CORNELL UNIVERSITY LIBRARY Date Due FE5^^9WTV' fH^r^^j^?^^ MWrry i96?gN > R^f^HS«2:G3t__ J ffN W 8 0W1 F 3/ 3r A HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. HISTORY OF xVLONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES FROM THE EARLIEST TIMES TO THE PRESENT. BY ALEXANDER DEL MAR, C.E., M.E. Formerly Director of the Bureau of Statistics of the United States ; Member of the United States' Monetary Commission ofi&']6; Author of a "History of the Precious Metals," &--C. &=<:. LONDON: GEORGE BELL AND SONS, YORK STREET, COVENT GARDEN. 1885. A// rigfits resented. Entered according to Act of Congress in the year ISfS by Ai/EXANDBB Del Mar in the Office of the Litearian of CongrePR at Washington, D.C. ic>(oi':iS ^:^^^wlc^: prkss : — c. \vHrTTiNr,ii.-i,,\[ and co., tooks coi'rt. CHAN'CERY t.ANR. ADVERTISEMENT. This volume will be succeeded by one on the " History of Money in Modern CountrieSj" a work already completed and undergoing revision for the press. A. D. The original of tliis book is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924032520177 PREFACE. THE great political revolutions which, during the half- century from 1775 to 1825, destroyed the Colonial governments in America and uprooted the feudal system in Europe, also broke down the most formidable barriers that stood in the way of international commerce. Corn, bullion, and other commodities, formerly forbidden to be shipped from one country to another, are now free to go whither price or profit may determine. These radical changes, followed by the extensive applica- tion of steam to water and land transit, and the opening of the Asiatic ports, have ushered in a new era of commerce, which, dealing with an infinite variety of objects, stretches its arms to the remotest corners of the earth. Among the notable consequences of this development of commerce has been the creation of a more or less common measure of value. This phrase is not used approvingly, as though a common measure of value were yet desirable ; it is not used in the sense that a geographical mile or a second of time are common measures, because these measures are employed in common and simultaneously by all countries, whereas the gold and silver portion of the world^s stock of money — the only portion used by various nations in com- mon — is used by them, to a certain extent, in turns, whilst the paper and copper portions are not used in common at all. The term common measure of value is employed simply to explain the different status of money, now and formerly. The money metals are no longer sought to be monopolized by means of commercial interdicts. Restraints, indeed, still exist, but they are all solubie in price; and Viii PREFACE. these metalSj wherever they may be, stand ready to become the property of any nation or nations who command the means to purchase them with other commodities. It is in this sense that they and their complementary adjuncts, paper notes, have, as a mass, become in a restricted sense a com- mon measure of value : the metals by means of free export and coinage, and the notes by means of elastic issues and a promised convertibility. As a mass of money, it is really heterogeneous and ill-cemented, but during the intervals when it does hold together it certainly operates as a common measure of value ; a fact abundantly proved by the approxi- mate uniformity of prices in various countries at such periods. The European system of money — if indeed that may be called a system which is chiefly distinguished by its lack of system — has thus become not merely the arbiter of the social order in a given state, it has assumed almost univer- sal sway over the destinies of mankind, a sway in one sense more potent, because more palpable and direct, than either politics or religion. Up to the present time, China is the one important country which has not succumbed to its influence. The study and regulation of this mighty engine concerns not only the nations to whom particular portions of it may belong ; they are of importance to all the nations whom the new development of commerce has knit together. Nor can this study and regulation be longer conducted on its present loose basis of partial or fragmentary information. Money has a history which is fifty centuries old, and filled with an experience too valuable and too dearly bought to be ignored or thrown away. From the fall of the Eoman Commonwealth to the French Revolution, coins, (made partly from old accumulations of metal,) were substantially the only moneys of Europe. During this lengthy period, all general and long-sustained changes in the level of prices are attributed to the changing level of the stock of coins, which slowly but continually PREFACE. IX diminished until the tenth century, and then slowly in- creased until near the nineteenth. So gradual were these changes that it has been remarked that in the first part of the fourteenth century and the last part of the eighteenth identically the same prices prevailed in at least one impor- tant country for all the common necessaries of life and articles of greatest consumption, such as corn and domestic animals and their products. "^ But with the introduction of bank and government paper notes, which only became an important part of the monetary systems of the various states of the Western world after the occurrence of the great revolutions above alluded to, this comparative permanency in the value of money has passed away. Paper notes now form an essential portion of the volume of money or Measure of Value in all countries; and in some of them it is, or has been, the only measure of the sort. Viewing the subject from a comprehensive stand- point, it may be stated that, during the past thirty years alone, the proportion of state and bank paper-money which helps to form the Measure of Value employed by civilized nations, has increased from thirty to fifty per cent, of the Entire Measure, and that the tendency — arising from insufii- cient supplies of the coinage metals — is toward a further increase of paper. Not only has the paper portion of money increased, the whole volume of money, comprising both coins and notes, has increased, even when compared with a vastly increased population. The volume of money in the European world, which, thirty years ago, scarcely exceeded nine dollars, or, say, thirty-eight shillings sterling per capita of population, now amounts to fourteen dollars, or, say, sixty shillings per capita.^ ' This relates to England. See pamphlet by " A Disciple of Franklin,'" in "Trans, of Am. Philos. Soc," No. 6332 of the Philadelphia Collec- tion. Consult Thorold Rogers on '' Statistics of Agricultural Prices in England." 2 Del Mar's " Hist. Free. Metals," London, George Bell and Sons, p. 220 n., and M. de Malaroe in " Eeport of the French Academy of Sciences" about 1882. X PEEFACK. This tendency of the volume of money to increase cannot be viewed by Capital but with alarm. It is not as though money consisted, as it did during the Middle Ages, nearly entirely of coins made from a stock of metals which could only be kept up or increased by prodigious exertions and during a long period of time. It now consists very largely of paper notes, which are emitted both by governments and banks without any reference to the Whole Volume of Money, in which volume, alone, is Price susceptible of expression. In consequence of this loose system the measure of value is being continually swollen (this is not stated in reference to any particular country, but to all countries), so that it continually disturbs the natural tendency of prices towards an equilibrium. Barring occasionally brief periods of re- action, the constant tendency of prices during the period adverted to has been upward. The result of this movement is that property has passed and is still passing away, insen- sibly, from the hands of its original possessors and rightful owners, to be distributed among classes who never earned it, and who neither know how to keep it nor to dispose of it economically. On the other hand, the interests of Labour forbid the consideration of any policy designed to diminish the Mea- sure of Value. We may with justice oppose further infla- tion, we may put an end to those mischievous agencies which tamper with the Measure of Value ; but we can never dare, we should never wish, to contract it, nor permit it to contract ; for, as history abundantly testifies, a contraction of money, when production is increasing and commerce ex- panding, means the arrest of one and extermination of the other. And it is, perhaps, the conviction of these conse- quences, crudely formed in the popular mind, which lies at the basis of the many illiterate plans and ill-advised clamours for inflation, which, both in Europe and America, mark the financial and political measures of recent years. Amid this conflict of interests and the arguments by which the pretensions and claims of each interested class PREFACE. XI. are strengthened, the student, the legislator, the magistrate^ the advocate, seeks in vain for that steady light of recorded experience, those fixed monuments of history, which can alone guide him toward correct theories and practical results. To offer such a guide — howsoever much the exe- cution of the work might fall short of the design — was one- of the principal motives which led to the preparation of the present volume. If we turn from illiterate plans and popu- lar clamours to those teachers whom the world has been led to regard as masters of financial science, instead of obtain- ing from them a ready solution of the difficulties sur- rounding the question of Money, we only encounter dis- cordance, dogmatism, and intolerance, a condition of afiairs which, it is believed, has resulted solely from the want of some general fund of information, open to all, which should embrace the monetary experience of many countries, of many ages, and of many phases of society : for if there is any one great truth which more than another is bound to impress itself upon the student of monetary history, it is- this, that the evolution of money as an institution of law, is inalienably connected with the evolution of society, and that monetary systems which are quite impossible at one period may be entirely practicable at another. Many of the prevalent fallacies concerning the nature,, function, and use of money have arisen from the systems now in vogue, all of which are of feudal origin. These fal- lacies are similar in character to those fictions of the Com- mon Law which were only dissipated when the older and clearer light of the Roman Law was brought to bear upon them, and they can only be successfully dealt with in a similar way. To the modern mind, money is a commodity which derives its value from the cost of production. In the free states of antiquity money was a concrete series of num- bers whose value arose from state monopoly, legal limita- tion, and forced currency. The growth, establishment, and decay of this conception of money and its displacement by the feudal conception of it as a commodity, lie at the thres- 3;ii PREFACE. hold of all precise inquiries into the science of money, and must be thoroughly mastered by the student who designs to make any practical use of his researches. To afford ample opportunity for the study of this essential feature of mone- tary history, extended space has been accorded to the expe- rience of China and Rome, in which two great states of the ancient world numerical systems of money have left behind them the clearest traces and most important conse- quences. Where the imperfection of existing evidences may lead to doubt concerning the details of the systems •described, it is hoped that the conclusions at which the author has arrived will be found as worthy the scrutiny of the learned as it is confident they must awaken the attention of the curious. BIBLIOGEAPHY. Adam : Eonian Antiquities by Dr. Adam. London, 1854. Alison : Essays by Sir Archibald Alison. London, 1850. 8vo. American Cyclopedia (TheI. New York, 1861. Anthon : Tables of Coins, Weights, and Measures. Arbdthnot : Tables of Ancient Coins, Weights, and Measures, by Joh» Arbuthnot. London. 4to. 1727. Aristotle ; Works of Aristotle. Bohn's edition. Arnold : History of Rome, by Kev. Thomas Ai-nold, London, 1857. Akrian : Periplus. AtheNjEUS : Bohn's edition. Ball : Geological Survey of India, by V. Ball. London, 1881. Babclat : Bimetallism, by Robt. Barclay. Buenos Ayres. BakthSlemt : Numismatique Ancienne, parBarth^leray. Paris, 1851. 18mo.- Bastiat: Hal-monies of Political Economy, by Fred. Bastiat. London, 1860. Bernadakis : Quantite des Metaux Pr^cieux, par A. N. Bernadaki;,. Paris,- 1875. Pamphlet, 8vo. Berrt : Etudes historiques sur les Monnaies et le Monnayage des Romaines,. par V. H. Berry. Paris, 1852. 8vo. 2 fr. Bey : See Mariette Bey. Blair : See Rosse. BoECKH : Political Economy of the Athenians. American edition. Bonneville : Encyclopedie Monetaire, par Alphonse Bonneville. Paris,. 1849. Eol. 100 francs. BOTEKO : Relations (Resources) of Kingdoms, by John Botero. Translated from Italian to English. London, 1630. Small 4to. Pp.650. Brandis : Money of Further Asia. Bronson : Connecticut Currency. Browke : Report on Mineral Resources of the United States, by J. Ross Browne. Washington, 1868. BnCKLB : History of Civilization by Henry Thomas Buckle. New York ed. BcDE : Trattato delle Monete evaluto loro, ridotte dal costume antico all' uso moderno, di M. Guglielmo Budeo, tradotto per M. Gioun Bernado Gualandi Fiorentino. Fiorenxa, 1562. 12mo. 309 pp. BuDELio: De Monetis et Re Numaria. Viro Renero Budelio. Colonise Agrippinse, 1591. 4to. 798 pp. BuR&ESS : Topography and Antiquities of Rome, by Rev. Richard Burgess- London, 1831. Burnof: Introduction a I'Histoire de Buddhisme. Paris, 1844. Calvert : Gold Rocks of Great Britain. Caret : Political Economy, by Henry C. Carey. Phila. edition. Cernuschi : Noraisma, or Legal Tender, by Henry Cernuschi. New York,. 12mo. 1877. Cicero : Offices. Bohn's edition. Cicero : Orations. Bohn's edition. Chardin : Voyages, by Sir John Chardin. Amsterdam, 1835. XIV BIBLIOGEAPHY. ■Chakpentiek-Cossigny : Voyage to Brazil. Coke ; Institutes of Sir Edward Coke. CoLQUHOUN : Commentaries on the Civil Law. •CoL"WELL : Ways and Means of Payment, by S. J. Cohvell. Am. ed. •Cooper: Institutes of Justinian. New York, 1841. CoPEKNicus : La Monnaie, entretien sur le traite de la Monnaie de Copernic, par L. Wolowski. Paris. 8vo. 1864. Ckevier : Histoire des Empereurs Eomaines. Cbump : Review of the Position of the Bimetallists, by Arthur Crump. London, 1882. CcNNiNSHAM : Laddak, by Maj. Cunningham CuEZON: Armenia, by the Honourable Robt. Curzon. London, 1854. Damathat : The Damathat, a Commentary on the Laws of Manou. Ed. by Maulmain. American Baptist Mission Press. 1847. Daniell: Gold in the East, by Claremont J. Daniell. London, 1880. Davids : Ancient Coins and Measures of Ceylon, by T. W. Rhys Davids. Davies : History of Holland. London, 1842. 3 vols. 8vo. D'AvENANT : Works by Sir Charles D'Avenant. London, 1771. 5 vols. 8 vo. Datis : The Chinese, by J. F. Davis. New York, 1858. De Ch asstsol : Trait^ des Finances et de la Fausse Monnaie des Romains . Paris. 8vo. 1740. De Lczac : Richesse de I'Hollande, London, 1778. 2 vols. 8vo. Del JIar : Works of Alex. Del Mar on Gold, Silver, Coins, Money, Finance, Political Economy, Philosophy, &c. For list see fly-leaf to this volume. Dennis : Cities and Cemeteries of Etruria, by George Dennis. Depping : Histoire Ge'ne'rale de I'Espagne, par G. B. Depping. Paris, 1814. 2 vols. 8to. De Saulct : Systeme monetaire de la r^publique Eomaine a I'epoque de Jules Cesar, par F. De Saulcy. Paris. 4to. 1873. 32 pp. Desor : Palatittes of Lake Neuchatel, by E. Desor in Smithsonian Report. Washington, 1865. DiciUNsON : Ring Money, by W. B. Dickinson in " London Numismatic Chronicle," vol. xvi. Diodorus Sicdlus ; The Historical Library of Diodorus the Sicilian, trans- lated by G. Booth. London, 1814. 2 vols. 8vo. Each of about 700 pp. Dion Cassius : English translation of Xiphilinus' Abridgment of Dion Cassius. London, 1704. 2 vols. 8vo. Dion Cassius : Histoire Romaine, par Dion Cassius. Trad, par E. Gros. Paris, 1845. 10 vols. 8vo. DiONYSius : The Roman Antiquities of Dionysius of Haliearnassensis, trans- lated by Edward Spelman. London, 1758. 4 vols. 4to. Each of about 450 pp. Draper : History of Civilization, by John Draper. New York edition. Du Cange : Moneta. Glossarium medife et infimse Latinitatis, conditum, a Carolo Dufresne Domingo Du Cange. Pai-is. 4to. 1766. Du'CROCQ: Le Sesterce et I'histoire de sa fabrication dans le monnayage Romaine, par Th6ophiIe Dueroeq. Paris, 1875. 8vo. DuHalde: History of China. Ed. 1736. Dureau de la Malle : Economic Politique des Romains. Paris. Ekskine : Baber. Erskine : History of India. Evans : Coins of the Ancient Britains, by John Evans. London, 1864. Fawcett : Gold and Debt. Chicago, 1877. Ferguson : History of Rome. Fekistah ! Dow's Translation. Fesius ; Sextus Pompeius Festus de la Signification des Mots. Traduit en Francjais, par M. A. Savaguer. Paris, 1846. 8vo. 755 pp. BIBLIOGRAPHY. XT Flite : Bactrian Coins. London Numismatic Clironicle, vol. viii. Forbes ; Five Years in China, by F. E. Forbes. London, 1847. ■Gamboa . Commentaries on the Mining Laws of Spain. Trans, by Heath- tield. Information on Ancient Mines. Ganilh 1 Political Economy. Gakniek : Memoire sur la valeur des Monnaies de Compte chez les Peuples de I'Antiquite', par M. le Comte de Garnier. Paris, 1817. Gibbon : Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, by Edward Gibbon ; also Essays and Miscellaneous Works. OiBES: The Double Standard, by Henry Hucks Gibbs. London, 1881. GoBET : Les Anciens Mlneralogie. GosCHEN : On the Probable Results of an Increase in the Purchasing Power of Gold, by the Rt. Hon. Geo. J. Goschen. London, 1883. ■GsKAVES : Miscellaneous Works. London, 8vo. 1737. Containing " A Dis- course of the Roman Foot and Denarius," by John Greaves, Professor of Astronomy in the University of Oxford. London, 1736. Motto: "Una fijies, pondus, mensura, moneta sit una, et status illjesus totius Orbit erit. Budeliusde Monetis." Griffis : The Micado's Empire. New York, 1876. Grote : Munzstudien, by H. Grote. Leipsig, 1862. Gdtzlaff : China. Hageb : Numismatiques Chinoise. Hale : Judicial Opinion of Sir Matthew Hale on Money, in Davies' Reports. Hamilton : Mussulman Laws of India. Hamilton : Report on Coins to the United States Government, by Alexander Hamilton, January 28, 1791. Hake : Days near Rome. Harris : Money and Coins, by Joseph Harris. London, 1757. Svo. Head ; Ancient System of Weight, by Barclay Head, in Transactions of the London Institute of Bankers for January, 1880. Head: Coinages of Lydia and Pei-sia, by Barclay Head. London, 1877. Heeren : Historical Researches into the Political Intercourse and Trade of the Principal Nations of Antiquity. By A. H. L. Heeren, translated from the German. Oxford, 1833, 8vo. 6 vols. Helps ; Spanish Conquest of America, by Arthur Helps. London, 1855. 4 vols. 8vo. Henrt : History of Britain. Herodotus : Bohn's edition. Herodotus : Rawlinson's edition. Hildreth : Japan as it Was and Is, by Richard Hildreth. Boston, 1856. Hobleb : Records of Roman History from Cneius Pompeius to Tiberius Con- stantius, as exhibited in the Roman Coins collected by Francis Hobler. Westminster, 1860. HODGSKIN : Travels in North Germany. HoLMBOE : Munzwesen Norwhen. Scandinavian Money. Humboldt : See Von Humboldt. Hume : Essays, by David Hume. Edinburgh, 1804, 8vo. Hume : Hist." of England, by David Hume. London, 1808, 10 vols. 8vo. Humphreys : Ancient Coins and Medals, by Henry Noel Humphreys. Lon- don, 1850, 8vo. Humphreys ; Manual of Coins, by Henry Noel Humphreys. London, 8vo. Ibn Batuta : Travels into Asia. Jacob : History of the Precious Metals, by Wm. Jacob. London, 1831 ; also another edition, Philadelphia, 1832. Jevons : Political Economy, by William Stanley Jevons. London, 1872, 16mo. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. London, 1872, Svo. A serious Fall in the Value of Gold. London, 1863, 8vo. XVI BIBLIOGRAPHY. Jevons: Primer of Political Economy. London, 1879. Johnson : Civil Laws of Spain. London, 1825. Jordan : The Standard of Value, by W. L. Jordan. London, 1883. JnSTiN : History. Kan6-he. Dictionary translated by Morrison. London, E. I. Co.'s edition. ICeary : Coinage of Western Europe, by C. F. Keary. London. Kelly ; Cambist. London, 1822. 4to. Klapkoth : Asia. Klunzinger : March through the Desert, from the Nile to the Red Sea. New York, 1878. Klunzinger : Upper Egypt. Knox: Voyages, by Robert Knox. London, 1817. KwANG Chang Ling : Why should the Chinese Go ? San Francisco, 1878. Lackoix : Middle Ages. Langlois : Numismatique des Arabes, avant I'Islaisme, par Victor Langlois. Paris, 1859. 4to. Leblanc : Traits historique des Monnaies de France, depuis le commencement de la monarchic jusques a present. Paris, 4to. 1690, Lee : Drain of Silver to the East, by W. Nassau Lee. London. Lenormant : La Monnaie dans I'Antiquite, par Fran5ois Lenormant. Paris, 1878 to 1880. 3 vols., 8vo. Letronne : L'Evaluation des monnais Grecques et Romaines, par M. Letronue. Paris, 1817. 4to. Liverpool : Lord Liverpool's Letter to the King. LivY : Bohn's edition. Lock : Gold. London, 1882. Locke: On the Value of Money, by John Locke. 1691. London edition, 1870. LoNGPERiER : Documents numismatiqnes pour servir h, I'histoire des Arabes d'Espagne, par A. Longperier. Paris, 1851. 4to. 3 fr. LoNQP^RiER ; Me'dailles des Sassanides, par. A. Longperier. Paris. Lubbock : Pre-historic Times, by Sir John Lubbock. New York, 1875. MacCullooh : Commercial Dictionary, by J. R.'MacCulloch. London, 1856. JIacCulloch : Geographical Dictionary. ilAcCuLLOCH : Principles of Political Economy, containing essay on Interest, by John Locke. London, 1878, 8vo. Macgregor : Geographical Dictionary. London, 1846. Maogregor : Commercial Statistics. London, 1850. 6 vols. 8vo. Madden : Jewish Coinage. London. Madox : History of the Exchequer, by Thomas Madox. London, 1769. 2 vols. 4to. Mahawanso : Tumour's Translation. Ceylon, 1837. Malcolm: Central India by Sir J. Malcolm, 1832. Malcolm : Persia. Malle : Economie Politique des Remains, par Dureau de la Malle. Paris. Malte Brun. Geography, English trans. Philadelphia, 1827. 5 vols. 8vo. Mandeville: Travels of Sir John Mandeville. Edition 1839. Manou: The Code of Manou, trans, by Sir Wm. Jones, edited by G. C. Houghton. London, 1825. Maeiette Bet : Histoire Ancienne d'Egypt, par Mariette Bey. 1867, Maesden : Numismata Orientalia, edited by Edward Thomas. London, 1874. Marsh : The Earth as Modified by Man. New York ed. ^Martin : History of China. London, 1847. 2 vols. 8vo. Martin : History of France. Mavor: Collection of Voyages. London, 1824, 26 vols. 12mo. jMcLeod : Political Economy. London, 1858. 8vo. Merivale : History of Rome. New York, 1864. BIBLIOGRAPHY. xvu Mill : History of India, by James Mill. London, 1820, 3 vols. 4to. MoMMSEN : Histoire de la Monnaie Romaine par Theodore Mommsen, traduite de I'AUemand, par le Due de Blacas. Paris, 8vo. 1865. Montesquieu : Spirit of the Laws. MoOKE : Ancient Mineralogy. New York, 1859. MORAN : On Money, by Charles Moran. New York, 1863. 8vo. MiJLLEE : History of Rome. MiiLLBE : Sanscrit Literature, by Max MUUer. Mtjkphy : The Arabs in Spain. 4to. MuKRAT : French Finance and Financiers under Louis XV., by James Murray. London, Svo, 1858. Napoleon: Life of Julius Caesar, by the Emperor Louis Napoleon. New York, 1866. Roman Coins and Monetary Laws. Newton : Report on Coins to the British Government, by Isaac Newton, Sept. 21, 1717. NiBBY : Antiquities of Rome, by Antonio Nibby. Niebuhk: Ancient History, by B. G. Niebiihr. Philadelphia, 1872. NiEBUHR : History of Rome, by B. G, Niebiihr. Trans, by Wm. Smith. London, 1851. 3 vols. Svo. Ndmisjiatio Chronicle : London. Patterson : Economy of Capital, by Wm. Patterson. London, 1865. Paucton : M^trologie. Pausanius : Taylor's Trans. London, 1824. Pautbier: Chine. Ed. 1835. Peecival : The Land of the Veda, by Peter Pei-cival. London, 1854. Peter : Geschichte Roms. Phillips : The Mining and Metallurgy of Gold and Silver, by J . Arthur Phillips. London. 8vo. 1867. Pilling : Money, by Wm. Pilling. Buenos Ayres. PiNKERTON : Medals. Plato : Bohn's edition. Pliny : Bohn's edition. Plutarch : Bohn's edition. Pollux : Julius Pollux's account of ancient moneys in " London Numismatic Chronicle," 1881, p. 281. Polo: Travels of Marco Polo, edited by Thomas Wright. London. Svo. 1854. Paper Money in Tartary, Thibet, and China. Polo : Travels of Marco Polo, edited by Col. Yule. London. Svo. 1871. Overvalued Moneys in Tartary, Thibet, China, India, and Persia. PoLYBius : General History. Translated by Mr. Hampton. London, 1772. 4 vols. Svo, each of about 400 pages. Another edition, Oxford, 1823. Price : Mahomedan History. Prinsep : Indian Antiquities. See Thomas. Prinsep : Useful Tables, by Thomas Prinsep. London. QuEiPO : Essai sur les Systemes M^triques et Monetaires des Anciens Peuples, par V. Vasquez Queipo. Paris. 4 vols. Svo. 1859. Raffles : History of Java, by Sir Stamford RafSes. London. Raper : Inquiry into the Value of Ancient Coins, by Matthew Raper. London. Rawlinson : Seventh Monarchy. Rawlinson : The Sassanian or Persian Empire, by Geo. Rawlinson. London and New York, 1876. Raynal : History of the East and West Indies, by the Abbe Raynal. Eng. Trans. London, 1779. 4 vols. Svo. Reclus : The Earth : The Ocean : by Elisfe Reclus. New York edition. Reid : The Enhancing Value of Gold and the Industrial Crisis, by W. S. Reid. London, 1883. b xvili BIBLIOGRAPHY. RiCARDO: Principles of Political Economy, by David Rioardo. London, 1821. 8vo. RiTTEB. Erdkunde. RoBEKTSON : History of India, and History of America. London. Roe : Embassy to the Great Mogol in 1615, by Sir Thomas Roe. London. Rogers : Glass Coins. " London Numismatic Chronicle," vol. xiii. EotjEES : Statistics of Agricultural Prices in England, by Thorold Rogers. RosCHEK : Political Economy by Wm. Roscher. Trans, from the German. New York, 1S78. 8vo. RosSE : Blab's Chronological Tables, by J. Willoughby Rosse. London, 1856. RosSE : Index of Dates, by J. Willoughby Rosse. London, 1858. Russ : Geological Researches, by Herr Camill Russ, in the "London Geological Magazine " for 1878. Moneys of Abyssinia. Sabatiee : Production de I'Or et 1' Argent et du Cuivre chez les Anciens. Petersburg et Londres. 8vo. 1850. Sallust : Bohn's edition. Sandars : Institutes of Justinian. Schmidt: Civil Law of Spain and Mexico. New Orleans, 1851. Schubert : Monnais Russes, 1547-1855. Paris, 8vo. 100 fr. Seyd : Coins, Bullion, &c,, by Ernest Seyd. London. Silver : British Parliamentary Report on, 1876. Silver : Report of United Monetary Commission on, 1877. Sinclair : History of the British Revenue, by Sir John Sinclali'. London, 1803. 3 vols. 8vo. Smith : Carthage and the Carthaginians, by R. Bosworth Smith. New York. Smith : Dictionary of the Bible and Classical Dictionary. Smith: Italian Irrigation, by Baird Smith. Smith : Money the Moral Power of Exchange, by John Prince Smith. London, 1844. 8vo. Smith: Political Economy, by John Prince Smith. London, 1844. 8vo. Smith : Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith. Edinburgh. Smyth : Roman Imperial Large-Brass Medals, by Capt. Wm. Henry Smyth, R.N. Bedford. 4to. 1834. Smyth : Descriptive Catalogue of a Cabinet of Roman Family Coins belonging to His Grace the Duke of Northumberland, K.G., by Rear- Admiral Wm. Henry Smyth. London, 1856. Spencer : Essa3's by Herbert Spencer. Stanton: Laws of China. London, 1810. Stieglitz : Catalogus Numorum Veterum Grsecorum, by Chris. Ludov. Stieg- litz. Leipsig, 1837. Steabo : Bohn's edition. St. Maue: Valeur des Monnoies et le Prix des Grains, par Dupr6 de St. Maur. Paris, 1762. 12mo. Suetonius : Bohn's edition. Tacitus ; Bohn's edition. Tavernier. Travels, English edition. Thomas: Chronicles of the Pathan Kings of Delhi, by Edward Thomas. London, ^871. Thomas : Essays on Indian Antiquities, b}' the late James Prinsep. Ed. by Edward Thomas. London, 1858. Thomas : Marsden's Numismata Orientalia, by Edward Thomas. London, 1874. The same work, ed. 1876.. is entitled, International Numismata Orientalia. Thompson : The Land and People of China, by E. Thompson. London and New York, 1876. Paper Money in Pekin. Timue : Institutes of Timur. Oxford, 1783. Titsingh : Verhandelingen Van het Bataviaasch genootschap. BIBLIOGRAPHY. Xlx ToMKiNS AND Lemon : Commentaries on Gaius. London, 1869. ToMKiNS AND Jencken : Modem Roman Law. Loudon, 1870. TooKE : History of Prices. Ed. by Newmarch. London. 6 vols. 8vo. TowNSEND ; Travels in Spain. London. 8vo. Teansactions of the Royal Asiatic Society. Turcot : Wealth of Nations. Eng. Trans. London, 1793. TuKNOUR. Mahawanso. See Mahawanso. Univeksal History : London, 1782. Vaillant : Roman Colonial Coins. Valleius Paterodlus. Vaux : Ring Money, by VI. S. W. Vaux, in '■ London Num. Chronicle,'' vol. xvi. Vessering : Chinese Currency. Leyden. Voltaire : History of Europe. London, 1754. Von Humboldt : Fluctuations of Gold, by Baron Alex. Von Humboldt. Berlin, 1837. Ward : Mexico in 1827, by H. G. Ward. London, 1828. 2 vols. 8vo. Wilkinson : Ancient Egyptians. London edition, 1878 ; also Scribner's, New York edition. Williams : Chinese Commercial Guide, by Dr. Wells Williams. Hong Kong, 1863. Williams : The Middle Kingdom, by Dr. Wells Williams. Hong Kong. Williamson : India and the Silver Question, by Stephen Williamson. Liverpool. Wilson : Ariana Antiqua, by H. H. Wilson. London, 1841. Wright : The Celt, the Roman, and the Saxon, by Thomas Wright. Phila- dfelphia, 187.T. Roman counterfeiters. Xenophon : De Vectigale. Walter Moyle's English translation, in D'Avenant's works. Yeats : Growth and Vicissitudes of Commerce, by Yeats. London, 1872. CHAPTERS. PAGE Preface .......... vii Chap. I. Supply of Materials suitable for Money, AND Development or Coinage and Printing 1 II. China (History or Money in) ... 14 III. Japan 49 IV. India, prior to Alexander the Great . . 57 V. India, from Alexander the Great to the Mahomedan Conquest .... 83 VI. India, since the Mahomedan Conquest . . 94 VII. Ariana, Bactria, Caubul, and Afghanistan . 118 Vm. Egypt 127 IX. Persia, Assyria, Babylon, and Palestine . 151 X. Aboriginal Europe . . . . 157 XI. Greece and Greek Colonies . . . 161 XII. Carthage . . 173 XIII. Etruria .177 XIV. Rome generally ... . 181 XV. Earliest Monetary Systems of Rome . 192 XVI. The Servian System . . 207 XVII. The Republican System, e.g. 385-269 . 213 XVIII. Rise of the Roman Commonwealth . . 242 XIX. The Patrician SYSTE^L b.c. 269-250 . . 246 XX. First Punic War System, b.c. 250-216 . 256 XXI. Second Punic War System, b.c. 216-207 . 261 XXII. Decay of the Commonwealth . . . 265 XXIII. The Scipion System, b.c. 207-170 . . 271 XXIV. Agrarian and Social War Systems, b.c. 170-49 285 XXV. Julian System, b.c. 46-31 . . . .299 XXVI. Augustan System, b.c. 31 to a.d. 41 . . 302 XXVn. From the Augustan Era to the Dark Ages 313 XXVin. Ancient generic Terms for Money . . 334 XXIX. Conception of Money by the Ancients . . 339 XXX. Conclusion 343 .CONTENTS. PAJ3E Preface . ,. . . . . . vii Chapter I. Supply or Materials for Money and Development of Coinage and Printing. Money must be made of some tangible and ponderable material of ample and regular supply, capable of standing wear and tear and susceptible of being so marked as to be difficultto counterfeit — Clay — Gold — Its occurrence, diffiisiou, method of extraction — Used in the arts before it was used for money — Placer gold — Quartz gold — The principal gold placers of the world exhausted — The quartz mines usually unprofitable — Present supplies of gold declining — Its production at all periods of history fitful or scfiut — Hence it was never permanently used for money until the period of Julius Cffisar— The ancient supplies were ample at only three notable periods ; the discovery of Europe by the Phcenicians, the plunder of Asia by Darius and Alexander, and the conquest of Europe by the Romans — Copper more abun- dant and the supplies more regular — Hence better adapted for money in ancient times — Most of the Oriental moneys were of copper, indeed it was everywhere the principal money metal until the discovery of America — Silver rarely found native, generally in ores difficult to treat, hence last to be used for money — It is widely diifused, but as silver mines yield no alluvions or other progeny, the finds of silver are more concentrated, therefore its production more fitful than gold — This fact, and the operation of mint laws has continually tended to lower its value — Cessation of these influences — Silver first permanently used for money by the Greeks — Felted paper invented b.c. 177 — First paper money B.C. 140 — Introduction of paper into Europe — Not common until fifteenth century — Social condition of Europe not favourable to paper money at this period — No permanent system of openly overvalued moneys since the Roman Commonwealth — Experi- ments of the Venetian, Dutch, American, and French republics — The establishment of suitable paper manufactures in Europe XXIV CONTENTS. PAGE coincident with the influx of precious metals from America — In- fluence in retarding use of paper moneys — Bank and Government notes — Coinage — Cast moneys — Artistic excellence of the Greek coinages — Engraving — Printing with mo^'able types not invented imtil the art of making paper was sixteen centuries old — Its in- fluence in retarding the use of paper moneys . . . ■ 1 Chapter II. China. Antiquity of money greater than letters — Gold and bronze moneys of Sung, B.C. 2257 — Tortoise-back, or cowrie moneys — Knife, bell, and wheel-shaped coins — Clay or porcelain moneys — Paper — Various paper moneys from B.C. 140 to a.d. 1455 — Present system ; copper " cash" with silver bullion multi- pliers and fractional (provincial) notes — Laws affecting trade in metals — " Cash," formerly numerical — Foreign coins — Carolus dollar — Brick-tea money — Bullion trade — Mines . . 14 Chapter III. Japan. Ancient money — Earliest coins— Gold and Silver — Rice — Paper money — Copper zenni — Feudal period — Copper and Gold mines — Mining laws — Mints — Progressive period — Arrival of the Portugviese ..... .49 Chapter IV. India, prior to Alexander the Great. India never united under one government : hence difficult to describe its monetary systems comprehensively — These systems include several instruc- tive experiments, particularly those of Mahomed-bin- Tuglah, in the fourteenth century of our era — Antiquity of money in India — As ancient as in China — Proofs : from populousness and phase of civilization ; from Code of Manoii ; from the Vedic writings ; from the Buddhic writings ; from numismatic remains ; from lan- guage — Supply of coining metals from the mines, and from foreign commerce — Standard of money at various eras ; the copper stan- dard; the clay standard; the copper standard again — -Silver money not permanently employed until a.d. 1793 ; nor paper money, permanently, until during the present century — Ratios of value between gold and silver, between silver and copper — Review — -Historical eras of India marked by foreign invasions — Sesostris— Darius — Alexander — Seleucus — Embassy of Megas- thenes — Invasion of Antiochus — Mahomedan conquest . . 57 CONTENTS. XXV Chapter V. India, from Alexander the Great to the Mahomedan doNQUEST. Futility of depending upon Greek or Latin authors for the history of this period — Aid to be derived from Chinese authority — From archseological authority — Character of the In- dian trade with the West — Trifling proportion of silver shipments — Supply of coining metals from the mines — Modem numismatic finds — The topes — Misleading inferences to which such finds may point, unless studied with caution — Ancient Indian custom of coining; 1, gold and silver multipliers of copper money; 2, gold, silver, and other coins for commemorative and procla- matory purposes — These practices found then- way to Rome — Actual standard of money in India during the period under review — This was copper, with gold and silver multipliers, in Northern, and copper, with cowrie divisors, in Southern India — Abnormal camp coinages of invaders — These had no effect upon the copper standard — Rise of the Arabian power in the seventh century — Rapid conquest of Egypt and Persia, and monopoliza- tion of the Indian trade — The Italians carry a portion of the trade through Tartary, and afterwards submit to Mahomedan exactions and trade in Alexandria — The Crusades, and their influence in concentrating the Indian trade at Constantinople — Its engross- ment by the Venetians — The Genoese capture Pera, and compel the Venetians to again trade through Alexandria — Capture of Constantinople by the Turks, and end of the Genoese trade with India — ^ Rivalry for this trade leads to the discovery of the sea route by the Cape, and of America — Silver shipments to India during the Middle Ages — The Mahomedans invade India — Gra- dual progress of their arms, until they completely conquer the country in a.d. 1001 — Imperceptible influence of this conquest upon the monetary system of India — The standard continues to be of copper . . ...... 83 Chapter VI. India, since the Mahomedan Conquest. The Mahomedan Conquest led to attempts at monetary reform and deeper and more systematic mining — Increased, but insufiicient supplies of silver — Billon coins — Method of notation — Liability to error in trans- lating Indian sums into gold or silver moneys — Distinction between the tank and tankah — Minute gold coins shot from catapults for purposes of bribery — Bad state of the roads, and difficulty of gathering the tributes in kind — Attempt of Maho- met-bin-Tuglah to alter the standard from copper to silver — Failure of the scheme — Doubts as to the true date of this experi- XXVI CONTENTS. ment — Apparent adoption of silver payments — Thomas's opinion that the real standard was copper — Decline of power of Pathan kings of Delhi — Invasion and plunder by Timon the Tartar — Renewed scarcity of coinage metals — Efforts of Bahlol Lodi to sustain prices by means of highly overvalued copper coins — The particulars of this experiment not known — Fall in prices — Mi- nute gold coins — Return to copper standard — Advent of the Portuguese — Discovery of America — Influx of silver into India for gold and spices— New stimulus afforded to mining — Gold and silver become more plentifal — Akbar's experiment — Failure — Return to copper standard — Detached portions of the Mongol empire — The Dekkan — ^Bengal — Ceylon — European conquests in India — Continued influx of silver — Invasion and plunder by Nadir Shah — Renewed influx of silver — Establishment of gold, and afterwards of silver standard, by East India Company — Mode of determining weight of sicca rupee same as that adopted for the American dollar — Momentous consequences of changing the Indian standard — Stoppage of Bank of England — These conse- quences still in action — Local systems of money at the beginning of present century — Introduction of paper money — Continued influx of silver recently interrupted by operation of railway sys- tem — Existing monetary system of India — Comparative scarcity of precious metals — Difficulty of maintaining silver standard — Impracticability of gold standard — Estimates of quantity of pre- cious metals in India ........ Chapter VII. Ariana. Bactria. Caubul. (Kabul.) ArcHAKiJ-T.AN. The boundaries of Ariana as given by ancient writers- — It in- cludes the more modern Bactria, Caubul, and Afghanistan — At present rather an ethnical than political division of the earth — History of money in Ariana connects it with India — Includes the Greco-Baotrian empire — Brief history of Ariana, and its connec- tion with India — Ninus — Semiramis — Darius — Alexander — Its various dynasties, down to modern times — Character of its an- cient population — Development of agriculture and commerce — Ariana the supposed birthplace of the human race — Supplies of precious metals from the mines — From commei'ce — Successive standards of money — Clay — Copper- — Numismatic finds — Excep- tional coins — Experiment of Kanerkes with overvalued coppers — Scarcity of silver after the Grceco-Bactrian monarchy — Nickel coins — Longevity of bad money — Punch-marks on coins . .118 COMTENTS. xxvii Chapter VIII. PAGE Egypt. The gold mines of Egypt — Their vast extent — Changes wrought upon the face of the country by mining — The Bisharee region — Origin of Egyptian civilization — Nubia the land of gold — Analogy to Italy, Gaul, and California — The mining districts — The Bisharee mines — Immense excavations — Their antiquity — Probably coeval with the first colonization of Egypt by Indians — Placers impoverished and quartz worked so early as B.C. 2830 — Described by Diodorus — Further mining discouraged by Diocletian — Antiquity of money in Egypt — Probably derived from India — No coins of the early gold period remain — Probable moneys of the period between the decline of the gold mines and conquest of the Persians — The gold rings not money— Nor the gold plates — Scarab money — Stone nummulites — Iron money at Kordofan — Its Sanscrit name — Its resemblance to certain Chinese and Aztec coins — The Persian coinage — Since that period the money of Egypt has been that of its conquerors — Glass coins of the Fatimite caliphs — These in use so late as the eighteenth cen- tury. Originally issued as numerical money, they eventually, from reckless over-emissions, became nearly or wholly worthless . 127 Chapter IX. Persia, Assyria, Babylon, and Palestine. Little known of the monetary histories of these countries — Persia never an important mining country — Darius — The Mahomedan era — Overvalued copper system of Kai Khatu — Its failure — Melting of copper coins mentioned by Tavernier — Assyria has left no numis- matic remains — Babylon — Her moneys of baked clay — Palestine anciently a pastoral country, using cattle for money- — Conjectural system of money during its agricultural and commercial period — No coins struck previous to the Maccabees — The Roman and Mahomedan conquests— Interesting experiment of the Urtuki Turkomans — Silver-plated dii-hems and gilt dinars — Failure of this system, and causes of same — Restoration of the silver dirhem — Merging of Palestine into the Turkish monarchy . . . 151' Chapter X. Aboriginal Europe. The coasts of Europe discovered by Phoenician gold-hunters — The interior probably colonized from Asia at a later period — Proceedings of the discoverers — Destruc- tion of forests — Derangement of water-courses — Capti-sdty of the natives — Different habits of the mining colonists and the agricul- tural colonists — Traces of these habits to be found in the cha- xxviii CONTENTS. racter of the nations who have sprung from them — The monetary systems of Northern Europe were of the bronze bell and ring types, and came overland from Northern Asia, whilst those of Southern and maritime Europe were based on gold and silver — Introduction of Greek types of moneys about the sixth cen- tury B.C. ......-■•• 157 Chapter XI. Greece and Greek Colonies. In Greece generally the sup- plies of the coining metals were always irregular — Gold and copper had to be imported, whilst the silver mines were controlled by Athens — Hence the other Greek states were compelled to em- ploy numerical moneys — PhcKnician commerce and money — Pro- bable antiquity of coined money in Greece — Concededly older than Lycurgus — His memorable system of iron numeraries ; its per- manence ; its beneficial effects — Blunder of Plutarch — Decline of Sparta, and fall of its numerical system — Ionia — System of over- valued iron discs — Byzantium — Iron system — Its decline — Growth of corporations — Marseilles — Athens, first period — The Peloponnesian war — Issue of overvalued coins — These sup- planted by a numerary system of copper discs — Downfall of Athens and of her numerary system — The Thirty Tyrants — Syra- cuse — System of overvalued coins a failure — Due to her inferior civilization and despotic government — Athens, second period — Fall of the Thirty Tyrants — Recovery of Attic liberty, power, and wealth — Rehabilitation of the numerical system — The Social War — "Weakening of the State — Fall of the numerical system — Restoration of cattle, corn, and coin money — Growth of cor- porations — Seeds, leather, and other base moneys — Hopeless con- dition of the State, and final destruction of its free institutions . 161 Chapter XII. Carthage. Foundation and progress of Carthage — Commer- cial enterprise — Settlements and factories on the western coasts of Europe — Trade with Britain and the Orient — Treaty with Rome — Embassy to Athens — Numerary money — Conquest of Spain — Mining fever — Carthage becomes aggressive, and engages in foreign wars — Fall of her numerary money — Her gold and silver excite the cupidity of Rome — Punic wars — Defeat of Car- thage — Her destruction and disappearance from history . . 173 Chapter XIII. Etrdria. Roman accounts of the foundation of Rome fabu- lous — Rome an ancient city of the Etrurians — Origin, grandeur. CONTENTS. xxix PAGE and social progress of Etruria — Agriculture, commerce, arts, money — Type of the latter copied by the Romans — Copper coins the principal money — Scarabs — Numismatic remains . .177 Chaptbk XIV. Rome generally. Difficulties in studying the details of the monetary systems of ancient Rome — Destruction of contemporary laws and historical works— Blunders of Pliny — Errors of modern historians and commentators — Common theory of the subject — The historical theory — The legal theory — Reasons for doubt- ing these theories to be adduced farther on — Views herein enter- tained with regard to the true character of the monetary systems of Rome 181 Chapter XV. Earliest Monetary Systems of Rome. Notwithstanding the opinion of Pliny, it is evident that coins and other moneys were used in Rome long before the era of Servius TuUius — The term " pecunia " — The copper ingots ascribed to Servids TuUius were of an earlier or later date, and were not moneys, but com- mercial ingots, and probably Etruscan — The As of copper pro- bably never weighed an As or libra — The pound sterling never weighed a pound, nor the French livre, a livre — No system of money ever existed in which coins permanently passed by weight, because the value of coins is due to their numbers, and not to their weights — The so-caUed As (of the Janus-faced type) was a sesterce, and belongs to the era of Servius Tullius . . 192^ Chapter XVI. , The Servian System, b.c. 566-385. The large cast coins of Janus-face type formed the basis of the Servian system — These coins were originally but slightly overvalued — Weighing, at first, possibly, so much as nine ounces, they gradually fell, with open coinage, to about one-half or one-third this weight, when their fabrication was limited, and the outstanding pieces rose in value to several times that of the metal they contained — This induced counterfeiting, which imperUled the system and led to the coins being struck instead of cast ....... 207" Chapter XVII. The Republican System, b.c. 385-269. This system really lasted from b.c. 385 to b.c 207 — Reasons for limiting its dura- tion herein to b.c. 269 — Its characteristics were government XXX CONTENTS. PAGE monopolization, and limitation of the emissions of money ; one kind of money ; high overvahiation of the material used for making the symbols ; and security against forgery — Summary of arguments employed to support this view of the system — The arguments stated at length ... . 213 Chapter XVIII. Rise of the Roman Commonwealth. Trifling progress made by Rome during the first few centuries of its existence as an in- dependent power — Its substantial progress only began after the political reforms of e.g. 509 to 408 — These measures greatly in- creased its population and solidified its power — The conquest of Central and Northern Italy which followed, increased its wealth and resources — Expansion of the Republic now rapid — Political reforms and military victories followed incessantly — Progress in agriculture, manufacture, commerce, and the arts — Difference between an expanding and expansive money — The Republican system of money the natural corollary of the expansion of the Roman Republic . ... . 242 Chaptee XIX. The Patrician System, e.g. 269-250. The silver spoil of Southern Italy falling largely into the hands of the Roman com- manders, the latter obtain from the Senate the privilege to coin it into overvalued denarii — The circulation of these pieces as congeners and multiples of the overvalued Ases constituted the Patrician system of money — Details of the system — The As — Reasons for overvaluing the denarius — It was not a forced but a permissory money — Possibly received for taxes, and paid out for supplies and services — Resemblance to the old time American .state-bank notes — Seignorage — Number and rank of gentes coining overvalued denarii — No care taken to guard this privilege from abuse — Reasons for this neglect — Place of coinace the Temple of Juno Moneta ; hence the name, " money " — Effects of the new coinage — Its unexpected extent — Inflation of the cur- rency — Gradual fall of both silver and copper numeraries toward their bullion value — Destruction of the Republican system of money 246 Chapter XX. First Punic War System, e.g. 250-216. Reduction of the copper nummus from two-and-a-half to two ounces, in conformity -with the changed market relation of copper to silver Inflation CONTENTS. xxxi PAGE •of the currency, chiefly by means of the overvalued silver denarii coined without limit by the gentes — Probable fall in the value of both silver and copper coins against commodities — Extant coins prove that Pliny's account of the monetary system of this era is wrong as to both fact and inferences. Had the system been " intrinsic," and the state wished to make a financial resource of the coinage, as he supposes, it could have done far better by re- ducing the silver rather than the copper coins . . . 256 Chapter XXI. Second Punic War System, e.g. 216-207. \Veights of the nummus and denarius both lowered, the ratio of value between them altered, a silver sesterce coined worth four copper sesterces, and the coinage of silver probably monopolized by the State — Effects of these measures — Decline in the overvaluation of all money, but particularly of the copper sesterce or nummns — Fluctuations in money occasioned by the war . . . 261 Chapter XXII. Decay of the Commonwealth. The industrial progress of Kome ceased and its social decadence commenced after the first Funic ^Var — Proofs of the correctness of this opinion found in the neglect of the arts and decrease of population which followed this event — The second Punic War left it completely exhausted and without recuperative resources — It had thenceforth either to maintain itself by spoliation or to perish — Its subsequent progress due to its policy of Conquest — Impracticability of maintaining a numerary money under such circumstances — Decline of the nume- rary system ........ 265 Chapter XXIII. The Scipion System, b.c. 207-170. Ambiguity of the Pliniau narrative — Effort to fix the era of the Lex Papirius — Features of the Scipion system — Position of gold — An arithmetical puzzle — M. Parisot's unsuccessful attempt to solve it — A simpler and more rational solution found by admitting the existence of an overvalued sesterce — W^eight of the scruple gold coin unknown — It was coined by gentes, was not a legal tender, and passed by courtesy — Position of silver — Silver coins made full legal tender, for the first time, during this period — This adoption of silver for money due chiefiy to the conquest of Spain and the assurance of ample supplies of silver metal — Abundance of silver in Rome ■derived from spoils of war — Silver coins formerly overvalued as xxxil CONTENTS. PAGE against commodities, rapidly fall during this period to their bullion value — Position of copper — The numerical system de- finitely ended — Copper coins, fallen nearly to their ingot value, are shipped away to the provinces in vast numbers — The legal tender function of copper coins probably restricted — They thus become tokens — Recapitulation ...... 271 Chapter XXIV. Agrarian and Social War Systems, e.g. 170-49. Political events which influenced the monetary history of Rome during' this period — Chiefly foreign coins, which brought in vast, though fitfiil, supplies of the precious metals, the working of the Spanish sUver mines, the conquest of the Alpine gold mines, and closure of those of Italy — Position of gold coins : legal tenders only during the two years of Sulla's constitution — Position of copper coins : reduced to tokens — Position of silver coins : interruptions to the supplies of silver : occasional scarcity of silver : emissions of alloyed, debased, plated, and forged denarii : silver eoins full legal tender — Variable value of the denarius in Ases — Lex quadrante — Temporary revival of full legal tender : overvalued copper coins by Sulla — Their speedy downfall — Summary of the period — Its monetary systems varied and conftising — This con- fusion increased by the use of corn money .... 285 Chapter XXV. The Julian System, b.c. 46-31. Gold now becomes the standard of value in Rome — The change of standard probably due to Caesar's desire to monetize his plunder of Gaul — Resem- blance to the monetary position of Germany in 1870 — The position of silver and copper coins. ..... 299 Chapter XXVI. The Augustan System, b.c. 31 — a.d. 41. Exhaustion of the richer portions of the placer mines and falling off of gold and silver supplies — Octavius averts the consequent threatened fall of prices by issuing a new overvalued copper sesterce — Precau- tions taken to secure approval of this measure — Resemblance to Mr. Chase's financial measures — Complete success of Octavius — Scale of values adopted — Gradual rise of gold and silver coins to a premium — Their disappearance from the circulation — Measures of Tiberius — Of Caligula — The latter seizes the muni- cipal and provincial mints, and without consent of the Senate CONTENTS. XSXUI PAGE coins an incredible number of overvalued sesterces — It is in the overvalued and redundant sesterces of this period that the stupen- dous sums of money mentioned by Pliny are couched — Difficulty of computing their value in silver — The minute "token" As, a degenerate descendant of the great archaic coin . . . 302 Chapter XXVII. From the Augustan Era to the Dark Ages. The moneys of this era substantially " intrinsic " — Every exchange a barter — Numismatists and numismatics — Growing scarcity of the coinage metals — Debased coins — They form the bulk of the circulating medium — Degradation of coins — The silver denarius dwindles until it becomes too small to handle, and is thereafter made of copper — Though rarely debased, because not lawful money, the aureus continually dwindles — It eventually becomes reduced to less than half its original size — Known as the " solidus," and afterwards the " bezant " — Dwindling and disappearance of the copper As — Dwindling and disappearance of the copper ses- terce — The copper denarius alone survives, and confers its name upon all money in Southern Europe — Legal tender — Revenues in silver ; payments in copper — Imperial plunder of the provinces, the depositories, and the citizens — Position of gold mining — Silver mining — Copper mining — Right of coinage — Ad- ministration of the mines — Counterfeit coins — Difficult to be dis- tinguished from the debased coins of the moneyers — Revolt of the moneyers — Their removal to Gaul and Britain — Seignorage — Decline of the Empire — The Dark Ages — -Review . . . 313 Chapter XXVIK. Ancient Generic Teems for Money. Kasu, Kas, Karsha- pana and cash — Dinar, dinarius, and dinero — Floos, feloos and foUis — Nomisma, nummus and numerary — Pecunia — As — Nummus — Moneta — The last-named term, though it dates back to the Scipion period, did not come into general use until the Dark Ages — Its defects — Specie — Coin — Unit of money — The generic term for money a key to the conception of money . . 334 Chapter XXIX. Conception of Money by the Ancients. The measure- ment of value by means of coins is only a momentary equation ; that by mfeans of a regulated money is an equation in time — This idea was familiar to the republican leaders of antiquity, and; coupled with the violent fluctuations in the value of the coining metals, led to the establishment of numerary systems — C XXXIV CONTENTS. PAGE The ancient conception of money is embodied in the terms " nomisma " and " numerato " — Foreign wars broke down these systems, and lowered the conception of money to that expressed by moneta — The decline of the Roman Empire led to a still lower conception of money • that of ponderata — This was the conception of the Dark Ages, and from it have sprung all modern laws and ideas on the subject — The ponderata has since advanced to the moneta conception, but no farther ..... 339 Chapter XXX. CoNCLtrsioN ..... ... 343 A HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. CHAPTER I. SUPPLY OP MATBKIALS POK MONEY AND DEVELOPMENT OP COINAGE AND FEINTING. Money must be made of some tangible and poiaderable material of ample and regular supply, capable of standing wear and tear and sus- ceptible of being so marked as to be difficult to counterfeit — Clay — Gold — Its occurrence, diffusion, method of extraction — Used in the arts before it was used for money — Placer gold — Quartz gold — The principal gold placers of the world exhausted — The quartz mines usually unprofitable — Present supplies of gold declining — Its production at all periods of history fitful or scant — Hence it was never permanently used for money until the period of Julius Ctesar — The ancient supplies were ample at only three notable periods : the discovery of Europe by the Phoenicians, the plunder of Asia by Darius and Alexander, and the conquest of Europe by the Romans — Copper more abundant and the supplies more regular — Hence better adapted for money in ancient times — Most of the Oriental moneys were of copper, indeed it was everywhere the principal money metal until the discovery of America — Silver rarely found native, generally in ores difficult to treat, hence last to be used for money — It is widely diffused, but as silver mines yield no alluvions or other progeny, the finds of silver are more con- centrated, therefore its production more fitful than gold — This fact, and the operation of mint laws has continually tended to lower its value — Cessation of these influences — -Silver first permanently used for money by the Greeks — Felted paper invented'E.c. 177 — First paper money B.C. 140 — Introduction of paper into Europe — Not common untU fifteenth century — Social condition of Europe not favourable to paper money at this period — No permanent system of openly overvalued moneys since the Roman Commonwealth — Experiments of the Venetian, Dutch, American, and French republics — The establishment of suitable B 2 HISTOKY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. paper manufactures in Europe coincident with the influx of precious metals from America — Influence in retarding use of paper moneys — Bank and Government notes — -Coinage — Cast moneys — Artistic excel- lence of the Greek coinages — Engraving — Printing with movable types not invented until the art of making paper was sixteen centuries old — Its influence in retarding the use of paper moneys. WITHOUT entering upon the Doctrine of Money,' and confining ourselves strictly to its History, it may be said that what is commonly understood as Money has always consisted, tangibly, of a number of pieces of some material, marked by public authority and named or understood in the laws or customs : that its palpable cha- racteristic was its mark of authority ; its essential character- istic, the possession of value, defined by law ; and its func- tion, the legal power to pay debts and taxes and the mechanical power to facilitate the exchange of other objects possessing value. Whatever view may be held of the value of money — whether it is due to the material of which the pieces are rciade, or to their number, or to the operation of law, or to some other circumstance ^ — it will be admitted that to be of practical use, money must be made of some tangible and ponderous material, as porcelain, glass, copper, gold, silver, wood, clay, leatherj or paper, and that the supply of such material must have had and must continue to have an im- portant influence upon the history of money itself. So, in like manner, it must be conceded that whatever marks of authority it bore, it was necessary to affix those marks to it so skilfully as to distinguish genuine money from ' This will be fully treated in a volume on the Science of Money. ^ The value of money has been attributed to a variety of circum- stances, sometimes to the material of which the pieces were made; sometimes to their number, sometimes to mint, tender, tax, redemp- tion, endorsement, or bank, or to certain sumptuary laws or customs ; sometimes to the laws or customs of foreign countries ; sometimes to the vicissitudes of war, or other causes threatening the subversion of existing laws ; and sometimes to two or more of these causes combined. SUPPLY OP MATERIALS FOR MONEY. 3 ialse, and therefore that the development of coining, casting, engraving, stamping, and printing has also had an important influence upon the history of money. For these reasons, it will be profitable at the outset of a work which must concern itself with all kinds of money, the practical and impractical, the unsuccessful and successful, to briefly glance at the conditions of production relative to the principal materials of which money, or strictly speaking, its symbols, have been made, and at the progress of invention in the art of fashioning, stamping, or otherwise marking, those materials for the purpose of money. Of these materials the principal ones have been clay, copper, gold, silver, and paper. The principal arts relating to its fabrication have been punching, casting, and printing. Of the former, clay is so common a material, and has been so familiar to man from the earliest ages, that nothing further need be said of its production or fabrication than that the one has always been ample and the other facile, and that the art of making and stamping baked clay tablets for money is probably coincident with the earliest period of systematic agriculture. Gold was undoubtedly the first metal produced by man. It is more generally diffused than any other. It is always found in a native state, that is to say, but slightly mixed with other metals and rarely in mixed ores. It is therefore easy to detect. It is equally easy to mine; the process for placer gold being washing in a gourd or hand-bowl, and for quartz gold, first, pulverization in a hand mortar, and second, washing in a bowl. It would be a grave mistake to suppose that gold was originally procured for use as money symbols or coins. Such was not the case. It was used in the arts long before any kind of money or monetary symbols were invented. Gold arrow-heads, gold knives and swords, gold rings and bracelets, and golden chairs were fabricated, long anterior to the era of money. This is proved not only by such few finds of prehistoric golden objects as the avarice of con- 4 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTBIES. querors has left untouched in the old and oft plundered countries of the Orient : it is corroborated by the condition in which the aboriginal inhabitants of Africa, America^ and Australia were found by modern discoverers. The negro King of Dahomey had a golden stool or throne, but no money : the North American Indians had golden ornaments and idolsj but no money: and the Bushmen of Australia used golden arrow-heads, while they were so far removed from the use of money that they were not even familiar with the art of exchange. Gold was undoubtedly first used for monetary symbols in the Orient ; and that too, at a period as ancient as that of any extant scriptures or monuments ; but before it was thus used, other moneys must have been long in vogue. It is a substance but poorly adapted for use as money. Although it is so widely diffused by nature that it may be found in almost any kind of volcanic rock or earth, or in any of the drift, washings, or sediments from such rocks, yet it is usually deposited in such fine particles that it is difficult and expensive to collect. Hence its supply is scant and irregular, and these are fatal objections to its use for money. Gold is found in two ways. First, in placers or beds of gravel or sand ; second, in rocks, usually quartz gashes or " veins." In all old countries the placers have long since been sifted of the larger pieces or grains of gold which they contained; and nothing is left in them, but those minute and invisible particles of gold which it did not pay, even for slave and captive labour, to collect. Among the exhausted countries are all Asia, except Siberia, all Europe, the coasts of Africa, and the whole of America except the Pacific coast of the United States, and some neglected spots in the interior of South America. It is in these few regions — chiefly Siberia, California, Australia, and the interior of Africa — that any considerable quantity of " pay gold " in placers is left. The combined annual product of these countries now amounts to less than 4,000,000 ounces. It has been de- clining year after year, and in spite of what discoveries of SUPPLY OF MATERIALS FOR MONEY. 5 new placers may take place in the interior of Africa^ or what improvements may be invented in the art of mining, this product must continue to decline ; because the African placers, no matter how inaccessible to the white race, have long been worked by the blacks on the basis of nakedness and slavery, and because no method of mining gold is so cheap as that one which only costs the exertion necessary to rob the metal from him who has already produced it. This was the origin of most of the gold now extant. As for the gold found in quartz gashes or veins this usually occurs in quantities too minute and in situations too difficult to extract it with profit at the prevailing level of prices ; a level, which, it must be remembered, has been made not by gold money alone, but by the combined influ- ence of gold, silver, copper, nickel, and paper moneys, all more or less interchangeable and all operating together in one volume upon the mass of exchanges. Of course there are exceptional quartz mines which must pay hand- somely, just as there are exceptional placer mines which did pay, and perhaps will pay for generations yet to come. But on the whole, placer mining — except in the few regions alluded to — and quartz mining, everywhere, must continue to decline; it having long been a losing industry. If such is the case now, when the various regions of the earth are so widely opened to commerce, that what is pro- duced in one country is free to become the property of any other which may bid the most in exchange for it, it certainly was more than once the case when each country was a world by itself, and held no other relations than those of warfare with the rest of mankind. Gold is now scarce and irregular of supply, because the principal gold placers of the world are exhausted, and the quartz mines will not pay to work. In the ancient world, gold — except ,when a new placer was discovered — was scarce, not merely for these reasons, but also for other ones. It could rarely be obtained by foreign commerce ; and when it did come, whether from discoveries of new 6 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. placers at home, or through the opening of a rowboat or caravan commerce abroad, it came suddenly and as sud- denly stopped coming. As a material for coining, it possessed every requisite ; ductility, divisibility, reunite- ability, etc. : as a material for money, it failed in the most important requirements : amplitude and regularity of supply. Hence although gold pieces for use as multiples of money were occasionally employed by the Bast Indians and other nations of high antiquity, gold pieces for use as money itself, were probably unknown until a much later date. The inscription on the bronze coins of Sung, B.C. 2257, viz., good for gold, points to the use of this metal for money multiples in China more than a score of centuries before our era, and although the inscription is ambiguous, the sub- stantial correctness of the indication to which it points, is confirmed by the high antiquity of gold multiple moneys in India. These moneys were not in common use : that is to say, no debtor could be compelled to pay with them. The common moneys of China were usually made of copper-bronze, and so were those of India. The gold moneys were merely multiples, probably overvalued and certainly used only for convenience in making up large sums. The permanent use of gold as legal money, cannot be positively traced back farther than the time of Julius Csesar, although it may have been used for this purpose by Alexander the Great, by Darius of Persia, by some of the Pharaohs of Egypt, and for brief intervals by other monarchs. The ancient method of extracting gold is the same as that still practised, excepting as to the use of mercury for amalgamation ; and even as to this art, there are not want- ing evidences that it was known to the East Indians, the Phoenicians, and the Greeks. The old and the new methods of obtaining gold differ only in details, not in principle. It was separated from the gravel, sand, or pulverized rock, which contained it, by means of water and its own superior SUPPLY OP MATERIALS FOE MONEY. 7 gravity ; and auch is still the method in vogue. The mechanical power in ancient times was the labour of starv- ing slaves and captives^ and this was quite as cheap, perhaps cheaper than either steam or water power is now. If any era existed when the supplies of gold in Asia were sufficiently ample and regular to warrant its use for money, it must have been long anterior to the historical period, which may be approximately fixed at about thirty centuries B.C. Twelve or fifteen centuries later the coasts of southern and western Europe were explored by the Phoenicians, and the supplies of gold which they obtained from the aborigines were carried to Egypt, there to maintain a system of gold multiple money which had been based upon the at first abundant supplies of her own placers, and the expectation, equally common and fallacious in' all gold countries — that these supplies would last for ever. At this period and to the Phoenicians, Europe was, what America at a later period seemed to the Spaniards, the world's Dorado. It was valued chiefly as a source of gold and afterwards silver ; and the various colonies which were founded on its shores were all planted with reference to this expectation. But when these colonies grew, as many of them did, into self-sustaining agricultural communities, the Phoenician domination was thrown off, the search for the precious metals gave place to more necessary and permanent industries, and the supplies of gold to Egypt fell off, so that, eventually, that country was obliged to relinquish the use of gold for money. The next period when gold became common enough in any large country to warrant its use as money, was when the Persian and Greek conquerors plundered Asia of its ancient accumulations of this metal ; and the final period (previous to the discovery of America) when a similar condition of affairs existed, was when the Romans plundered Europe, Asia Minor, and the northern coasts of Africa, in like manner. Copper was probably the next metal to gold which man 8 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. learnt to extract and reduce. It is often found in a native state, it is very widely diffused, it is quite abundant. The present state of archasological research does not enable us to locate the principal copper mines of the ancients, nor to compute the quantity of metal which they yielded : but it is known that both the Chinese and Bast Indians com- manded supplies sufficiently ample to warrant them in making moneys of this metal at a period which may approximately be fixed at twenty-two to twenty-five cen- turies before our era. From that time down to the Eoman period, the vicissitudes of mining and of wars which altered the possession of mines, were such that copper was often too scarce in one or another country to warrant its use for money ; and other expedients had to be resorted to. But on the whole, it maintained its ground longer and more satisfactorily everywhere than either gold or silver; and until the discovery of America, it was, throughout the entire civilized world, much more truly and essentially the basis of money than either of the other metals or than indeed any other substance. Viewed from this point, its history as one of the precious metals, has not received the attention which its importance deserves. Silver is rarely found in a native state, and then only in com- paratively small quantities. It is commonly mingled with other metals and minerals, forming a compound known as ore and presenting none of those attributes, either to the eye or the other senses, which distinguish it when freed from its matrices. Most of the ores of silver are difficult to reduce, a fact that bespeaks a long familiarity with the art of smelting before silver could have become as amenable to treatment as copper. It is therefore deemed quite safe to regard this one as the last of the three great coining metals which came into use. With regard to its diffiision, silver is originally as widely spread as gold, that is to say, it occurs in nearly all the volcanic rocks and always in conjunction with gold. But there is an important diffe- rence in the deposition of the two metals. SUPPLY OF MATERIALS FOR MONEY. 9 Gold is usually carried away long distances from its original place of occurrence, by the breaking down of the rocks which contain it, and their formation anew elsewhere either as other rocks, or as placers of gravel or sand, whilst silver is only to be found in the places of its original occurrence. This difference results from the fact, that gold remains unaltered and uninfluenced by the action of the elements, whilst silver is soon driven into new mineral combinations or dissipated and lost to view. A single gold belt, as the mother lode of California, may be the parent of innumerable gold districts and mines, some of them far removed from the mother lode ; but a silver belt, though it be as rich as the Comstock lode of Nevada, produces no progeny. Hence the finds of silver are more concentrated than those of gold, and this fact has had no little influence in determining its relative value. Apart from other considerations there can be but little doubt, that the average cost of producing a pound of silver, from the beginning of the world to the present time, has been far greater than that of producing a pound of gold, but silver, when it was produced at all, was produced in such great quantities, all at once, that combined with the operation of seignorage laws — a circunistance explained elsewhere ^ — it fell in value from time to time and continued thus to fall until a very recent date. There are, however, strong reasons to believe that this fall has quite ended, and that hereafter silver will always continue to rise. We are left in almost as great doubt with regard to the location and prolificacy of the most ancient silver mines as to those of copper. Such information as has trickled down to us through the bewildering ruins of history will be found in the author's work on the Precious Metals. There is no evidence to show that silver was common enough for money in any country previous to the discovery of Europe by the Phoeni- ^ " Hist. Precious Metals," by Alex. Del Mar, pp. 229, 233, 238, 244. 10 HIST.ORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. cianSj and the silver procured by these Argonauts of the Levant, most of which found its way to India, was insuffi- cient for this purpose. The first great supplies of silver known of with certainty were those from the Greek mines of Laurium, and the first monetary systems positively based upon this metal were those of the Greek states and colonies. Indian silver coins of an undoubtedly far more ancient date than the remotest settlement of Greece by the Phoenicians, are still extant; but they do not bespeak a system of silver money wherein the creditor has the right to demand silver coins at their market value as metal in discharge of his claim. They were used merely as multiples, the essential standard being copper coins, or some numerary system of money, in which the number of pieces emitted, and not the material of which they were made, formed the basis of value. Paper (felted) is said to have been invented in China B.C. 177, and pasteboard notes were certainly used for money during the reign of Wu-ti, B.C. 140.^ Judging from the flimsy appearance of a Chinese paper note, which the author has seen, of the Ming dynasty — some fifteen centuries later — this pasteboard, though answering well enough in theory, was found to be practically inconvenient for monetary symbols, on account of its inability to stand the wear and tear of circulation. The ancient Egyptians made a sort of paper from the leaves of the papyrus, but this also, was too flimsy for use as money. That the idea of making paper serve this purpose was not wanting in remote times is proved by the quickness with which the Chinese adapted it for money, and by the fact that numerical money symbols, and also the idea that money of all kinds was symbolical, was familiar to all the nations of antiquity. Felted paper was flrst brought into Europe from Asia by the Arabs about the sixth century of our era, but no Euro- pean manufactures of it were established until about the twelfth century, and it did not become common until the fifteenth century. The social condition of Europe was at ' See chapter on China and the several authorities therein quoted. SUPPLY OP MATERIALS FOR MONEY. 1 1 that period wholly unfit for the use of any system of money which depended^ as paper notes do, upon the rectitude and permanence of government or the proficiency of the me- chanic arts. Indeed, any sort of overvalued money, unless it was overvalued surreptitiously, was impossible. Such a system had ceased to be openly used when the Roman Re- public merged into an Empire ; it had been repeatedly tried by the feudal lords who at various times ruled the dis- jointed fragments of that empire, and they had always failed. It was eventually to be restored to the service of the world by another republic. Venice had long and successfully main- tained a paper system without notes ; to Holland remained the task of introducing one with notes. An emission of pasteboard tablets about the size of a silver dollar, and stamped with somewhat similar designs, was tried in Leyden during the struggles of the Dutch for freedom ; but this, too, failed ; and it was not until the American and French republics were established that systems of this character obtained any footing which lasted longer than a few months. Indeed, no entire system of numeraries, whether of paper or other materials, has ever been openly and avowedly attempted since the fall of the Roman Commonwealth, and it yet remains to be seen, if the power, integrity, and self-restraint of any state and the perfection of the mechanic arts are such as to render such a system as practical, politically and mechanically, as it un- doubtedly is financially. The era when the manufacture of paper suitable for cir- culating notes became so common in Europe as to render a system of paper numeraries mechanically possible happened to coincide with the arrival of new and great supplies of the precious metals from America, and this fact, together with the yet feudal condition of the European states, may have had its influence in retarding the use of paper for such a purpose. However, paper soon crept into use for making another kind of money — credit notes. These were first issued at about the same period in the American colonies 12 HISTORY or MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTEIES. and in Sweden^ and not long afterward by the Bank of England, since which time their use for this purpose has become common throughout the entire civilized world. India never seems to have used paper notes until the last century ; whilst China and Japan have never ceased to use them from the earliest period when the manufacture of paper was established in those countries. With regard to the progress of coinage, or the art of im- pressing emblems and letters upon moneys with a punch (cuneus, whence coin) , the belief prevails that this art arose in Asia Minor about the ninth century B.C., but this belief must give way before the well established greater antiquity of Indian coins ; and if the term coin may be taken to include all kinds of metallic monetary discs with emblems or letters upon them, as, for example the Chinese cast coins, which go back to a period nearly thirty centuries before our era, the prevailing belief is susceptible of being overwhelmingly refuted. However, so much attention is devoted to this subject in the following chapters that no fur- ther allusion to it is necessary in this place. At all periods and in each country where metallic moneys were used, the issuing power — commonly the State — doubtless employed the best workmen to fabricate them, so as to prevent coun- terfeiting ; but it cannot be admitted that their mechanical excellence was ever quite sufScient to attain this object until the era of the later Greek coinages, than which no issues of moneys were more artistic, and therefore none more difficult to imitate. Some of the earliest Chinese cast moneys were exceedingly well done, but it is believed that in spite of this fact they were not hard to counterfeit — so much fewer are the difficulties of imitating cast moneys compared with punched ones. For many ages subsequent to its invention, coinage — and this includes both the casting and punching of coins — was invested with a sacred character. The archaic Chinese and Indian, as well as the early Greek coins, were often marked with emblems, which in the former cases are supposed to SUPPLY OP MATERIALS FOR MONEY. lo he, and in the latter case are known to be, religious. The mints were in the temples, and the priests monopolized, or tried to monopolize, the secrets of metallurgy/ This cus- tom may have arisen either from the cupidity of the priest- hood to reap the profits of coinage, or solicitude on the part of the sovereign to prevent counterfeiting or to render it the more heinous. Whichever was the case, the industry and skill of counterfeiters rarely failed to tear these secrets from the temples, and there is scarcely a coinage, however antique, which was not closely imitated by contemporaneous counterfeiters. Engraving has rarely been bestowed directly upon moneys. It has rather been reserved for the dies, matrices, types, and plates from which moneys have been punched, cast, or printed, and it will be found that this art — known to the earliest ages of civilized society — -has faithfully kept pace with the opportunities which have been presented for its exercise. This is not the case with printing, when this term is con- fined to the use of movable letters. Paper had been known and widely used in the Oriental world for upwards of sixteen, and in the Occidental one for upwards of three, centuries, before printing was invented ; and this circum- stance may not have been without some slight influence in retarding the introduction of paper moneys. ' Tract 6332 Am. Phil. Soc. Library. CHAPTER II. CHINA. Antiquity of money greater than letters — Gold and bronze moneys of Simg, B.C. 2257 — Tortoise-back, or cowrie moneys — Knife, bell, and wheel-shaped coins — Clay or porcelain moneys — Paper — Various paper moneys, from e.g. 140 to a.d. 1455 — Present system : copper "' cash " with silver bullion multipliers and fractional (provincial) notes — Laws affecting trade in metals — " Cash," formerly numerical — Foreign coins — Carolus dollar — Brick-tea money — Bullion trade — Mines. IP history be examined by the discerning eye^ it will not fail to impart this lesson on almost every one of its pageS; that social life at a certain phase of its development cannot go on without commerce or exchange, and that exchange, as it progresses, necessitates the use of money : or to put it in the terse language of Bastiat, society implies exchange, and exchange, money. The phase of social life in which the use of money is im- plied is that one which follows after the agricultural state has begun, and before the pastoral state has entirely ceased. A proof of this is derived from the pastoral roots for the names of moneys, as pecus, feoh, etc. When society has passed beyond this phase: when its main support is a varied agriculture, when an extensive commerce and numerous manufactures have grown up on the basis of this agriculture, it is unnecessary to look for evidences as to whether money was in use or not. Money must have been in use, because such a phase of civilization is impossible without it. The niceties of exchange and division of labour which are involved in the conduct of a varied agriculture, the com- bination of capitals, and the partition of profits which result from an extensive commerce, and the still greater refine- ments of efibrt and result which are comprised in the CHINA. 15 organization and conduct of manufactures^ all bespeak the employment of that measure of value^ that common denominator of unlike equivalents, which we call money. There is little room to doubt that for more than fifty centuries China has enjoyed that phase of social life, and that degree of civilization which implied the use of money. To be convinced of this it is not necessary to scrutinise the regnal marks upon her numismatic remains. Her general history, her religion, her language, her archeeo- logical monuments, all tell the same story of progress in a remote antiquity. To doubt these proofs in favour of an ambiguous passage in a classical writer of a comparatively recent age, to whom Greece or Italy was the centre of the habitable world, and when to go a couple of thousand miles from these countries in any direction, was to walk off into infinite space, is to lend the ear to doubt and close it to conviction.^ Another point. Notwithstanding what seems to be asserted by Herodotus that the invention of the alphabet preceded the use of money — I say, seems to be asserted, because perhaps conscious that he was treading on question- able ground, his statements on both of these subjects are loose and ambiguous — it may safely be believed that the facts are precisely the reverse, and that money preceded the use of letters. This not only follows from the necessity of the case — money being of so much earlier and more pressing importance to man than letters — it is proved by two very curious facts : the earliest writings known to man invariably allude to money ; whilst the earliest moneys are invariably destitute of letters. Money is mentioned in the Vedic writings, in the Code of Manou, upon the oldest ' Concerning some blunders of classical writers consult Barclay Head on Herodotus, Penardeut on Pliny, Dr. Robertson on Plutarch, &c. Contrariwise see a curious confirmation of the vex-acity of the Chinese annals in Robertson's " History of India," p. 37, and Kote XVI. in connection with the disco\-ery of Greco-Bactrian and Indo- Scythic coins in 1840 and subsequently. 16 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. monuments of Bgypt^ and in the Bible. But neither the Archaic moneys of India, of Egypt, nor of Greece contain a line of writing. Among the first forms, perhaps the first permanent form, of money used in China was porcelain tablets or coins. Says Du Halde, on the money that at different times has been current in that country : " There was also money made of tin, lead, iron, and even baked earth, on which figures and characters were imprinted. It is related that after the reign of Han (b.c. 2119), a prince caused money to be made of stamped earth united with a strong glue, and taking it into his head to put down copper money, he gathered as much as he could, buried it very deep in the earth, and killed the workmen that were employed about it, that none might know where it was hidden." ^ Clay money was probably used in Archaic India, Babylon, and Egypt, and we know it was used in Siam, Etruria, Rome, Palmyra, Arabia, and other ancient countries. Following the era of clay money came that of the per- manent use of copper money, which, in China, has lasted to the present day. Nevertheless, at numerous periods in the long history of this extremely ancient country, notable experiments have been made, either with the object of reforming the system of money in the interest of the public, or of subverting it to the necessities or cupidity of the Crown ; and as such experiments are the best guides which the philosopher and legislator can rely upon for correct doctrine and enlightened law, they will be among the chief objects of research and subjects of explanation in this work. Owing either to the poverty of her silver mines or the inability of her ancient inhabitants to work silver ores ' Du Halde's "History of China," ed. 1736, ii. 288. It is possible that Du Halde alludes to a prince of the dynasty of Han. This began B.C. 206, and ended B.C. 189. But I have preferred the Emperor in- dicated in the text, because the introduction of coins is ascribed to Hoang-ti (b.c. 2687). Ibid. i. 276. CHINA. 17 economically, China does not appear to have ever adopted the silver standard for money. At a very remote date she appears to have tried the gold standard, and failed to main- tain it, owing probably to the uncertain and fluctuating supply of the metal from the minesj and the absence of an active foreign commerce to make good a deficiency, or dis- pose of a surplus. This experiment tooV place so early as the reign of Sung, 2257-07 B.C., and is attested by the somewhat ambiguous legend on existing coins which reads " Tong King Fo," or Good for Gold. Other notable experiments took place in the second cen- tury B.C., when skin and afterwards pasteboard notes were used as money, and during the ninth, tenth, eleventh, twelfth, thirteenth, fourteenth, and fifteenth centuries of our era, when various emissions of paper notes were used for the same purpose. Of these emissions, that of which we have the most definite information belongs to the reign of Hong-wu, A.D. 1368-99, and will be treated of at length in the following pages.' Previous to the era of Fuhi, which, according to Du Halde, commenced about B.C. 2942, the annals of China are mingled with fable. From Fuhi to the present time we possess a complete history of the sovereigns of China, with the details of their reigns, their personal character, and the circumstances of the Empire during their sway.^ The commercial character of the Chinese in very remote times, and therefore the use of money at such periods, is established, in one way, by tracing the intercourse which existed between them and the Western world. Small Chinese vases or bottles have been found in Egyptian tombs of the eighteenth dynasty, at Thebes.^ Others are ' Facsimiles of the notes are engraved in Du Halde's " China," Yule's " Marco Polo,'' and " Harper's Magazine." The author saw one (of three or four said to survive) in the hands of Mr. Douglass, of the British Museum. He valued it, for the owner, Sir Harry Parkes, at £200. ^ ' These wiU be found in Du Halde's " History of China," i. 269-509. ^ Wilkinson's " Ancient Egyptians," ii. 237. The eighteenth dynasty C 18 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTEIES. claimed to have been found by Dr. Schliemann, in the ruins of the Troad ; but the inscriptions on the latter which are alleged, on the authority of the Chinese Ambassador at Berlin/ to be in Chinese, are asserted by Professor James Legge of Oxford, to be in some other language, and that they differ from Chinese writing, in reading from left to right." Certain porcelain seals with Chinese characters, have also been found during the present century in various parts of Ireland, particularly in the Southern counties ; but doubt has been thrown on the antiquity of these monu- ments ; and although the finding of them in so strange a place has not been accounted for, it cannot be asserted that they prove any ancient intercourse between China and Ireland.^ China is believed to be alluded to in Isaiah xlix. 12, as the distant " land of Sinim." This was during the eighth century B.C. It is alluded to by Herodotus, B.C. 450 ; by Aristotle, B.C. 350; by Eratosthenes, B.C. 230; by Strabo, d. A.D. 25; and by Pliny, d. a.d. 79, who mentions the various Chinese products and manufactures which were imported into Egypt. The Greeks and Carthaginians appear to have occa- sionally traded overland with China, via India, several centuries before our era. At a subsequent date, the latter began during the sixteentli and ended during the fourteenth century, B.C. The vases or bottles alluded to appear therefore to have been sealed up in the tombs for upwards of thirty-three centuries. These seals have been since regarded by Wilkinson to be spurious. " The Chinese vases in Egyptian tombs are of recent date," says Wilkinson, in Edition 1878, chap. ix. p. 154. ' Li-fang-pao. ^ For an allusion to these vases see London " Quarterly Review " for April, 1874 ; and for a detailed account of them, see London " Times " for 1879. Prof. Legge's doubts -with regard to their alleged character are expressed in a letter to me, dated Oxford, July 17th, 1880. ' Prof. Legge writes me that about forty of these seals' have been found in different parts of Ireland, that they were not found in burrows or mounds along with Celtic remains, but picked up or dug near the surface. He claims that such seals were first made in China during the twelfth century of our era, but herein he must be mistaken. CHINA. 19 maintained regular commercial intercourse with the Chinese. The Romans also maintained a similar intercourse^ which began about the fourth century B.C. In the third and second centuries this trade went through Palmyra^ the Per- sian Gulf, and the Indian ports. A Roman commercial expe- dition to China is mentioned during the reign of Domitian, A.D. 94. Envoys from Marcus Aurelius Antoninus reached China, a.d. 166. An embassy sent by Alexander Severus, reached Canton in a.d. 220 ; other Roman embassies entered China in a.d. 265 and 287.^ After this the Arabians were the first to visit China by sea. See Robertson's "India," p. 102. These dates are those which have survived the wreck of time : the absence of earlier ones do not prove that no earlier intercourse existed between Europe and China. The very early use of the Chinese abacus and stove in Rome affords an evidence of this trade ; '' and the imports of silks, presumed to be Chinese, into Rome, and exports of silver to " Seres," mentioned by Pliny, prove that this intercourse, at least in his day, was regular and important.^ According to Mr. Medhurst'stranslationof the dictionary or encyclopjBdia, edited by the Chinese emperor Kang-he, A.D. 1722, " in ancient times the money of China was of tortoise-shell." * Kang-he's meaning of " ancient times " is defined by the fact that he himself possessed a cabinet of coins dating from the reign of Yaou, B.C. 2347 to his own time.^ The "ancient times" of tortoise (cowrie ?) money seem to relate to a period anterior to Yaou. The Chinese annals ^ For early voyages of Europeans to China, consult Martin's " His- tory of China;" also Appleton's " Cyclopedia," v. 110. ^ Martin's " China," i. 244. ' " Natural History," xii. 18. * " Five Years in China," by Lieut. F. E. Forbes, R.N., London, 1847, p. 57. The author says that Mons. Hager, in his "Numisma- tiques Chinoise,'' translates poei into cowrie shells, but remarks that so far is this from being correct that the cowrie shell is unknown in China. There is an English translation of Kang-he's Dictionary by Morrison, London, five vols., pub. by East India Company. Davis, " China," ii. 388 n., says that cowrie shells, known to the Chinese as hae-fei, or " fat of the sea," are used in Yun-nan and other places bordering on India, for money. " Forbes, p. 58. 20 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. carry this date back six centuries earlier than Yaou, for they state that metallic coins were used in the reign of Fuhi, B.C. 2942, Shin-nung, b.c. 2827, and Hoang-ti, B.C. 2687/ and that during the last-named reign, both coins, weights, and measures were employed.'^ There may be some uncertainty in fixing the reign of these monarchs within a century, or even two centuries, but notwithstand- ing the suspicion usually thrown upon the validity of Chinese annals, there can be little doubt that these per- sonages are authentic, and that they were acquainted with the use of coins. In addition to the evidence on this head already adduced, we are informed, that during the Hia dynasty, B.C. 2207- 1767, the punishment of crime was commuted with metal j ' that coins struck by Tai-Kung or Ching-Wang, B.C. 1120, are mentioned by various European writers on the subject;* and that in B.C. 1000, six taels of " metal ^' would ransom a criminal from mutilation.^ These archseological and literary evidences of the early commercial character of the Chinese, and their use of coins, prepare the way for the introduction of that more positive evidence which is to be gathered from the coins themselves. I have before me at the moment of writing, twenty trays of coins collected in China by the Rev. Dr. Justus Doolittle, an American missionary at Foo-Ohow. From Dr. Doo- little^s hands they passed in 1872 into those of a merchant of San Francisco, who politely placed them at my disposi- tion for the purposes of this work. These trays contains 464 bronze coins, the dates of which, derived from the regnal periods of the monarchs whose mortuary names they bear, range, according to Du Haiders ^ Forbes, p. 57. ° After trying copper coins, they fell back upon clay. Du Halde, ii. 288. ^ Monseigneur Hager, cited in Forbes, p. 58. * W. Vessering on " Chinese Currency, Coins, and Paper," Leyden ; Chinese " Repository,'' xx. 290 ; Dickeson, in London " Numismatic Chronicle." ° Forbes, p. 58. CHINA. 21 chronology, from B.C. 2257 to the present time. With the exception of seven coins among those of the most ancient dateSj they are all round, with square or round holes, nearly always square ones, in the centre, and they vary in weight from a few grains to half a pound each. The seven exceptional coins are of the bell and knife shapes. These are as follows : 1st. Bronze coin of Sung, B.C. 2257, bell shape ; weight about 325 grains. Inscription in ancient Chinese, as read in China, Tong King Ho. As read by Mr. H. T. Kuen,^ Chinese Vice-Consul at San P^rancisco, an American acade- mician, Tong King Po, For gold good, or Good for gold. 2nd. Bronze coin of the Chau or Chow dynasty, B.C. 1122 to 245. Scimitar or knife-shaped ; length, 5 inches ; weight about 280 grains. Leu To. These coins are called Kin-taou- tseen, or money of the metal knife. Kang-he's dictionary assigns to this type a place among the earliest coinages, that is to say, among coinages that long preceded the Chow dynasty. Such coins, says the imperial writer, vary in length from three to seven inches. Some of the larger ones, he con- tinues, have the characters Yih-taou and Ping-woo-neen, i.e. one knife worth 5000 (Le) of the smaller. He says, there are several kinds of these coins, one of which having the characters Yih and Taou, inlaid of gold, has also the value of 5000 Le.^ The coin before me has none of these peculiarities ; but I have seen others that have. 3rd, -dith, 5th, and 6th. Pour bronze coins of the Han dynasty, a.d. 9. Two are knife-shaped, rather "Yale lock key'' shaped. Length 2^ and 2| inches; weight 280 to 320 grains. Two are bell-shaped, weight 220 and 200 grains. Legends : Kie To. Yih Taou. Fo Pu. Pou To. Thornton relates that the usurper Wang-Mang, of the Han dynasty, established an innovation by imitating in his coinage the knife-shaped coins of the Chau dynasty. The coins before me prove that the imitation was not a close one. To procure metal for his mints Wang-Mang despoiled ' Or Kwan. ' Forbes, 59. 22 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. the tombs of coins which ancient custom had caused to be buried with the dead. Beside the six coins described^ there are twelve others in the collection before me of very ancient date. These are : — 7th. Half Tael, B.C. 178. Paun Liong. 8th. Another^ same date. 9th. Another, B.C. 139. 10th. Five chue or units, B.C. 139. Ung Chue. 11th. Fifty chue, a.d. 9. Tai Chuen. 12th to 18th. Seven coins of same period. The last twelve named coins are of the familiar " cash " type, round with square holes in the centre and ^ to 1 inch in diameter. They are smaller than the modern cash and the square holes are larger. In addition to these, I have seen in the collection of the Bibliotheque Nationale in Paris, bell- shaped bronze coins, measuring upwards of six inches in length, by four in width, and round bronze coins, fully five inches in diameter, and weighing a pound . These ancient coins have been submitted to the inspec- tion of Chinese numismatists and antiquarians, both in China, Europe, and America, and by them pronounced genuine. Among those who have passed this judgment upon them are natives of China who have been educated in European and American colleges. In short, there are no reasonable grounds for impeaching their validity, and, until such grounds are discovered, these coins must be accepted as authentic monuments. Thus accepted, they open a wide field for the history of money. They prove not only that money was known and used at least twenty-three centuries before Christ, but that even at this remote period representative and probably numerical systems of money were employed. The bell- shaped coin of Sung announces itself as good for gold, im- plying that gold had previously been used as money and that bronze coins were now used to represent it. Coins CHINA 23 Nos. 7 and 11 contain the inscriptions " half-tael," and fifty " chuen," or units of account. Chuen are now called "cash." ' Coupled with the fact that these coins are quite light (weigh- ing from 30 to 60 grains each) , the inscriptions prove that their value was many times that of the metal they contained."^ This value was probably maintained by limiting their num- ber. In such case the system was numerical. When we come to examine the history of money in other countries of the ancient world, we shall find that owing to the unequal distribution of the precious metals, and the obstacles to foreign commerce, commodity systems of money would have been dangerous to employ, and that, at one time or another, numerical systems were established in all of them. That China should have employed a numerical system is therefore no matter for wonder. The same reasons that im- pelled other nations to do so, impelled her likewise.^ The only wonder is that she should have employed one so long ago as the period of Sung ; and that at this period, almost the very outset of monetary history, we are brought face to face with a system whose advocacy and establishment form at the present day the objects of influential political parties in the United States and elsewhere. The Chow dynasty lasted during the long period B.C. 1122-245. Towards the end of this dynasty the empire fell into decay and feudalism. It was divided into 123 dif- ferent states, each probably with its own system of money.* ' Cash is of Indian origin from Karshipana, a certain coin. The coins, tokens, or numeraries, whichever they happened to be at the time, called by the English cash, were termed by the Portuguese traders sapeca and by the French sapeque. The smallest of the modern bronze coins are two-cash pieces. The Chinese name for cash is chue. ^ " Copper money of a nominal value has in times of scarcity been made to represent a certain amount of rice or grain, payable at the granaries." Forbes, 63. ^ Scarcity of metal is mentioned at numerous periods in Chinese history. See Forbes, 60, 61, 63, 67, etc. * Forbes, 64. Du Halde alludes only to the imperial systems of money. 24 HISTORY or MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. The Tsin dynasty began B.C. 245. In the reign of Che- hwang-te or Tsin-chi-hoang-ti, the unity of the empire was restored, and the building of the Great Wall completed ; but this Emperor sullied the lustre of his administration by destroying all the ancient literature upon which his emis- saries could lay hands. It is this destruction of original works that obscures the earlier annals of China and renders her numismatic remains peculiarly valuable. The Han dynasty began B.C. 206, with the reign of Lew- pang, otherwise Kaou-tsoo. During the reign of one of this line, Wu-ti or Woo-te, B.C. 140, the ancient literature was restored so far as possible. It was during the reign of Wu-ti that the first paper money of which we have an account was issued in China.^ According to Klaproth and Forbes,^ the notes were called p^i pi or skin notes, and they were made of white stag skin, a Chinese foot square, each note representing 40,000 chuen. According to Martin^ there were others of about the same date made of pasteboard ; and it is said that one of the latter, which had been preserved among the relics of a temple of worship, is still in existence.* Between the third century of our era and the accession of the Tsuy dynasty which began a.d. 590, with the reign of Yang-keen, we have few accounts either of the money of China or indeed any important circumstances which connect the history of the empire with that of the outer world. The first coins extant bearing the actual name of an em- peror are those of Ho-EIing, deposed a.d. 465.* Unless this was the son of Wan-te, who (the son) reigned from 454 to 465 and then died, I cannot identify this monarch. In 605-618, during the reign of Yang-Kwan of the Tsuy dy- ' Nearly three centuries previous to this date, coins covered with leather or parchment were used as money in Carthage. ° Klaproth's "Asia," i. 375, quoted in " Chinese Repository," xx. 289-95. Forbes, 67. Du Halde. ^ Martin's " Hist. China," i. 173. * Private information,, considered doubtful. ' Forbes, p. 60. CHINA. 25 nasty, a period of great confusion and scarcity of metal, round bits of iron, pieces of pasteboard and even articles of wear served as money ^ or media of exchange. During the Tang dynasty, a.d. 619-907, the empire seems to have enjoyed the advantages of peace and prosperity. In the reign of Leshimen or that of his immediate successor, Tai-tsung, the Nestorian Christian Olopwen or Olopuen is said, A.D. 636, to have entered China from Judea and preached the religion of Christ ; the emperor having ac- corded him permission to do so, and having even erected a church for his convenience ; but this account, upon the strength of an alleged anachronism, has been regarded by Voltaire as a pious fraud of the Jesuit Kircher.^ Tai-tsung was an enlightened prince who gave encou- ragement to science and literature. His successor, Kau- tsung, carried the arms of China into Thibet and Persia. A subsequent emperor of this line, Yiou-tsung, who as- cended thQ throne at some date between a.d. 713 and 757, has been called the Haroun Alraschid of China. During his reign in a.d. 740, a census of the population was taken — of itself no insignificant evidence of national prosperity and growth — the result being 48,143,600 mouths — pro- bably an increase over the population of the preceding era.^ In a.d. 807 during the reign of Heen-tsung and in con- sequence of the scarcity of copper at that time, paper notes were issued in place of copper coins. Forbes says that they were issued upon deposits of metal money in the public coffers. They were suppressed within three years.* ^ Klaproth in " Chinese Kepository," xx. 289-95. ^ Voltaire, " Hist. Europe," English Translation, London, 1754, vol. i. part 1, page 14. ^ Populations are rarely counted in periods of decay. Consult Essay on " Population and Specie," by the writer in Rep. U. S. Mone- tary Commission, vol. i. App. p. 70. A census of China was taken during the first century of our era, when the number of mouths proved to be 59,594,978. This number probably fell to something like 40,000,000 at more than one period previous to the Tang dynasty. * Forbes, 67, and Klaproth in "Chinese Repository," xx. 289-95. 26 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. Some Arabian travellers who reached China in the ninth century describe the metallic cash in use at the time.^ The Tang dynasty ended in 907 and was succeeded by five dynastiesj the last of which ended in 960. During all this time it has been argued that copper must have con- tinued to become scarcer, or else the copper chuen were con- tinually degraded, for the sake of the profits arising out of the coinage; because, it has been alleged, during the Sung dynasty which began a.d. 960, they became " so small that they were called geese eggs " and so thin that they would " swim upon the water." ^ In A.D. 960, reign of Tai-tsu (Sung dynasty) the imperial treasury was constituted a bank of deposit from which notes were issued upon deposits of silver, precious articles, and other merchandise, in government warehouses. In A.D. 997 there were 1,700,000 nominal taels of these notes in circulation; in 1021 there were over 3,000,000 taels. These notes are described as having been a foot square in size and negotiable.® Metal was scarce at this period.** During this century (the tenth) paper bills of ex- change were employed in China. ^ During the early part of the eleventh century, iron chuen were in circulation, whether as numeraries or commodities is not stated. They were probably at first highly over-valued, and being issued redundantly, fell to or near their commo- dity value. It was to represent these coins that the first notes of true (felted) paper were issued in China. These were emitted by a private banker in Sze Chuen province and were made payable in three years. Bach note was for ' " Chinese Repository.'' ^ jMinister Seward's dispatcli in Rep. U. S. Mon. Com. i. 545. This is an exaggeration, for 1 have over 100 of these cash before me. They are of bronze, measure one inch in diameter, and weigh about 20 to 50 grains each. Some of them are very thin ; but neither in this respect, nor any other, do they differ essentially from the cash of the present time. '' Klaproth and Martin. * Forbes, 67. ° Martin, i. 173. CHINA. 27 1,000 chuen or one tael of pure silver. The example of tlie Sze Chuen banker was soon followed by others — some fif- teen in number — and by the year a.d. 1032 more than 1,256,340 nominal taels of these notes were in circulation. In that year all the bankers who issued them failed and the notes became discredited. Yet they must have con- tinued in circulation, for we read that in 1068, counter- feits of these notes were current. The notes were called tchilse.^ In A.D. 1131, reign of Kau-tsung, according to Du Halde and Klaproth, or of Prin-tsung, according to Martin, paper due-bills were issued by the government for military supplies. During the reign of the same monarch a new sort of paper money called hwui tsz or exchanges was put into cir- culation. These notes were at first redeemable. They were in denominations of 1,000 chuen each. Later on 600^s, 300's, and 200's were issued. This emission was continued during the reign of Hiao-tsung, which began in -1163. During the five years ending 1167, there were outstanding more than 28,000,000 taels of this paper, and by the end of the same year over 43,600,000 taels.^ Besides these, the provincial governments issued circulating paper of their own."' It is probable that by this time the government had suspended metallic payments and that the notes it issued were irredeemable. During the remainder of the Sung dynasty, which con- tinued until the Mongolian invasion, these paper emissions were increased. At the same time the three-year private bank notes which had been issued during the previous century, continued to remain in circulation. After the Mongol dynasty was pretty well established, in 1224, the ' Klaproth and Martin. ^ Klaproth. ^ Martin. In addition to these emissions we are informed by Kla- proth that in a.d. 1155, in the Tongusian kingdom of Kin, North China, copper being very scarce, paper notes were issued to replace the sopper coins previously in circulation. 28 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. notes of the Sung dynasty were all " suppressed ; " whether by redemption or repudiation is not stated ; probably the latter. In A.D. 1215,- Genghis Khan, emperor of the Mongol Tartars, entered China at the head of a vast host, attacked and captured Pekin, and, leaving an army to further reduce the empire, marched to the west and entered upon that series of astonishing conquests which rendered his name a terror to the farthest ends of Europe. Genghis died in 1227, leaving the command of his armies to his four sons, under one of whom the conquest of China was completed, his grandson Kublai-khan, otherwise Shi-tsu or Chi-yuen, ascending the throne of that empire in 1281. Previous to the submission of the empire, that is to say in February, 1236, the Mongols revived the use of silk or paper money similar to that which had before been used " by Chang-fong, sixth emperor of the Kin " dynasty.-^ In 1260-68, and still previous to the submission of the empire, Kublai-Khan then in command of the Mongol army of occupation, issued paper notes and introduced them iuto those parts of China which his forces had subdued. These issues soon became redundant and fell in purchasing power. They will be distinguished herein as the First Mongol Issue. Between 1264 and 1290 a Second series of notes were issued. Like their predecessors they were without specific limit as to numbers, and thus became in time depreciated below the level of the coins after which they were named, and for which the law compelled them to pass in the pay- ment of debts. "Pauthier has given, from the Chinese annals of the Mongol dynasty, a complete table of the issues of paper money during every year of Kublai- Khan's reign (1260-94), estimated at their nominal value in ting or tens of silver taels. The lowest (annual) issue was in 1267, of 228,960 taels, and the highest was in 1290, of 50,002,500 ' " Universal History." Modern part, vol. iv. p. 200. This was a dynasty of the kingdom of Kin, referred to in a previous note. CHINA. 29 taels, whilst the total amount in 34 years was 249,654,290 taels.' A tael really meant 1 ,000 copper " cash " or " chuen/^ The depreciation first became rapid in 1287, when the emissions were very extensive. Before this occurred the notes of the First issue of 1260-63 had been exchanged at the rate of five for one of those of the Second. It is these notes of the Second issue that are described in the pages of Marco Polo. This was the most brilliant period in the history of China. Kublai Khan, after subduing and uniting the whole country and adding Burmah, Cochin-China^ and Tonquin to the empire, entered upon a series of internal improvements and civil reforms, which raised the country he had con- quered, to the highest rank of civilization, power, and pro- gress. Tranquillity succeeded the commotions of the pre- vious period ; life and property were amply protected ; jus- tice was equally dispensed ; and the effect of a gradual increase of the currency, which was jealously guarded from counterfeiting, was to stimulate industry, and prevent the monopolization of capital. It was during this era that the Imperial canal, 1660 miles long, together with many other notable structures, were built. ^ There is some little discrepancy in the dates assigned by Du Halde and Pauthier to Kublai Kahn^s reign, which I am not prepared to reconcile. No specific limits having been assigned to this emis- sion of notes, they fell in value, until in the reign of Woo-tsung, 1309-13, a new emission, which we will call the Third Mongol, was begun. Like the Second series with respect to the First, the Third were now exchanged ' Col. Yule's " Marco Polo," London, Murray, 1875. I have not been able to find this table of Pauthier. Col. Yule says that in both issues (those of 1260 and 1287) " the paper money was in official valua- tion only equivalent to half its nominal value in silver ; a circumstance not very easy to understand." The reason may have been that the note represented taels of copper chuen, which themselves were overvalued as against silver. . '' Malte-Brun, ii. 69. 30 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COITNTRIES. for the Second at the rate of five of the latter for one of the former. Population and trade had greatly increased, but the emissions of paper notes were suffered to largely outrun both, and the inevitable consequence was depreciation. All the beneficial effects of a currency which is allowed to ex- pand with the growth of population and trade were now turned into those evil effects that flow from a currency emitted in excess of such growth. These effects were not slow to develop themselves. Ex- cessive and too rapid augmentation of the currency, re- sulted in an entire subversion of the old order of society. The best families in the empire were ruined, a new set of men came into the control of public affairs, and the country became the scene of internecine warfare and con- fusion. This condition of things did not occur all of a sudden, but became slowly evolved during the reigns of the five monarchs, between Woo-tsung, 1309-13, and Shun-tee, 1333-68. It was at this period, viz., a.d. 1330, that the Moorish traveller, Ibn Batuta, reached China, whose paper money is described in his itinerary.^ Sir John Mandeville was also in China at this period (about 1327) ; but whether it is of the reigning monarch of that country or one of his pre- decessors that he speaks in the following extract, is un- certain : — " This emperor maketh no money but of leather im- printed or of paper. And of that money is some of greater price and some of lesser price, after the diversity of his statutes. And when the money hath run so long that it beginneth to waste (wear out) then men bring it to the emperor^s treasury, and then they take new money for the old. And that money goeth throughout all the country and ^ Ibn Batuta states that gold and silver coins (foreign) were melted down. He instances tlie dirhem. " The Chinese," by John Francis Davis, 2 vols. New York, Harper, 1858, pp. i. 23 ; and ii. 394. CHINA. 31 throughout all his provinces. For there and (even) beyond them they make no money neither of gold nor silver." ^ During the last days of the Mongol dynasty^ in 1351, an effort was made to reform the currency ; but by this time the evil lay too deep for remedy ; for many kinds of paper money were in circulation — government, provincial, and private — besides many counterfeits; and the government was powerless to limit the circulation. The notes there- fore continued to depreciate. In 1368 the Mongol dynasty was overthrown, and the Ming dynasty commenced with the reign of Hung-wu. In the seventh year of his reign (1374) a new issue of govern- ment notes took place, a facsimile of one of which is pub- lished in Colonel Yule's " Marco Polo." It is correct as to colour, but fails to convey a truthful representation of the thin, flimsy silk paper upon which the original notes were printed, one of which, the property of Sir Harry Parkes, the writer inspected in 1883. In 1374 the notes of the Mongol emperors were still in circulation, though at what relation of value to the Ming issue is not stated. At a subsequent date during the same reign the Mongol notes were retired from circulation. The new Ming notes read : — " This paper money shall have currency, and be used in all respects as if it were copper money." The de- nominations were from 100 to 1,000 chuen. Martin states that as they were issued redundantly, it was attempted to maintain their value by forbidding the use of gold and silver ; but since, in point of fact, these metals were not then coined or used as money in China, neither their use nor disuse could have had any effect upon the value of the paper notes ; and Martin must be mistaken. Their value could only have been affected by their number and that of any other pieces of money then in circulation, such as copper chuen, private bank notes, counterfeits, &c. At the outset of the Ming issues, 17 paper chuen were equal to 13 metallic chuen; by the year 1448, the issues of ' " Travels " of Sir John Mandeville (Ed. 1839), p. 239. 32 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. paper notes having meanwhile been greatly increased, this relation became 1000 paper to 3 metallic chuen. In 1455 the government decreed that the taxes should be paid in paper moneyj and forbade the circulation of coins (chuen). The Mings, so far as excessive issues are concerned, were but too clearly following in the worst footsteps of the Mongols. Nevertheless, the condition of the empire had greatly improved. Whilst Hung-wu, who reigned 1368-99, was still on the throne, that is to say, in 1393, a census of the population showed 60,545,812 mouths,^ although there had occurred but half a century previously — in 1342 — one of the greatest famines of which mention occurs in history, when no less than 13,000,000 of human beings were de- stroyed in this empire alone.^ But the prosperity which this increase of population evinces, gradually disappeared, and after Hung-wu the empire again fell into decay and was repeatedly subjected to the incursions of the Tartars. In 1448, and with a view of improving the credit of the government paper notes, the circulation of metallic chuen was prohibited ; but this measure proved abortive, and by the year 1455 the paper issues appear to have become entirely discredited, and metallic chuen resumed their old place in the circulation. This was the last issue of impe- rial government notes in China.^ H. T.Kuen (Chinese vice-consul at San Francisco) states that leather notes were issued by the Ming dynasty during the rebellion of Lee-cheong. Undated porcelain coins are still extant, stamped with Chinese letters signifying " Eternal prosperity." One in the author's possession measures about three-quarters of an inch in diameter and one quarter of an inch thick. Another one, of different type, is in the San Francisco Mint collection. Towards the latter part of this century (the fifteenth) the population of the empire had fallen to 53,281,158 ^ Malte-Brun. ' App. Cyc. ' " American Almanac," 1879, pp. 65-68. CHINA. 33 mouths.' Even at this figure it was greater than that of all Europe.'' We now come to the period when China was opened to the maritime commerce of Europe. This was effected by the Portuguese in 1518."' It would be interesting to know what had been the ratio between gold and silver in China previous to this event, and how such ratio came to be afterwards changed by its influence ; but the data on the subject are too meagre to warrant any definite conclusions. We are informed that at about the beginning of the four- teenth century the ratio was 1 tael of silver equal to 1 mace of gold, or 10 to 1 ; * but there is no other datum for up- wards of three centuries after this date. The ratio was, however, not important. The Chinese coined neither gold nor silver,^ and although the latter is at present used for money, and was probably so used, at least to a small ex- tent, at the date mentioned (1264-94), the national policy of keeping the mines closed, which appears to have been adopted so far back as that period, and perhaps for ages before, must have caused the ratio to depend upon sur- rounding countries rather than the relative abundance of the precious metals within the empire. The countries most likely to have exercised this influence at the date mentioned were those which had then recently been over- run and plundered by Genghis Khan and his successors, to wit, Turkestan, Persia, Asia Minor, and Eastern Europe. In 1596 the emperor (contrary to the advice of his ministers, and probably at the instigation of the Portu- guese) ordered the opening of six mines of gold and silver ^ Malte-Brun. ^ " Discourse on Political Economy," by the writer, delivered before tlie Alumni of the University of California, January, 1879. ' " Why Should the Chinese Go ? " by Kwang Chang Ling ; pamphlet. San Francisco, 1878, p. 5. * Klaproth in "Chinese Eepository," xx. 289-95. " " The government of China issues no other coin but the base metal token, composed of copper and zinc with, perhaps, some lead." Davis's " China," ii. 388. D 34 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. in the provinces of Honan^ Chensij and Shansi ; but six years afterwards they were closed.^ Mr. Colwell says " that " in China, the skill of counter- feiters is such as wholly to prevent the use of coins (mean- ing gold and silver ones), and that vast population is — for that reason, it is said — confined to the primitive mode of weighing, in payments, all the gold and silver used in com- merce." But this opinion is clearly wrong. It is true the Chinese are skilled in counterfeiting ; but they are more than equally skilled in being able to detect counterfeit coins or even impure metal. The fact is, they do use silver coins, only they are all, with the exceptions men- tioned below, and when not counterfeit, coins of foreign nations. The real reason why gold and silver coins are not fabricated in China is that the money of the country is, and, ex- cept when replaced by paper notes, has always been, " cash," generally copper, but sometimes iron coins. These cash have been issued from time to time, not as commodity but numerary or highly over-valued coins, the value of which is endeavoured to be regulated by laws limiting their issue. Under these circumstances, it is only necessary to say, in reply to Mr. Colwell's theory that the money of the country whether commodity or numerary being made of copper or iron, it is impossible to introduce gold and silver coins into the circulation or to make them legal tender at any fixed ratio of value to the cash ; because the latter are com- posed of metals whose value in gold or silver is subject to violent fluctuations; there being now no great hoarded stock of them on hand in the commercial world, as there is of gold and silver. Since the opening of China to maritime commerce the changes in her monetary system have not been important. During the last years of the Ming dynasty, which ended in 1645, the empire became the theatre of internecine wars, ' Pauthier, " Chine," p. 405, ed. 1835. ' " Ways and Means of Payment," p. 109. He gets his infoi-mation from Du Halde, ii. 287. CHINA. 35 and the numerary cash being issued without limit both by the imperial and provincial authorities, and largely counter- feited at that, they fell to their commodity value, and, as such, formed, together with the tribute rice, the principal, almost the only, moneys of the empire. The Tsin, or Taetsing, or Mantchoo Tartar, dynasty began in 1645 with the reign of Shun-che ; and an era of peace and progress succeeded. The Russians were allowed to trade with the northern parts of the empire. Formosa and Thibet were conquered, and foreign trade was permanently opened at the seaports. A German Jesuit, Adam Schall, was ap- pointed prime minister to the emperor ; the Christian churches were restored to the missionaries (1671), and the country was surveyed and mapped out by Europeans. These re- forms indicate an era of prosperity, which soon demanded a more equitable and efficient currency than copper cash ; and accordingly paper money, at first consisting of private bank notes, followed afterwards by provincial government credit notes, crept into the circulation. Towards the end of the eighteenth century the popula- tion of China had grown to perhaps 175,000,000 souls, and notwithstanding current belief to the contrary, and the pretended censuses adduced to support this belief, this must be deemed the greatest number known to have been ever attained in China, and to mark the highest point of its prosperity, which, since the period mentioned, has greatly declined. In 1875, at the beginning of the present reign — that of Kuang-soo, ninth emperor of the Tsin dynasty — the population of the empire could scarcely have exceeded 128,000,000.^ These numbers and the condition of pro- gress which they indicate, have, it is thought, lost their previous tendency to retrograde, and at the present time the empire, if not slowly progressive, has at least attained for a time a stationary condition. ' Fourth Letter of Kwang Chang Ling in San Francisco " Argo- naut," Sept. 17th, 1878, and the various authorities therein adduced, including the last actual Chinese census (1761). 36 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. The monetary system of China at present consists, and for some time past has consisted, principally of cast copper or bronze cash, of which there are two classes in circulation. The first of these are the large cash, which are cast by the Imperial authorities, and circulated almost exclusively in the city of Pekin and its suburbs, where no other cash is current. It is presumed to be these coins whose composition is said to consist of six to eight parts of copper, and from four to two parts of alloy, either lead, zinc, or tin, and whose legal composition is described as follows : copper 54, tutenag (zinc) 42, lead 3.4, unenumerated 0.6 ; total 100. The ingredients are, however, not always the same.'^ Between these cash and silver bullion there is said to be established a legal relation of 1000 cash to the tael of silver.^ But since cash are legal tender and silver bullion is not, this relation cannot be deemed effective.^ However this may be, the cash, if composed as above set forth, are, at this relation, undervalued, and silver bullion overvalued. The second class of cash consists nearly entirely of copper, and are smaller and lighter, weighing when new, about eight to the ounce avoirdupois, and when worn, say after fifty to one hundred and forty years of use, exactly nine to the ounce. These cash are cast by the provincial authorities or by private parties under their permission.^ The market relation between cash and foreign dollars varies from 1200 to 1800 cash to the dollar; the variance being influenced by the local supply and demand of par- ticular coins at the Treaty ports. ' Gutzlaffs " China." ^ Stanton's "Laws of China," London, 1810, pp. 124-5. ^ Farming out the mintage to private parties by the imperial government is mentioned by Torbes, 65. The same author (p. 63) states that companies of merchants have been permitted to issue coins. * For size, fineness, and variableness of Chinese cash see Wiley in " Transactions of North China Branch of Eoyal Asiatic Society," for (about) the year 1865. The weights given in the text are from my own experiments. CHINA. 37 The laws of Chiua contain provisions designed to pre- vent the exportatioUj sequestration, monopolization or dearth of copper metal or copper cash and the counter- feiting of the latter. Copper metal may be used in the arts only for certain specific purposes. None is to be con- cealedj or sold except to the government.' Copper ore, copper sheathing old, and copper wares, may be exported on payment of export duties,'' but not copper in ingots. OflBcers of the Chinese government are forbidden (under pain of sixty blows) from retaining and accumulating coin.^ The Penal Code of China provides that when cash is cast it shall be deposited with the Board of Revenue until required for public service. " The quantity of metal coined and the periods of its issue are fixed by the Board of Revenue in order that the successive supplies of coin for the use of the people may correspond with their wants and be regulated according to the market prices of gold, silver, grain, and other articles in general use and consumption." ■* Sir R. Murchison's opinion,* why the gold mines of China were forbidden to be worked, may have been derived from these regulations. Copper coin is forbidden to be cast by individuals under pain of death.^ Copper cash is forbidden to be exported abroad on penalty (to foreigners) of a sum equal to its value ; ^ but it may be ' Stanton's "Laws of China," p. 125, and Chinese "Repository," ii. 68. ^ "Treaty between the United States and China," June 18, 1858. "Statutes at Large." Little and Brown, ed. 1862, p. 190. The export duty on copper wares by this Treaty is fixed at 1.15 taels per 100 catties. ' "Laws of China," Stanton, p. 124. * " Chiaese Repository," ii. 68, and Stanton's " Laws of China," p. 124. ' Quoted by McCulloch in " Encyc. Brit." 1858, xv. 470. '^ Stanton's " Laws of China,'' p. 397. ' "United States Treaty with China." Statutes at Large, 1862, p. 194. Similar enactments formerly prevailed in England. Consult the statutes of 28 Edw. III., 38 Henry VIII., and 2 Edw. VI., cited in Calvert's " Gold Rocks of Great Britain," p. 69 38 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. shipped by foreigners under bond, from one seaport of China to another.^ No provision appears to be enforced at present against the importation of silver, which in regard to China is unim- portant ; for the relation established by the Chinese law is not between copper coins fabricated by the Chinese authori- ties and silver coins similarly fabricated (of which there are none) , but between copper coins so fabricated and silver bullion. Nevertheless, such an interdict was probably enforced in former times, for Postlethwayt, an old author, informs us that silver was imported into China, surreptitiously, in order to counterbalance the export of gold, which, being prohibited, was also effected surreptitiously." Martin says that " gold and silver may not be legally exported from China except in limited quantities, and in foreign metal," whilst in another place he says " the Censor of Fuhkein has appealed against this law, (permitting the exportation of the precioiis metals,) saying that the expor- tation of silver 'touches the vitals of the empire.'" The fact is that these, in common with most of the other, laws relating to the money of China, are grossly violated. Says Martin : " A large amount is, however, annually taken away (exported) in broken Spanish dollars and sycee silver and gold.'' And in another place : " A Cen:;or from Che- keang complains of the exportation of silver and yellow gold and that there is no law to punish the guilty." ^ Copper metal is concealed, copper cash is either de- signedly or unavoidably rendered scarce at times in one place and abundant in another ; * it is largely counterfeited ; * ^ " United States Treaty with China." Statutes at Large, 1862, p. 194. ^ Postlethwayt's " Die. of Com.," article " Gold." ^ Martin's " History of China," i. 178, et supra. ^ Dr. Wells Williams's " Middle Kingdom." ' Counterfeit cash are so common that it is customary in trade to allow five to ten per cent, of payments in cash to be made in counterfeits. Information from Mr. James White, M.P., long a resi- CHINA. 39 and it has been surreptitiously exported by foreigners; sometimes by shiploads.^ Another important consideration in this respect is^ that ■whilst the Chinese authorities undervalue copper cash as against silver bullion^ they overvalue cash as against rice exacted as tribute. This grain is so important an article of commerce in China that the over-valuation of copper cash in rice has the effect of over-valuing it in all other com- modities except silver. The taxes which are payable in money are collected by the tax farmers or official collectors, as the case may be, in copper cash, and by the latter paid to the Imperial Government in silver. From these transactions the col- lectors derive a considerable profit, for they always charge the people for the exchange more than enough to protect themselves from loss through fluctuations in the value of silver measured by cash. In 1847 it was estimated that eight-tenths of the population paid their taxes in cash, the value of which had to be remitted to the government in silver .° It is believed that these arbitrary and complicated regu- lations are somewhat similar to those which prevailed in Eome during the failing periods of the Commonwealth and the Empire. There can be no doubt that the true principles of money, the causes of its value and its relations to the growth of industry, have been more than once caught sight of in China ; nay, even that they have been acted on and put into practice. But owing to the absence of advanced education among the people and of strength in the govern- ment, this never continued long. The theory of money is dent in China. Davis, " China," ii. 390, quotes from the " Peking Gazette" of June, 1824, the confession of a forger who counterfeited 7000 chue (plural, chuen) by casting them in lead. ^ The British commercial returns show something of the export movement in copper from China. ^ Consult " Chinese Repository," xvi. 275-277, and Martin's " China," i. 178. 40 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTEIES. very correctly outlined in a memorial to one of the emperors of the present century.^ However, it was known in China ages before. At present, it is forgotten. The cash of the empire have always been issued as numerary moneys ; several circumstances have at times more or less altered this character. These are the vicissitudes of the government, which have induced it to break down the limits it had set to the emissions ; its inefficiency in guard- ing against counterfeits, which at these or other times have had a similar effect ; and the emission of private bank notes. These circumstances have frequently altered the numerary character of the cash to their commodity value. In other words, they have lowered the value of the cash to that of the metal they contained. Precisely at what several periods this occurred, and therefore at what several periods the cash and their paper representatives possessed a more or less numerical value, and at what periods a merely com- modity value (that of the copper, etc., contained in the cash) it is often difficult to determine. But the general fact that the cash are or have been numerical appears to be beyond dispute. This fact is proved by several circumstances. I. The government mints for coining cash were stopped in the province of Puhkien for upwards of twenty years, in Chihli for sixteen years ; in Hupeh for upwards of ten years ; and in Hunan for ten years ; and during this time no new cash were coined in these provinces. The motive for this measure was to diminish the number and thus increase the value or purchasing power of the cash already existing. This long continued course of contraction, whose only mitigation arose from the fabrication of counterfeits, must have had a most depressing effect upon industry and population." II. It is proved by the enormous profits which, at some ^ The " Chinese Kepository," ii. 279, contains the memorial. It is well worthy of perusal. " " Chinese Kepository," ii. 279. CHINA. 41 not very remote date — not mentioned^ but probably within the present century- — were derived by the government from the fabrication of cash. The metal contained in the cash annually coined in fourteen provinces cost 800,000 taels of silver and was coined into cash amounting by tale or num- ber to 1,200,000 taels, a profit of fifty per cent/ III. It is proved by the absence of open and gratuitous coinage in China. This is an institution without which a radically material or commodity system of money is impos- sible. Coins that are not free to be supplied in response to the demand for their use are, or become, necessarily over- valued, and therefore to a more or less extent assume the character of numeraries. Turning now from Chinese coins to paper money it must be stated again that no paper money has been issued by the Imperial government since the middle of the fifteenth century, or during the Ming dynasty.^ Other paper money has, however, obtained circulation from time to time, and at present there are vast quantities of it in use. Of the paper money which has circulated in China during the past four centuries, namely, since the last issue of Imperial govern- ment notes, there are three classes, all of which were expressed either in cash, or silver taels at a fixed ratio to cash ; and were therefore in effect, cash. These classes are : I. Private bank notes. These are issued by private bankers chiefly in the cities. They are of all denominations from one cash to 1000 taels i They sometimes pass with ^ " Chinese Repository," ii. 279. With reference to counterfeit moneys see Martin i. 176 and " Chinese Repository," iv. 344 and xvii. 483. Those mentioned in the passage last referred to were, some of them, light cash, and others made of lead and sand. '' Per contra, Mr. Sit Ming Cook, formerly Vioe-Consul of China at San Francisco, informed the author that the Imperial troops were paid in silver, that Imperial government notes were then (1880) afloat and current at 90 per. cent, discoiint in silver, and that these notes were not legal tender, but were receivable in payment for purchased titles of nobility. For this reason they were in demand by money brokers at ten per cent, of their face value in silver. 42 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. an endorsement or "chop;" at others without. Their circulation is strictly local, and as to quantity, it rises and falls with local demand. The notes are payable on demand or in five or ten days, in cash or in taels of cash, that is to say, taels of silver at a fixed relation to cash. Failures of banks or bankers are rare. They have no connection with the government.-' These notes are preferred to metallic cash. They are easier to carry and their redeemability is unquestioned. In Foochow in 1845 many of the mercantile firms issued similar notes for 400 cash to 1000 taels. ^ Similar notes are issued by banks or bankers payable not on demand, but in five or ten days' time. These pass current as money the same as the others. Demand notes for one, two, and five cash each are also issued by the salt farmers throughout the empire. These also pass as money. The use of cheques is so common that people travel with their blank bank cheque books which can be filled up to any amount.® II. Provincial notes. An emission of these during the seventeenth century was alluded to on a previous page. It is not known to the. writer if any have been emitted since.* III. Notes for brick tea used near the northern boun- dary. These are unimportant. Being unconnected with the cash system they will be alluded to further on undet' the head of " brick tea money." Besides the cash and the various sorts of paper money which have been issued to represent them, other forms of money have been or are used in China ; though only to a limited extent. These will now be briefly treated and in the order of their importance. Silver bullion and foreign silver coins. — Neither silver ^ Martin's " China," i. 172-3. ° " Chinese Repository," xv. 21 1 and xx. 292. ■* Information from Mr. Jas. White, ]\I.P., and Forbes, p. 71. ' Mr. Sit Ming Cook says there are none of these notes in circula- tion now. CHINA. 43 coins nor gold coins are fabricated by the Chinese authori- ties. Private parties have^ however, fabricated foreign coins within the empire, although such an act is contrary to law. This was done at Fuhkien about the year 1834.'- At a later date it was reported that a similar illicit fabri- cation was conducted in the district of Shunlih, south of Canton, and that so many as one hundred workmen were employed in a single establishment. They used European dies and other appliances. Furthermore that an English mercantile firm at Canton had a mint there in which Spanish dollars were coined.^ Even the Crown has not disdained to engage in this business. In 1845 the reigning Emperor, Taouk-wang, caused silver dollars to be cast at Hangchow and Formosa. They were called " Soldiers' Pay." ^ In the course of time the emissions became debased, when they lost credit and disappeared from circulation.'' Silver bullion is generally cast into ingots, in shape rudely resembling shoes ; hence its name of " shoe silver." Native silver is called sycee,^ and, as the means of refining the metal were formerly imperfect, sycee differed in purity with the metal from various mining districts. Altogether, there were five kinds, all of different " touch," or per cent, of purity, " the best, Kwan-heang or Kwan-leang, in which the Imperial duties are paid, being ninety-seven to ninety- nine touch." ^ At present all silver is the same, whether ^ " Chinese Kepository," ii. 445. Imitation dollars are mentioned at a later period. They were made of base metal and sometimes plated. Dr. AVells Williams, " Chinese Com. Guide," 134, and Davis, " China," ii. 392. ^ Martin's "China,'' i. 178. ^ The later Romans called the ancient aureus, the solidus. From solidus are derived sol, sou, etc. * Martin's " China," i. 176. ' Prom Se-sye, fine floss silk, Forbes, 61. " Martin's " China," i. 178, and Forbes, 61. Silver of different kinds reminds one of the copper of different kinds enumerated in Pliny. In modern times all silver and all copper are the same, because they are reduced, in reckoning, to absolute purity. 44 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. from one district or anotlierj or whether native or foreign. The name sycee has^ therefore, a different meaning. It now simply means any silver bullion which is pure or nearly pure. The foreign silver coins which circulate in China are chiefly Spanish and Spanish- American pieces-of-eight and dollars and American dollars and trade dollars. As these pass from hand to hand they are " chopped ; " i.e., marked with the seal, device, or stamp of the owner, by way of endorsement; hence the name of "chopped^' dollars. When these chop marks become so numerous that there is no room on the coins for more, the coins are reduced to bullion. The value in cash of the various foreign dollars circulating in China is much subject to local caprice ; a given coin being worth more or less in one city than another. It is also subject to caprice in favour of particular coinages, a dollar of one date being worth more or less than one of another, although both may contain the same weight of silver. Something of what is regarded as caprice is, however, due to difference in weight and also to the presence of a small proportion of gold (from 2f to 5 per cent.) present in some silver coins, particularly the Mexican and old Spanish,^ a fact due to the imperfect assays and mint- ages of Spanish-American silver. The presence of this gold is certain to be detected by the superior acuteness of modern Chinese bullion dealers." The most extraordinary anomaly in valuation relates to the Spanish Carolus dollars, or more properly speaking, pieces-of-eight. These coins are no longer fabricated by the Spanish mint. The supply is thus very much limited. ' Speech of Senor jM. Romero in the Mexican Congress, reported in the " Diario " (official gazette) October 14, 1876, and quoted in the Report of United States Monetary Commission, vol. i. App. p. 393. ^ Consult as to all these particulars my Minute on " China " in Appendix to Rep. U. S. Monetary Commission ; also Du Halde, Richtofen and " Chinese Repository," passim. CHINA. 45 whilst the demand — due to Chinese habit — being uninter- rupted, it has occurred that they have gone to a premium of 30 to 40 per cent, over Mexican dollars said to contain an equal amount of pure silver.^ Something of this is due to the fact that these pieces-of-eight are old ones, and contain more silver than the modern Mexican dollars. Gold Bullion and foreign gold coins. — Gold bullion is used for money to a small extent. It is cast into ingots, several of which, assayed by the TJ. S. Mint in 1858, weighed on the average 11.8 ounces Troy and were 0.966 fine, value $235.50. They were intended to represent ten taels (of gold) each, which would make the value of one tael at that date, $23.55.^ Gold leaf, thickness not stated, is said to have been used for money in China ; ^ but this use was probably merely local and temporary. Bullion Trade. — During the 250 years when plate-ships ■ went direct from Acapulco to Manila, it is stated that $400,000,000 of silver found its way thither, and that one- fourth of this sum was shipped from Manila to China. ^ From 1784 to about the year 1850 (date of Martin's work) $100,000,000 in silver were shipped from the United States to China. Siam and Cochin China were also accustomed to send large quantities of both gold and silver to China. During sixty years of free intercourse between Japan and China, there were shipped from the former to the latter country at least $100,000,000 in the precious metals. Prom all other sources during the past (eighteenth) cen- tury, China received over $50,000,000 in the pi-ecious metals.* At one time or another in the long history of this extra- ordinary country, either the importation or exportation, and sometimes both, of silver and the exportation of gold, have been prohibited. It is doubtful, however, how far ' Tooke's " Hist. Prices," vi. 680. ' United States "Finance Keport," 1868, p. 62. ' Martin's " China," i. 175. * Martin's " China," i. 176. 46 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. the government succeeded in practically enforcing these interdicts.^ Brick tea money. — Brick tea is a mixture of spoiled leaves and stalks of the tea plant, of leaves of wild plants and of bullocks^ , blood, dried in ovens. These substances being pressed together in the form of bricks receive the name of brick tea. It is manufactured in Southern China. The infusion made from it is mingled with rye meal, mutton fat, and salt, and this mess is used as an article of diet by the inhabitants near the frontier which separates China from the Eussian territory. Bach brick weighs from 3 to 3 5- pounds, and in the year 1851 they were worth about two Russian roubles each, and passed, in the neighbourhood where they were consumed, as money. Written promissory notes payable in brick tea were also employed for the purpose of money .^ Mines.— IvL 1838, a memorial addressed to the emperor stated that forty to fifty thousand workmen were employed in silver mining in certain specified districts of the empire ; and that the annual produce was "not far from two million taels of silver." ^ The same memorial adds that there are also other mines in the empire, not so rich as those named, but which probably produce more silver. Martin, writing a few years later, says, that the working of some of the silver mines is forbidden ; and that the others employ 20,000 workmen and yield $3,0®0,000 a year. Also that very little gold is obtained.'*' Randot says, that " some one has estimated the produce of the Chinese mines at 6000 kilograms of gold and 2,000,000 of silver." ° Otreskoff, writing in 1856, is " dis- posed to think that the present production of gold in ' Consult Postlethwayt's " Die. of Com.," art. " Gold." ^ " Chinese Repository," xx. 30. ' Dr. Williams, "Commercial Guide,'' ed. Hong Kong, 1863, p. 275. * Martin's " Hist. China," i. 177. For quicksilver, see Martin, i. 379. This metal is now obtained from California. ° Report of the United States Monetary Commission, i, 560. CHINA. 47 China is about £600,000 per annum, and of silver £180,000 per annum." ^ Baron Richtofen, writing in 1872, gives a graphic account of the impositions, robberies, and violence to which the miners are subjected, and declares that mining is impossible under such circumstances. The proceeds are divided into three parts, one for the emperor, one for the mandarins, and one for the owner, who rarely succeeds in getting his product to market. Mr. Seward says, that since 1872, the roads are more secure from highway I'obbers, and that it is possible that silver mining may have gained encouragement. Baron Richtofen says, that gold is produced in at least sixty-four departments distributed throughout fourteen pro- vinces and always at a loss. "The gold washers probably earn less than they can get for ordinary labour, and take to that occupation only when there is the least demand for field work. We can, therefore, safely assume, speaking generally, that the yield of gold is a measure of the poverty of the province." Mr. Kingsmill says essentially the same thing. ^ From these various evidences I have ventured to make the following rough estimate of the production of the pre- cious metals in China at the two periods named. 1838: workmen in silver mines 30,000, annual product of silver $3,000,000. 1856 : workmen in silver mines 10,000, annual product of silver $1,000,000. 1838 : workmen in gold washings 30,000, annual product in gold $3,000,000. The product in gold has since diminished. It will probably be safe to assume the production of the precious metals in China at the present time at about $5,000,000, one-half each of gold and silver. ^ Tooke's " Hist. Prices," vi. pp. 761-2. ^ Mr. Seward's communication. The latest information concerning the gold and silver mines of China is embodied in the following para- graph from "Lloyd's Newspaper " of June 1, 1884: — "The Empress of China has issued a decree ordering the Viceroy and Governor of Yunnan to start public companies, with a view to open all the mines in Yunnan to procure gold, silver, copper, &c." 48 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. I have now brought the Monetary History of China down to the present time. If it appears to have been treated too briefly^ my apology is the difficulty of condensing events, covering fifty-eight centuries of time, into the few pages to which I am limited for the purpose. These events are full of interest to the world; and it is my sincere hope that the course which I have herein so rapidly outlined, may prove sufficiently attractive for other scholars to more thoroughly and definitely trace. CHAPTBE-III. JAPAN. Ancient money — Earliest coins — Gold and Silver — Rice — Paper money — Copper zenni — Feudal period — Copper and Gold mines — Mining laws — Mints — Progressive period — Arrival of the Portuguese. THE historical period and era of Japan ^ commence with the year B.C. 660. Previous to that period its history is obscure. Some native writers are of opinion that the present inhabitants owe their origin to aboriginal Ainos; while others regard the Ainos as the degenerate survivors of an ancient race, which also gave birth to the Japanese, and whose history is lost. The curved and perforated pieces of soap-stone occa- sionally dug up in various parts of the country, and ascribed to a pre-historical period, may have been used as money,^ or not J it is difficult to determine. There is little about the appearance of the oldest known coins of Japan to sustain a conjecture that these soap-stone relics were money, unless it be the holes through the middle of them ; and as to drawing any inferences in this connection from the condition of society in the remote times to which the soap-stones belong, the Japanese themselves appear to place too little reliance upon the historical accounts of their own anti- quity, to warrant the act. The analogy between the perforations in these Japanese ' Known to the natives as Dai-nippou ; corrupted by the medieval Chinese into Shi-pen-kue ; written by Marco Polo as Zipan-gu or Jipan-gu, whence Japan. ^ See " The Mikado's ' Empire," by Griffis, New York, 1876, p. 53. E 50 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. soap-stones and in the copper coins of a later period on the one hand, and the clay scarabse of Egypt, whose peculiar design or shape was stamped upon the early coins of the neighbouring Greek colonies, on the other hand, is certainly worthy the study of antiquaries and archaeologists. It may lead to a corroboration of the view maintained by Japanese scholars, that there existed in Japan a pre-Aino civilization of a high order. ^ Our accounts of money in Japan begin with its earliest historical date. Mr. Titsingh, a Dutch author quoted by Malte-Brun, was said to have possessed a collection of Japanese coins which went back "as far as 600 years before Christ." ^ These coins, if genuine, and if there is no mistake as to the date, are probably all of copper ; for we hear of no gold or silver in Japanese history, either as money or otherwise, until the period of the invasion of Southern Corea, a.d. 203, from which country, it is stated, the Japanese conquerors returned home with " eighty ships well laden with gold, silver, articles of wealth, silk, and precious goods of all kinds." ^ With regard to the metal of which these coins are composed, it is worthy of remark that Mr. Titsingh says that some of the coins were " engraved," a fact that would seem to point to a more valuable metal than copper.* The much higher antiquity of money in China, the intimate relations between China and Corea, and the proximity of Corea to Japan, suggest the probability that money was introduced from the first into the last-named ^ Mr. Griffis, on the contrary, insinuates that the Ainos, some of whom still dwell in remote parts of the islands, were the aborigines, and preceded all civilization in Japan. ^ Titsingh is quoted as the author of " Verhandelingen Van het Bataviaasch genoostchap." Malte-Brun, ii. 61, Philadelphia edition, 1827. Sir Stamford Raffles, "Hist. Java," i. xxvii., mentions in the same connection a Mr. C. Tetsingh. ' Griffis, 78, 79. * Malte-Brun, ii. 59, quoting Titsingh, as cited by Charpentier- Cossigny in his " Voyage to Bengal." JAPAN. 51 country at an earlier period than the seventh century B.C., but the writer has met with no historical trace of such an occurrence. The next mention of money occurs in the fifth to the seventh centuries of the Christian era. In the fifth and sixth centuries the religion, laws, customs, and inventions of China were introduced into Japan, and it seems probable that among the latter were the kinsatsu, or small paper notes. They were emitted exclusively by the feudal lords or daimios.' Until a very recent period they were never issued by either the imperial or shogunatic governments.^ They were probably redeem- able,^ and if so, were redeemed in early times in rice. This grain was the standard of value in the eighth century, and probably earlier. It is stated that " silver was first presented to the emperor in a.d. 670." * It is difficult to reconcile this statement with the account of gold and silver captured in Corea, a.d. 203. Surely some of these spoils, if indeed not all of them, were delivered to the emperor. Whether we believe that gold or silver pieces were used as money at the time of the Corean invasion, or in the seventh century, or at neither time, but that instead, kinsatsu, representing either copper coins or rice, were used as money at these early dates, it sounds strangely to be informed that in the eighth century "rice was the standard '■ " For centuries past every great daimio has issued paper money current only in his han. There are over one hundred local varieties in the empire, of varied colours, values, and sizes." GrifSs, p. 425. ° Information communicated by the Japanese Consul at San Francisco. ^ " Nanou, Japan, Lat. 37.02 IS., Long. 136.58 E. August 17, 1866. At this place I first learned the fact that the princes issue, each in his own territory, paper money, taking the place of copper and silver. . . . This paper money is redeemed by the prince at his yaski (residence) in his own territory, or at Yeddo." B. B. Van Vlakenburg to the State Department of the United States. * Martin's "History of China," chapter on Japan, vol. i. p. 291. 52 HISTOEY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. of value and all taxes were paid in this grain," and that " the treasury consisted of imperial store-houses and granaries, as money was not then in general use." ^ Grain of any kind is greatly inferior as money to either metal or paper. Why, then, should a nation which had once learnt to employ the latter, return to the former ? One answer is : irregular supplies of metal and danger (from counterfeits) of using paper ; but this is not proYod. Another answer is : that during the interval between the ancient times, when metallic money was exclusively employed in Japan, and the mediaeval times, when rice formed some part^ or else the basis for some part, of the currency, the empire sustained a decline of peace, security, and civilization, such as that which befell Europe at about the same period, and that corn-rents in Japan — for, except as to the extent that it was represented by paper-kinsatsu, corn-money seems to have been used only in the payment of agricultural rents — - corn-rents in Japan are explicable upon precisely the same grounds as corn-rents in medieeval Europe.'^ A review of the history of money in Japan from the earliest times to the eighth century of our era leads to the following conclusions : — It is possible that money formed of perforated pieces of soap-stone was employed at a very remote period, and previous to the era of the Ainos. At the beginning of the historical period, viz., in the seventh century B.C., metallic discs were employed. In the third century a.d. it seems probable that metallic discs were in use, and that at this date, if not earlier, some of them were of gold and silver. In the fifth and sixth centuries a.d. the use of small paper notes emitted by the feudal lords, and, at first, probably redeemable in rice, was introduced from China. GrifSs, p. 104. Agricultural incomes bave for centuries past been reckoned in rice ; indeed, they are still reckoned in it. " See, on this subject, Adam Smith on Corn-Rents in England, and Hodgskin's " Travels," ii. 84, on Corn-Rents in Germany. JAFAS. 53 In the eighth century a.d. corn (rice) rents became common, and rice appears to have been the standard of value in the limited class of large transactions which the times permitted. This currency was probably supplemented by local kinsatsu and copper zenni for small change, the kinsatsu being probably redeemable in rice, and the copper zenni receivable only in retail transactions and at some fixed ratio to rice. . The period under review — particularly the last five centuries thereof — seems to have been one of political and social decay. Among the marks and consequences of this decadence were the interruption of commerce with sur- rounding countries,^ the practical overthrow of the imperial government, the destruction of inland commerce from civil war and insecurity, the prostration of credit, the era of feudalism, the emission of kinsatsu by the feudal lords, who at first liquidated them in rice, but afterwards over-issued and failed to redeem them, and paid their debts in this depreciating paper, while they collected their rents in grain. Although some of these indications of decay are traceable so late as the eighth century, a contrary movement seems to have begun at an earlier period. Commerce was opened with China in the fifth and sixth centuries, ^nd in the seventh, the central government of Japan resumed its authority,^ and the progress of feudalism was arrested. With these changes commenced another phase in the history of money in Japan. During the period a.d. 708-715, copper mines were dis- covered.^ In A.D. 749, gold mines were opened.* The copper obtained from Suruga is said to have contained a considerable admixture of gold, a fact which, in the early days of their intercourse with Europeans, was probably not ' " And the stoppage of those supplies of copper from which the circulating zenni had theretofore been fabricated." Martin, i. 291. ' Griffis, p. 94. ' Griffis, 111. * Ten years before this, to wit, in a.d. 739, a colossal copper figure of Buddha, fifty-three feet high and covered with gilt, was set up in a Japanese shrine. As to date of opening gold mines, see Martin, i. 291. 54 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. known to the Japanese, and of little value to them after it was known, for until quite recently they do not appear to have been acquainted with the art of separating these metals economically.^ These facts will perhaps account for the eagerness of the Dutch to obtain Japanese copper, and for the enormous quantities of this metal which they exported to Holland. The mediaeval Japanese mining laws concerning copper are not known. Of the gold produced, two-thirds were claimed as his proportion by the emperor, and only one- third allowed to the proprietor of the land,^ who, in all cases, was the lord of the feud. The actual miner, a serf or villein belonging to the soil, probably received a mere pittance of rice for his labour. No mine could be opened without express permission of the emperor, and there was a prohibition against digging beyond a certain depth.^ In recent times these rules have been greatly modified.* The first mints, we are informed, were established in 1588, forty and odd years after the arrival of the Portuguese.^ This statement appears to need qualification; for, if the account concerning Mr. Titsingh is to be credited, metallic moneys were fabricated in Japan 600 years before Christ, and, according to other evidence, copper zenni of native fabrication were common, though not plentiful, when the Portuguese arrived. Previous to 1588, the only metallic moneys fabricated were the zenni, and some rude gold and silver pieces ; the former having been cast, and the latter ^ Martin, i. 289, and Galownin, p. 165. " Malte-Brun, iL 53, and Martin, i. 288. ' Malte-Brun, ii. 53, and Martin, i. 289. The former asserts the reason for this rule to have been the desire to steady the value of the metal by regulating its production — a policy not without wisdom in a small and isolated country. The latter asserts the reason to have been the fear that the mines would be too soon exhausted. * The existing mining laws of Japan are set forth in Mr. F. R. Plunkett's Report to Sir Harry Parkes, 1876, and summarized in Griffis, 602. ' Martin, i. 292, and Griffis, 286. JAPAN. 55 hammered. The meaning of the statement quoted from Martin and Griffis may therefore be^ that in 1588 the first coining presses were introduced, and that moneys of gold and silver were first made in considerable quantities, and after some regular system of size, weight, fineness, and designs. Or it may mean that in 1588, metallic moneys were first systematically or exclusively made by authority of the shogunate ; those of a previous date having been fabricated chiefly by the daimios.^ From the seventh to the twelfth centuries of our era, the money of Japan appears to have consisted of rice, supple- mented by copper moneys of provincial, or yet more local, fabrication. There are no evidences of paper money during this period ; although, as its history is somewhat obscure, it is not impossible that such money may have been employed. Feudalism was still the characteristic condition of society, but the feudal system was passing away ; at least, it was not gaining ground. The physical resources of the country appear to have increased during the first part of this era and during the last to have diminished. From the twelfth century dates the usurpation of the shogun and the establishment of the shogunate as the prac- tical government of Japan. Feudalism was now again repressed — this time with greater energy than before. The daimios were compelled to personally reside at the seat of the shogunate ; the mikado, though respected as the supreme power, was secluded and deprived of all substan- tial part in the afiairs of the empire ; and the usurper exer- cised many centralized functions, and in after years con- ducted all transactions with foreigners and foreign govern- ments. During the four centuries from the establishment of the shogunate to the arrival of the Portuguese, the money of Japan differed from what it had been during the previous five centuries. Generally speaking, it consisted chiefly of ^ " Japan as it Was and Is," by Richard HUdreth, Boston, 1856, p. 200, n., and " Universal History," vol. ix. p. 708. 56 HISTORY OF MONET IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. rice with copper moneys for small change. These may have been supplemented by rude pieces of gold and silver moneyj and kinsatsu.^ I have not been able to determine whether the copper or other metallic moneys (if any) which circulated during this period were emitted by the shogun or by the feudal lords. Probability points to the former. This brings the history of money in Japan down to the opening of intercourse with the Portuguese in 1542; an event that has at length had the result of bringing Japan within the family of Modern nations ; while the same events operating upon a different state of affairs in the other countries of Asia, has left them where it found them, be- longing to the Ancient world. ' In Japan paper money was emitted from 1319 to 1331 under the dairi Go Daigo No tenoo. It remained in circvilation for sixty or seventy years. " Chinese Repository," vol. xx. pp. 289-295. CHAPTER IV. INDIAj PEIOE TO ALEXANDEE THE GEEAT. India never united under one government : hence difficult to de- scribe its monetary systems comprehensively — These systems include several instructive experiments, particularly those of Mahomed bin Tuglah, in the fourteenth century of our era — Antiquity of money in India — As ancient as in China — Proofs : from populousness and phase of civilization ; from Code of Manou ; from the Vedic writings ; from the Buddhic writings ; from numismatic remains ; from language — Supply of coining metals from the mines, and from foreign commerce — Stan- dard of money at various eras : the copper standard ; the clay standard ; the copper standard again — Silver money not permanently employed until A.D. 1793 ; nor paper money, permanently, until during the pre- sent century — Ratios of value between gold and silver, between silver and copper — Keview — Historical eras of India marked by foreign inva- sions — Sesostris — Darius — Alexander — Seleucus — Embassy of Megas- thenes — Invasion of Antiochus — Mahomedan conquest. LTNLIKB China, India has never been united by one / government ; hence an attempt to describe its nume- rous and varied monetary systems under a single view runs risk of becoming misleading. Notwithstanding the objec- tion to such a course, the paucity of historical materials compels it to be pursued until the period of the Maho- medan conquest, when a consideration of the subject under the three great natural divisions of north-western, north- eastern, and southern India becomes feasible. To describe a series of monetary systems extending back- ward for, perhaps, fifty centuries, would appear an idle task in a work which, like the present one, aims to be of prac- tical utility, did not such a retrospect serve to prepare the mind to understand and derive instruction from the more modern systems of the series, among which are the very 58 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. interesting experiments of Mahomed bin Tuglahj a mone- tary reformer of the fourteenth century of our era. The antiquity of money in India appears to be as great as in China^ and is susceptible of being traced backward to about thirty centuries before Christ. The proofs of this great antiquity are derived from various sourceSj each of which will be examined in due order. These sources are : (1) The most ancient accounts of the population and con- dition of society in India ; (2) The Code of Manou ; (3) The Vedic writings ; (4) The Buddhic writings ; (5) Nu- mismatic and other archffiological remains; (6) Comparative philology. 1. Accounts of the 'population and society of ancient India. — It is generally conceded by those who have made a study of the subject, that the race who now form the bulk of the Sudra, or lowest class of persons in India, were very anciently a numerous people, who had " attained to a high condition of civilization, so as to form large communities, to establish kingdoms, and, besides cultivating the soil, to carry on extensive commerce ; " ^ that the Hindoos entered India from a foreign country, and having possessed themselves of the soil, they reduced the Sudra, or aboriginal inhabitants, to serfdom ; that they brought with them the Sanscrit lan- guage ; and that all this happened more than three thou- sand, and possibly more than four thousand five hundred years ago. At later, though still very ancient periods, the populousness and commercial phase of India are proved by Manou, by the Vedic writings, by the Indian remains found in Egyptian tombs of the fifteenth century Bic, and, lastly, by Herodotus.^ A people may exist in the pastoral state without the use of money ; it may enter upon the agricultural phase of social ' " The Land of the Veda," by Rev. Peter Percival, London, 1854, p. 31. ' Lieut.-Gen. Briggs, F.R.S., as quoted in Percival, pp. 29-32. ^ See extracts from the Code of Manou further on in the text ; Wilkinson's " Ancient Egyptians ; " Herodotus, lib. iii. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 59 existence before the necessity of employing money becomes overpowering ; but when, as in the present case, the agri- cultural phase has continued so long that manufactures and foreign commerce have begun to develop themselves, it is ventured to be assumed that no large society could long hold together without the agency of money,^ and therefore, that such a society which did hold together, must, of necessity, have employed money of some sort ; not merely commo- dities used in voluntary barter, but money, that is to say, either commodities, symbols, or numeraries, stamped by public authority, and used as the common means of pay- ment and legal or customary expression of price. That India, at the time it was invaded by the Hindoos, contained a population sufficiently dense and civilized to require the use of money, there can be but little doubt, and, upon the strength of the implication which these facts convey, it is regarded as quite safe to date back the use of money in this country to, at least, the period of that event. 2. The Code of Manou. — Amongst the most ancient lite- rary monuments of India are the civil and religious institutes commonly known as the Code of Manou. The age ascribed to this work — varying usually with the cosmogonal belief of the commentator — is from the sixteenth to the ninth century B.C., the former being the view of Mr. Colebrooke, and the latter that of Sir William Jones and Mr. H. H. Wilson.'' As a mean between these discordant opinions it has been decided to adopt the view of M. Vivien de Ste. Martin, who, after a very careful consideration of the subject, has ' "Society implies exchange, and exchange, money." F. Bastiat, "Har- monies of Polit. Econ." This is certainly the case when society, as in India at the period referred to, is not only exceedingly numerous, but advanced in civilization beyond the early agricultural into the manu- facturing and commercial phase. " Messrs. Max Miiller and Cowell hold very extreme views on this subject. See Marsden's " Numismata Orientalia," edited by Edward Thomas, London, 1874, p. 5. It is to be remarked that, in the title of the edition of this work published in 1876 the word " Marsden " is replaced by " International." 60 HISTORY OF MONET IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. assigned the era of the extant Code of Manou — not that of Manou himself — to the twelfth or thirteenth century B.c.^ Like all civil and most religious codeSj this one has evi- dently undergone modification, and part of this modification may possibly be traced down to so late a date as that assigned to the entire code by Max Miiller. Among the unmodified, or at least most ancient portions, would however seem to be included all those to which are prefixed such phrases as, " This law was enacted by Manou," chapter viii. section 139 ; " I will next propound the established law concerning assault and battery," viii. 278 ; " The names of copper, silver, and gold weights which are commonly used among men," viii. 131, &c." That the equivalents alluded to in the last paragraph were handed down from a higher antiquity than that of the extant code appears to be also implied in the fact that while the order of importance in the paragraph is, 1st, copper, 2nd, silver, and 3rd, gold, in the table which follows it is Ist, silver, 2nd, gold, 3rd, copper. This bespeaks re- arrangement of some previous table. ^ What is far more certain, however, is that the table relates to moneys as well as weights. Omitting the first portion of this table, which relates to minute equivalents of mustard seeds and barley corns, and adapting Marsden^s English equivalents, determined after the studies of several distinguished metrologists, the table stands as follows : * — ^ " Clironicles of the Pathan Kings of Delhi," by Edward Thomas. London, Triibner, 1871, 8vo. p. 168. ^ "The Code of Manou," trans, by Sir Wm. Jones, ed. by G. C. liaughton, London, 1825. ^ Marsden holds that alteration in the Code is implied in the use of two discordant systems of enumeration in the table of weights and moneys, viz., the binary and decimal. There is no doubt that the Code has • undergone many changes ; but this particular reason for thinking so is far from being conclusive. It is possible that the binary and decimal systems were used simultaneously ; and if not, it is probable the change was made long before the era of the Code now extant. * Marsden's "Numis. Orient.," p. 13. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 61 Code of Manou. Silver Weights, or Coins. English gi-ai: 1 Rati 1.75 2 Rati = 1 Mashaka .... 3.50 32 Rati = 1 Dharana (from dhri, to hold), or 1 Purana (purana, old) 56.00 320 Rati = 1 Satamana .... . 560.00 Gold Weights, or Coins. 5 Rati= ] Masha' .... 8.75 80 Rati = 1 Suvarna .... 140.00 320 Rati = 1 Pala or Nishka . . 560.00 3200 Rati = 1 Dharana .... . 5600.00 Copper Weights, or Coins. 80 Rati := 1 Karshapana .... 140.00 Elsewhere in the Code of Manou there are references to the precious metals, that is to say, gold, silver, and copper, which point to a higher estimation of them than of mere commodities. The italics in the following examples do not appear in the original text : — " Of old hoards and precious minerals in the earth, the king is entitled to half, by reason of his general protection and because he is lord paramount of the soil," viii. 39. " From a junction (combined use ?) of water and fire, arose gold and silver," v. 113. Of a witness it says : " By speaking falsely in a cause concerning gold, he kills the born and the unborn^' — an ex- treme anathema, viii. 99. " Let the judge cause ... a merchant to swear by his cattle, grain, and gold," viii. 113. Other classes of persons are to swear by other characteristic or important objects. " Day by day must the king, though engaged in forensic ^ Silver mdshas are alluded to in the Code, viii. 298 ; " a mdsha of gold," in viii. 319; and a plant called a mdsha, in ix. 39. Wilkinson translates the Egyptian word masha as weights or balances, and mer masha as superintendent of weights or balances. See his "Ancient Egyptians," Scribner's Am. Ed. i. 285. 62 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. business, consider the great objects of public measures, and enquire into the state of his . . . mines of precious metals, &c. viii. 419. The precious metals are meant, of course, to include copper. " Eobbing the gold of a priest," ix. 235, and stealing " sacred gold," ix. 237, are classed with the highest crimes. A similar solicitude and high regard for sacred gold occurs in chapter viii. and elsewhere. The words which follow the quoted clauses in chapter ix., namely, " Such is the ordi- nance of Manou," seem to indicate that, whatever may be the date of the Code which has come down to us, gold was held to be " sacred " so far back as the time of Manou him- self. " Debasers of metals " are classed with rogues, ix. 258. " The most pernicious of all deceivers is a goldsmith who commits frauds ; the king shall order him to be cut piece- meal with razors," ix. 292. We now come to plainer implications of, and allusions to, money. " If he speak falsely, through covetousness, he shall be fined a thousand panas," viii. 120. As no reference is here made to gold, silver, copper, clay, wood, or any other sub- stance of which these panas may have been composed, the fact was probably of no importance, and this could only have been the case when the panas were money .^ The prices of commodities are to be fixed by the king, viii. 402. This clause not only implies the use of money, but also that the whole sum of money in use, as related to the number of exchanges to be effected by it, had ^ The word " money " occurs in many places in tlie English trans- lation of the Code, e.g. viii. 212, 213, &c. This word in any document older than the dedication of the temple of Juno Moneta as a mint in the city of Rome is an anachronism, although an unavoidable one, because in English there is no other well-known term for nummvx, '' numerary " being too technical. For the reason that '' money " in the Code of Manou is an anachronism, and is not warranted by the original Sanscrit text, no attention has herein been paid to its appear- ance in the translation. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 63 undergone, or was subject to violent or injurious fluctua-_ tions. There could have been no other reason for the enact- ment of such a law. " Usurers " are mentioned in viii. 102, and a tax of 5 per cent, on the profits of sales, in viii. 398 — both of which pas- sages are regarded as implying the use of money. The law of usury or interest is set forth at some length in viii. 140, and in the section which follows it. Alluding to the very proper regulation that the scale is " in propor- tion to the risk," the rates are fixed as follows : — on pledges, 1^ per cent, a month; without pledges or security, 2 per cent. ; from a priest, 2 per cent. ; a soldier, 3 per cent. ; a merchant, 4 per cent. ; and a mechanic or servile man, 5 per cent. Compound interest is forbidden altogether, viii. 245. While it is true that usury or interest may be a payment in commodities for the loan of other commodities, yet it is held that, where the usurious transactions are so numerous as to call for the use of a refined scale of payments like the above one, and a scale wherein no provision is made for the dete- rioration of the things loaned, they relate not to commodities, but to money. The employment of pledges also indicates the use of money. Whatever doubt there may be on the subject will certainly be dissipated by a subsequent para- graph of the same chapter, which reads as follows : — " Interest on money must never be more than enough to double the debt ; " on grain, fruit, wool, animals, or other things in kind (translated "same kind"), "it must never be more than enough to make the debt quintuple." ^ Whilst in making this distinction between a just rate of interest on money and on commodities Manou commits an error of principle which is not to be passed unnoticed, it is held that this passage conclusively establishes the inference that, when the extant Code was written, money was, and had been for a long time, in use in India. ' This law is repeated in the " Damathat," a commentary on the Code of Manou (" Damathat," Eng. trans, p. 88). There was a similar law in Pharaonic Egypt (Rawlinson's "Herodotus," ii. 136k.). 64 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. 3. The Vedic writings. — These scriptures have been as- signed to so remote a period as the thirty- second century B.c.'^ With more moderation they are attributed by Ste. Martin to about the year 1200 b.c.^ In the Eig Veda Sanhita^ 4th ashtaka, 7th adhyaya, sukta xlvii. verse 22, an allusion is made to purses of gold. In verse 23^ purses and lumps of gold are mentioned in a connection that appears to indicate money. Marsden, p. 33, supposes that the passage refers to stamped lumps of the value of a suvarna. In another part of the Vedas^ allusion is made to dindra,^ a name long used in India for that of a coin or sum of money. Prom India it made its way to Persia and Arabia as the dinar, and to Rome as the de- narius. From the denarius it became corrupted into the denny and penny, for which coin or sum of money its original initial letter^ d, is still in use in England. The Sutras of Panini, a Vedic work which is assigned to a period ranging from the twelfth to the sixth century B.C., speaks very distinctly of coined money, and derives rupya from rupa, i.e. struck, or coined. It is from this word that the modern rupee is derived.* The Mahdbhdrata, sometimes called the Fifth Veda, is an epic composition whose subject is a great war that occurred about B.C. 1400. The date of the poem itself is not deter- mined, but it is beyond all doubt earlier than the fifth cen- tury B.C. It makes frequent and unmistakable mention of money.^ 4. The Buddhic writings. — The next allusions to money in Indian literature occur in the institutes of Buddha. The age of these scriptures is variously ascribed to periods be- tween the eleventh and sixth centuries B.C. The weight of evidence, however, is in favour of the more modern date. ' Dow's " Peristah," p. xxvii. ^ Marsden, " Numis. Orient.," p. 5. ^ Marsden, " Numis. Orient.,'' pp. 34, 35. ■' Marsden, "Numis. Orient.," p. 39; Sutra, v. 2, 119. ' Some of the passages appear in Marsden's " Numis. Orient." INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 65 The Sramanas contain an ordinance forbidding the touching of gold or silver/ Whether this singular inter- dict is to be attributed to an observed immoral influence exercised by mining for the precious metals, or was part of a system of clay or copper moneys, the integrity of which demanded the prohibition of all other moneys or materials out of which moneys might be made, or whether it had some other origin or object, is not to be gathered from the account of it before us. Mr. Ball recently noticed that, in Laddak, in the Punjab, the Buddhists, not daring to search for gold, had abandoned the industry to certain Mahomedans from Bali, and, evidently unaware of the interdict in the Sramanas, he ascribes the avoidance of gold mining to a desire not to neglect agriculture.^ The Buddhist scriptures, in other places, are full of allu- sions to moneys and coins, many of which allusions have been collected together by M. Burnouf.' A commentary on the Vinaya, which (the commentary) is supposed to have been written about the fifth century of our era, mentions gold, silver, copper, wooden, and lacquer moneys, the latter being of lac or resin with a figure stamped upon them ; but, aside from its allusion to these singular moneys, the passage is assigned to too recent a date to have any bearing upon the present inquiry.* 5. Numismatic Remains. — Modern archaeological dis- covery and research have done much to elucidate the early history of money in India. The credit of the former be- longs chiefly to Englishmen ; of the latter, to the French and Germans.^ ' Del Mar's "Hist. Free. Met.," p. 345. ^ V. Ball, " Geological Survey of India,'' part iii., on Econ. Geol. London, 1881, p. 213 ; and Cunningham's " Laddak," p. 232. ' B'urnouf, " Introduction k I'Histoire de Bouddhisme," Paris, 1844, pp. 91, 102, 103, 146, 147, 236, 238, 243, 245,258 k, 329 n, 597. '' Marsden, " Numis. Orient.," p. 42. ' "In England the medals (coins) of the East have never been thought worthy of attention. . . . We must seek for information in Continental rather than English publications." Wilson's " Ariana An- F 66 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. Numbers of ancient Indian coins have been unearthed m various parts of the country, chiefly, however, in Bactria, the Punjab, and generally the more northern regions ; few having been found below AUabahad.^ By far the greatest number of those found in north-western India were of stamped copper, although many were of gold, silver, billon, plated copper,^ bronze, brass, cast copper, nickel, tin, and even lead. In Bengal the principal money finds have been of cowries, the metallic moneys being comparatively few. Some of the coins in these various finds belong to an archaic period, one that must have antedated any of the foreign invasions of India. This inference rests upon the rude and unconventional forms and types which the coins present, and upon the absence of symbols belonging to any known political or religious system. Upon first seeing the Behat coins,' the learned Prinsep cautiously ascribed them to the early part of the Christian era ; * but a closer study induced him to attribute them, without reserve, to a period anterior at least to the Greek invasion of the fourth cen- tury B.c.^ They are entirely independent of the Greek type of coins, and undoubtedly preceded them.'' Still later on, tiqua,'' p. 27. The principal English contributors to Oriental numis- matics are Masson, Prinsep, Maj . Cunningham, Gen. Ventura, Col. Stacey, Col. Tod, Marsden, Wilson, and Thomas. ^ Marsden, " Numis. Orient.," p. 37. ^ Plated copper coins of Indo-Soythic kings of the second and first centuries b.o. " Essays on Indian Antiquities of the late James Prinsep," edited by Edward Thomas. London, Murray, 1858, Svo. ii. 89, 214. ' Pound by Capt. Cautley, in 1833, near Behat, the ancient capital of a district extending down the Doab of the Ganges and Jumna below Hastinapura, and westward along the last-named river, and along the foot of the Himalayas to the Punjab. The coins were of silver and copper, chiefly the former, and belonged to periods beginning with the most ancient archaic time, and ending with that of Buddhism. Con- sult Prinsep's " Essays," i. 204, and Wilson's " Ariana Antiq.," pp. 16, 20. * Prinsep's " Essays," i. 202. ' Ibid. pp. 208, 209. ' Marsden, " Numis. Orient.," pp. 35, 36, 43. INDIA, PEIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 67 Prinsep says : " We may infer that at or about the era of Manou, the Hindoos were already in possession of such a scheme of exchange as recognized the use of fixed and de- terminate weights of metal, not only as general equivalents and measures of value, but further, that the system had already advanced so far as to adopt small and convenient sections of metal into the category of current money ; and that the punch-marked pieces may be taken to exemplify the first germs of improved commercial and fiscal aptitude expressed by the transitional movement from normal weights to absolute coins." The view herein assumed by Prinsep, that these coins were the earliest moneys of India, may or may not be correct ; it does not afiect his arguments that they were ante-Grecian, and that they were also ante- Vedic. Says Thomas : " They were the produce of purely home fancies and local thought, and have no reference to either the Veda, the doctrines of Buddha, or any other religious or political belief or tradition." ^ Says Wilson : " They extend downward from the most ancient period, until that one which immediately preceded Buddhism." ' Says Marsden : " We can produce flat pieces of metal, some round, some square or oblong, adjusted with con- siderable accuracy to a fixed weight, and usually of uniform metallic purity, verified and stamped anew with distinctive symbols by succeeding generations, which clearly constituted an efiective currency long before the ultimate date of the engrossment of the Institutes (Code) of Manou." ' A large hoard of this class of coins, supposed to have belonged to the remote Pandu race (a sort of Indian Druids), was found in 1807 in Coimbatore.* From a careful study of the types of the archaic coins of ^ Thomas, in Marsden, pp. 58, 59. ' Wilson's " Ariana Antiq." pp. 16, 20. ' Marsden, p. 52. * Walter Elliott, "Madras Jour, of Lit. and Science," 1858, p. 227. 68 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. India, from observations based upon the respective methods of coining these coins and those of the western world, and from the fact that the finds of Grseco-Bactrian coins always included some of these dissimilar, and evidently older coins, it was concluded by Marsden that the various steps of the art of coinage in India, both as to stamping and casting, ''must have been effected before the advent of the Greeks." ^ Thus much with respect to the numismatic evidences of the antiquity of money in India. With regard to the indi- cations afforded by the relative numbers of coins found of copper, silver, and gold, no safe dependence can be placed upon them. It is well known that where copper coins will corrode and disappear from the action of the elements, silver, and especially gold ones, will survive. Moreover, as it does not appear that either silver or gold coins were ever used as money in India until very recent times, but only as adjuncts to or multipliers for the copper coins, it follows that the silver and gold coins were overvalued, and there- fore that it did not pay to melt them down ; whilst, on the other hand, whenever, indeed, the copper coins themselves were not overvalued — as against commodities, which might have been done by means of limiting their emission, or by an arbitrary regulation of prices — they were worth as much in the melting-pot as in the form of money, and immense numbers of them were doubtless melted from time to time.^ 6. Comparative philology. — From this source are obtained still further proofs of the antiquity of money in India. Among the archaic coins found at Behat, only one pos- sesses what appears to be alphabetical characters, and these resemble the Lat, or most ancient form of Sanscrit.^ In allusion to the term kasu, corruptly cash, meaning coins, or coined or cast money, it is stated that the study of ^ Marsden, p. 55. An instance of this sort (the melting of copper coins) is supplied by Tavernier, and relates to Persia, a.d. 1664. Marsden, p. 53. ^ Prinsep, i. 210. <^ INDIA, PKIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 69 Dravidian roots in the existing Tamil language tends to " prove that coined money was in use at the period of the compilation of the text of India's earliest lawgiver." This carries it back to the period of the oldest Veda, and it may- have been in use ages before.^ The occurrence of the word dinwr in both the Vedas and Buddha is another proof of the same character.^ We can now advantageously survey the evidences of the antiquity of money in India. They are derived from so many independent sources, and some of them are so strong, that it will be diflB.cult to successfully impugn their validity. They certainly prove the use of money, nay, of coined money, in India, long before the date assigned to it in Asia Minor (Lydia) , a date which, by the way, rests solely upon the testimony of Herodotus, and the conjecture — perhaps well enough founded — that certain unlettered coins dis- covered in Lydia and Greece are those to which the Greek historian refers. That the Lydians and Greeks coined money at the date assigned to them is not what is doubted herein, but that they coined the first moneys known to man. This is an assumption which, in the face of Chinese and Indian history and archeology, should no longer be ac- corded a footing.^ It not only shuts out all the ancient history of money, it asks us to believe that the earliest ^ Marsden, p. 22; also see note 2, p. 77 of the present work, on Kdrshapana, or Kaliapanu. - Marsden, pp. 84, 35. ' Yet this is one of the most recent authoritative opinions on the subject. Says Mommsen : " From all that is to be gathered from the remains of antiquity, both historical and traditional, it is established beyond a doubt that money was first made in Asia Minor, and that the first moneys were of gold The most ancient moneys [moniiaies) are incontestably the staters of Phocee, of Cyzique, and of Cresus." " Histoire de la Monnaie Romaine," par Theodore Mommsen, traduite de FAllemand par le due de Blacas. Paris, Feuardent, 1865, 3 vols. 8vo. vol. i. p. 1. It is needless to say that this sweeping assertion is over- whelmingly contradicted both by oriental literature, philology, and numismatics. Lenormant blindly follows Mommsen, and with much more heat than becomes a numismatist. 70 HISTORY or MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. moneys were of gold, and that their value was regulated by the cost of producing this metal^ both of which assumptions are quite erroneous. Supply of coining metals froyn the mines. — From Mr. Ball's able survey of the economical geology of India it is quite clear that, although indications of gold are to be found all over the country, from Thibet to Malabar, yet that the placer deposits were exhausted at a very early period — probably before that of the Vedic writings — except of what little gold the freshets brought down each year into the river valleys, always an insignificant supply. The gold quartz deposits, if not naturally shallow, which is usually the case,^ were not capable of being worked by the natives to more than a superficial depth. ^ The silver deposits were few and inaccessible to all except the inhabitants of the extreme northern regions.^ The copper deposits of India were more ample and more widely diffused ; yet copper was always scarce in Bengal, and difficult to obtain in the Dekkan : facts which were due to the infrequency of the deposits, to the political disunity of the country, and to the bad state of the roads. ^ The author is prepared to assert, after a lifetime of study and practice as a miner, and after having personally inspected nearly every important auriferous region of the world, that it contains but few gold quartz districts which have paid to work at a depth exceeding 300 or 400 feet. ^ The ancient East Indians worked their quartz mines down from 50 to 70 feet, in some instances 100 feet, and in a very few 150 feet. In recently found excavations exceeding this depth, the excess was the work of their successors, the Mahomedans. Allusion is made to ancient gold mines in the ranges of the Hindoo Koosh, Belur Tagh, and Altai, by Heeren, in his " Asiatic Nations, i. 47. ^ Sir Roderick Murchison had previously alluded much more favour- ably to the argentiferous resources of India, especially to the "wealth" of the Kulu Valley of the Vasour country, between the Beas, Sainji, and Parbutti rivers, and of the Manikaru mines ; but Mr. Ball's opinion on the subject is entitled to the most weight. An old silver mine was found at Perwan, lat. 35.9, long. 69.16, near the Hindoo Koosh. Others are mentioned by Ouseley, p. 225 ; in Erskine's " Baber," pp. 139, 146 ; and byMasson, iii. 166. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 71 Supply of coining metals from foreign commerce. — It has been conjectured by at least one antiquarian that in very remote times commercial intercourse existed between India and the silver-producing countries of America/ Without assenting to an opinion so little susceptible of convincing proof, it is tolerably well settled that commercial intercourse prevailed between India and the silver-producing countries of Europe. Evidences exist of Indian trade with Egypt fifteen centuries b.c. ; ^ with Babylon and Phoenicia, and therefore with Greece and Spain, previous to the seventh century B.C. ; ^ and with all these countries, by way of Pal- myra, at a later, though still very ancient date.* By all these channels of commerce silver was transported from Greece and Spain to India, although in what quantity cannot now even be estimated. In the time of Pliny, the annual shipments of silver to India and China were given at a sum which modern commentators have computed as equal to about three hundred thousand ounces.* Assuming this computation to be correct, and that two-thirds of the silver was destined for India, it yet remains too insignificant in amount to have been of ajry practical assistance towards the maintenance of a system of silver money in any con- siderable portion of India. In the very much more ^ Such is the opinion of Mr. Treadwell, of Brooklyn, New York, an antiquarian who has devoted many years to the study of this subject. ^ Wilkinson's " Ancient Egyptians," ii. 237. " Yeat's " History of Commerce," p. 25. At that period Greece and Spain possessed the only considerable silver mines in the world. * Robertson's " India." " Pliny, " Nat. Hist." xii. 18 : " Minimique computatione millis centena millia sestertium annis omnibus. India et Seres, peninsulaque ilia (Arabia) imperis nostro adimunt. Tanto nobis delicise et feminse constant." This sum has been variously translated at from ^£70,000 to £800,000. As this equivalent depends upon the value of the numerical sestercium, in metal coins, at a given time, and as both of these factors are undeterminable, the translation is purely chimerical. On this subject, consult Del Mar's " History of the Precious Met.," p. 191. Many of the silver coins exported to India were filled in with iron or lead. Lenormant, "La Monnaie," i. 234. 72 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. ancient period under review the shipments of silver to India must have been even less than they were in the time of Pliny. After all conceivable sources of supply^ both domestic and foreign, are considered, there does not appear to have been enough, either of silver or gold, obtainable in India after the period of the Hindoo invasion to have maintained a system of money composed of these metals at cost of production ; and it must be admitted that no such system could have pre- vailed throughout any considerable portion of the country. Standard of money in India. — Taking together the various evidences before us, it would appear most likely that the earliest money of India was made of copper. Of this money no traces now remain, except such as are to be found in the archaic languages and literature of the country. The fitful and uncontrollable supplies of copper from the mines, and the difficulties of transport, must however have soon caused it to be abandoned for use as money, and to be sup- planted by some other substance more amenable to control. Before this took place it could hardly fail to have been per- ceived that the number of pieces, rather than the quantity of material in them, was what affected prices, and no doubt many unsuccessful experiments were made with the view of enabling light coins to do the work of heavy ones — unsuccessful, because coins are easily, and at that period were sure to be, counterfeited. The fixing of prices enjoined in Manou, viii. 402, is a proof of such an experi- ment. But even after the adoption of mint monopoly and overvalued copper coins (an expedient which every nation of antiquity has tried at least once), the supplies of copper metal must have been too irregular for a permanent govern- ment to endure, and this must have compelled all such governments to have recourse to some other material for money. The material out of which money or monetary symbols can safely be made — no matter in what age or country — must combine the following essential qualities : — INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 73 1. Abimdance. — -It must be sufficiently abundant to enable a suitable number of pieces to be made from it. 2. Certainty of Supply. — The supply must be regular, and not subject to interruption from the chances of mining discovery, from private monopoly, the seasons, the condi- tions of transport, nor the vicissitudes of war. 3. Divisibility. — It must be readily divisible into small pieces of uniform size and appearance. 4. Plasticity. — It must be sufficiently plastic or impres- sible for the pieces to take suitable marks of authority certifying their legitimacy. 5. Durability. — It must be capable of standing a consi- derable amount of wear and tear. In archaic periods no substance combined these qualities so well as clay, and it is, accordingly, of this substance that all of the earlier moneys of any extended or permanent use were made. As it may be difficult for those whose reading has taught them the easy creed that money has always been made of gold, silver, or copper, to believe that populous and civilized countries have ever entirely dispensed with these metals and employed far different materials to embody money, it is deemed essential in this place to adduce those authorities upon the analogy to be derived from whose testimony this assertion is made. Says Du Halde : " It is related that after the reign of Han (B.C. 21 19), a prince caused money to be made of stamped earth united with a strong glue, and, taking it into his head to put down copper money, he gathered as much as he could, buried it very deep in the earth, and killed the workmen who were employed about it, that none might know where it was hidden." ^ Says Humphreys : " It will be at once obvious that some other species of money preceded the use of coins." Stieglitz says that the most ancient moneys of the ' Du Halde's " Hist. China," ii. 288. ^ Noel Humphreys' " Ancient Coins," p. 15. 74 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. western world were scarabse of clay or stone. ^ In this opinion he is supported by S. Quintino.'^ Suidas says that the moneys of the early Romans were scarabse of baked clay.^ And to strengthen this testimony it may be added that porcelain coins or moneys of China, clay coins (probably) of Assyria and Babylon, terra cotta coins of Palmyra, and glass coins of Egypt and Arabia, are still extant. They will be described in this work under the heads of the countries to which they severally belong. With regard to the aflBnity of clay dies to metal dies, and the derivation of mint stamps from the presumed earlier use of seals, the celebrated Thomas Burgon, in the course of an essay on Representations on (upon) Ancient Moneys, has said : "As the act of impressing a seal or signet was an understood sign of solemn compact from the most early periods, and as engraved seals and signets were un- doubtedly in general use long anterior to the invention of coining, it appears highly probable that the original idea of impressing a stamp on the uncoined lumps of gold or silver was derived from the common application of a seal to wax. The earliest coins " (not moneys, generally, but coins) " may be therefore looked upon as pieces of sealed metal, which in fact they are, it being well known that at first, coins were impressed only on one side." "* Marsden, writing on the same subject, has said : " The universal employment of clay for almost every purpose of life naturally led to marked improvements in the processes of stamping and impressing the soft substance nature so readily hardened into durability and indestructibility Yielding metals were speedily subjected to a similar process ; for the transition from the seal to the die would demand but a single step in the development of mechanical appli- ' Stieglitz, " Catalogus Numorum Veterum Grfficorum," Christ. Ludov. Stieglitz, Leipsig, 1837, pp. vi. and 2. ^ Humphreys, " Ancient Coins," p. 17. ' Ibid. p. 17. ' "London Numismatic Journal," 1837, p. 118. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 75 ances. In effect, the first mint stamps were nothing more than authoritative seals." ' Both of these writers alluded to Assyria and Babylonia, whose clay seals they knew to be older than the supposed origin of metal coinage in Lydia.' Whilst the affinity of clay and metal moulds or dies alluded to by them is of interest in this connection, the derivation of mint stamps from the assumed earlier use of seals cannot be admitted without reserve. Money and even coined money is pro- bably older than the art of writing, and certainly as old as the use of seals. Many of the supposed seals of Babylon are, in all probability, coins ; but whether they are seals or coins, they are fifteen centuries later than the copper coins of Sung,^ and therefore at least that interval of time later than the origin of stamped money. If it be objected to the assumed use of clay coins in ancient India that no such coins have yet been found, it is to be replied th^jt when Henry wrote his " History of Britain " no coins had been found of the Scots, Picts, or Welsh of the Anglo-Saxon period ; yet that the ancient Welsh laws on coinage, which still survived, proved that such coins must have existed.* Similarly, when Mill wrote his " History of India," no coins had been found in that country of a date prior to the Mongol conquest, a fact that led that author into the extraordinary conclusion that none had ever before been used in India. ° Since the publication of MilFs " History," myriads of such coins have been found. It remains now to show how it was financially practicable to employ clay coins or tablets for money. With this object in view, it was merely necessary that the state should assume the monopoly of their fabrication, that they should ^ Marsden, " Numis. Orient.," p. 56. ^ See note 3, p. 69 of the present work. ' See chap. ii. herein on the History of Money in China. * Henry, " Hist. Britain," iv. 263, 282, 283. ' Mill, "Hist. India," ii. 183. 76 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. be rendered an exclusive and unlimited legal tender in all payments^ that their number should be specifically and permanently limited, and that counterfeiting should be successfully kept down. History and analogy combine to a,ssure us that these regulations will confer a value on any money, no matter of what material it may be composed, and that they will sustain that value without any other variation than that which may be occasioned by the greater or less frequency of the exchanges. Practically, and in order to maintain prices at the accustomed level, the number of such coins, tablets, pieces of paper, or what not, should not exceed the number of copper, silver, or other pieces which they may have been made to supplant. If such a system of money existed in India — and there can be little doubt that it once did — it remains to show by what means it came to an end. These are to be found in the comparative ease with which clay tablets can be counter- feited and the difiSculty of preventing unlawful additions to the circulation, and in the temptation on the part of a despotic and irresponsible government to surreptitiously increase the emissions of such a highly overvalued money. The inconveniences arising from the weight, cnmbrousness, and liability to breakage of clay tablets, or the discovery of new mines of copper, or of other metals suitable for coinage, or the conquest or re-occupation of old ones, may have hastened its downfall. Whatever the cause or causes, it is quite clear, both from the Veda and Manou, that at the date of those writings the standard of money in India had returned to copper. Says Marsden : " The entire text of Manou proves that the standard of money, when metallic at all, was always of copper, a metal which in remote times was superior to any other for the purpose, on account of its more ample and steady supply — that of gold or silver being deficient and irregular.' This view is, no doubt, substantially correct ; yet, con- sidering the long period covered by the mutations through ^ Marsden, p. 53. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 77 ■whicli this ancient and probably oft-altered code of Manou has passed, it is reasonable to suppose that more than one experiment was made during this period to economize the use of copper, or avoid the inconvenience of its variable supply, by resorting to the use of overvalued moneys, whether of clay, wood, lacquer,^ or copper itself. In the end, however, these experiments gave way to the copper karshapana standard,^ as set forth in Manou. The scarcity of kdrshapana appears to have been eked out with multipliers composed of overvalued silver and gold coins, and perhaps dividers composed of lead coins, cowries, almonds, or something of the sort ; but the standard in India, as we understand it, was essentially and permanently of copper. With certain interruptions occasioned by experiments which will be noticed in their proper place, this system of ancient India, similar to that of Japan previous to 1853, and of China at the present day, continued down to the year a.d. 1766, when it gave way to the regulations intro- duced by the British Bast India Company. Before closing this account of the monetary standard in India, it is worth noticing that, except as to the Isle of France, which can scarcely be considered as part of India, no paper money was ever issued in this country until the year 1861 of our era. The Hindoos of India had, in this respect, the example of China before them, and the Mahomedans of India that of China, Persia, and other countries ; yet no effort appears ^ Wooden and lacquer moneys are mentioned in the present text under the head of Buddhic testimony. ^ Karshapana : copper coins which, in the time of the extant Code of Manou, are calculated to have weighed about 140 grains each. Kar- shapana appears to have always meant copper coins, except in Ceylon and on the western coasts of India, where it is applied to gold and silver ones (Marsden, p. 41). This diversity of custom may be ex- plained either by supposing that Karshapana became a generic term for money, or that the copper coins were overvalued. In this respect it will be observed that the gold coin (?) Suvarna, of 140 grains, and the copper coin Karshapana, of 140 grains, were both of the same value, namely, 80 rati. 78 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTKIES. to have been made to utilize printed paper for monetary purposes. This may have been due to frequent wars and changes of administration, to the absence of a suitable material for making paper, or, as is most likely, to the inability of the people to read.^ Ratio of value between the coining metals. — The few notices and inferences concerning the ratio of value between the metals, which are to be gleaned from the ancient history of India, are too unreliable for use as the basis of any precise inferences. It is probably safe to assume that, previous to the Phoenician and Babylonian commerce with India, silver was more valuable in that country than gold ; ^ that during that commerce, or at least during the earlier portion of it, silver was exchanged for gold at an equal value, weight for weight; and that, owing to the prolificacy of the Phoenician silver mines in Spain and the Laurium silver mines in Greece, the value of silver continued to fall until at about the period of Alexander's invasion of India, when it stood in India at probably about 2 silver= 1 gold. As for the ratio used by Herodotus in computing Darius' spoil in Bactria and the Punjab, this was the ratio prevailing in Greece and not in India. From Alexander's time, owing to the establishment of systematic commerce between the East and West, the ratio in India gradually ' In China everybody is compelled to learn the art of reading ; in India it is forbidden by the Brahminical code to instruct the Sutra, or most numerous class of the people. " Land of the Veda," by Eev. Peter Percival, London, 1854, p. 40. ^ The superior value of silver to gold in very ancient times is attested by Boeckh, " Polit. Econ. Athen." i. 6. After any long interruption of commerce between the Bast and West, this superior value asserted itself. The ancient inhabitants of Germany valued silver more than gold. Tacitus, " German." 5. In the time of Nadir Shah, a.d. 1749, the Kurds gave gold for silver, weight for weight. Ritter, " Erdkunde," 395, in Wm. Roscher's " Polit. Econ.," New York, 1878, i. 356, and note 10. He adds " copper," but this appears incredible. A similar ratio of exchange is said to have prevailed in recent times between the Chinese and Indians (Tavernier's " Travels," Eng. ed. ii. 2, 23, -156) ; but this must have been quite local and temporary. INDIA, PRIOE TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 79 widened, until in the fifth century of our era it probably stood at 5 or 6 silver =1 gold, and there remained until the opening of the sea route to India by the Portuguese was effected. As for the ratio between copper and silver, our informa- tion on the subject is too meagre to warrant any general conclusions. During the Mahomedan domination it is esti- mated by one author to have stood at 60 to 120 for 1 ; but the present writer believes that copper was more valuable — how much more, cannot be determined with precision. "^ Reviewing the history of money in India, we find that money was employed by the aborigines prior to the Hindoo invasion ; that it was employed successively by the earliest Hindoos, and by the earliest Brahmins and Buddhists ; and that, in short, there is no period of written history so re- mote that it does not contain allusions to some kind of money. We find that the supplies of the coining metals in India were so irregular and precarious, that overvalued moneys of clay, wood, and other substances were probably experimented with at very remote periods, to give place at last to copper coins ; and that, substantially, copper metal, coined, may be regarded as having been the standard of value from at least the period of the Hindoo invasion to the British conquest. In proceeding to divide the further history of money in India into convenient eras, it will be found that these are best determined with reference to the great foreign invasions which from time to time have changed the dynasties and altered the destinies of the country. The next after the Hindoo invasion is that one imputed to Seaostris of Egy^^, about B.C. 2000.^ After a careful examination of the subject by Dr. Robertson, that historian was forced into the conclusion that the account of this expedition which has come down to us is apocryphal.^ About the year 525 B.C., Darius Hystaspes, King of ^ Consult Festus ; Letronne ; Peyron ; Thomas ; and Lenormant. ' Diod. Sic, i. 34. ^ Robertson's "India," p. 7, and note 1. 80 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. Persia, appointed Scylax of Caryandra to take command of a squadron of boats fitted out at Caspatyrus, toward the upper part of tlie navigable course of the Indus, and to fall down its stream until he should reach the ocean. This task Scylax performed, though the obstacles he encountered lengthened the period of the expedition to two and a half years. The account he gave of the populousness, fertility, and high cultivation of that region of India through which his course lay, resulted in its being invaded about the year 521 by Darius himself; and although his conquests do not appear to have extended beyond the district watered by the Indus, he returned to Persia after having imposed tributes which were equal in amount to nearly a third of the whole revenue of the Persian monarchy.^ So far as the conquest of Bactria and Ariana are con- cerned, these tributes may have been paid, as Mr. Mill argues, in graiu.^ Herodotus does not specify the mode of payment. But as to the Indian tribute he is explicit, and says it consisted of 360 talents in " gold dust/' and esti- mates the value of this, according to the Greek ratio, at " thirteen times the value of silver." I am inclined to believe that if such a tribute was exacted, it could not have been paid for more than a very short period. Columbus, Cortes, Pizarro, and the other conquerors of America tried the same thing, i.e. to exact a permanent tribute of the precious metals from the peoples whom they had subdued — and they all failed. After the usual preliminary plunder of trinkets and robbery of graves, the gold tribute must have come either from the placers or the river bars. The former are always exhausted of their principal contents when a country is T-rst opened to that phase of civilization which demands the use of metals ; the accumulations of the latter are too meagre to satisfy the requirements of a conqueror. The invasion of Alexander the Great occurred about the ' "Herod.," iv. 90, 96, aud 166. ^ Mill's "India," ed. 1820, i. 280. INDIA, PRIOR TO ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 81 year b.c. 330. This commander crossed the Oxus, subdued and ravaged Bactria, climbed the Hindoo Koosh, descended into the Punjab, defeated Porus on the banks of the Hydaspes (Chelum), and thus made himself master of north- western India, Like that of Darius, Alexander's army did not advance far beyond the Indus. On the banks of the Hyphasis (B^yah), his troops, worn out with fatigue, satiated with slaughter, and overladen with spoil, demanded to be led back to Persia ; and their leader was fain to submit to their wishes. He retreated in boats or rafts down the Indus to the ocean, and thence marched overland to Persia ; whilst his fleet, under Kearchus, sailed up the Persian gulf, and re- opened a long forgotten channel of commerce between India and Europe. The gold and silver spoil of this expedition, must have consisted of trinkets, jewellery, idols, furniture, and mural ornaments. To appease the clamour of his men for a speedy division, Alexander coined it in his camps.^ Although, on account of the native standard of money being copper, there were probably but few gold or silver coins in this spoil, yet the total quantity of these previously in circulation (as multipliers) , was so small, that there is evidence of an extra- ordinary scarcity of these metals for a long time after the conquest ; an inference gathered from the subsequent use of overvalued nickel coins (about three-fourths copper and one- fourth nickel) by Buthydemus and Agothocles, kings of the Bactrian Greeks.^ These coins were also used as multipliers. About the year B.C. 312, Seleucus Nicator, a Greco-Baby- lonian monarch and one of the successors of Alexander, is said to have conducted an expedition into India, which penetrated further than Alexander's had done ; ^ although this is doubted by Robertson.* Desirous of cultivating ^ Marsden. A circumstantial account of Alexander's line of march will be found in Wilson's " Ariana Antiqua," p. 165. ' Marsden, 43. ^ Justin xv. 4 ; Pliny vi. 17. * Robertson's "India," note 12. G 82 HISTORY OF MONET IN ANCIENT COUNTEIES. friendly relations with the sovereign of the Gangetic regions, Seleucus accredited to him, as ambassador, one Megasthenes, who, after reaching AUabahad, continued to reside there for several years. He is probably the first European who ever beheld the Ganges.^ His account of the country, published after his return to the West, furnished the source of most of that information concerning India, which Diodorus Siculus, Strabo, and Arrian have transmitted to us. About the year B.C. 200, Antiochus the Great of Syria, after subduing Parthia and Bactria, entered India and, con- cluding a peace with one of the sovereigns of the country, received from him a present of elephants and money and retired. From this time until the Mahomedan invasions, which commenced during the seventh, and ended with the conquest of the country in the eleventh century, no Western powers acquired any territory or established any dominion in India. In view of these various conquests of India and their several degrees of importance, it has been determined to divide the monetary history of the country into two other portions, the first of which will cover the period from Alexander the Great to the Mahomedan conquest, and the second from the latter event to the present time. ' Robertson's " India," p. 33. CHAPTER V. INDIA, FROM ALEXANDEE THE GKEAT TO THE MAHOMEDAN CONQUEST. Futility of depending upon Greek or Latin authors for the history of this period — Aid to be derived from Chinese authority — From arohEeo- logical authority — Character of the Indian trade with the West — Trifling proportion of silver shipments — Supply of coining metals from the mines — Modern numismatic finds — The topes — Misleading infe- rences to which such finds may point, unless studied with caution — Ancient Indian custom of coining: 1, gold and silver multipliers of copper moneys ; 2, gold, silver, and other coins for commemorative and proclamatory purposes — These practices found their way to Rome — Actual standard of money in India during the period under review — This was copper, with gold and silver multipliers, in Northern, and copper, with cowrie divisors, in Southern India — Abnormal camp coin- ages of invaders — These had no eSect upon the copper standard — Else of the Arabian power in the seventh century — Kapid conquest of Egypt and Persia, and monopolization of the Indian trade — The Italians carry a portion of the trade through Tartary, and afterwards submit to Mahomedan exactions and trade in Alexandria — The Crusades, and their influence in concentrating the Indian trade at Constantinople — Its engrossment by the Venetians — The Genoese capture Pera, and compel the Venetians to again trade through Alexandria — Capture of Constantinople by the Turks, and end of the Genoese trade \vith India — Rivalry for this trade leads to the discovery of the sea route by the Cape, and of America — Silver shipments to India during the Middle Ages — The Mahomedans invade India — Gradual progress of their arms, until they completely conquer the country in a.d. 1001 — Im- perceptible influence of this conquest upon the monetary system of India — The standard remains of copper. THE examination and comparison of the fragments left us by Greek and Latin authors^ or their monkish censors of the Middle Ages, was for a long time ranked among the highest efforts of learning. Modern research 84 HISTORT OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. has done much to overthrow this view by proving that the classical authors, particularly where they treat of affairs in countries other than their own, are often too unreliable to repay the effort to reconcile their discordant accounts.^ An instance has already been given where reference to Chinese annals supplied a link in the chain of history, which subsequent numismatic research proved to be authentic.'"^ Archaeology has supplied further information, and the in- dustry and patience of Prinsep and others in deciphering inscriptions in the dead and forgotten languages of India has resurrected a number of philological evidences, which add their testimony to the rest, and, combined with the closer study of Arabian authors, serve to throw a strong light upon the obscure portions of Indian history.' From the conquest of Alexander to the Mahomedan in- vasions, several commercial routes were opened between India and the West, among the most important of which were those by the Persian Gulf via Bassora, by the Red Sea via Berenice and Alexandria, and overland by Samarcand and Palmyra, or vi& the Caspian and Eusine Seas. The trade ■* Arrian's account (in Greek) and Quintus Curtius' (in Latin) of Alexander's invasion of India both state that money formed part of his spoil. Arrian, vi. 16, 4 ; Quintus Curtius, viii. c. xii. 14, 15 ; see also iii. c. xiii. 16, and v. c. ii. for meaning attached to Signatus (Consult Marsden, 6, 7). On the other hand, Arrian (v. 4) says the Indians with whom Alexander was engaged were without gold ; while Pausanius the traveller, second century a.d., says (iii. c. xii. 3) that no coins were in use in India (trans, of T. Taylor, London, 1 824, vol. i. p. 264) \ Strabo is still more extravagant. " Gorges, the miner of Alexander " is his authority for the statement that " the Indians, unacquainted with mining and smelting, are ignorant of their own wealth." Strabo, xv. i. 30 ; see Dr. Robertson's criticism on Plutarch, Robertson's " India," p. 306. ^ See chap. ii. p. 15, note 1, of present work. ' The principal writers upon the history of India, from Alexander to- the Mahomedan invasions, are Megasthenes, fourth century b.c. ; Diodorus Sioulus, b.c. 44; Strabo, died a.d. 25; Arrian, a.d. 140; Cosmus of Egypt, sixth century a.d. ; and the two Arabian travellers of the ninth century a.d., edited by Abu Zeid al Hasan, of Siraf See Robertson's "India," 331. INDIA, FROM ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 85 was successively engrossed by the Egyptians, the Greeks, the Babylonians, the Persians, the Eomans, the Persians again (sixth century a.d.), the Arabians of the seventh and eighth centuries, and the Italian republics. The exports from India were chiefly cottons, spices (mainly pepper), silk, precious stones, ivory, and tortoise-shell. The exports from the West were chiefly woollens, linens, glass vessels, wine, and the precious metals, chiefly silver. Allusion has already been made to the possible quantity of the latter, which, at the utmost, could have been but trifling. As to the supply of coining metals from the mines, no change can be discerned from the condition of affairs that existed before Alexander's invasion. Prom Gorges' exag- gerated account it is probable that although the Hindoos were far from being " ignorant " of mining, their mode of treating silver ores was inferior to that which had been ac- quired by the Greeks in dealing with the refractory cala- mine deposits of Laurium. With regard to gold washings, no improvement upon the most ancient method was possible, and as to gold quartz, it was rather a question of ability to excavate the rock below certain depths, and of the con- tinuance of the deposits, than of art in extracting the metal from the ore. In neither of these respects, however, could the Hindoos have learnt anything from contemporaneous nations until after the Mahomedan conquest. In dealings with the monetary systems of this period, the most important guides to their proper understanding are the numismatic finds and comparisons, which have rewarded the labours of modern archaeologists. The bulk of these finds are represented in the following list : — Era. Dynasty. Character of coins found. B.C. about 330 to 312 Perso-Bactrian Satrapy . . . Gold, Silver, Copper. 312 Seleucus of Babylon, in Bactria . Gold, Silver, Copper. 310 Bactrian Gold, Silver, Copper. 256 to 98 Greco-Bactrian .... Silver, Copper. 100 to 40 Indo-Scythic G. C. and P. C 100 to 40 Indo-Parthie G. S. C. and P. C. ' Prinsep, ii. 89, 214, and Wilson's " Ariana Antiq." 86 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. Era. Dynasty. Character of coins foond. B.C. about 85 to — Indo-Scythic Kings of Kabul (Kad- A D. abont phises and Kanerkes) . . . Gold, Copper. 161 to 319 Gupta G. S. C. (the latter overvalued).' 226 to 632 Sassanian 6. S. C. Billon. 6th-8th cent. Gupta 10th cent. Brahmin kings of Kabul and Punjab Silver, Copper. lOth-l 2th cent. Eajput coins, W. and N.W. India . Gold, Silver, Copper. 1 1th & 12th cent. Kanauj coins Gold, Silver, Copper. 12th cent. Ghazni, N.W. India . . . G. S. C. and Brass. G., gold; S., silver; C, copper; P. C, plated copper. Some of these coins were found in circulation, others in buried hoards, amongst them a single find of 35,000 coins in brass boxes/ whilst others, again, were found in temples, topes, and other secure places of deposit. Gold, silver, and copper coins have been secured of all the dynasties mentioned, together with the following excep- tional pieces : a gold slug, weighing 2593^ grains, of Bukratides, Greco-Bactrian line, B.C. 185 ; ' nickel and copper coins of Buthydemus and Agathocles, two other monarchs of the Greco-Bactrian line ; billon coins of the Sassanian dynasty; and cowries; the two last-named speci- mens coming from the Manikyala tope in the Punjab.^ A large proportion of all the finds hitherto made in India have been in the Punjab. Whether this resulted from the superior opportunities or industry of the antiquarians stationed in that region, or the comparative scarcity of ancient coins, cannot yet be determined. The period from ^ " The Mahdwanso," one of the Buddhist books, states that the Brahman Chanakya, a minister of Chandra Gupta, " with the view of raising revenues, converted (by recoining) each kah^pana into eight, and thus gained eighty kotis of kahipanas. Tumour's " Mah^wanso," Ceylon, 1837, p. xl., and Max Miiller's " Sanscrit Literature," p. 289 ; from Marsden, 45. ^ These were found in 1853 at Korch Bahir, three miles south-west of Decahatta on the Dhurla ("P. K. D." 114, 115). ' Akber, a.d. 1550, coined a gold slug worth 1000 rupees. * In this tope, opened in 1830, were found mingled together cowrie shells, gold coins of the Kadphises and Kanerkes, Roman consular coins shortly before the Christian era, and copper coins of the Sassanian line. Marsden, 35, 36, and " Ariana Antiqua," p. 15. INDIA, FKOM ALEXANDEE THE GREAT. 87 the fifth to the tenth century of our era is also but slightly represented. No safe inferences can be drawn from these circumstances. The tope was a species of shrine built of solid masonry, and having a small apartment in its remotest interior, to gain access to which the entire pile had to be perforated. The pur- pose of the structure was evidently the preservation of the sacred relics and valuable historical signs found within them. From the emblems found in or upon the topes, they are conjectured to be all of Buddhic origin, and from these and other indications, their date is assigned to the period from Buddha until about the fifth century of our era.^ Because gold and silver coins, among others, have been found of nearly all the dynastic lines of India, it would be rash to assume that coins of these metals were used by them as money. Many of these coins have been found in the topes, a fact that of itself, and in the absence of contrary evidence, appears to indicate rarity, as is certainly the case with regard to the Roman coins and sacred relics found with them. Others of these gold and silver coins have been mingled in very small numbers with copper coins in vast quantities; and a considerable proportion of them are unique or nearly so. Bearing in mind the ancient and long accustomed use of gold and silver coins in India as multipliers for copper moneys, and the comparative scarcity of these metals, whether from the poverty of the mines or the remoteness and difficulty of obtaining further supplies by means of foreign commerce, it is regarded as quite safe to conclude that these coins were either used as multipliers or else for commemora- tive or proclamatory purposes. The entire history of India is a protest against the assumption of their use as money. ^ The Ceylon topes are identified as belonging to the fourth, third, second, and first centuries b.c, whilst others belong to later dates — that of Hidda, five miles south of Jelalabad, in Afghanistan, having contained some Roman coins of the Lower Empire, a.d. 407-74. Marsden, 35, 36, 43. 88 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. As the use of coins for multiplying, and also for memo- rial and notarial purposes — the latter would be called medals in modern days — are subjects that have an important bear- ing upon the history of money, it is deemed essential at this point to refer to them more particularly. Until the Mahomedan conquest — and then only in those parts of the country completely subjected to the cdnquerors -^the sovereigns of India did not claim or enforce the pre- rogative of coining gold or silver. It was a privilege con- ferred upon anybody who chose to ask for it, and who agreed to fabricate the coins of a given weight and fine- ness.^ This clearly points to their use as merely multipliers of the standard copper moneys fabricated by the State, pre- cisely as Spanish and other foreign coins, having no legal function, are to-day used by the Chinese to multiply sums in their standard copper cash. This custom appears to have found its way from India to Rome, where it appeared in the license accorded to the various gens to coin denarii of silver, having no legal tender function. Whenever these multipliers were overvalued by law, the government, of course, monopolized their coinage. At certain periods of the Mahomedan supremacy in India, whilst attempts were being made or contemplated, to change the long time standard of money from copper to gold and silver, the prerogative of coining these metals was asserted and enforced by the sovereign, but this exceptional practice did not long prevail, and the common license of coining gold and silver was resumed. Traces of it are to be found from the remotest era until very recent times.'' The fact that the value of the gold and silver could only be ^ Marsden, 57. The sovereigns of the Dekkan and others accorded to village gold- smiths and others the privilege of coining gold and silver with the royal devices. " Pathan Kings of Delhi," p. 344. This custom was noticed by Ferishtah, 1357-74. " Bombay Text," i. 537. And so late as 1832, before the British East India government had been extended to all parts of the country, it was extensively practised in Central India. Sir J. Malcolm, " Central India," 1832, ii. 80. INDIA, FROM ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 89 expressed in copper coins is sufficient to prove that they were not the standard money of the country. Their func- tion was simply that of representing large sums of coppers. The most significant evidence of royal accession or conquest in a country whose inhabitants were entirely illiterate, was the appearance of the new sovereign's superscription on the coinsj and as this announcement could not, with conve- nience, be made on the copper coinage, on account of its great extent and diffusion, it was made on the gold and silver multipliers. A curious proof of this custom was afforded by the action of the Persian general of an Indo- Mahomedan army, who having been victorious over the Turks, ajid being suspected of high treason, diverted suspi- cion from himself to the king's son by coining and circula- ting pieces with the latter's superscription.^ This custom can, however, be traced to the earliest period of lettered coins, both from the distinct proofs that copper was always the standard of money, and the rarity of gold and silver pieces and their fineness, which latter quality unfitted them for the wear and tear to which circulating money is subjected.^ Says Thomas : Some (perhaps many) of the Mahomedan coinages of India constituted merely " a sort of numismatic proclamation or assertion and declaration of conquest and supremacy." Where printing was rare and reading un- common, a new gold and silver coinage, and a change in the prayers for the royal family were the most efiective and rapid means of proclaiming the accession of a new ruler.' This custom also found it way to Eome, and is to be traced in some of the otherwise superfluous coinages of that empire.* ' " Pathan Kings of Delhi," p. 34. ^ The gold and silver coins of the Korch Bahar find were 981 to 990 fine, and in general the Delhi and Calcutta coins of these metals were 990 to 996 fine. " Pathan Kings of Delhi," 114-15. ' "P. K. D." 1 and 111. * " Were every other record destroyed, the travels of Hadrian might be kno-ivn by his coins alone." Gibbon, " Declii)e and Fall of the Roman 90 HISTORY OF MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. The standard of money in India during the period under review remained substantially what it had been during the previous one. There are not wanting indications — to be derived from the plated coins of the Indo-Scythic monarchs, the over-valued coppers of the Gupta race, and the billon coins of the Sassanian dynasty — that efforts were made at various times to change the standard from copper to silver, or from copper to a numerical system ; but all these efforts appear to have failed. So few particulars are left to us of these experiments, that the causes of their failure can only be surmised at as having resulted from the insecurity of the governments which tried them, the backwardness of the art of coining, or the absence of any well defined monetary principle to support them. In all cases the standard of money reverted to copper. In Northern India the copper pieces were supplemented by gold and silver multipliers, in Southern India by dividers of cowrie shells ; ^ a fact which, by the way, points very clearly to the higher value of copper in the south, and the proximity of copper mines to the north. It is true that certain abnormal coinages of gold and silver took place from time to time as the result of invasions and conquests, and for the purpose of enabling the con- queror the more readily to divide the plunder of the expe- dition among his followers. We know that camp coins were struck by Alexander, by the Greco-Bactrian kings, and by others ; but it must not be forgotten that even these coins, no matter what their number, were only multiply- ing tokens; that they did not derive their value from the materials out of which they were composed so much as from the quality which the law or immemorial custom conferred Empire." " With the assistance of coins you teach posterity the events of my reign." Theodoric the Goth, in " Cassiodorus." Humphreys' " Ancient Coins," London, 1850, p. 2. ^ " P. K. D." 110. Marsden (37) says that cowries formed the bulk of the currency between the beginning of the Christian era and the Mohamedan dynasty of a.d. 1203. INDIA, FROM ALEXANDER THE GREAT. 91 upon them of being exchangeable for a specified number of copper coins or cowries, which formed the real monetary circulation of the country. The advent of Mahomet and rise of the Arabian power gave a new direction to the commerce between India and the Westj and eventually subjected the former country to a new set of conquerors, whose dominion lasted until its pre- sent subversion by the British. So rapid was the spread of Mahomedanism, that within a few years of the Hegira, Omar, the second in descent from Mahomet, conquered both Egypt and Persia, and thus secured the two principal gates of the lucrative commerce with the East. To obtain the productions of India without being obliged to subject themselves to the humiliating and ruinous exactions of the Arabians, the Christian states of Europe were obliged to conduct their trade through Tartary,, a course that subjected it to great inconvenience, expense, and danger. Towards the close of the seventh century the Italians so far conquered their aversion to the Mahomedans, as to purchase Indian products in the markets of Alexandria ; and this city again became the principal emporium of the Indian trade until the occurrence of the Crusades in the eleventh century. At this period, and by assisting the crusaders with sea transportation for their armies, the Italians- secured the valuable privilege of buying in the markets of Antioch and Tyre those products of India which found their way to the West by the Persian Gulf. In 1204 the Venetians, by taking part in the reduction of Constantinople, secured the exclusive privilege of the Indian trade which centred at that great city, and acquired, with the Peloponnesus and some of the islands of the Archi- pelago (portions of the Greek empire), a complete chain of settlements from the Adriatic to the Bosphorus. With these advantages the route by Constantinople and the ports of the Euxine Sea became the most economical. The Genoese conquest of Pera in 1261 broke up this trade, andl l92 HISTORY 0¥ MONEY IN ANCIENT COUNTRIES. compelled the Venetians to resort once more to Alexandria, -where the duties levied on the transit of Indian goods by the Soldans of Egypt amounted to one-third the value of the commodities. Nevertheless the trade was so lucrative, that the Florentines in 1425 petitioned for and obtained a share of it. At this period the most valuable goods were ■transported by the Persian Gulf, Bussora, and Bagdad, and the heavier ones, including spices, by way of the Red Sea, •the Nile, and Alexandria. In 1453 the Turks conquered Constantinople, and the Genoese trade came to an end. The rivalry for the trade to India had now become so in- tense, that every means were resorted to in order to com- mand it ; and it is to this feeling, far more than to any hope