where more interest is manifested in outgo than in income, where political corruption spreads its tentacles into the public treasury, or where men are elected or appointed as supervisory accounting officers whose technical qualifications are nebulous and whose possession of office represents the reward for party service, sound accounting principles of public finance must perforce give way at times to chaos and opportunism. There still are states that have not discarded their timeworn and antiquated systems of accounting, the retention of which would have long been conducive to bankruptcy were a private organization to pursue the same methods. Perhaps in few other fields of economic research is the investigator confronted with such in- adequate, heterogeneous and disconnected data as in the domain of American public finance. The only attempts at systematic and regular collection of data relating to the public finances of state and local govern- ments have been made by the United States Bureau of the Census. Every year the latter now publishes a volume en- titled "Financial Statistics of States" and "Financial Sta- tistics of Cities over 30,000."^ Financial statistics of munici- palities under 30,000, of counties, villages, towns, town- ships, school and other districts, etc., are not regularly col- lected and published. The latest figures on tax levies for all the minor civil divisions of the states published by the Census Bureau appertain to the year 1902.'' In 1913, the Census Bureau undertook the publication of financial data of cities under 30,000 but over 2,500 and also of counties, in addition to data for states and for cities over 30,000, which have appeared annually or biennially since 1902. Data for other local governments were not, however, included in the scope of the investigation. For both 1902 and 1912, the Census Bureau presented figures which gave the ad valorem tax levies of all states and local governments. Special assessments on property were omitted from the totals in this report wherever the character of the data was such 'Because of pressure due to the decennial Census, this series was interrupted in 1920 but was resumed in 1921. "U. S. Department of Commerce and Labor. "Wealth, Debt, and Taxation." Special Reports of the Census Office, Washington, 1907. 42 as to render this course possible. Special assessments consti- tute exactions from the owners of property to defray the cost of a special public improvement which is made in the interest of the general citizenry, but which accrues to the special benefit of the individual involved. While a tax in its generic sense falls as a direct burden upon the payee, a special assessment theoretically leaves the property owner no poorer than there- tofore, since he is usually compensated by the special benefits conferred or the special services rendered. A tax is a recurring charge levied on all forms of tangible and intangible property, on rights, privileges, occupations, etc., to be disbursed for any object which the legislative authorities see fit. Special assess- ments are, however, intermittent and non-recurring; they are levied only on realty and the revenue therefrom cannot be utilized for any other purpose than the particular improvement or services mentioned in the special legislation enacted. In this report cash receipts for taxes were utilized in the case of federal and state finance, but levies of ad valorem taxes were pri- marily used in determining local burdens because of the paucity of statistics relating to their finances. Allowances were made for other tax levies and miscellaneous licenses. Whether or not the tax levy is wholly or partly collectible in the year to which it refers varies from state to state. Furthermore, the levy does not necessarily correspond to the actual collections, since practically every tax-levying authority has outstanding un- collected taxes, often running into high figures. On the other hand, receipts are to be recorded on account of taxes collected in any given fiscal period other than that in which they were originally levied. In the long run, these items may be assumed more or less to balance each other. As far as the data permitted, duplications appearing in state and local finance accounts were eliminateid. Local governments very often share in state sources of revenue or vice versa, and many difficulties presented themselves in the proper allocation of the items . In a few instances where the state accounts were presented in gross form, it was found necessary to credit the state government with the full amount, thus un- derstating somewhat the local burdens . The total of state and local taxes was not, however, affected by this procedure. In the following paragraphs the procedure in determining the tax burden by principal receiving sources is outlined: 43 (a) Financial Data of the Federal Government. Receipts of the Federal Government from income and excess profits taxes for the year 1919 classified by states, were derived from "Statistics of Income, 1919," published by the U. S. Bureau of Internal Revenue. These data represent the actual tax pay- ments made by individuals and corporations, in the various states.* The grave shortcoming to be noted in the use of this material is that payments do not afford a true and accurate picture of the actual burdens borne by residents and legal entities of the respective states. An individual files his income tax return in the district where his local residence or principal place of business is located, and local entities file their returns in the districts containing their principal place of business or principal office. Obviously, if individuals or corporations de- rive their income from two or more states, their income tax is not apportioned among the states concerned, but the whole amount is credited to the one state in whose districts the returns are filed. This circumstance undoubtedly tends to upset the relative distribution of the federal tax burden by states, and detracts in no small way from the usefulness ol the data. No satisfactory remedy appears at hand wherewith to make the proper allowances or corrections for this factor. This defect must nevertheless be continually borne in mind and any conclusions that are formulated must be qualified by this limitation. Since payments on amount of income and excess profits taxes and the distribution of national income by states relate to the calendar year 1919, it was deemed essential that the balance of federal taxes be referable to the same period. The classification of other federal tax receipts by states, is under- taken only for the government fiscal year, and hence to secure comparability an average of the two fiscal years 1919- 1920 and 1920-1921 was used. Taxes on legal and business transactions, on documents and on insurance, excise taxes on consumers and dealers, and miscellaneous taxes on occupa- tions, acts and privileges, were considered as personal taxes, virtually always borne by the person upon whom they are at first levied. They present on the whole no complications with respect to the matter of state boundaries. Taxes on con- sumption and on services are, however, of interstate char- •These fieures are likely to be swelled by collection of back taxes after returns are com- pletely audited, but records of these adjustments are not available. 44 acter and it would be wholly indefensible to credit to a state where the article or service originates the total of taxes paid by the manufacturer or wholesaler in that state. Taxes on tobacco, beverages, excise taxes on manufactures, postage tax, customs duties and transportation taxes, all fall into this category. These taxes are in large part paid for directly by the ultimate consumer or are later shifted through the various stages of manufacture. These items were allocated among the states according to relative population, on the strength of the theory that they are primarily consumption taxes and that their weight falls more or less evenly on all economic classes, varying directly with the number of consumers. In so far as an appreciable portion of our customs duties is levied on luxuries which find their way among the wealthier classes that are centered in a few states along, say, the Atlantic coast, this method of distribution cannot perhaps be well defended, but taken by and large, the distribution of these taxes by states will vary with their population. {b) Financial Data of States. As stated above, financial data relating to states are now published regularly by the Bureau of the Census. The latest one of the published, series bears the date 1919 and presents tax receipts of state governments whose fiscal years end in the period between July 1, 1918, and June 30, 1919. For the purpose in hand, it was possible to use the Census figures for only fifteen states, viz., Arizona, California, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Michigan, New Jersey, New York, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, South Dakota, West Virginia, Wisconsin and Vermont, since their fiscal years all end June 30, 1919. Figures given by the Census Bureau for the remaining states refer to the fiscal year ending in 1918; hence it was necessary to secure data for the fiscal year ending in 1919 from reports of auditors, comptrollers and treasurers. In some cases captions and titles in the latter reports and statements were not clear enough to indicate the differentia- tion between fees and licenses, for example, and some tax items were highly doubtful. The cooperation of responsible officials was usually sought, but correspondence in some cases failed to bring about a satisfactory disposition of the queries submitted. These uncertainties were allowed to remain in the table, but the percentage of possible error due to their inclusion is relatively small or negligible. 45 (c) Financial Data of Local Governments. Difficulties abounded in securing local government material. In only a few states is an attempt made to secure and publish receipts and expienditures of counties, cities, towns and minor civil divi- sions. Such information is compiled annually principally in Cali- fornia, Iowa (cities and towns only), Massachusetts, Nevada, New Hampshire, Pennsylvania and Wisconsin, and quadren- nially in Connecticut. In a few states it is compiled in in- complete form, as in Virginia; in others, only disbursements are shown, as in Maine. Hence, to obtain comparable re- sults, it was found necessary to utilize levies of general property taxes for all local governments, with allowances made for mis- cellaneous taxes and license receipts, but even here obstacles presented themselves. In not all cases are such data collected. In Florida, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maryland, North Caro- lina, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas and Wyoming, however, county and district taxes were available, or else rates and valuations for these civil divisions were extant on a basis of which computations could be made, with interpola- tions required wherever certain figures were lacking. Taxes and licenses of other civil divisions per capita were assumed to have grown as rapidly as county tax revenues per capita since 1902. For seven states no data whatever could be secured as to local taxes, viz., Alabama, Arkansas, Delaware, Missis- sippi, Montana, Nebraska and Oklahoma; tax receipts per capita of local governments were in these cases estimated on the basis of the increase in state taxes per capita since 1902. The latter figures constitute the least satisfactory in the table. For purpose of comparability, levies of ad valorem taxes, either actual or partly estimated, were usually employed with allowances made for miscellaneous tax receipts and licenses. Taxation by States While a knowledge of the burden that taxation places upon society serves a useful purpose, the value of such a study is considerably enhanced when it becomes localized and assumes a more specific and definite character than a national study permits. Estimates of the national income have recently been made available covering the years 1909-1919.* In connection with these estimates an attempt has been made to distribute 'National Bureau of Economic Researcli, Inc. "Income in the United States," of. cit. 46 the national income for the year 1919 by states, which enables us to make a study of the real burden of taxation state by state, in order to bring out clearly local differences.' The state disclosing the highest percentage of its income diverted to the support of government in the form of taxes is New York with 17.2%. New York State contributed in 1919 one-eighth of the total income and excess profits taxes collected by the Federal Government. As stated elsewhere, however, federal tax payments in any state do not necessarily emanate from the income of the citizens of that state, and hence the burden is somewhat exaggerated. The same conclusion ap- plies with equal or greater force to the state of Delaware, where federal tax collections are swelled by the fact that a large number of corporations operate under Delaware charters and file income tax returns from that state, although the business is conducted mostly in other commonwealths. Texas shows the lowest ratio of total taxes paid to income, namely 7.4%. In the vast majority of the states the ratio exceeds 10% and the general average is 12.1%. This means that in the calendar year 1919 the total tax bill represented one- eighth of the national income. (See Table 17 and Chart 4.) That the burden of state and local taxes is higher in agri- cultural and mining states and that federal taxes fall more heavily on manufacturing states is one of the outstanding observations to be made from Table 17. State and local taxes constituted 9.1% in Montana; 8.1% in North Dakota; in Minnesota, 7.7%; Wisconsin, 7.1%; Nevada, 6.8%; Idaho, 6.6%; Utah, 6.5%; New Mexico, 6.4%; South Dakota, 6.3%; Colorado, 5.8%; Washington, 5.7%; Arizona, 5.6%; and New Hampshire and Nebraska, 5.5%. In New York, on the other hand, the portion of the respective state income diverted to state and local taxes was only 4.7%; in Pennsylvania, 3.1%; Michigan, 4.5%; and Ohio and Illinois, 4.3%. Federal tax collections constituted 12.5% of New York's income; 11.9% in Rhode Island; 11.5% in Delaware; 10.5% in Massachusetts; 10.3% in Michigan; 8.4% in Connecticut; 8.0% in Illinois; 7.8% in Missouri and Pennsylvania and 7.6% in North Caro- lina. In South Dakota, the ratio of federal taxes to state income was only 3.1%; in North Dakota, 3.2%; in Nevada, 3.1%; and in Idaho and Arizona only 3.5%. •Knauth, O. W., National Bureau of Economic Research, "Distribution of Income by States in 1919," Harcourt, Brace and Company, New Yorlc, 1922. 47 An explanation of this circumstance is to be found in the nature of the respective tax systems. Local taxes, which com- prise the bulk of what falls under the combined heading "state and local" taxes, are based on realty and very little on personalty, in view of the evasions which are extensively practiced under the present administration of the general property tax laws in most states. They take no cognizance of profits, earnings, turnover, volume of sales, etc., except in a very general and indefinite way. State taxes are levied partly on property and partly on the basis of other norms. The farmer's wealth is largely tangible and conspicuous; that of other groups in society is in great part intangible and thus often escapes the eye of the tax assessor. Hence, the amount of income expropriated for local taxation is higher in agricul- tural states than in manufacturing states. Federal taxes, on the other hand, are largely based on income, both personal and corporate. Because of the general exemption features and defects inherent in estimating the farmer's income, the latter is not affected, as a general rule, by direct federal tax- ation, but the brunt of the burden falls on the industrialist. This disparity is very marked as between agricultural and industrial states. Per capita taxes in 1919 were highest in New York, with $148.36; followed by Massachusetts, with $125.35; Delaware, J124.41; Rhode Island, |115.25 and Michigan, $105.71. The distinction of having the lowest per capita tax falls to Alabama with $26.47. In sixteen states, viz., Arizona, Florida, Idaho, Iowa, Kansas, Minnesota, Montana, Nebraska, Nevada, New Hampshire, New Mexico, North Dakota, South Dakota, Utah, Washington and Wisconsin, state and local burdens per capita exceeded federal figures. Table 18 shows the distribution of federal taxation by states in 1919 and Tables 19 to 21 inclusive present figures which afford a picture of the growth of state and local taxation in recent years. In Table 22 there are tabulated per capita receipts from taxes and licenses of the principal cities of the United States. The growth of municipal taxes is merely a reflection of what has transpired in the finances of other civil divisions. In 1921, as far as data have been released by the Bureau of the Census, 48 Boston, Mass., shows the highest per capita tax, followed by Los Angeles, Cal., Seattle, Wash., Pittsburgh, Pa., and Bridge- port, Conn. The lowest per capita tax is shown by Mobile, Ala. Chart 4: Distribution of Total Taxation by States, United States (National Industrial Conference Board) TOTAL TAXES .6.a33.TD3.DDD — IDDV. ^LEADING tvlANUFACTUniNG STATES 49 Table 17: Taxes Related to Income, by States, 1919 states Total Income by States> (thousands) All Taxes Federal^ (thousands) State (thousands) Local (thousands) Total Taxes (thousands) Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Dist. of Columbia Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts. . . . Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire. . New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina. . . North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina. . . South Dakota ... Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington. West Virginia. . . . Wisconsin Wyoming ,^. Total $812,496 223,208 666,354 2,816,710 603,538 991,276 174,862 388,256 408,156 1,144,924 262,708 4,968,008 1,710,953 1,711,725 1,071,445 950,801 770,704 449,750 1,000,786 3,017,861 2,580,409 1,391,378 629,512 1,825,325 284,367 916,751 66,500 266,092 2,394,845 147,971 8,960,762 981,034 335,520 3,971,647 1,086,829 558,711 5,950,620 433,114 738,091 440,470 855,467 2,517,469 234,042 186,812 994,443 1,073,048 657,729 1,472,664 154,552 $42,468 7,760 33,019 189,531 39,224 82,809 20,135 22,388 21,843 68,657 9,121 398,969 88,037 64,838 54,677 58,836 61,654 26,522 66,997 321,365 270,137 86,560 32,240 142,973 11,882 35,852 2,093 15,154 163,132 6,141 1,121,074 74,458 10,697 292,427 48,310 34,714 464,894 51,367 44,996 13,705 56,833 126,990 11,947 9,465 65,931 56,076 42,943 91,369 5,656 $6,220' 3,191' 5,551' 24,383' 6,339» 12,651" 3,463" ' '4^,639" 8,11 8« 3,509" 28,385" 11,291" 11,931' 5,630' 10,851' 6,963" 8,552*' 10,509" 33,9142* 21,313' 20,637^ 4,757«' 11,491» 3,640" 7.519" 1,401«' 3,396" 25,623'= 2,112" 76,112" 7.178» 2,493' 20,003' 8,526' 4,500» 46,075" 4,761" 4,357" 3,104' 7,770«i 23,143" 4,997*' 3,247' 11,936" 11,791" 4,207' 15,924' 1,580« $13,476* 9,383' 15,428' 111,377' 29,088' 38,922' 4,148" 9,334" 16,043" 21,194" 13,945' 186,077' 62,808' 74,817' 49,409« 28,782" 29,468" 12,624' 24,122" 127,6102' 96,352' 86,284' 22,4102' 76,285" 22,18828 42,830« 3,170« 11,396' 85,225' 7,316» 343,506' 24,849" 24,852' 150,870' 34,724* 24,298' 132,825' 13,520' 13,638" 24,434' 24,839" 43,643" 10,349' 5,415' 18,819« 50,106' 28,113' 89,155' 5,688" $62,164 20,334 53,998 325,291 74,651 134,382 27,746 31,722 42,525 97,969 26,575 613,431 162,136 151,586 109,716 98,469 98,085 47,698 101,628 482,889 387,802 193,481 59,407 230,749 37,710 86,201 6,664 29,946 273,980 15,569 1,540,692 106,485 38,042 463,300 91,560 63,512 643.794 69,648 62,991 41,243 89,442 193,776 27,293 18,127 96,686 117,973 75,263 196,448 12,924 $66,250,695 $5,068,866 SO $569.683 $2,395.154 $8.033,703 Table 17: Taxes Related to Income, by States, 1919 — continued Total Fed- Taxes eral as Taxes Per as Per Cent Cent of of Total Total In- Income come State and Local Taxes as Per Cent of Total In- come Per Capita Total In- come of States Federal Taxes State Taxes Local Taxes Total Taxes States 7.6 9.1 8.2 11. S 12.3 13.6 IS. 8 8.2 10.5 8.6 10 12 9 8 10 10 12 10 10 IS IS.O 13.9 9.4 12.6 13.3 9 9 11 11 10 17 10.8 11.3 11.7 8.4 11.3 10.9 16.1 8.S 9.4 10.4 7.6 11.6 9.8 9.7 10.9 11.4 13.3 8.4 5.2 3.5 5.0 6.7 6.5 8.4 11. S 5.8 5.4 6.0 3.5 8.0 5.1 3.8 5.1 6.2 8.0 5.9 6.7 10.6 10.5 6.2 5.1 7.8 4.2 3.9 3 5 6 4 12 7.6 3.2 7.4 4.4 6.2 7.8 11.9 6.1 3.1 6.6 5.0 5.1 5.1 6.6 5.2 6.5 6.2 3.7 2.4 5.6 3.2 4.8 5.8 5.2 4.3 2.4 5.1 2.6 6.6 4.3 4.3 5.1 5.1 4.2 4.7 4.7 3.5 5.3 4.5 7.7 4.3 4.8 9.1 5.5 6.8 8.1 4.3 4.0 5.1 .3.1 4.2 2.4 6.3 3.8 2.6 6.5 4.7 3.1 5.7 4.9 7.1 4.7 12.1 7.6 4.5 $627 $346 668 380 822 642 718 784 887 421 395 608 766 584 712 606 393 429 586 690 783 703 583 352 536 518 707 859 601 759 411 863 383 519 690 536 713 682 717 438 692 366 540 521 530 431 791 449 560 795 $18.08 23.22 18.84 55.31 41.75 59.98 90.29 51.16 22.55 23.71 21.12 61.52 30.04 26.97 30.90 24.35 34.28 34.53 46.22 83.42 73.64 36.26 18.01 42.00 21.65 27.65 27.04 34.20 51.69 17.04 107.95 29.10 16.54 50.77 23.82 44.31 53.31 84.99 26.72 21.53 24.31 27.23 26.58 26.86 28.55 41.34 29.34 34.71 29.09 $47.95 $2.65 9.55 3.17 7.11 6.73 9.16 15.52 '4!79 2.81 8.13 4.38 3.85 4.96 3.18 4.49 3.87 11.14 7.25 8.80 5.81 8.65 2.66 3.37 6.62 5.80 18.10 7.67 8.12 .86 .33 .80 .85 .47 .21 .74 5.28 7.88 2.59 4.87 3.32 4.96 11.12 9.21 5.17 8.69 2.87 6.05 8.13 $5.74 28.09 8.81 32.50 30.95 28.18 18.60 21.33 16.57 7.32 32.28 28.69 21.43 31.12 27.93 11.91 16.38 16.44 16.64 33.13 26.26 36.15 12.51 22.41 40.42 33.05 40.95 25.72 27.00 20.30 33.08 9.71 38.41 26.20 17.12 31.02 15.23 22.38 8.10 38.39 10.62 9.36 23.03 15.36 8.15 36.93 19.20 33.87 29.26 $5.39 $22.66 51 $26.47 60.86 30.82 94.92 79.43 97.32 124.41 72.49 43.91 33.84 61.53 94.59 55.32 63.05 62.01 40.75 54.53 62.11 70.11 125.35 105.71 81.06 33.18 67.78 68.69 66.50 86.09 67.59 86.81 43.20 148.36 41.61 58.80 80.44 45.15 81.07 73.82 115.25 37.41 64.79 38.25 41.55 60.73 51.43 41.87 86.96 51.41 74.63 66.48 $76.00 Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware .Dist. of Columbia Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada . . .New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York .... North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island .... South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Total References: Table // •Figures derived from "Distribution of the National Income by States, 1919," published by the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (Harcourt, Brace & Company, New York, 1922.) 'For details, see Table 18. 'Annual Report of the Auditor of the State of Alabama, Year ending Sep- tember 30, 1919, pp. 27-29. ^Estimated by allowing the maximum constitutional rates, plus miscellaneous taxes and allowances. Figures of assessed valuation were derived from the Annual Report of the Auditor of the State of Alabama for the Fiscal Year ending September 30, 1919, p. 81. ^Financial Statistics of States, 1919, Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, pp. 64-65. 'Includes also estimated amounts received from taxes other than on general property and licenses of every nature, based with certain adjustments on the experience of counties and cities over 8,000 in 1902 and 1913. In addi- tion to Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1907 and 1913, op. cit., the following sources were used in securing the general property levy of counties and all local civil divisions: Arizona, Fifth Biennial Report of the Arizona Tax Com- mission, December 31, 1920, inserts, pp. 76, 78-79, 80-81 and 82; Colorado, Tenth Annual Report of the Colorado Tax Commission, 1921, pp. 100-103; Connecticut, Report of the Tax Commissioner for the Biennial Period, 1919 and 1920, pp. 140-147; Idaho, First Biennial Report of the Department of Finance to the Governor, 1919-1920, Exhibit G; Illinois, Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts, Nov. IS, 1920, pp. 179-183; Indiana, Annual Report of the Auditor of the State of Indiana for year ended Sept. 30, 1919, pp. 27-32; Iowa, Report of the Auditor of State for the Biennial Period ending June 30, 1920, pp. 140-149; Kansas, Seventh Biennial Report of the Tax Com- mission of the State of Kansas, for the period Oct. 16, 1918 and Oct. IS, 1920, pp. 256-257; Maine, 29th Annual Report of the Board of State Assessors of the State of Maine, 1919, pp. 134 and 135, with state taxes levied on cities and towns deducted (Cf. Seventli Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the Fiscal years ending Dec. 31, 1919 and Dec. 31, 1920, p. 54); Michigan, Report of the Board of State Tax Commissioners and State Board of Assessors, 1919-1920, pp. 96-97 and 102-103; Minnesota, Seventh Biennial Report of the Minnesota Tax Commission, 1920, p. 19; Nebraska, estimated on the basis of total levies of 1921, as furnished by the Department of Finance in specially tabulated form; Nevada, Biennial Report of the Nevada Tax Commission, 1919-1920, pp. 58-59; New Hampshire, 10th Annual Report of the New Hampshire State Tax Commission, tax year of 1920, pp. 39-40; New Jersey, Fourth Annual Report of the State Board of Taxes and Assessments for the year ending June 30, 1919, pp. 167, 356 and 360; New York, Annual Report of the State Tax Com- mission, 1919, pp. 497-501; North Dakota, Fifth Biennial Report of the North Dakota Tax Commissioner for the fiscal years 1919 and 1920, pp. 80-81; Ohio, Uth Annual Report of the Tax Commission of Ohio for the year ended Dec. 31, 1920, p. 8; Oregon, Sixth Biennial Report of the State Tax Commission, 1921, pp. 38-39; Pennsylvania, based on Report on Productive Industries, Railways, Taxes and Assessments, Waterways and Miscellaneous Statistics of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania for the year 1920, Dept. of Internal Affairs, pp. 80 S., with state license collections eliminated as far as possible; Rhode Island, Eighth Report of the Board of Tax Commissioners of the State of Rhode Island, for the Biennial period, 1919-1920, p. 42, insert, with esti- mated figures included for fire districts and other municipal subdivisions for which no data were available; South Dakota, Annual Report of the Tax Com- mission of the State of South Dakota, 1919-1920, pp. 88 et seq.; Utah, Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the period ending Nov. 30, 1920, p. 47; Ver- 52 mont. Biennial Report of the Commissioner of Taxes of the State of Vermont for the term ending June 30, 1920, pp. 126-131; Washington, Second Biennial Report of the State Tax Commissioner of Washington for the period ending Sept. 30, 1920, pp. 30-32; JVest Virginia, letter of the State Tax Commissioner to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 15, 1922; Wisconsin, 10th Biennial Report of the Wisconsin Tax Commission, 1920, p. 124, and Financial Statistics of Cities of Wisconsin, Wisconsin Tax Com- mission, pp. 20 S. 'State taxes represent the average for the two years beginning Oct. 1, 1918 and ending Sept. 30, 1920. Biennial Report of the Treasurer of State of Arkan- sas, for the Biennial Period beginning Sept. 30, 1918 and ending Sept. 30, 1920, p. 24. Local taxes were estimated on the basis of suggestions and figures furnished by the Auditor of State in his letter to the National Industrial Con- ference Board, under dates of June 24 and June 28, 1922. 'Annual Report of Financial Transactions of Municipalities and Counties of California for the year 1919, pp. 33, 186-187 and 189, and idem, for the year 1920, pp. 61, 188-189 and 191. Average for the two years was employed in view of^the fact that the tax figures cover the years ended June 30, 1919 and June 30, 1920. •Biennial Report of the Auditor of State of Colorado, 1919-1920, pp. 37 ff. •"Report of the Treasurer for the Year ended June 30, 1920, Public Document No. 10, pp. S if. Figures appertain to the fiscal year ended June 30, 1920, inasmuch as the preceding fiscal year was of only 9 months' duration. "Annual Report of the State Treasurer, 1919, pp. 13-15 and p. 26. Local taxes were estimated on the basis of the per capita increase in taxation in the City of Wilmington and in the County of New Castle. The latter information was furnished by the State Tax Department in its letter to the National Indus- trial Conference Board, dated June 30, 1922. •^Annual Report of the Commissioners of the District of Columbia, Year ended June 30, 1919, Vol. I, pp. 70-71. "Report of the Comptroller of the State of Florida for the year ending December 31, 1919, pp. 7 ff. '^Property taxes for civil divisions other than counties were estimated on the basis of increases in county tax levies since 1902 with allowances for receipts from miscellaneous taxes and licenses. In addition to Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1907 and 1913, op. cit.j the following sources were used which gave only property tax levies of counties: Florida, Report of the Comptroller of the State of Florida for the year ending December 31, 1919, pp. 136-137; Ken- tucky, based on a table forwarded by the State Tax Commission bearing date of January 23, 1922, which furnished a comparison of county tax levies in 1917 and 1921, with 1919 figures interpolated; Louisiana, State and Local Taxes for the year 1919 compiled by the Board of State Affairs, April, 1920, pp. 30 and 54-55; Maryland, Third Biennial Report of the State Tax Com- mission of Maryland, 1919-1920, pp. 27 ff, and Annual Report of the Comp- troller of Baltimore City, for the fiscal year ended December 31, 1919; Mis- souri, Report of the State Auditor of Missouri for the Two Fiscal Years begin- ning January 1, 1919 and ending December 31, 1920, p. 607; North Carolina, Report of the State Tax Commission, 1919, p. 421; South Carolina, Report of the Comptroller General of South Carolina to the General Assembly for the Fiscal Year 1919, pp. 50-53; Tennessee, First Biennial Report of the Tennessee Board of Equalization, 1919-1920, p. 114, with municipal taxes estimated on the basis of the figure given for 1920 {ibid., p. 135); Texas, Annual Report of the Comptroller of Public Accounts for tie FiscalYear ended August 31, 1919, Tatle 46, with estimates made in the counties for which rates lyere lacking; Wyoming, First Biennial Report of the State Board of Equalization, 191^1920, pp. 44-64 and Appendix F. "Annual Report of the Treasurer and State Bank Examiner of the State of Georgia for Year ending December 31, 1919, pp. 14 ff, and Report of the Comptroller-General of the State of Georgia for the Year ending December 31, 1920, pp. 25 ff. Local taxes were estimated on the basis of the average 53 rates paid by public service corporations on their assessed valuations: Report of the Comptroller-General for the Year ending December 31, 1919, pp. 239, 391 and 394. "Average for two years. Fifteenth Biennial Report of the Auditor of the State of Idaho, October 1, 1918 to September 30, 1920, p. 26 ff. "Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts, November IS, 1920, pp. 10 fF. "Annual Report of the Auditor of the State of Indiana for the Year Ended September 30, 1919, pp. 6 fF. "Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts of the State of Louisiana, for the years 1918 and 1919, Part II, pp. 38-42. ^Seventh Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the Fiscal Years Ending December 31, 1919 and December 31, 1920, pp. 53-56. ^•Annual Report of the Comptroller of the Treasury of the State of Mary- land for the Fiscal Year Ending September 30, 1919, pp. 10 fF. '^'Report of the Auditor of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts for the Fiscal Year Ending November 30, 1919, pp. 2 ff. "Thirty-third Annual Report on the Statistics of County Finances for the Year Ending December 31, 1919, Commission of Corporations and Taxation, Division of Accounts, pp. 17-18, and 14th Annual Report on the Statistics of Municipal Finances, for City and Town Fiscal Years Ending between November 30, 1919 and March 31, 1920, Commission of Corporations and Tax- ation, p. viii. '^Figures appertain to the fiscal year ended June 30, 1920, the previous fiscal period being only of eleven months' duration. Biennial Report of the State Auditor to the Legislature of Minnesota for the Fiscal Years Ending June 30, 1919, and June 30, 1920, p. 104. '"Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts of the State of Mississippi, from October 1, 1917, to October 1, 1919, pp. 184 ff. Local taxes were esti- mated at suggestion of the Mississippi Tax Commission, on the basis of the average tax rates paid by the Cumberland Telephone and Telegraph Company in the State of Mississippi "which pays taxes in nearly every municipal, school district, road district and county in the State" (letter to the National Indus- trial Conference Board, dated June 24, 1922). This information was secured through the courtesy of the American Telegraph and Telephone Company. ^'Report of the State Auditor for the Two Fiscal Years beginning January 1, 1919, and ending December 31, 1920, pp. 7 ff. "According to a letter of the State Treasurer to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of May 10, 1922. *'Based on figures compiled by the State Board of Equalization and the Montana Taxpayers' Association, Bulletins 1, 2 and 3, with allowance made for miscellaneous taxes and licenses. ^'Average for the two years ending November 30, 1920. Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts, State of Nebraska, 1919-1920, pp. 20 ff. '"Annual Report of the State Controller, 1919, pp. 6-7. "Report of the State Treasurer of the State of New Hampshire for the Fiscal Year Ending August 31, 1919, pp. 5 ff. '"Report of the Joint Committee on Treasurer's Accounts and of the State Treasurer for the Fiscal Year Ending June 30, 1919; also Financial Statistics of States, 1919, op. cit. ''Biennial Report of the Auditor of the State of New Mexico for the Seventh and Eighth Fiscal Years Ending November 30, 1920, pp. 5 ff. Local taxes comprise local levies as given in Report of Special Revenue Commission to the Governor and Legislature of the State of New Mexico, 1920, pp. 296 and 324, plus miscellaneous taxes and licenses estimated. ''Report of the Comptroller for the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1920, pp. 6 ff. 54 "Biennial Report of the Treasurer of North Carolina, 1919-1920, pp. 24-25. ^Biennial Report of the State Treasurer, 1919-1920, pp. 25 S. "SmuU's Legislative Handbook and Manual of the State of Pennsylvania, 1920, pp. 1005-1007. ''Annual Report of the General Treasurer from January 1 to December 31, 1919, pp. 13-14 and 29 S. "Report of the Comptroller-General of South Carolina to the General Assembly for Fiscal Year 1919, pp. 18 fF. "Figures relate to the fiscal year ended June 30, 1920, the previous fiscal period extending only from December 19, 1918 to June 30, 1919. Biennial Report of the Comptroller of the Treasury, December 19, 1918, to June 30, 1920, to the 62nd General Assembly, pp. 29-32. ^'Annual Report of the Comptroller of Public Accounts for the State of Texas, for the Year Ended August 31, 1919, pp. 8 fF. **Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the Period Ending November 30, 1920, pp. 15-16. ^'Annual Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts for the Fiscal Year End- ing September 30, 1919, pp. 5 fF. Taxes and licenses in counties, districts and municipalities were derived from ibid., pp. 245-260, with estimates made wherever data were lacking. **Average for the two fiscal years ended September 30, 1920. 16th Biennial Report of the State Treasurer, October 1, 1918, to September 30, 1920, pp. 9 fF. and 79-80, and 16th Biennial Report of the Secretary of State, October 1, 1918, to September 30, 1920, p. 6. "■Average for the two fiscal years ended September 30, 1920. Biennial Report of the Treasurer of the State of Wyoming for the Two Years Ending September 30, 1920, pp. 8-9. 55 5SS ^H CO"* \0 oo VO VJ-I ,-H OO C^ »-< lO CS 00 oo CO oo Tf* CO u^ t^ o» CO a\ 1-H O -^ C\ oo oo N^ CO oo ^ u-i (S \0 CO , '~lv^°'^^ *"!> ^ ®« 'cTcT.-h'oo' oCocT ocT CS C4 CS VD OS OO CO «j-» t— I CO '— ' r^ oo CO t^ CO »o cs Os oo ^0O^^O^»J-l^ON \o »0 lO \c cs ^o ONVO ^O CO CO -H cocs ■^--^coco 'oCcTcn'cs lo -^ 1^ oo ^o CN On OO CO CO ^ »ooo Wto" in ON OO o ICO ON *— t pq O 'THr^*^»o\oio»ot^ roi>**-HiOvO<00\t— O^ThONOsOO^»-icOO'-'*^*OOOt*rot^ 00^0fOf0lOO'Ot--O^Tt*00OlO^0^^CS^H\0^-^^0^Ov^H^0^ ONO'^a^oooi-i''-toocsiooMoosO\eNT-ioovo»ooooo*^r*c*« ^OOO es i/^ ^ ooo 00 lOOs^-i CO O NO Vio^oo «-* tH ro S '■«*'qo'' H cooo t- fO^lO lO CO '^ lOOOO ^On^C^I^C^ cor^ "O ^cocs ONOOOiOCOt^vOC-lxOOsC^tO iopo^co^oo*^r^^rooo ^oq^oo^Ttj^io^vo^oq^ON^io^ON^-^NO o •HO^CSvOcoCSt^xOOv ^tO* ^ — ' "^ ^ni ' ^ ^ "^ » ' ^ V '^ 4 '^ ^^ ^A '^^ ■* J cooo\0"«*«o>o t^O^t^O^^^^ Th VO *-t "* lO ^-H CO CS ^^ (N t^ lO CO CS lO c^ 10 fl si t- H to 00 CScovO tnt^ VO 00*^ Ov -, _ ,_ t^OOCSCNfOlOO^-lOOtOOOCOf^NOOfO TJ^^O^^lO^(N^cs^c*^^«^lr^^^•^^^^T^^oq^^^oq^e^^to^Ti^^l^ .^ q^ cooOvOO^OOOiOroONiOv-iPOt^CN^HOt^OcSPO OcT^-^rrT 0siOP0iO^OC0'rt^vO^O\ Ov^co i-H r* eS CfTt^^CM io*io t^ ooc^v*^oof*^o^^cP^f^c^tn'>G'^-r^ lO^CN ^co Oscococscoes CNvOT**cocsrl< «-i to S.2 JS T3 3 CB Q, e.r g. .!^ a 3) s « 3 S W'r' rt-SS* si eg = w ;i^-g^ssg-i^i:i.siil 3^-3 & " " _55 56 11- •sis •2-1 1sl| s 8! <> DO OJ ^ n A 1 1^ ■ssiss C: >S S ?! !2 S2 fTTiS'^'Q "^^"^"o'lo'cs-oo \o 32i2£!£5;S22®'"t-0'N=^"2< ^^ O op ^O ^J CO W ^ ^> v-^ '(^ WW (v' "J *"*■ tJ tJV t. ■. •». .... (Art OtO gcsi(NCS'*o ^KSSj OM-t~rt vo^^irj t^ 00 VO ro r^ ^lO t^ TjToTTircxr C; £: rt t-T ,-1 CO OO C^^H CO eS(Ni-(OOlOO»CS'-*"OOM>-CSP*:i'^fOiOOOOOOPO \0 c^i lo es t^ 00 ^cTon c*HOTt'^o HPOOO^T^^O■^'^'-lOOvOw^*O^C^^O^u^^ bO\0»-''^'O00CJ|^-00CS-»-H'*C^0sQ0'«*es|t^ ^ ^ ► C o CO rt J? S" . b. CO rt « 0) ^^ (i» c y a a 60,3 -a c H-5 .S-a-S S " ;^A-";5 o o "^"A^^jr-fefefefe- ES o* 2 SS a I: OJ ^S 2 "u I"* _ ™ Rl ° a 3 S w S 0) " V Sia .» 3 o o is 2 eg "B "Is ■a toM*' s:§§ oJ fl S •- .as!ai saa* l^-so-S «a5ag ■a S'« o s •fill si iSSS-sg Itiisga u v 57 00 1* rCOO JiO^^ OS «^ OO Ov CO O^ O* C^ O I') fi^H'^ ' «4* 00 1^ lO t^ C^ C4 rO 00 00 TirSfo • lo'e^Too'cTo ro^oToO tJ* t^ 3iO<^ ■ lO M -^ 00 -^ CN NO 'O 0\ C^J acsoo . CO -^ *^ "<** «s t^ CO 00 r* o\ ■< ^-H tH . O 0\ "O '^ r*5 '-I CO fO CO 0\ ;coM :32 aoo 3 00O0 ■ro '0000 • irj •»» vo ^2 •§ -^S H 15 W S a! M > O O roo l,vO OS »0 ooog\ CM 00 o, ) lOVO O ■* lO ■* C 00 Ot coco OS VO com '0\0\ CO 00 e« M « op t^ CO OS r^^t^u^Os, t* lo-oo 00 ^H CN »-i ■^c-^xnoo - cosOOvO NOt^ OS SO lOCS Os-^ CMO OsO* CO CO ' CO CO cot* ^ CO CO *-! lOCOt CO CO <>• »-i O OS CO»OtJ«OS SO t^t^lOoTcO CO Orjt O'^ T*co ■^^"^ 00 to OS NO 58 s R S5 > O O < u o O U o Oh is M O n e2 0\ cq >ooo OS a o f4 M eo . m D9 ^ V ^ ■« C^OOvH NOOO 00t^lO'HO\00 OvoO «~t^ . ■c^ mt^ tJ< cor* « in CO B 3 rot~ 31O00 roor-' 5^.2 « 00 A O r4 M M c« eg M ^ ^ •* ^ SCO lO ^ ^ X^ J>. -^ r* CO lo vo O o 0»Hcoe>l COON ooo\ <-H CO 00 00 to CO o e^ t^O\00O *-t vQ *:}* ^N ^ t"^ i"* ^ OOtJ* Tj< T-i 00 \o ^O O t t* 00\»0 W VO^ lO CO '-I Ov O ** c C^OJ,« t* CO 0\^ O to CO »0 ON t-i'i^' M CO NVOOp C« a a lljllii-iili.il 0^ O^ O^ ^ Ob (h 1-1 t-< Lj u u u I. > > > 3 O O O \ 0\ ON 0\ ON 9t ON ON tui ■§-62 1-1 iH vH 22 OvO\0\ S u u a> fe S fe o o o OvOO O^ ON vt gZt-HMl-Ht< I o_fl „ ._ -_ <^d V V V S: b u u u r^^ fl fl a I •z^ 59 References: Table ig 'Unless otherwise stated, the figures appertain to counties, cities, towns, townships, villages, boroughs, school, fire and other districts, etc., and represent lemes of general property taxes, but in the case of California and Pennsylvania figures of actual collection (including licenses) were used. In some cases, the figures include taxes other than those falling under the head of general property taxation, because of the fact that comparability might be vitiated were a segre- gation made in the data presented. Appropriate notations to this eiFect are made in the footnotes wherever such instances occur. ^Derived from Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1913, Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Vol. I, pp. 797 flF, unless otherwise noted. 'Fifth Biennial Report of the Arizona Tax Commission, Dec. 31, 1920, pp. 76, 78-82 and inserts. Figures for 1921 were submitted by the Arizona State Tax Commission in a letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 12, 1922. 'Annual Report of Financial Transactions of Municipalities and Counties of California for the year 1912, pp. 32, 72 and 73; idem, for the year 1919, pp. 33, 186, 187 and 189; idem, for the year 1920, pp. 61, 69, 188, 189 and 191; idem, for the year 1921, pp. 56, 63, 165 and 185. 'Third Annual Report of the Colorado Tax Commission, 1914, pp. 60-61; Tenth Annual Report, 1921, idem, pp. 100-103. 'Report of the Tax Commissioner for the Biennial Period 1919 and 1920, pp. 140 and 151. For 1912, the Census figures were used (Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1913, Vol. I, p. 797) diminished by the amount paid out by the towns as a military tax to the state (Report of the Tax Commissioner for the Biennial Period 1913-1914, pp. 187-188.) 'Annual Report of the Commissioners of the District of Columbia, Year ended June 30, 1912, Vol. I, p. 62; idem. Year ended June 30, 1920, Vol. I, pp. 114 ff.; idem, year ended June 30, 1921, pp. 8-9. 'County taxes only. Report of the Comptroller of the State of Florida, for the year ending Dec. 31, 1912, pp. 194-195; idem, for the year ending Dec. 31, 1919, pp. 136-137; idem, for the year ending Dec. 31, 1920, pp. 88-89; idem, for the year ending Dec. 31, 1921, pp. 166-167. 'First Biennial Report of the Department of Finance to the Governor, 1919-1920, Exhibit G, and letter from the Department of Finance, addressed to the National Industrial Conference Board, bearing date of July 7, 1922. Figures for 1920 and 1921 include, however, special assessments of cities and villages. '"Biennial Report of the Auditor of Public Accounts, 1913-1914, p. 135 and idem, 1919-1920, pp. 10 ff. Figures for 1920 were submitted by the State Auditor in a letter to the Board under date of June 13, 1922. Includes dog taxes. "Annual Report of the Auditor of State of the State of Indiana for the Fiscal year ending Sept. 30, 1913, pp. 32 ff; idem, for the fiscal year ending Sept. 30, 1919, as reprinted from Year Book, pp. 27-32; idem, for the Fiscal Year ending Sept. 30, 1920, pp. 153-158. Figures for 1921 were obtained from a letter by the State Board of Tax Commissioners addressed to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 23, 1922. "Report of the Auditor of State for the Biennial Period ending June 30, 1914, p. 378; idem. Biennial Period ending June 30, 1920, pp. 140-149; Valu- ation and Taxes, compiled by the State Auditor, 1922, pp. 7 ff. "Third Report of the Tax Commission of the State of Kansas, for the Period Oct. 16, 1910 and Oct. 16, 1912, p. 168; idem, for the Period Oct. 16, 1918 and Oct. 15, 1920, pp. 256-257. Figures for 1920 and 1921 were furnished by the State Tax Commission in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 29, 1922. "County taxes only. Figures for 1919 and 1920 interpolated. Chart pre- pared by the State Tax Commission bearing date of Feb. 14, 1922. "County taxes, including City of New Orleans. State and Local Taxes for the year 1919, compiled by the Board of State Affairs, April, 1920, pp. 60 54-SS and p. 280; and Fifth Annual Report of the Louisiana Tax Commission (formerly Board of State Affairs) for the year 1921, pp. 284-287. "Twenty-ninth Annual Report of the Board of State Assessors of the State of Maine, 1919, pp. 134-135; 30th Annual Report, 1920, idem, p. 13S; 22nd Annual Report, 1912, idem, p. 135. Figures for 1921 were submitted by the Board of State Assessors in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of May 6, 1922. State taxes on cities and towns were deducted, being derived from the Third Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the Fiscal Years ending Dec. 31, 1911 and Dec. 31, 1912, p. 53; 7th Biennial Re- port, idem, Dec. 31, 1919 and Dec. 31, 1920, pp. 40 and 233; and letter from the Board of State Assessors, dated June 20, 1922. '"County taxes, including City of Baltimore, as computed from rates and valuations given in Third Biennial Report of the State Tax Commission of Maryland, 1919-1920, pp. 27 if. Fourth Biennial Report, idem, 1920-1921, pp. 13 fF. "Including polls. Annual Report of the Commissioner of Corporations and Taxation for the year ending Nov. 30, 1921, Public Document No. 16, p. 65. "Report of the Board of State Tax Commissioners and State Board of Assessors, 1913-1914, pp. 78-79; idem, 1919-1920, pp. 96-97 and 102-103. Figures for 1920 and 1921 were submitted by the Board of State Tax Commis- sioners in its letter to the Board under date of June 14, 1922. '"Fourth Biennial Report of the Minnesota Tax Commission, 1914, p. 343 ff; Seventh Biennial Report, idem, 1920, pp. 240-259. Excludes money and credits taxes. Figures for 1921 derived from a chart furnished by the Minne- sota Tax Commission. "Counties only. Report of the State Auditor for the Two Fiscal Years, beginning Jan. 1, 1911 and ending Dec. 31, 1912, p. 483; idem, 1919-1920, pp. 605-607. '^Figures obtained from compilations of the State Board of Equalization and Bulletins 1, 2 and 3, of the Montana Taxpayers' Association. '"Estimated tax revenue. Biennial Report of the Nevada Tax Commission, 1919-1920, pp. 58-59; County and City Budgets for the year 1922, compiled from budgets filed with the Nevada Tax Commission, which give figures for 1921 and 1922. '^Tenth Annual Report of the New Hampshire State Tax Commission, Tax Year of 1920, pp. 39-40; 11th Annual Report, idem, 1921, pp. 29-30. Includes polls. ^Eighth Annual Report of the Board of Equalization of Taxes for year ending Oct. 31, 1912, p. 135; Fourth Annual Report of the State Board of Taxes and Assessments for the year ending June 30, 1919, p. 167; idem, for the year ending June 30, 1920, p. 140, idem, for the year ending June 30, 1921, p. 121. Excludes municipal franchise and gross receipts taxes. ^'Report of the Special Revenue Commission to the Governor and Legislature of the State of New Mexico, 1920, pp. 296 and 324. ^'Annual Report of the State Board of Tax Commissioners, 1912, pp. 520- 521; Annual Report of the State Tax Commission, 1919, pp. 497-501; idem, 1919, pp. 497-501; idem, 1920, pp. 369-371; Figures for 1921 were furnished by the State Tax Commission in letters addressed to the National Industrial Conference Board and bearing dates of June 13 and July 11, 1922. "Counties and schools only. Capitation taxes and miscellaneous licenses included. Report of the State Tax Commission, 1913, p. 339; idem, 1920, p. 439. ''Fifth Biennial Report of the North Dakota Tax Commissioner for the Fiscal Years 1919 and 1920, pp. 80-81; figures for 1920 and 1921 were derived from data enclosed by the Tax Department in its letter to the National Indus- trial Conference Board under date of June 23, 1922. '"Fifth Annual Report of the Tax Commission of Ohio, 1914, p. 376; idem, for the year ending Dec. 31, 1920, p. 8. The figures for 1920 and 1921 were 61 derived from a, circular issued by the Office of the Tax Commission, Depart- ment of Finance. "Second Biennial Report of the State Tax Commission, 1913, p. 85; Sixth Biennial Report, 1921, idem, pp. 38-41; and letter of the State Tax Commission to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 16, 1922. '^Includes licenses collected by local governments, part of which reverts to the State government. Amount for 1912 was secured from Report of the Secretary of Internal Affairs for the year ending Nov. 30, 1912, Part I, p. 9B; figures for 1919 were interpolated; figures for 1920 and 1921 were derived from Report on Productive Industries, Railways, Taxes and Assessments, Water- ways and Miscellaneous Statistics of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania for the year 1920, Dept. of Internal Affairs, p. 889. ''Data refer to municipalities and are exclusive of amounts reverting to the State. First Annual Report of the Board of Tax Commissioners, Jan. 15, 1912, pp. 119 ff; Eighth Annual Report of the Board of Tax Commissioners of the State of Rhode Island for the Biennial Period 1919-1920, p. 42 insert. Figures for 1921 were derived from data submitted by the Board of Tax Com- missioners in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 14, 1922. '^Counties and schools only. Includes capitation and dog taxes. Report of the Comptroller-General of South Carolina to the General Assembly for the Fiscal Year 1912, Part II, pp. 93-96; idem, for the Fiscal Year 1919, pp. 50-53; idem, for the Fiscal Year 1920, pp. 61-64, Seventh Annual Report of the South Carolina Tax Commissioii, 1921, pp. 111-114. ''Annual Report of the Tax Commission of the State of South Dakota, 1919- 1920, pp. 108-109; idem, 1920-1921, pp. 106-107. Figures for 1921 were sub- mitted by the State Tax Commission in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 15, 1922. ''Counties only. First Biennial Report of the Tennessee State Board of Equalization, 1919-1920, pp. 114 and 135; letter of the State Tax Department to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 20, 1922. "For counties only, computed from tax rates and valuations with figures interpolated in the case of counties for which rates were lacking. Annual Report of the Comptroller of Public Accounts for the Fiscal Year ended Aug. 31, 1919, Table 46 and idem. Fiscal year ended Aug. 31, 1920, Table 80. "Biennial Report of the State Auditor for the Period ending Nov. 30, 1920, pp._ 47-48; mimeographed compilation furnished by the State Board of Equali- zation. "Biennial Report of the Commissioner of Taxes of the State of Vermont for the Term ending June 30, 1920, pp. 126-131, and letter of the Commissioner of Taxes under date of July 8, 1922, addressed to the National Industrial Conference Board. "Second Biennial Report of the State Tax Commissioner of Washington for the Period ending Sept. 30, 1920, pp. 30-32; Statement of 1921 Taxes Due in 1922, prepared by the Division of^ Municipal Corporations, pp. 7-8. ''Letter of the State Tax Commissioner to the National Industrial Confer- ence Board, dated June 15, 1922. ^^Includes soldiers' bonus in 1919. Tenth Biennial Report of the Wiscon- sin Tax Commission, 1920, p. 124 arid Bulletin No. IS of the Wisconsin Tax Commission, June, 1922. Figures for 1921 were submitted by the Wisconsin Tax Commission in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June 15, 1922. ^'Counties and school districts only. Third Biennial Report of the Com- missioner of Taxation of Wyoming, 1913-1914, p. 76; First Biennial Report of the State Board of Equalization of Wyoming, 1919-1920, pp. 44-64 and Appen- dix F. Figures for 1921 were furnished by the State Board of Equalization in its letter to the National Industrial Conference Board under date of June IS, 1922. 62 » X M B. O CM < Pi H o M W (X O 05 H •J ■51 o o a, < o M Ph n S?3 :S 00P0iO\0f0\0T-ii-MJ:^t^'^'OCS'-<'-fO»OO»O-^iO0MOP0f0iO lo,-^cococor-cs^H^OO^»-^fOco^OPOt^OesOOcscs'Ot^^*c*^ 'OOsOi>»OOCSt^OO\OO^fOtOiO^*'OrOt*500tO^ONOOOO CJ Cq CO 6l CS ^ f*3 CS CS CS CN tH ^-H i-H CS CS fO T-t CO CS «S ^^ fO CO ^-l^-H00OO^^^»T^^00^O^0C0^OvO'O'^t^'O00e^^^'-'C0^*O^-^ ■^*OO00'^'^\0C0^^H00eSC0'^'^C*^C»O\0s\0C^«*^"^C>'O'^ fO■<*^t^co^*lOlnTHTi^loco'cslOlOOO^CS•^^^*^>•^^^'^vOCSC^^li^ ^HCSiH^-lirH ,H»-li-lT-l*-l ,-ii-l"»-l>»-Hi-* ■t-Hi-H^-l CS '-t s d.y ° o _ "C rt o o t3 3 SJ3 0) M . ■ O S S S « (U " -W.S C fe"SSj3 "5 M tS !>. !» 1» !» *3 *2 =33-2 g § s g;i|j-a.s| 1 1 yji S ■^.s'-g & 63 R w CL, o b; Ph < M M o s O h-l ■< o o U M M .J n {2 CO •O -OPOfOVO ^tOiO*-lOOMOOOr*ONPOOQO On fO vH 00 ^H \0 WO\ O CS O "^ 0\ *0 ^osoootot^in'^csior»odvd'^ cscs»-ics ro cs '-f ro *H cs cs Ocoesooe4'^t^vo^'^oo»oooo '-H tS ^-( tH tH ,-( ,^ tH tI »-( 14 • S-SzSS . ..„ S So S : ■ e s .jlijiiii^ils I 5js."3 5 9 ," ." ja J" tS ^ s ^ S 9 ^ o 5! S ■'IC •a J, 64 h M u > o o M H I O !? O (-1 H < • -< 0\ VO M « ■ Oit^ ■ • •roO'O^uo 00 '^ iiO'^r.;^' c«5"l00t^_'rt«0NO>»-;O\aO\r0OMOO\'-lO'H«^0\00O0\'*S cs0^oC)>o■^»-lc-^c^^locoo^^<^^~t~o^c^"^CMOooooc^^ooO'-| o»0'H'HO*^vooO'-cS'-OONCS (A 00vg0'*^0000-<*OW>000\vOOm-iM <*^^O^^CC»^0^00'*CO^OCSOOOfOOOO\t^0^fC^OOO^OO^C^^\0 '^ CO r*3 eS eSI »H ^H T-4 ,-1 T-l ^ i-( ^-H rH ^ (N tH M cs cs ^ ^ C^ ^H ^ 65 • \0 "lOOv •ONCS\OrO ^OO^H '0\tri • 0\ 'it K o H z M iz: > o O u O O S o b! Ch O] H B. »H M U u 0. ■< O ti a n a OfC0000^OC^t^^00Tt^Ttl0^^0^OO^000C0e^^PC■<* 00 00V0 00eM*HO»OC^C^'^(N\O^HlO0\P*3»O0vOTl On ^-i cmn ••<*■* «>■* ■Csoo»». J2lSS;tJ2'2'^'^'^°00Niot^t^O^»->O0\r000rqOO^-H S;S!2!2J2S£3°!2'^0'*o-^ooooo\ioodcsvO'-^-^o\c>i-* ^iM<>JCS.oq<»5iOOJ-.^(>)VOCSt-'*VO'0>00'0?5o\OOCSOOOO SSSSSSl;;n2£200NO\r<5iocf)t~^rt'iocf>r-;od-»cscNeswsN.t<5f'5e»5CNpgtsiisN'rtcsescsi--i.l-ies0»HCSO«^c«5'<})c>jc«acsiroror«awirtc^-HcscOi-(cscsW)0)pgc>irqcvi-H-HrtC-)>-(,-irti-irtrt 10QOCN|0\'^\0»0^0000*^10fOroOvt^>OfO^HCSO^HrO»^^VO»-) QOCN*^'-<0\t-t\OOOVOrgOs^CN'-i\0*-Ht^t-HO\»0\OC*30\Ot^Os to^H^-iQovo^^io^Hi-(^ootr>ooo\*Hcoo>o»o-^cocoo\oocc ■^cor^f^*^'^»ooOTHOOc»'-HTj >. ii ii •o CO ,f! H ^ K ^ "S ■a « S.S =3o OS. O (U iD "> si** rt " 3 M** m'C.S.S'o so J6H ?<§! "•a ■IE "I . e e B go „-£ . . ■ . o i«.a-n 83.2 s C5 Oh BB Q >-i to 6S a w H u H O M M M u l CS tH OOTt<'^t^Os^HvOi-iC^^HOO*HMvO'^0*-i^ ■«-lOt^Osr^O\\0OP0P0^O'^s00sOOv^f0'^00^^'^00v0'^OO r0N0t^^00c0THr0OOf0"^CSiOC\P0i-i^-iTt*t^i-i^O^O"^f0O rOiOO\^vOt*cq»00\C^OO^I>.0\ri<0\0^^"^t^»OOOPOfO":>T-it^ ^-HO\0^^Of^fOO'H0^f0t^'O0^*-l▼-^^-HO00»O0^CS^*cSQ000CS^»T-( OC»^0,t^^^^^ooO'^^Ooo^»^OO^oofO^*'^000^»oco■^^coO■^ tort*vOODOr*ooroc>ics^OO\'«*OOOiJDfO»oesOrOfOO\0\'^'-tiO'<-i €SO\OvCS^H.OodTHod'^0\»-(C4fOrOOscMOsroiOriiOOOiN>'JfO 00tfO\CS0000O^'^f0C^*^t^"^<*5f^"^O\O\r*r0^»OvO^^O^O^00fO t* 06 t^CSoO^-iro»0^0\t^C>l'^sO*>-OOfOTt<0'OvOC>1'OOOQNMON 00 00* 00 N O N O 0\ ^' O VO C<1 0^ O C^* M ff> <» O 0\ «* "^ tH .\d *d ^ ^ O O^00vOr^t^00•HlOl0l-^^lO^000^00^rt^^0«-^TJ^^* ■^00P0t^r-^O\C0^nO■»-lf0r^P0'»-^^0lOCS•:|^v0Ol>'^>■v0^OC0O"^lO 'Ot^»OOsO'-ivdosr*in»0»-•O^»'llO»O^Of0O0^O\^^-lO^00^0'OlOO00lOl-l 0\^^OV0f0^H^iO00\0»Ot^'-tCSO00O\iOr0"O^'-*Tj< 00\0\ ^" ^ fo t^* Os ♦-< fO oo es -A irj 00 1*' oo CSLfO c< rj< v© rt< M •h o ri"^ od O O V ■ * C4 C — ! P O! R SQti;,^;? S±! 6 13 S ^ B rt-a^ 1- 3 ■= s-^ a ■8-S e u =^1 B B & ' M 3 E >-]U i.H « — N.a q.Ss rt^^ 69 Q H H D o h U M o n Bi o m M en M O O*-lt^ir5N0*^C^fr?00C^00O\^O^H^^H^\0^H0\^00t^C^tO00Q (NOO^CSt^OOO^^TiH0010t^vOCN100VO>0»00\C^QOOO\rOt^C«l«0 OoOvOOQTj^t^CNIt^T-*Tj*C^'^vO-^rOOvt^TPOsvpr9r*^*-iOOPOM ^,-IIO00^00C0^CSTiJ OO^C0»0-^OsPO'-H(N»0'-HCOOST-iCN^-IOOvOOeNO,t^O^»'3^ t^O^HCNOOfoeS'#CNlt^rO^^'csO\^ioC>T!*»-(ON'\OOTji^HCSO\C^ (A 00■^OOQ^c^^Or»^^l0U^O00Ot^c*^lO^0^-H*-^O0^^00■^000^ coON*-noc4o^t^pocspoov»ooioo\roa*cx>to-^^o\voooo^»o 100'-t^HmfO'-HTj<*-(OOf*3^HPs|^-HO\0\Ot^OT-lt^ro0010^-HCSt^O voo^t^^lD^^fO^-^oo■^ooov0^00^c^^c^^^^oovot^^OPOOO•^ 10CSO»-<^0\O^HO"^0\00\\0*^T-IOOr^'-HOOONVO'^PCOv*H-*IOOOVO f*50vO'-IC^CO^^rOO*^eN^HC^^HO\00»0'^fO^HCO^OO»-HOi-tlOVO Q Iz; < CO M !»! o (X h u u u Ph I t^ooOvOON'-tO^rflt^vOO^t^rot^ \o^»ot^oo^cqpoo ^H ^-( s-H 1-H *H ^-l i-H CO cq ►5-0 BG bo -^ "^ T3 g ta a rt -'I— I o iisilllfi-llililslilllil^^ co-g , C w rt „M • u en -g »»3 ^ Mix, o > n o a t3 d «.a S " k „<3 sq. o cue h P u HWtO 70 a u H Hi M W O < u l-H Pi O coo ■0\ -vOOt-c re ON o a u o Pi « 1-4 a o H -I cs w ^^ n 3 « • Tt^iOOvOOt^CSt^'0^*-OtO 0^^^00'-lOOo'^^od^"cdQ6^C^'ocoodo^O^'-lO^C^I'0^ \0^iO»0i0V0O^CflC0»0Tt0»0'»-iO\00\vOOOOvO'MVOiOOOvO'0'HOroeOfO^oo\ot^'^ !2 225*2t:Q^^^"^"^o<^^f*50^0roONt^esT-n>.fOrH '^Oc0'C00^v0'-i^^0\^CS0MOCS0ON00vOtOv0CS'Or000^-i»O CO CO ^ lo t^ o* \d Ti< o o "^q" ^* ""d vd o o od vd u^ o\ »o o OS o\ fo o ■^ ■t^-rH O^iOeS tH-^ '-ICO COCOOOO-^ C^ CO ^OcocoOOO'^ c^loco^0^*'-^^*co^*co"0^oc>^csoooo^* t* ■oioodoiocoo\oodT-Hio'<:jH^ococoioodioasodo\coo CO •^cO'-^^^c^^l-HO^Oco^-nor>^coovocoo^^oc^^C)cO'H^cs ^ro^HCvi^-iioo^cO^OtNCSlThONOt^t^cO'^^OCSOvt^CS^H •OtOO^OOiOTiio\00\COI>-\H«--io\odpO»Ocd»noot*t^C»l(>I 'OCSOooost^ooi>.eNJO\OfO'^coc coc^vOONt^^oovO'^O'-fCOcovO^ JCSiOvOCO'-HCSIcovO'^QOi irJH^COlOmiOOlO-rH^OO '-lTJ^O\cooOOO■<4^co^OOO^O'«^(NO\O^^OcOMOO'-^^**^^000^ T-t rH ^H ,-( ^-H l-H l-H l-H l-H l-H ,-1 i-H i-H i-H ■»-( i-H *-l O^'O^oot^coioOOCsr^t^i r-ooiooocooN>ot^oooNcsooooooco §^ so ho eg .S-B '^ -id' • '*5 5? #i* _S ^r_r 19 C - 1.^ ° . ps! o •T3 CO .pjiaj u vi t^ 00 00 vo CN 00 ■3 c 5 o HI B O S« -Ph " o S o eo"S ■tS u3 .i tti S B. bo £■ iT ^^m M« £3.5-5 a D,D,^ OX! rt S Bj3 «.S *-• ^ X S ? 8 St J 71 IV THE PRESENT PROBLEM OF TAXATION IN THE UNITED STATES The fact has been impressed on the popular mind within the last year or two that the yield of federal taxes has been declin- ing, and this coupled with the exaggerated importance often assigned to the position of federal taxes in the entire system of American public finance has served to lull taxpayers into the belief that the peak of the burden is a matter of the past. It cannot be gainsaid that the federal tax burden, measured in terms of dollars, irrespective of price changes, has grown smaller in bulk although it does not necessarily follow that it is more easily borne. Federal taxes totalled $4,926 millions in 1919; in 1921 actual collection by the Federal Government amounted to $4,430 millions — a decline of 11.2%. But it should not be overlooked that the 1921 dollar had a purchasing power of 26.9% more than the 1919 dollar,' and hence the federal tax burden in 1921 was actually 15% higher in the aggregate than in 1919. Furthermore, with slower movement of stocks and relatively large inventories, payment of federal taxes in 1921 very likely presented a much more difficult problem to the average business man than in 1919. Growth of State and Local Taxation Aside from this situation, the increase of state and local taxes has been nothing short of phenomenal. During the war, as stated above ,^ local expenditures were kept down to the abso- lute minimum; borrowings of local governments were subordin- ated to the needs and necessities of the emergency. High prices of labor and materials in themselves discouraged the con- struction of public improvements and the undertaking of public works which could be postponed to a period of greater advantage without loss or detriment. It was after the war that we find a mercurial ascent in local government expendi- tures. Stimulated, on the one hand, by the decline in prices of labor and materials, and on the other, by the desire to aid in •Based on index number of wholesale prices of the U. S. Bureau of Labor. 2See p. 13. 72 partially solving the unemployment problem which became acute as the depression set in, the state and local governments entered into ambitious construction programs. This situa- tion was accentuated by later efforts to increase salaries of government employees and by the stimulus embodied in lower money rates and in tax-exemption features attaching to government security issues. By virtue of the latter fact, local governments were able to secure better terms than private enterprises. Bonds issued by states and municipalities of the United States totalled ?2,020 millions in 1921, compared with |1,438 millions in 1920, $736 millions in 1917 and $647 millions in 1915. The growth in long term issues has been much more pronounced in the last two years than that in short term issues, indicating that borrowings have been more for improvements, the benefit from which extends over a long period of time, than for the purpose of meeting current liabilities and paying off maturing obligations, as is indicated in the following table: BONDS ISSUED BY STATES AND MUNICIPALITIES* (thousands of dollars) Long-term Short-term Total 1922 (9 months) 1921 1920 1919 1918 1917 1916 1915 1914 1913 1912 $1,039,939 1,304,289 773,664 770,195 262,819 444,933 497,404 492,590 445,906 408,478 399,046 $210,605 716,104 664,087 450,094 4/3,135 392,444 292,407 154,728 286,055 483,218 192,450 $1,250,544 2,020,393 1,437,751 1,220,289 735,954 837,377 789,811 647,318 731,961 891,696 591,496 *BondBuyer, Jan. 7, 1922, p. 5, and Oct. 7, 1922, p. 27. That local taxes have risen prodigiously is attested by figures relating to levies of general property taxes presented in Table 19. Information was obtained for forty-one states, including the District of Columbia, and in all probability the conclusions that apply to them hold also for the remaining ones. The gain in local taxes levied in 1919 over those levied in 1912 was 82%; in 1920 the increase over the preceding year was 21%; and in 1921 a further gain of 12% was registered. Similarly, data have 73 been compiled for thirty state governments, which reveal an increase of 37.5% in taxes and licenses collected in 1921 as compared with 1919. When cognizance is taken of the rise in purchasing power of the dollar since 1919, local burdens have been increased still further and compare in importance with federal tax receipts. A comparison of the nation's tax bill in the past two decades (Table 23 and Chart 5) reveals the shifting of the center of gravity in variance with economic conditions prevailing in this period. Before the war, federal taxes constituted but three- tenths of total taxes. State and local taxes had been growing faster than federal taxes. During the war and immediately alter the armistice, the tables were reversed and state and local taxes began to occupy a subordinate position. In 1921, however, we find that federal taxes have fallen from over three-fifths of the nation's total to slightly more than one-half, while state and local burdens have been rapidly approaching the point where they begin to share equal importance with federal taxes. Taxation and National Income It will be ascertained from Table 23 that whereas taxes related to national income constituted but 6.7% in the calen- dar year 1902 and 6.4% in the calendar year 1913, the per- centage had increased to 12.1% in the calendar year 1919, and in the calendar year 1921, on the basis of a rough estimate of that year's income, the tax burden of all government authori- ties in this country represented 16.7% of the nation's income. The latest estimates of the national income' by the National Bureau of Economic Research relate to the year 1919; the 1921 figures were estimated on the basis of declines in the value of crops and animal products since 1919 and in the physical volume of principal manufactures, which, translated into dollars, was further accentuated by a drop of 12.1% in average prices. What is the significance of these figures ? How does this tax situation aflFect the national income ? What problems does this suggest with which the period of reconstruction must grapple ? The national income is a composite figure; it represents the aggregate of individual incomes, the greater part of which is ■National Bureau of Economic Researcti, Inc., "Income in the United States," op cit. 74 Chart 5: Growth of Federal, State and Local Taxa- tion, United States (National Industrial Conference Board) BILUONS °'' °°^ Y^^ GRaWTH OF TAXATIO N 1312-13 1913-14 IEI4-I5 I3I5-IB I9IB-I7 I3I7-IB I9IB-I3 I9I9-ED I3SD-EI 1321 1912-13 1313-14 1314-15 1315-lB I3IB-I7 1917-16 1913-13 1313-20 192D-2I 1921-22 75 consumed every year. Part of this consumption is for neces- sities and part for luxuries. In proportion as the damper is placed on luxury expenditures, larger amounts are available for productive investment, which yield > a return and serve to increase the national income and raise the general standard of living. The United States is spending huge sums on lux- uries and semi-luxuries. The falling-off in the consumption of luxuries has by no means been commensurate with the degree of change in the business cycle. In 1920, the luxury bill, exclusive of liquors, amounted to $10,078 millions and in 1921 it had dropped to slightly below $9,860 millions, or a decline of 2.1%y If cognizance is taken of the fact that 1921 compared unfavorably with 1920 from the standpoint of employment and that the national income in that year experienced a con- traction of over 30%, a decline of 2% in expenditures on lux- uries and semi-luxuries appears to be a rather inadequate reflection of altered economic conditions and connotes on the whole the adoption of an expenditure policy no saner or more wholesome than that prevailing heretofore, especially in view of relatively limited price recessions in some luxury articles. The portion of the national income remaining above the necessary consumption demands and depreciation of capital is devoted to the support of government and to the increase in capital funds. It has been estimated that the savings of the nation averaged about one-sixth of the national in- come in normal years. During the war there was so much destruction of wealth that despite the tremendous increase in personal savings, a net deficit was recorded. The nation's savings represented on the average 17% of the total income in the years 1909-1914, as may be observed from Table 24. Striking a rough average, it will be found that total taxes and savings amounted to somewhat less than 24% of the na- tional income in the six years preceding the war and that the remaining 76% represented consumption requirements of indi- viduals, depletion, depreciation and obsolescence of property, 'Partly estimated on the basis of returns of the U. S. Commissioner of Internal Revenue and partly on the basis of information furnished by trade associations. Because there exists a wide variance of opinion as to what are articles of luxury and semi-luxury , the estimate made here cannot be considered otherwise than as a rough approximation. Some pianos, for example, may be purchased for strictly commercial use or may find their way into schools where they are used for educational purposes, and organs may be purchased for the use of churches. Refinements of the crude data to take cognizance of these varying cir- cumstances have not been undertaken because of the paucity of information on the basis of which modifications of the original estimates could be made. An attempt has been made only to indicate a rough total of these expenditures. 76 < s ^ 'o O -a ^■3 ., n CO *H n feH o a g^-B 8 ■i-t u a B o n cd 0) o d 6§ 6? 6^ \0 0\iO O t^ CM CO tH coH 100^*00 CO CO Ov '-' ^ On ^ O^ g o ■s ^ o > . o o 1 il O\00Oc0CMP0»Ot^»O0s T-HCM^-tT-ii-H^-ieMfO'^ 1 s 8 NOOCSOOVp^t^Ot^O W^tH'.-HOs'^OOIOIOCOCO u^xcTiO lO lO lO 00 CO 0\ CM -. 1 1 rl a 1 .2 1 3 o lOvOOO-^OvOO^OOOvO t^VOOOlOCOPOO'^^^ J>^i>^^i0^iO^ON^^-J^TtJ^CO^fO^ 00 ^'f-H CO lO CO o to fO o cscorOfOrocOPOTt'iO'O 1 ,H ^ s u 0\ O ■«-< (N fO Tt^ to O" !>■ 00 d a ■§ 77 etc. With our national wealth showing a very small change since 1916 when measured in terms of an unchanged dollar, and with the industrial depression enforcing economy, it is highly likely that this percentage was increased. On the presumption that it is not a desirable policy to have the tax program interfere with present standards of living, and apply- ing roughly 25% to the national income of 1921, we have $12,500 millions available for taxes and fresh capital invest- ments, of which $8,400 millions were absorbed by taxes, leav- ing approximately $4,000 millions for the latter purpose. It was recently estimated that fresh capital investments needed annually in this country at March, 1921 price levels amount to approximately $6,000 millions.^ This would seem to indi- cate that under present conditions our tax bill is fast making inroads on the surplus considered vital for our economic progress, and threatens to continue to hamper our growth materially, especially in view of the hitherto uninterrupted rise in local government taxes. Productivity of Government Expenditures It should be realized that the bulk of our national govern- ment expenditures are due to the war and represent a diversion of national funds into unproductive' channels. Not only does the cost of maintaining the military and naval establishments come within the scope of this statement, but also the cost of carrying and paying off the public debt incurred during the war, the straggling burden of soldiers' relief, etc. It is true that part of such government expenditures goes into the pockets of bondholders, i.e., for the service of the national debt, and part for war pensions and the like. The net reduc- tion of the private incomes by virtue of taxation must, there- fore, be somewhat smaller than at first appears, but the prob- lem of high taxation nevertheless remains a serious one. The argument might be advanced at this point that in view of the fact that expenditure for education, health and other social functions of the state stimulates productivity through their reaction on the individual, the recent growth of public ■Douglas, Paul and Dorothy. "What Can a Man Afford?" American Economic Review, December, 1921, supplement No. 2, p. 34 ff. The U. S. Bureau of Labor indtx number of wholesale prices was 155 for August, 1922, compared with 162 in March, 1921; hence this estimate of capital requirements is but slightly affected by the change in prices since the date when the calculations were originally made. ft. nn the sense that they went largely for destructive purposes and involved in the final analysis a waste of national resources and human life. 78 expenditures more or less justifies itself. To what extent the premises which form the basis of this conclusion are valid is beyond human measurement. All depends on the efficiency with which these outlays are made and the direction in which they are made. Whether or not a wastage occurs and whether or not society receives in return more than it spends, as re- flected in the totality of national income, is an open question. Certainly the effects cannot in any manner be accurately esti- mated and the problem must remain an abstract one, subject to varying opinions. That the limits of taxable capacity have about been reached, or at least that taxation is on the verge of becoming more or less unbearable, appears to be generally recognized. The consequences of this unwise policy are bound to have an un- favorable reaction on our entire national economy. Our present and prospective national income cannot much longer support any tax program which tends to encroach on the surplus available for the development of industry to the extent that recent years have witnessed. The problem bids fair to become aggravated as industry recovers from the lethargic state which characterized the past year and begins to require more capital for expansion . The continuance of so burdensome a system of taxation, aside from its stifling effects on individual initiative and effort, spells a lower standard of living for the American people. The war has left as a heritage for the next decade or more a federal budget which is from three to four times its pre-war proportions. A large part of this amount is not susceptible of immediate reduction, and hope of materially lowering it in the course of the next few years cannot now be entertained. Under this heading there fall interest and amortization of the public debt which now absorb about J 1,300 millions annually, com- pared with $23 millions in 1914; the care of war veterans, 1500 millions annually; enlarged expenditures for army and navy, which now amount to $800 millions annually against $217 millions in 1914; and straggling outlays in connection with the operation of government enterprises during the war which still constitute a drain on the treasury.' While installa- tion of a budget system in the conduct of the federal govern- ment's finances has undoubtedly resulted in large economies, lit must be considered in this connection that the purchasing power of the dollar in 1922 was about 60% of that in 1914. 79 there still is room for further retrenchment, but it is also becoming increasingly evident that the field in which the budgetary axe can be successfully wielded has been narrowed down to a point where there is little hope of immediately reducing the government's requirements below their present levels. Local Financial Economy It is primarily in the field of local finance that attention should first be focused. Students of the unemployment problem have constantly been urging that the government undertake the construction of public improvements and public works in a period of depression, primarily because this policy helps to relieve the hardships of the unemployed, while at the same time advantage can be taken of lower costs. In a more normal period than at present, this suggestion merits commendation and assumes a practical form, but it is doubtful whether, under present conditions, it could be carried out to the extent to which it has been in recent years. A survey recently made by The Bank of America shows the gross indebtedness of state governments alone in the United States in 1922 was $1,072 millions,' compared with ?667 millions in 1918-1919." Of the total debt outstanding early in 1922, about 34% was incurred for the construction of highways, 20% for waterways and harbors (principally New York, Louisi- ana, California and Massachusetts), and 12% for soldiers' bonus payments. Of the total increase in state indebtedness in the last three years, ?63 millions or 21% was incurred for highway purposes, and $191 millions or 63% was for water- ways and harbors. The outlays for soldiers' relief paid through the flotation of securities amounted to $130 millions. These figures take no cognizance of the enormous increases in local government indebtedness, which amounts to many times the debt of state governments.' The fact should be borne in mind that in this study we con- cern ourselves with taxes only and give no consideration to special assessments, for reasons enumerated elsewhere.* iThe Bank of America, "A National Survey of State Debts and Securities," New York 1922. >U. S. Bureau of the Census, "Financial Statistics of States, 1919," p. 114. 'In 1918-1919, the combined gross debts of cities having a population of over 30,000 wa s $3,904 millions, compared with {667 millions in the case of state governments. Data on Indebtedness of other local governments are not available but their totality must assume very large proportions. The French system of progression in rates cannot be directly compared to that of some other countries which have adopted income taxation, and hence, in so far as the statement applies to France, it must be subjected to modification due to these peculiarities . 82 matter how small or nominal this sum may be, it would represent a dividend coupon upon which the citizen could draw in the future, in the form of an aroused civic pride and concern, of widened pohtical horizon, and greater efficiency in the services that government renders. It would be an investment whose capitalized value would be immeasurable, yielding an annual return which would more than offset the sacrifice entailed in the payment of the tax. 83 GENERAL SUMMARY The foregoing analysis of the growth of public expenditures and taxation in the United States, the United Kingdom, France, Germany, Italy and Japan, and of the relation between taxation and national income in these countries brings out the following outstanding facts: Public Expenditures, by Countries 1. From 1903 to 1914 the total expenditures of all govern- mental disbursing authorities in the United States increased from $12 to $35 per capita; in the United Kingdom (England, Scotland, Wales and Ireland) from $40 to $42; in France from $24 to $33; in Italy from $14 to $22; in Germany from $44 to $69 and in Japan from $5 to $8 per capita. 2. The war greatly increased public expenditures in all these countries. Allowing for the influence of inflation and the changed price level, and reducing outlays to the pre-war internal purchasing power basis, public expenditures in the fiscal year 1918-1919 were substantially $88 per capita for the United States, $130 for the United Kingdom, $84 for France, $46 for Italy, $114 for Germany and $6 per capita for Japan. 3. The cessation of hostilities did not radically reduce public expenditures, largely because of the huge growth in outlays by minor political units such as states or provinces and local governmental bodies, particularly in the United States, the United Kingdom, France and Italy. Computed on the pre-war internal purchasing power basis, per capita expenditures in the fiscal year 1920-1921 were $45 for the United States, $61 for the United Kingdom, $77 for France (calendar year 1921), $26 for Italy, $56 for Germany and $7 for Japan. Total Taxation, by Countries 4. From 1903 to 1914 the per capita taxation of national, state, provincial and local governments combined rose from $18 to $23 in the United States, from $24 to $27 in the United Kingdom, from $17 to $22 in France, from $10 to $12 in Italy from $12 to $19 in Germany, and from $3 to $6 in Japan. The 84 percentage increase during the ten-year period was largest for Japan (95%), and lowest for the United Kingdom (15%). Germany showed an increase of 62%, France 36%, the United States 31% and Italy 27%. 5. At the end of the war the per capita total taxation, re- duced to the pre-war internal purchasing power basis, was J32 in the United States, |42 in the United Kingdom, $9 in France, $8 in Italy, |20 in Germany, $4 in Japan. In 1920-21 this per capita taxation had risen to |41 in the United States, $46 in the United Kingdom, $15 in France ($25 in the calendar year 1921), $8 in Italy, $19 in Germany, $5 in Japan. 6. At present, of the six countries studied, the United King- dom ranks first in tax burdens per capita, with the United States following close behind, Germany third, France fourth, Italy fifth and Japan last. Federal Taxation, United States 7. In the United States federal taxes totaled $4,926 millions in 1919; in 1921 they amounted to $4,430 millions, a decline of 11.2%. The 1921 dollar, however, had a purchasing power of 26.9% more than the 1919 dollar. Hence the federal tax burden in 1921 was actually 15% higher in the aggregate than in 1919. Taxation and National Income, by Countries 8. Comparing the total per capita tax burden on the pre-war internal purchasing power basis with the pre-war national income for each of the six countries studied, it is found that in the fiscal year 1920-1921 about one-eighth of the pre-war national income of the United States was diverted into tax channels; one-fifth in the United Kingdom; one-twelfth in France (one-eighth in the calendar year 1921); one-sixteenth in Italy; one-eighth in Germany and slightly less than one-fifth in Japan. 9. In the fiscal year 1913-1914, taxes paid to national, state and local governments in the United States represented 6.4% of the current national income. By 1919-1920 the ratio had grown to 13% and by 1920-1921 to 14.3%. In the calendar year 1921, one-sixth of the national income was diverted into tax channels for the support of governmental bodies in the United States. State and Local Taxation in the United States 10. Per capita tax burdens in the United States in 1919 were 85 highest in New York State ($148.36), followed by Massachu- setts ($125.35), Delaware ($124.41), Rhode Island $115.25), and Michigan ($105.71), the lowest per capita tax being that of Alabama ($26.47). 11. In the year 1919, among all the states, the highest per- centage of income (17.2%) was diverted in taxation to the support of government in New York State. Texas and Alabama showed the lowest ratio of taxation to income (7.6%). In the majority of states the ratio of taxation to state income ex- ceeded 10% and the general average was 12.1%. State and Local vs. Federal Taxation in the United States 12. The burden of state and local taxation is highest in agri- cultural and mining states, while federal taxation falls most heavily on manufacturing states. Furthermore, the burden of state and local taxation is increasing rapidly. The gain in local taxes levied in 1919 in 41 states was 82% over those levied in 1912; in 1920 the increase over the preceding year was 21% and in 1921 a further increase of 12% was shown. 13. Before the World War federal taxation constituted but three-tenths of total taxation and state and local taxes had been growing at a faster rate than federal taxes. In 1919, how- ever, federal taxation constituted over three-fifths of total taxation. In 1921, federal taxes fell to slightly more than one- half of the national total and state and local burdens began to share equal importance with them. 14. In sixteen states, viz., Arizona, Florida, Idaho, Iowa, Kansas, Minnesota, Montana, Nebraska, Nevada, New Hamp- shire, New Mexico, North Dakota, South Dakota, Utah, Washington and Wisconsin, per capita state and local taxation combined in 1919 exceeded federal taxation per capita. 15. Under present conditions, the tax bill in the United States is fast making inroads on the surplus necessary for eco- nomic progress and threatens materially to hamper our growth, especially in view of the uninterrupted rise in state and local government taxes. 16. It is a question of growing importance whether a reduction in and wider diffusion of national tax burden may not be desirable, not only for the protection of the national surplus but in order to awaken a more general interest in the activities of the government. 86 PUBLICATIONS OF THE NATIONAL INDUSTRIAL CONFERENCE BOARD (Prices given are for paper-bound copies; cloth binding Hfty cents additional) Research Reports Research Report No. 1. Workmen's Compensation Acts in the United States — ^The Legal Phase. 60 pages. April, 1917. Revised, August, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No. 2. Analysis or British Wartime Reports on Hours or Work as Related TO Output and Fatigue. 57 pages. November, 1917. $1.00. Research Report No. 3. Strikes in American Industry in Wartime — April 6 to October 6, 1917. 20 pages. March, 1918. 50 cents. Research Report No. 4. Hours of Work as Related to Output and Health of Workers — Cotton Manufacturing. 64 pages. March, 1918. $1.00. Research Report No. 5. The Canadian Industrial Disputes Investigation Act. 31 pages. April, 1918. Revised and reprinted, April, 1920. 50 cents. Research Report No. 6. Sickness Insurance or Sickness Prevention? 24 pages. May, 1918j 50 cents. Research Report No. 7. Hours of Work as Related to Output and Health of Workers — Boot and Shoe Industry, 76 pages. June, 1918. $1.00. Research Report No. 8. Wartime Employment of Women in the Metal Trades. 79 pages. July, 1918. $1.00. Research Report No. 9. Wartime Changes in the Cost of Living. 78 pages. August, 1918. $1.00. Research Report No. 10. Arbitration and Wage-Fixing in Australia. 52 pages. October, 1918. $1.00. ResearchReportNo.il. The Eight-Hour Day Defined. 9 pages. December, 1918. 50 cents. Research Report No. 12. Hours of Work as Related to Output and Health of Workers — Wool Manufacturing. 69 pages. December, 1918. $1.00. Research Report No. 13. Rest Periods for Industrial Workers. 55 pages. January, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No. 14. Wartime Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^November, 1918. 33 pages. February, 1919. 75 cents. Research Report No. 15. Problems of Industrial Readjustment in the United States. 58 pages. February, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No. 16. Hours of Work as Related to Output and Health of Workers — Silk Manufacturing. 54 pages. March, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No. 17. Wartime Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — March, 1919. 31 pages. May, 1919. 75 cents. Research Report No. 18. Hours of Work as Related to Output and Health of Workers — Metal Manufacturing Industries. 62 pages. July, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No. 19. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^July, 1919. 31 pages. September, 1919. 75 cents. Research Report No. 20. Wartime Changes in Wages: September, 1914 — March, 1919. 128 pages. September, 1919. $1.50. Research Report No. 21. Works Councils in the United States. 135 pages. October, 1919. $1.50. Research Report No. 22. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — Fall River, Massachu- setts, October, 1919. 18 pages. November, 1919. 50 cents. Research Report No 23. Conciliation and Arbitration in New Zealand. 46 pages. Decem- ber, 1919. $1.00. Research Report No 24. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — ^Lawrence, Massachu- setts, November, 1919. 21 pages. December, 1919. 50 cents. Research Reports — continued Research Report No. 23. Changes m the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^November, 1919. 24 pages December, 1919. IS cents. Research Report No. 26. A Works Council Manual. 32 pages. February, 1920. $1.00. Research Report No. 27. The Hours of Work Problem in Five Major Industries. 91 pages March, 1920. $1.00. Research Report No. 28. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^March, 1920. 24 pages. May, 1920. 75 cents. Research Report No. 29. Practical Experience with Profit Sharing in Industrial Establish- ments. 86 pages. June, 1920. $1.00. Research Report No. 30. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — July, 1920. 28 pages. September, 1920. 75 cents. Research Report No. 31 . Changes in Wages During and Since the War: September, 1914 — March, 1920. 53 pages. September, 1920. $1.00. Research Report No. 32. Practical Experience with the Work Week of Forty-Eight Hours or Less. 88 pages. December, 1920. $1.00. Research Report No. 33, Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^November, 1920. 29 pages. December, 1920. 75 cents. Research Report No. 34. Health Service in Industry. 61 pages. January, 1921. $1.00. Research Report No. 3S. Wage Changes in Industry: September, 1914 — December, 1920. 50 pages. March, 1921. $1.00. Research Report No. 36. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — March, 1921. 28 pages. April, 1921. 75 cents. Research Report No. 37. Cost of Health Service in Industry. 33 pages. May, 1921. $1.00. Research Report No. 38. Experience with Trade Union Agreements — Clothing Industries' 134 pages. June, 1921. $1.50. Research Report No. 39. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — July, 1921. 25 pages. August, 1921. 75 cents. Research Report No. 40. Wages in Great Britain, France and Germany. 110 pages. August, 1921. $1.50. Research Report No. 41. Family Budgets of American Wage-Earners: A Critical Analysis. 97 pages. September, 1921. $1.00. Research Report No. 42. The Metric versus the English System of Weights and Measures. 261 pages. October, 1921. $2.50. Research Report No, 43. The Unemployment Problem. 91 pages. November, 1921. $1.00. Research Report No. 44. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^November, 1921. 30 pages. December, 1921. 75 cents. Research Report No. 45. Wages and Hours in American Industry: July, 1914 — July, 1921. 202 pages. December, 1921. $2.00. Research Report No. 46. Railroad Wages and Working Rules. 130 pages. February, 1922. $2.00. Research Report No. 47. Wages and Hours in Anthracite Mining: June, 1914— October, 1921, Inclusive. 67 pages. March, 1922. $1.50. Research Report No. 48, The International Labor Organization of the League of Nations. 159 pages. April, 1922. $2.00. Research Report No. 49. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — March, 1922. 33 pages. April, 1922. 75 cents. Research Report No. SO, Experience with Works Councils in the United States. 191 pages. May, 1922. $2.00. Research Report No. 51. Unemployment Insurance in Theory and Practice. 127 pages. June 1922. $1.50. Research Report No. 52. Wages and Hours in American Manufacturing Industries: July 1914— January, 1922. 235 pages. July, 1922. $2.00. Research Report No. 53. Wages in Foreign Countries. 131 pages. August, 1922. $1.50. Research Report No. 54. Changes in the Cost of Living: July, 1914 — ^July, 1922. 34 pages. August, 1922. 75 cents. Research Report No. 55. Taxation and National Income. 86 pages. October, 1922. $1.50. Special Reports special Report No. 1. A Case of Federal Propaganda in Our Public Schools: Some Criti- cisms OF "Lessons in Community and National Life;" Issued by the U. S. Bureau or Education. 13 pages. February, 1919. SO cents. Special Report No. 2. War Revenue Act of 1918: A Brief Analysis. 18 pages. March 14, 1919. SO cents. Special Report No. 3. Interim Report of the European Commission of the National Indus- trial Conference Board. 34 pages. July, 1919. SO cents. Special Report No. 4. Is Compulsory Health Insurance Desirable? 12 pages. October, 1919. SO cents. Special Report No. 5. The Vital Issues in the Industrial Conference at Washington, D. C: October 6-23, 1919. IS pages. November, 1919. SO cents. Special Report No. 6. Problems of Labor and Industry in Great Britain, France, and Italy. Report of the European Commission. 406 pages. November, 1919. $2.S0. Special Report No. 7. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — ^North Hudson County, New Jersey, January, 1920. 20 pages. March, 1920. SO cents. Special Report No. 8. The Cost of Living Among Wage-Earners — Greenville and Pelzer> South Carolina, and Charlotte, North Carolina, January and February, 1920. 25 pages. May, 1920. SO cents. Special Report No. 9. Proceedings of the National Industrial Tax Conference at Chicago, Illinois, April 16, 1920. 113 pages. May, 1920. $1.00. Special Report No. 10. Should Trade Unions and Employers' Associations Be Made Legally Responsible? (Prize Essays, 1919-1920.) 3S pages. June, 1920. 7S cents. SpecialReportNo.il. The Closed Union Shop versus the Open Shop: Their Social and Economic Value Compared. (Prize Essays, 1919-1920.) 27 pages. July, 1920. 7S cents. Special Report No. 12. Should the State Interfere in the Determination of Wage Rates? (Prize Essays, 1919-1920.) 1S8 pages. August, 1920. $1.S0. Special Report No. 13. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — Cincinnati, Ohio, May, 1920. 18 pages. July, 1920. SO cents. Special Report No. 14. Unwarranted Conclusions Regarding the Eight-Hour and Ten-Hour Workday: A Critical Review of . . . U. S. Public Health Bull. No. 106. 21 pages. Au- gust, 1920. SO cents. Special Report No. 15. Problems of Labor and Industry in Germany. 6S pages. September' 1920. $1.00. Special Report No. 16. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — ^Worcester, Massachu- setts, June, 1920. 16 pages. October, 1920. SO cents. Special Report No. 17. Proceedings of the Second National Industrial Tax Conference, New York City, October 22 and 23, 1920. 200 pages. December, 1920. $1.S0. Special Report No. 18. Report of the Tax Committee of the National Industrial Conference Board, on the Federal Tax Problem. S8 pages. December, 1920. 7S cents. Special Report No. 19. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — Detroit, Michigan, Sep- tember, 1921. 22 pages. October, 1921. SO cents. Special Report No. 20. A Digest of "The Metric versus the English System of Weights and Measures" (Research Report No. 42). 11 pages. December, 1921. 2S cents. Special Report No. 21. The Cost of Living Among Wage Earners — Anthracite Region of Penssylvahla, February, 1922. 41 pages. April, 1922. 7S cents. Special Report No. 22. The Physician in Industry: A Symposium. 98 pages. June, 1922. $1.00. Industrial News Survey Important Industrial news in concise form. A Digest of Industrial News and Comment as Published in Reliable Newspapers, Maga- zines, Reviews, Special Articles, and Government Documents. Weekly ?2.00 per year. Wall Chart Service Graphic presentation of vital and outstanding facts of industrial- economic conditions and movements in the United States and foreign countries, based on the Board's investigations and on other reliable sources. Single charts (18" x 24") $1.00 each Sets of fifty consecutive charts J37.S0 per set