publications in' THE UlnfversftE of Pennsylvania SERIES IN Political Economy and Public Law asro. 15 RAILWAY CO-OPERATION AN INVESTIGATION OF RAILWAY 1 TRAFFIC ASSOCIATIONS AND A DISCUSSION OF THE DE^-FEE AND FORM OF CO-OPERATION THAT SHOULD BE GRANTED COMPETING H aILWAVS IN THE UNITED STATES nv CHARLES S. LANGSTROTH # AND WILSON STILZ INTRODUCTION HY MARTIN A. KNAPP Chairman of tlie Interstate Commerce Commiv Pull 'IsftJett for tin- University PHI! tDELPHty IS! I' I Ctnx & Co., Selling Agents, Tremonl Place, Moston, Mass &tate OfnUegc of Agriculture Kt <5orncll Hmwecaitg Htljara, ». f. Sihranj Cornell University Library HE 1829.L28 Railway co-operation.An investigation of 3 1924 013 692 896 „., The original of this book is in the Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924013692896 publications OP THE TUniversfts of Pennsylvania SERIES IN Political Economy and Public Law asro- Z5 RAILWAY CO-OPERATION AN INVESTIGATION OF RAILWAY TRAFFIC ASSOCIATIONS AND A DISCUSSION OF THE DEGREE AND FORM OF CO-OPERATION THAT SHOULD BE GRANTED COMPETING RAILWAYS IN THE UNITED STATES BY CHARLES S. LANGSTROTH AND WILSON STILZ WITH AN INTRODUCTION BY MARTIN A. KNAPP Chairman of the Interstate Commerce Commission Published for the University r £ \ (, 1899 I r L( ' t PHILADELPHIA K i ,- Ginn & Co., Selling Agents, Tremont Place, Boston, Mass. ; [ Is PREFACE. The two essays constituting this monograph on Railway Co-operation were written in competition for a prize open annually to a limited number of students in the senior class of the Wharton School of Finance and Economy of the University of Pennsylvania. This prize was established in 1896 by Mr. Henry C. Terry, of Philadelphia, in honor of his son, Willis Terry, who died suddenly two months after graduating from the Wharton School. The second set of essays submitted in competition for the Willis Terry Prize were prepared under my supervision during the academic year 1897— 1898. The subject which the five competitors investigated and wrote upon was given to them ten months before the essays were submitted in final form for examination. The five essays were all prepared with care ; but two of the contestants, Mr. Charles S. Langstroth and Mr. Wilson Stilz, gave a large amount of time and research to the preparation of their essays, and when the judges came to pass on the merits of the manuscripts, it was agreed by the judges, not only that the essays by these two young men were the best of the five, but that the studies were of such exceptional value as to make it desirable for the University of Pennsylvania to include them among its publications. In making their award, the judges gave the prize to Mr. Langstroth and made honorable mention of Mr. Stilz's essay. They recommended that both papers be published, not only because each possessed a high order of merit, but also for the reason that the two authors had treated the subject differ- ently and in such a manner that the two essays complemented (iii) iy Preface. each other in a large degree. Although not one of the judges, I fully agreed with them. The two essays taken together constitute what seems to me to be a most useful contribution to the literature dealing with the railway question. In submitting the subject of the essays to the contestants, I accompanied the statement of the subject with the following explanatory remarks : "The essay is to be a concrete study of the practical question of the co-operation of the railways in the United States at the present time. Present and former traffic asso- ciations will require investigation, not for the purpose of setting forth the details of their history, but for the purpose of depicting the economic and social forces that account for the efforts of the railways to promote co-operation and of the public to maintain complete competition. The past and pres- ent agreements of traffic associations, the legislation of the States and of the United States, and the more important judicial decisions affecting railway associations constitute the chief materials to be used in the preparation of the essay, which is to deal, first, with the interpretation of these materials, and, second, with a discussion of the present, prac- tical, economic and political question — the extent and form of railway co-operation which, in the light of our past experi- ence, should be granted to competing railways." The authors carried on the investigation thus outlined each in his own way; and, although they consulted with me frequently, the work in the strictest sense of the term is their own. As counselor and critic, I took pains to give each contestant the fullest intellectual freedom. The literary work of the two authors whose essays are printed in this mono- graph was such that but few changes in style were required. Both essays were accompanied by a bibliography, but as the two bibliographies did not differ very greatly, only one, that prepared by Mr. Langstroth, has been printed: Preface. v The views held by Mr. Langstroth and Mr. Stilz on railway questions, as well as those entertained by myself and all other students of those problems, have been largely influenced by the work and reports of the Interstate Commerce Commission. The writings of the present chairman of the commission, the Honorable Martin A. Knapp, hold a high place in transporta- tion literature, and it is a source of especial pleasure to the authors of this monograph and to myself that he has prepared an introduction to this study. He has set forth the relation of these essays to a treatment of the general subject of rail- way transportation, and has outlined the principles of govern- mental regulation of railroads in such a manner as to add very much to the value of this publication. Emory R. Johnson. August, 1899. INTRODUCTION. And no doubt, when the whole subject is carefully examined and wisely con- sidered, it will be found that the true interests of the owners of railroad property may be made to perfectly harmonize with the true interests of the public, and that it will be as wise for the state to encourage and protect whatever in corpo- rate arrangements is of beneficial tendency as it will to suppress what is mis- chievous. — Thomas M. Cooley. This was the utterance fifteen years ago of an eminent jurist and thoughtful student of railroad transportation. The forecast thus expressed embodies a weighty truth which is rapidly gaining recognition and will ultimately come to full acceptance. Contrasted with actual conditions, however, it seems in one aspect an impracticable view, while in another it suggests the magnitude and complexity of the railway prob- lem. How to secure from carriers by rail the most efficient and most equitable service at the lowest reasonable cost ; how to promote the development and increase the usefulness of these agencies of commerce, and at the same time hold them in such control as to prevent the abuse of corporate power ; how to combine their facilities to the ends of highest utility without incurring the risk that public rights will be impaired or public welfare imperiled ; how to harmonize conflicting interests of such vast proportions and place the people and the railways on a plane of equal advantage and protection, are questions of such grave import as to test the wisdom of statesmanship and tax the resources of public authority. It cannot be doubted that the solution of these questions will be greatly aided by an intelligent use of experience. While they are presented in many phases and frequently modi- (vii) viii Introduction. fied by new conditions, the careful study of what has already occurred must prove of unquestioned value. For this reason it is highly important that the facts of transportation history should be known and their significance understood not only by those who own and manage our railway properties, and are primarily responsible for their operation, but quite as much by the masses of people whose interests are directly involved and who have the power to determine the nature and extent of control to which public carriers shall be subjected. While the railroads of the country have been of incalculable benefit, the chief agency of our wonderful growth and pros- perity, their construction and management as private enter- prises have brought about more or less friction and conflict with those who are dependent upon their services. This happens so frequently that in popular estimation there is an almost continuous controversy between the public on the one side and the carriers on the other. Both parties have been influenced by a desire to bring their differences to a fair adjustment, and each of them has tried in its own way, though without much assistance from the other, to reach a satisfactory settlement. On the part of the public the contest has been mainly carried on by means of legislation. The law-making power has been constantly resorted to for relief from real and protection against imaginary evils, and to force from the roads by statu- tory enactments compliance with popular demands. Scores of measures for controlling the methods and charges of rail- way carriers have been passed, many of which were well con- sidered and useful, though not a few were distinctly unwise and mischievous. At the outset some effort seems to have been made to provide restraints by means of charter provis- ions, which were modeled after those granted to canal and turnpike companies, but this method of furnishing safeguards against corporate wrong-doing was an undoubted failure. At best it was only a preventive remedy, which was tried in a few Introduction. ix cases and found of no value. The doctrine of non-interfer- ence by the government was stoutly maintained during this period, and most of the States appear for a time to have abandoned all efforts to impose exceptional or restrictive laws upon railway carriers. The two feverish decades that followed the civil war were characterized by prodigious activity in railroad building. Excessive and premature construction was encouraged by popular demand or found its incentive in visionary expecta- tions. In the eager haste to secure railroad facilities an unwarranted premium was offered to those who would furnish them. Enormous grants of public lands, donations of private property and endless obligations in the form of county, town and municipal bonds were freely and often inconsiderately given to aid the extension of roads into remote and undevel- oped regions. Schemes of crazy speculation often resulted in capitalization unwarranted by cost or earnings, while the temptations of financial necessity furnished excuse for dis- honest management. The opportunity to engage in the business of railroad transportation was almost unlimited, because under state laws the formation of railway corpora- tions was easily effected and the restraints to which they were subjected meager and ineffectual. The inevitable outcome of this prolific creation of carriers was a brood of railroad evils, arising from reckless financiering and the intense competition of rival lines. About 1 870 attempts at regulation were made in several of the States, and although only partial success was attained, much of permanent value was accomplished. It was speedily seen, however, that State legislation is inadequate. It is influ- enced by the circumstances and prejudices of locality, and is therefore variable in its aims and unequal in its requirements. So far as it undertakes to control railroad operations, it is liable to be so feeble and inefficient as to be practically with- out benefit, or it may be so vexatious and burdensome as to be x Introduction. plainly oppressive. While the laws relating to property may be dissimilar and conflicting in different sections without serious injury, the laws relating to transportation need to be uniform, or at least harmonious, in all the territory under a common government. Prior to 1887 Congress had made no comprehensive effort to regulate commerce "among the several States." Its con- stitutional power in this direction had never been exerted and consequently never tested. The railroads had already absorbed a large portion of the international carrying trade, and were prosecuting their operations regardless of State boundaries and restrained only by the lax and insufficient provisions of the local statutes under which they were organ- ized. Under this system, or want of system, which charac- terized the history of railway legislation up to a recent period, abuses arose which the States were powerless to correct, and which assumed such startling proportions that the interference of the national government was vehemently demanded. This demand was fortified by a decision of the United States Supreme Court, in 1886, to the effect that a State has power to regulate rates only on such traffic as does not pass its boundaries, thus confining State authority within narrower limits than its exercise had been attempted. The agitation which had already aroused public sentiment culminated in the passage of the Act to Regulate Commerce, approved February 4, 1887, and thus was inaugurated a scheme of federal regulation. It is not the province of these introductoiy paragraphs to review the results thus far attained by State or national efforts to control the business of railway carriers ; nor was that the principal purpose of the writers of the two essays contained in the following pages. Although it was only incidental to the development of their main topic, nevertheless Mr. Langs- troth and Mr. Stilz have set forth these results with such clearness and accuracy that their productions will be found Introduction. xi of great value to the student of public regulation. Under the title of Railway Co-operation these essays are primarily a study of the attempts of railway companies, through volun- tary action induced by self-interest, to deal with the difficulties of unrestrained competition. Those difficulties were not seri- ously felt in the early history of railroad operations. The lines first constructed were mostly of limited extent and their business largely confined to traffic originating in the several sections where they were located. The opportunity for com- bination seems for some time not to have been appreciated, while the aggregation of capital and unification of control were generally regarded with distrust and hindered by opposition. Gradually, however, the union of connecting lines was effected until finally there came into existence the great railway systems with which we are familiar. The objections to consolidation of this character have mainly disappeared, for the predicted evils have not been experienced and the benefits to the public are everywhere recognized. Although the relations of the roads have been gradually changed by this process of development, the resulting compe- tition between systems has correspondingly grown in force and intensity. The conditions are different, but the difficulties have greatly increased. For many years railway managers have tried to maintain harmonious relations with each other and thereby avoid the losses and demoralization of interline warfare, Yet during all this period the public opposition to rate agreements, division of competitive traffic and other arrangements of similar character has been constant and decided. The cause of this opposition can be understood only when our railway history is viewed in connection with the social and economic development of the United States during the last half century. In dealing with this complex situation it is necessary to test the various measures adopted by their effects upon the service and the relations of that ser- vice to the public ; and the student of railway questions xii Introduction. should examine the results of efforts put forth from time to time by railroad managers and by the public, as different aspects of the difficulty have been viewed from their respec- tive stand-points. The writers of this volume have been highly successful in co-ordinating the events of railway history with other social and economic activities, and by so doing have contributed to a better understanding of both. Regarded simply as a historical and critical review of the leading inci- dents in railroad development, these essays combine the merits of a work of reference and a philosophical treatise upon the subject. The concluding sections of each monograph are devoted to a consideration of " the extent and form of railway co-opera- tion which, in the light of our past experience, should be granted to competing railways." This, after all, is the vital point of the whole discussion. How can the benefits of asso- ciated action be made available without incurring dangers from the concentration of corporate powers ? If this far-reaching inquiry can receive a satisfactory answer the difficulties of regulation will be largely removed. So far as railway expe- rience can guide to correct solution, it will be found epito- mized in the history of the various traffic associations through which railroad managers have endeavored to put some effec- tive restraint upon rate competition. The papers contained in this volume exhibit the most thorough and exhaustive study that has yet been made of these organizations ; and it is specially interesting to note that both writers, examining the question in the light of past events and with reference to public advantage, have reached the conclusion that co-opera- tion by rival carriers should be sanctioned by law. This conclusion accords with the views of those who have bestowed the most intelligent reflection upon the subject of railway regulation. In the last analysis it is seen that all' measures of legislation are designed to the one end of securing at all times and to all persons just and equitable charges for Introduction. xiii public transportation. To attain this result and secure its consequent advantages, the railroads of the country should be regarded in their entirety and treated so far as possible as a single system for all the purposes of legal regulation. Practi- cally there is no such thing as an independent or isolated railway. There are many members, yet but one body. Between the different parts of this complex organism there is such relationship and mutual dependence that whatever affects one must in greater or less degree affect the others also and the public interest as well. Whatever, therefore, tends to harmonize action between different lines, whether connecting or competing, whatever operates to bring the railway service into more uniform and systematic operation should be pro- moted and encouraged by suitable enactments and appropriate administration. Nor will any just theory of legislation proceed upon the assumption that the public alone are in need of protection and that the railroads can take care of themselves. Such a view is unfair and illogical. The shipper is entitled to have his property transported at a reasonable price, the carrier equally entitled to reasonable compensation for performing the service. The collision of pecuniary motives by which both parties are influenced gives rise to the controversy over rates and charges. This conflict is incessant and sometimes extremely severe. But the shipper is not always worsted in the encoun- ter. He is quite often the successful contestant. The necessity of the carrier is often the opportunity which the shipper unscrupulously turns to his own profit. Odious extor- tions have been practiced by railway managers; shippers likewise have been unreasonable and dishonest. The public service in which the carrier engages is undertaken for private gain. The shipper avails himself of this public service, like- wise for private gain. The selfishness of human nature is on both sides of the transaction. Now, the object of legal regu- lation is to hold these opposing forces in stable equilibrium; to xiv Introduction. reduce contests and complaints to a minimum, and to bring the dealings between the railways and their patrons under the control of mutual justice. The sufficient scheme of legislation, therefore, will recognize the possibility of wrong-doing on one side as well as the other ; it will be judicial rather than parti- san in its aims and requirements, and while equipping the shipper with ample protection will also furnish the carrier with all needful defenses. This is true not only as to rates on competitive traffic, but also as to relative rates between com- peting centres of trade. So far as the law can provide reme- dies for grievances which grow out of these conditions, those remedies should be available both to the carrier and the public. Reasonable charges to the one and reasonable remuneration to the other are alike involved in any just idea of regulation ; and laws which realize that idea in practical results will conserve the rights of the railways to the full extent consistent with the rights of the people. These beneficent ends cannot be reached without conferring upon railroad corporations privileges of association and rights of contract with each other which are denied by existing laws. The facts of experience and familiar knowledge demonstrate the error and inconsistency of a legislative policy which makes rate competition compulsory and at the same time condemns, as criminal misdemeanors, the methods and inducements by which in all other spheres of activity competition is mainly effected. The time has come for combining the facilities and unifying the operations of railway carriers that they may better meet the demand for stable rates, equal treatment and cheaper transportation. We must surely believe that the government of the United States has the strength, the courage and the sagacity to permit this indispensable service to be performed by friendly association, and at the same time provide ample safeguards against the dangers of railway federation. Introduction. xv These theories of legislation find much support in the thoughtful essays of Messrs. Langstroth and Stilz. They are a valuable contribution to railway literature and will be read with interest and profit by all who desire accurate knowledge of railway history and correct views of railway regulation. Martin A. Knapp. Washington, D. C, August 3, 1899. Railroad Co-operation in the United States* BY CHARLES S. LANGSTROTH. TABLE OF CONTENTS. CHAPTER I. Co-operation of Connecting Railroads. page Causes. — Consolidation. — Fast freight lines. — Consequent stimulus to com- petition 9 CHAPTER II. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. Part i. — Economic and Social Eorces^Accounting for such Co-operation. — Railroad problem due to competition. — Excessive competition leading to rate wars. — Personal discriminations. — Place discriminations . . 14 Part 2. — Agreements to Sustain Rates — Early history. — Agreements be- tween trunk lines. — Failure almost universal 20 Part 3. — Agreements to Divide Traffic. — Idea at the basis of such agree- ments. — Early history. — In the West. — In the South. — In the North. — Review 31 CHAPTER III. Legislation and Its Results. Part I. — Prohibitive Legislation. — Public opposition. — Legal status and State legislation. — Federal legislation 55 Part 2. — Evolution of Traffic Agreements. — Necessity for reorganization — In the East. — In the South. — In the West. — Present status .... 61 Part 3. — Extent of Evils Due to Competition. — Discriminations pro- hibited. — Prohibition evaded. — Difficulty of detection. — Strong in- ducement to discriminate. — Injurious effects. — Summary 7° CHAPTER IV. Degree and Form of Co-operation That Should be Granted Competing Railways. Public nature of the railway's services. — Competition relied on for regulation. — Competition under the pooling agreement. — Possible abuse of the right to pool. — Pools, if allowed, should be regulated. — Form of regulation 79 Sources of Material and Bibliography 100 (7) CHAPTER I. Co-operation of Connecting Railroads. The earliest combinations of railroads in the United States were those made by several lines jointly engaged in the carriage of through traffic. This form of combination was merely a consolidation of different links into one connecting line, in order to secure the benefits of unified management. The railroads in this country were at first of a purely local character ; their traffic originated and ended at places on the same road. Very often the railroads were regarded merely as feeders for the canals. With the development of a large through traffic, however, a system of transportation which required frequent transhipments of the goods naturally involved great waste. The shipping public also suffered, since, each link in the chain being under a separate management, it was difficult if not impossible to determine responsibility for loss or damage. The actual condition of affairs under such a system has been described by Edwin D. Worcester, secretary of the New York Central, in his testimony before the Senate Committee on Transportation Routes to the Seaboard. The description applies to the conditions which existed before the consolida- tion which took place in 1851 and 1853 : " We had ten roads between Albany and Buffalo. There was just about as much efficiency in operating ten roads as there would be in ten men trying to do a thing that one ought to do. Every board of directors had its own profit to make and its own schemes to advance. There was no obligation on the part of any one company to do anything for any other. Through lines of cars could be run only by very complicated and embarrassing arrangements. I can remember the time when conductors were changed at the end of each one of the (9) io Railroad Co-operation in the United States. roads of the old line between Buffalo and Albany. In some cases a ticket could not be bought through from Albany to Buffalo. The elements of usefulness and economy were very few. In regard to freight, there was no obligation on the part of any one of the roads to take a single pound of it from another. Except as far as they might agree with each other, it involved changing at each terminus." 1 Consolidation. — It was to overcome this state of affairs that the railroads entered into their earliest combinations. Con- solidation had been begun in some sections before i860, but in general it was not until well along in the seventies that any considerable number of the roads had given up their inde- pendence. The Pennsylvania engaged more extensively in such oper- ations than any other company. With an original line of 249 miles, by 1869 this company had secured, through purchase and leases, and by construction of certain connecting links, a line of 2,458 miles. The New York Central forms another good example of the growth by consolidation during this period. It was formed in 1853, of what had been originally eleven railroads. Within five years five more lines had been added, and in 1 869 there was under one general management a line of more than 4,000 miles long. During this same period were developed in a manner nearly similar the other trunk line systems — the Erie and the Baltimore & Ohio. In the West the great railway systems have grown and consolidated even more rapidly than in the East. There has been not a little public apprehension in regard to the growth of these enormous companies, with the concentra- tion of such great power in the hands of a few men. If great power has been placed in the hands of a few, however, at least one of its uses has been to promote public interests. Facilities for cheap, rapid and convenient movement of pas- sengers and freight between distant points have been improved, 1 Windom Report, 1874, Evidence, p. 157. Co-operation of Connecting Railroads. n delays and changes of cars have been avoided, and the respon- sibility of the carriers has been increased, to an extent that without consolidation would have been impossible. In 1873, the Massachusetts Railroad Commissioners said of consolidation, "not only have the evils anticipated not resulted, but it would seem that the public has invariably been better and more economically served by the consolidated than by the independent companies. The larger companies employ abler officers, and seem to be managed more on the system of great departments of commerce and less on that of lines of stage coaches. There is, in fact, far less of friction in the work of transportation and far more of a system. Finally, as regards the community at large, it is found that large companies can be held to a closer responsibility than small ones." 1 In 1874, the*Windom Committee expressed itself in favor of the consolidation of separate links into through chains, on the ground both of economy and of increased and centralized responsibility. 2 Fast Freight Lines. — Forms of combination other than actual consolidation have been entered into by connecting railroads to secure the advantages of unified management. For the purpose of handling the traffic with which several roads were concerned, entirely distinct organizations were established; these "fast freight lines," as they were called, owned the cars used for through traffic and assumed the necessary responsi- bility. They collected the charges from the shippers and paid the railroads certain specified tolls for motive power and use of road-bed. The most serious abuse connected with the system was that the officers of the railroads were also inter- ested in the freight line and would consequently give it exceptional advantages. This evil was obviated by the establishment of the co-oper- 1 Report, p. 138. 2 Transportation Routes to the Seaboard, p. 138. 12 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. ative fast freight lines. These were neither separate organiza- tions nor partnerships ; they were simply car clearing-houses, whose main duties were to keep the accounts of the traffic in which several roads were concerned and to adjust balances. 1 Their plan of operation was this : the through traffic was hauled in the cars of any of the roads forming the line, the company owning the car received a certain mileage for its use (say three-fourth cents per mile run) ; 2 and the remain- der of the receipts was divided up among the roads in propor- tion to the distance each had hauled the freight. Collections and disbursements were made by the line, but only as agent for the different roads. It accordingly had no income of its own and was supported by assessments on the different roads. As Hadley says, " It cannot be made a means of fraud, any more than a clearing house can be made a means of fraud. The sum of debit balances for one set of roads must equal the sum of the credit balances for the rest, leaving the line itself neither the gainer nor the loser." 3 A typical example of the saving resulting from this system is shown in the experience of the New York and Erie. By simply changing from the old form of handling through ship- ments to the co-operative form, the expense of looking after through freight was reduced by this road from 9 per cent of the earnings on such freight to 3 per cent. 4 The service performed by the two kinds of fast freight lines can hardly be overestimated. Without their aid only a very small proportion of the through rail freight movements would have been possible. They have been the main factor in bringing about the abolition of the practice of transferring 1 Hepburn Committee Report, p. 8 ; testimony, p. 2963. 2 Varying according to the condition of the track — largest in the South, smallest on the trunk lines. (Hadley " Railroad Transportation," p. 88.) » " Railroad Transportation," p. 89. * Report on Transportation Routes to the Seaboard, testimony. (Blanchard) P- 364- Co-operation of Connecting Railroads. 13 freight from one set of cars to another at the connecting point between two lines, and in avoiding the many delays and expenses otherwise attached to long through shipments. 1 Stimulus to Competition. — The result of the cheapening of through rail traffic by means of consolidation and of fast freight lines, has been to increase the opportunities for compe- tition and to strengthen its intensity. 2 Without the aid of these factors a large part of the through traffic would never have gone by rail, and the amount shipped under the old extravagant conditions of transhipment would have been insignificant as compared with the volume of existing traffic. The ability of the railroads to haul a commodity a long distance without consuming its value, led, however, to the increase of competitive traffic, to secure which the railway* were willing to make strenuous efforts. 1 Ringwalt : Transportation Systems in the United States, p. 193. 5 Windom Report, p. 138. CHAPTER II. CO-OPERATION OF COMPETING RAILROADS. (i) Economic and Social Forces Accounting for Such Co-operation. Railroad Problem Due to Competition. — The motives that have led connecting roads to combine have been of a much less complicated nature than those that have actuated the co-operation of competing lines. The average railroad man regards competition as being responsible for nine-tenths of the evils of our railway system. To overcome these evils has been the chief motive leading to such combinations. From the establishment of our railway system, transporta- tion has been looked upon as being regulated by the natural safety-valve of competition. The earliest roads were constructed with the belief that they were merely improved highways, that every one would be at liberty to run his own wagons or cars upon them by the payment of a certain toll to the company, and that the only artificial regulation needed was to prescribe maximum rates of tolls. Although this idea of improved highways was soon abandoned, and the maximum rates either abolished or antiquated, the belief in the power of competi- tion remained unshaken. Competition was relied upon as the natural regulator of this and all other industries, and it is to the failure of competition to perform its part that we owe our railroad problem. Charles F. Adams says, 1 "As events have developed them- selves, it has become apparent that the recognized laws of trade operate but imperfectly at best in regulating the use made of these modern thoroughfares by those who thus both own and monopolize them ;" and he defines the railway problem as the question of finding some other means of making good 1 " Railroads," p. 81. (14) Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 15 the deficiencies thus revealed in the working of the natural laws. The unsatisfactory results of competition in regulating the railways of our country — and the numerous evils developed under it — may be attributed to certain inherent qualities of the transportation industry. These qualities, which seem to be peculiar to the railroad industry, may be considered as three in number : 1. Excessive competition, resulting from the oversupply of transportation facilities and the permanent character of the railroad when once constructed. 2. Slightness of the relation between the amount of service and the cost of each unit of service performed. 3. Partial application of competition, which exerts an influ- ence on only a portion of any road's traffic. Excessive Competition Leads to Rate Wars. — The intensity of the struggle between competing railroads arises from the existence of an oversupply of transportation facilities caused either by ignorance of the conditions of trade or by the profit to be made in mere construction. The influence exerted by an oversupply of facilities has not been so important a factor in the other industries as in the railway, for two reasons : the motives have not existed generally that cause such an over- supply ; and where an oversupply does occur its influence is not so powerful because of the more temporary character of the industry. In an ordinary industry, competition so works out that when, for any reason, an oversupply of facilities exists — when more products are being made than there is a demand for — the price of the product will fall, the producers carrying on business at the greatest disadvantage will be forced out, and production will be curtailed. But when a railroad is once established, it is established for good and all ; rather than shut down, a road will continue to run if its revenues pay run- ning expenses and leave anything at all to pay for running it. 1 6 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. The history of the railroad's development in the United States so abounds with examples of desperate competition for traffic that it is hardly necessary to cite any special instances. The point to which a railroad rate will fall during a " rate war" is fixed by the actual cost of each particular operation. During a rate war, a railroad cannot attempt to make each part of the traffic pay its share of the fixed expenses ; a man- ager is satisfied if he can make anything over actual operating expenses. This accounts for the desperate character of such wars as those between the trunk lines from 1869 to 1878, when rates fluctuated from 82 cents to 10 cents. 1 The violent reductions in rates during rate wars result in great evil to the business public, who depend upon stability of trade conditions, and to the railroads, whose revenue from competitive traffic is often practically annihilated. To sum up in a few words the first class of competitive con- ditions which we have found to apply with peculiar strength to the railway, they are : that powerful influences have caused the creation of an oversupply of transportation facilities ; that the consequent results have been more pronounced owing to the permanent nature of a railroad once constructed, and that these results in an industry with such a large proportion of fixed capital are violent strife and fluctuating rates. Personal Discriminations. — The roads have made every effort to avoid such strife by adhering to a sort of tacit agree- ment as to the rates charged. Of course it is desirable for the roads to keep up rates to a paying level, but then it is still more desirable for one road to ask just a little below the rate charged by its rivals. This brings us to the second great evil caused by competition — the special rate given to individual shippers. The temptation to give a discriminating rate does not lie in the fact that the total volume of freight will be increased, but in the fact that each additional unit of freight can be hauled at a proportionately less charge. 1 Albert Fink, New York, 1884. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. iy In the railroad industry we find a peculiarly slight relation between volume of traffic and the proportionate cost of each unit hauled. While the conditions in most industries are undoubtedly such that an increase in production will not mean a corresponding increase in the total cost, it is never- theless true that in no other industry is the cost of performing an increased service so low compared with the cost of the previous amount of service, as in the railway. The consequence of this peculiarity of the railway is the attempt made by the railroad to get the freight of a large shipper by offering him a slight rebate. The shippers them- selves often take the initiative in the matter of special rates> working one road off against another. Very often the ship- pers make the grossest misrepresentations and of course one railroad has no possible opportunity to verify the statements about its rival made by a shipper anxious to secure favorable rates. Under such conditions the result under unrestricted com- petition was that special rates were given to those who asked. This was well shown by the Hepburn Committee's report in 1879 : " He who goes into a railroad office and barters for a low rate gets it ; he who, relying on the equitable treatment which common carriers are bound to give, or not knowing that secret special rates may be had, delivers them his goods and calls for his freight bill, pays a higher rate." 1 That discriminations existed wherever it was possible for them to exist can hardly be doubted. The Hepburn Com- mittee report is the earliest reliable source of information regarding the prevalence of the practice of granting discrimi- nating rates. The report said : " The charge that the railroads discriminate in favor of certain individuals, as compared with others in the same locality, is fully proven. . . . The committee find, made and in force within the period of one year, a number of special contracts on the New York 1 Report, p. 66. 1 8 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Central and the Hudson River Road, estimated by the railroad people at six thousand. The number on the Erie was very- much less though the practice of giving them was the same." 1 The condition in the West was described in the Cullom Committee Report of 1886, where J. W. Midgely says: " While the tariff from Chicago to Kansas City on the first four classes of freight was 90, 70, 50 and 30 cents per hun- dred pounds respectively, large shippers had contracts at one- half the rates named, while a few secured contracts at even less than half." 2 These two examples are sufficient to show the conditions which resulted from competition ; it is hardly necessary to cite any further instances of what is a univer- sally admitted fact. Such a system of discriminating between individuals violates the fundamental premises of the law of competition and shat- ters the foundation on which the successful working of that law must rest — that equal opportunity under similar circum- stances must be afforded to all. We know what the effect would be if the government were to tax one firm at twice as high a rate as another; and no great depth of economic thinking is required to extend this knowledge to the railroad situation — that the very soul of competition is equality of treatment, and that wlrere this equality does not exist there will be monopoly. The injurious effects of this abuse of the railroad's power were felt not only by the shipper. It reflected on the rail- roads themselves — although they created this evil they were one of the greatest sufferers from it. Why they continued a practice from which they were the greatest sufferers, is, as Van Oss says, a mystery ; and he draws the following picture of their position : " Like gamblers in a Montana mining camp everybody knew he had to be on his guard against others, yet confidently expected not only to hold his own, but to be * one 'Ibid., p. 48. 2 Cullom Report — Appendix, p. 226. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 19 too many ' for all players, no matter how many cards each might have up his sleeve." 1 A good summary of the evils of discrimination was made by Haines, a prominent Southern railroad manager, before the Cullom Committee : " This system went on from bad to worse, centring the business of competitive points in fewer hands, drawing the business of neighboring stations to com- petitive points, and rendering it impracticable for a man with small capital to establish himself in business under such cir- cumstances. . . . The railroad managers no longer con- trolled their own business. Under the threat of losing busi- ness they were forced to make concessions which they knew were wrong. They were annoyed by applications which it was impolitic to refuse, and met with suspicion and treachery from the very men who were being made rich by rebates, and yet feared that some one else might be getting better rates." 2 Discriminations between Localities. — The third characteristic of the competitive conditions of the railway, which is not present in the conditions of any other industry, is that while part of the traffic of a road may be competitive, very rarely if ever are conditions such that all of the traffic of a road is sub- ject to the competition of another road. In other words, the influences affecting competitive railway rates, largely fail to apply to rates on traffic between places which are served by only one road. The instances of parallel competing roads serving absolutely the same territory are of very rare occurrence. The usual condition is that the through traffic is subject to the competition of two or more roads, while the local traffic of any of the roads is subject only to an indirect competition. This peculiarity of railroad competition — that its influence extends unequally to different parts of the traffic hauled by any road — that some communities enjoy the benefits of its influence more fully than others do — has been of great 1 " Amer. Railroads as Investments," p. 33. 2 Cullom Report, Appendix, p. 132. 20 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. importance in the history of the railroad problem, a problem which, as Charles Francis Adams says, arose out of the failure of natural law, or competition, to perform its part. 1 The effect of a system of transportation which tends to sup- press industry at localities having only one railroad, and which unduly encouraged industry at points enjoying direct compe- tition, was very injurious to the individual railroads, since they could safely rely for a profitable return upon only the non- competitive traffic. It has always been the aim of roads to pass through territory in which a large and remunerative local traffic can be developed ; but this development is often rendered impossible by the lower rates which manufacturers may obtain at competitive points. The community enjoying competition in railway service was the successful community, and consequently the one which supplied the bulk of the traffic of the railroads. This resulted in great injury to the roads, since it created traffic at non-remunerative points at the cost of destroying traffic at the remunerative non-competitive point. The roads attempted to overcome this evil by equal- izing local and through rates, partly by an open adjustment of published rates, but more often by making invidious and injurious personal discriminations. Agreements to Sustain Rates. Early History. — The co-operation of railroads to overcome the effects of competition began almost immediately upon the completion of those arrangements which made competition possible. We have seen that it was the co-operation of the connecting lines that rendered possible any large through all- rail shipments of freight, which in turn afforded an opportunity for the force of competition to play its part in determining what proportion of this traffic should be hauled by each of the available roads and what rates should be charged. 1 For a fuller discussion of the nature of railroad competition, see chapter IV. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 21 What is perhaps the first indication of an attempt on the part of the roads to co-operate in order to hold in check the influence of competition is to be found in the report of the Pennsylvania Railroad Company, dated January 31, 1855. There President J. Edgar Thomson says : " With a view of agreeing upon general principles which should govern railroad companies in competing for the same traffic, and preventing ruinous competition, a free interchange of opinions took place during the past year between the officers of the four leading East and West lines, 1 and also with those of their Western connections. The influence of these conferences, it is believed, will be felt in reducing expenses, correcting abuses and adding to the net revenue of the several companies, while the public will be served with equal efficiency and greater safety. In- stead of an army of drummers and runners, spread over the country and paid by each company, an agent is now main- tained, at the joint expense of the four lines, at all important points in the West, to distribute bills and give unbiased infor- mation to the traveler." 2 The " ruinous competition " spoken of by President Thom- son related to classes of business different from those which later furnished the most fertile source of strife. At that time the Eastbound movement of the great Western crops played a very small figure in trunk line traffic ; the passenger traffic occupied a much stronger relative position before i860 than it ever has since. The various trunk lines were making great efforts to become popular routes for travelers. The Pennsyl- vania acquired connections that enabled it to compete for the passenger travel not only to and from Philadelphia, but also to and from New York and Baltimore. Then, as now, the Baltimore & Ohio prided itself on the opportunity which it was able to afford travelers going to Washington, D. C. 3 1 New York Central, Erie, Pennsylvania, and Baltimore & Ohio. 2 Eighth Annual Report, p. 13. 3 " Development of Transportation Systems," p. 152. 22 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. This agreement seems to have been without much perma- nent success, for two years later we find the New York Central engaged in a bitter strife with the Erie over the pas- senger traffic between Lake Erie and New York. This strug- gle assumed nearly all those exceptionally hostile features which characterized the later wars. As Ringwalt says, 1 " this strife was exceptionally acrimonious and led to a fearful cutting of rates." This war came to an end with another treaty or agreement signed by the presidents of the four great trunk lines in 1858, which is spoken of as follows in President Thomson's report for that year : "The effects of the unwise competition for the carrying trade between the East and the West, which prevailed for a time during the past year, induced the officers of the New York Central, Erie, Baltimore & Ohio and Pennsylvania to meet in convention for the purpose of agreeing upon remuner- ative rates, abolishing injudicious practices, and effecting a harmony of purpose conducive to the mutual advantage of the railway interest and the public. An arrangement was agreed upon which took effect on the first of last October, and the advantages thus far resulting from this compact seem to demonstrate the propriety of its continuance." * According to Ringwalt, 3 this agreement provided that S. M. L. Barlow, then president of the Ohio & Mississippi, should act as umpire in case of a renewal of strife. It also clearly laid down a number of rules which related not only to the pas- senger traffic but also to the rates to be maintained on various classes of freight traffic, especially the Eastbound movement of live-stock, and the Westbound movement of merchandise forwarded from Boston. It is probable that rate agreements were also in vogue in New England before the War of the 1 Ibid., p. 133. 1 Twelfth Annual Report, p. 19. s «< Development of Transportation Systems," p. 153. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 23 Rebellion, but their history has not yet been brought to light. Agreements Between the Trunk Lines. — The history of the attempts of the railroads in the trunk line territory to combine is especially suggestive. The really severe competition between the trunk lines did not arise until 1 869, when the New York Central and Pennsylvania had each obtained virtual control of a Chicago connection. 1 The effect which this new competi- tive force arising from consolidation had upon the rates charged on freight from Chicago to New York was immediate and powerful. In 1868, the rates had been $1.88 per hundred pounds for first-class freight and 82 cents for fourth-class. In the summer of 1869, the rate fell to 25 cents per hundred on all classes. Of course such rates as these could not con- tinue for any great length of time, and as a matter of fact they did not. Rates were soon (in 1870) returned to an at least nominal basis of $1 to $1.50 for first-class and 60 cents to 80 cents for fourth-class. 2 Excessive competition culminated in the general collapse of 1873. As Charles Francis Adams says, 3 "at that time the unnaturally rapid construction which had been going on for ten years produced its results." The situation was still further unsettled in 1874 by the Baltimore & Ohio's acquisi- tion of a Chicago connection and also by the competition of the Grand Trunk of Canada, which had secured its line con- necting Milwaukee and Detroit with the Northern Atlantic ports. 4 There were now five great trunk lines competing for the East and West bound freight, the Grand Trunk, the New York Central, the Erie, the Pennsylvania and the Baltimore & Ohio. Up to this time agents from the last four of these lines 1 Hadley, p. 93. 1 Hadley, p. 93. 3 Railroads : Their Origin and Problems, p. 148. * Hadley, p. 94. 24 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. had been in the habit of meeting at regular intervals and pub- lishing agreed rates. 1 As Adams says, 2 the fact "that the whole business of transportation between the West and the seaboard, and the prices which should be charged for doing it, had long been performed under common tariffs binding on the roads (the New York Central, Erie and Pennsylvania), and made by their agents at stated times, was a matter of public notoriety." For instance, the newspapers had long given, among their regular news, accounts of these meetings, just as they had reported the doings of State legislatures or of Con- gress. " That such meetings should have been held and such common tariffs prepared and published, was obviously a mat- ter of mere necessity to the railroads. It would have been utterly impossible for them to live under the pressure of a war of rates knowing no limitation — a war in which freight of every description should be transported long distances abso- lutely for nothing. There was a time, for instance, when cattle were brought over the competing roads in New York at a dollar a car. Such competition as this plainly opened the widest and shortest way to insolvency, and it was to avoid it that the convention of freight agents met." As Adams says, 3 there was no secrecy about their meetings ; the news- papers openly published the tariffs arranged by them, which took effect at stated periods, and which were subject to revi- sion at other stated periods. The regular local tariffs, the tariffs which were not affected by competition, were no more open than the competitive tariffs so agreed upon. " The only difference," according to Adams,* " between the local and the through tariffs was that, whereas the former were fixed and Tarely changed, the latter were subject to sudden and violent fluctuations." 'Stuyvesant Fish, President of Illinois Central, in "American Railroad.s" 2 Railroads, p. 152. a Ibid. ■•Ibid. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 25 It was from a desire to make these agreements of some avail, if possible, and to prevent these sudden and violent fluctuations which resulted in such an unsatisfactory state of business in general, that the celebrated "Saratoga Confer- ence "took place. In 1874 Vanderbilt being at Saratoga, spending his vacation, a meeting was held there in which he conferred with representatives of the Pennsylvania and Erie roads. The result of the conference of three of the trunk lines was an arrangement by which, in addition to the usual agreement upon tariffs, the roads were to establish a board of arbitration to settle disputes. The idea was simply this : that the managers of the roads recognized the absolute failure of rate agreements .under such conditions that any fancied viola- tion, generally without even a suggestion of an investigation, was made a grievance which could be settled only by war ; and in the hope of obtaining some beneficial returns from, these agreements, they endeavored to substitute arbitration for war. To quote again from Adams, 1 " In place of the ' Rob Roy plan ' of leaving each company to assert its own rights and to maintain them if it was able, a central board was organized, the duty of which was to establish rules and tariffs which should be binding upon the various companies, and this cen- tral board it was intended should be clothed with sufficient powers to hold the companies firmly. It was an attempt to substitute arbitration among railroads for a condition of per- petual warfare." The attempt was a failure. President Garrett, of the Balti- more & Ohio, refused to surrender the independence of his road. He expressed his willingness to adhere to his old policy of charging the agreed tariff of rates on through traffic ; but he strenuously objected to submitting the action of his sovereign road to the supervision of some other power and followed strictly Washington's advice as to keeping aloof ilbid., p. 153. 26 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. from entangling alliances. The proverbial recklessness of the Grand Trunk was another disturbing factor. Nor could the Erie, being bankrupt, be relied upon as sure to follow a con- servative policy. The work of the conference was almost immediately upset by the Baltimore & Ohio, which began a severe war with its nearest neighbor, the Pennsylvania. A little later the Grand Trunk, assisted by numerous Western allies, started what was perhaps the most momentous railroad war on record ; in fact, so far did it carry things that, as Fish says, " it bade fair to transfer to Boston the commercial supremacy previously en- joyed by New York." In 1875, the New York Central felt itself obliged to take action, which it did most summarily by reducing all through rates 60 per cent. In December of that year reason seems to have prevailed in the minds of the great generals, for they patched up a sort of truce. The conditions of this truce, however, were violated almost imme- diately (in fact one might think that it was made only to be violated), and in a few weeks there was a general melee, in which everybody hit everybody else, the New York Cen- tral, Erie and Grand Trunk taking the most prominent part. After some eight months of strife, which was stemmed once or twice, but at best only partially, by attempts at agreement which were doomed to immediate failure, the five trunk lines were ready for pretty nearly any kind of an agreement. The Baltimore & Ohio had abandoned all pre- tensions to independence and was quite ready to enter into any alliances, no matter how entangling ; and the Pennsyl- vania having lost for the time being its ability to pay dividends, had lost with it all disposition to compete. 1 Hadley says, 2 "the fight ended in 1877, not because anything was settled, but because all parties were exhausted." I am rather in- clined to agree with Larrabee, that something was settled, in 1 Adams, p. 168. 2 Railroad Trans., p. 95. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 27 fact that a great deal was settled. Larrabee says, 1 that in time the railroad managers became convinced that, unless it was possible radically to reform railroad ethics, rate agree- ments could never be relied upon for the maintenance of rates at competing points. Experience convinced them that to make their agreed-upon tariffs effective it was necessary to deprive individual roads of the power or the inducement to cut below the agreed rates. Failure almost Universal. — The experience of the trunk lines, in their attempts to maintain an agreed tariff of the rates to be charged on competing traffic, seems to be typical of the experience of all roads that made such attempts. Of course the courts would not enforce compliance with these agreements on the part of the roads making them, as the law discountenances combinations of this character as being in restraint of competition and against its own policy. 2 There being no way of enforcing such agreements, beyond the mere word of the manager of the road, they were violated when- ever it came to be the interest of any of the agreeing parties to do so. Even where the principal officers made a simple agreement to charge only according to a certain agreed-upon tariff, where one would naturally suppose that if the managers were really in earnest they would stand by their pledge, the peculiar nature of the railroad prevented a satisfactory result. The rate-making power was turned over to numerous subordi- nate officials,. over whom it is almost impossible to keep a close watch and to whom motives of honesty do not strongly appeal. As Fink said in one of his reports to the Bureau of Statistics, " This history of the management of the transpor- tation business is constantly repeating itself. The general managers or heads of the departments attend generally to the establishment of rates, and make agreements with each other, and to this extent, but no further, this important business may 1 Railroad Question, p. 193. 2 Dabney — " Public Regulation of Railways," p. 144. 28 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. be said to be under their control ; but no sooner is it believed that one or the other of the competing lines has violated the agreement, and tries to deceive, whether this be a fact or not, the management is of necessity surrendered into the hands of subordinates, the soliciting commission agents, to whom the general instructions are given to do as others are doing, or supposed to be doing ;" * in other words, to make any rate they please, no matter how low. That even a railroad president did not have control sufficient to enable him to prevent his road from violating an agreement, was clearly brought out in the testimony before the Cullom Committee in 1885, when Charles Francis Adams, then presi- dent of the Union Pacific, said that, curious as it might seem, he was unable to prevent cutting by his subordinates. His testimony is so suggestive on this point, and the idea is so well brought out in the testimony, that I quote exactly what he said : 2 Mr. Adams. — If you could provide any way by which all freight and passenger agents could be absolutely debarred from making reductions from published rates, and from deceiving each other in some way or other while doing it, you would be very much more successful than I have been in my limited sphere. You would suppose that at any rate the president of a road would be able to get at the bottom of these things on his own road. I can only say that I cannot. Question. — As president of your road, can you not manage your own men ? Mr. Adams. — No ; theoretically I can, practically I cannot. Question. — You cannot control them ? Mr. Adams. — I want you to understand what I mean. I do not mean that I cannot issue orders, and I do not mean that in each individual case those orders will not be observed to a certain extent, but the freight agent and the passenger agent is under a terrible strain all the time. He is working for his living. He is judged by results. All the time he has to meet the sharpest of sharp practices. If he is successful, and gets what is called his "share of the business," that is all right. Question. — It is all right in the estimation of the company ? Mr. Adams. — I of course mean in the estimation of his superiors. If he does not get his "share of the business," he is very apt to be told some day that his 1 Internal Commerce of United States for 1876. 1 Cullom Committee Report, Part II, testimony, p. 1210. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 29 services are no longer needed. Accordingly he will have recourse to every con- ceivable evasion. "Smartness," as it is called, thus becomes the quality most highly prized, especially in subordinates. Honesty and good faith are scarcely regarded. Certainly they are not tolerated at all if they interfere with a man's " getting his share of the business." Gradually this demoralizing spirit of low cunning has pervaded the entire system. Its moral tone is deplorably low. This is the root of the trouble as it exists to-day. That healthy, mutual confidence, which is the first essential to prosperity in all transactions between man and man, does not exist in the American railroad service taken as a whole. Of course there are exceptions to this statement. But as a rule, agreements are made only to be broken, and superior officials, under the fear of " getting left," as the expression goes, are constantly shutting their eyes to acts of cheating and evasion on' the part of their subordinates, which are in direct disregard of solemn agreements those superior officers have themselves made. The blame for violating these agreements is not to be placed wholly at the feet of the subordinate officials of the competing roads. An unscrupulous manager would not hesitate to in- crease his business by a reduction in rates as long as he could hope to escape detection. Of course, as soon as the other agreeing roads discovered the condition of affairs, they would retaliate by offering still lower rates to close-tongued shippers, and the violation of the agreement was sure to be discovered sooner or later. In fact, there was little danger that they would not discover such violations ; often they thought they had detected a violation which had really not been committed. The roads were extremely suspicious of each other, knowing full well the advantages which would accrue to the road who could successfully keep secret the fact that it was asking a slightly reduced rate. In consequence, the roads were only too ready to listen to stories of violations of agreements by their rivals, and as it was to the interest of a shipper to make one line think its rival was already violating the agreement, the result can be imagined. Sometimes the roads made agreements, when they intended, at the very time that they signed the paper, to break them as soon as possible. After such an agreement there was a race to see which line could break the agreement first and thus 30 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. enjoy a temporary gain until the others would make like reductions. Fink describes this state of affairs very clearly in an address to the Southern Railway and Steamship Associa- tion in 1876, when he said : A number of competing lines agree upon certain rates to be charged by each, and pledge themselves to strictly maintain the same. There may be some of the managers who honestly mean to carry out the agreement, but generally there are others who make agreements with the intention to break them, and merely for the purpose of taking advantage of the more honest. The fact that these agreements are hardly ever carried out has been fully established by past experience. The managers have no longer confidence that they can ever be carried out, and there seems to be a tacit understanding that agreements to restore and maintain rates, after a period during which low rates prevailed, are, in most cases, merely made for the purpose of practicing deception upon each other, starting for a higher scale of rates in order to secure, for a short period at least, some remuneration for the work performed, until low rates are reached again in the natural course of events. This mode of transacting business, based upon deception and dishonesty, has been elevated into a business principle in the management of railroad property, and is pronounced by many experienced railroad managers and general freight agents as the only possible or practicable mode upon which competitive business can be conducted. Although Fink based the foregoing statement upon his experience with the railroads in the South, what he said would apply with equal force to the railroads in other parts of the country. All the railroad companies discovered, sooner or later, that agreements based merely on the word of the managers of the rival lines were of no avail in counteracting the influence of that disturbing factor, competition. Mere parole promises had failed, the law would not help the roads to enforce their agreements, and the railroad man was faced with a problem, the solution of which was necessary to pre- serve not only his own existence, but also the business inter- ests of the community as a whole. How were the roads to prevent the evil results of competition : secret cutting or personal discrimination, and open cutting, place discriminations and bankruptcy ? That was the problem. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 31 And this problem was solved in an intensely practical way — by removing the temptation which prompted the roads to violate an agreement. Some shrewd Yankee discovered that the railroad managers were only human — that, like the rest of us, they resemble the man in " Life " who said the only thing he couldn't resist was temptation — and accordingly for- mulated a device which would remove the temptation to violate agreements. Agreements to Divide Traffic. Idea at Basis of Pooling Agreements. — The idea at the bot- tom of all pooling agreements is to remove the temptation to violate them. A simple agreement based on word of honor failed. An agreement where each company made a large deposit to be forfeited in event of a violation of agreement failed, because of the possibility that a secret violation might •escape detection. If, however, a road is told — " you can haul ■one-third of the traffic between Chicago and Omaha" — that joad is not going to make secret rebates or discriminations, because they will only cause loss. Of course a road will yield to the temptation to cut if it can secure greater earnings by so doing, but if a manager knows that he is going to get ■only a certain portion of the traffic hauled on all the roads, he also knows that every rebate is just so much paid out of the coffers of the road for no return. The object of the pool was to maintain rates ; it attained that object by removing all temptation to charge any other rate. At least that was the foundation of the ideal pool, and an so far as that was the foundation, the pool was successful. Early History. — Exactly when and where the idea of pool- ing Originated is difficult to determine. From the very nature ■of things, their early history is obscure and almost impossible to be gotten at (if indeed it ever existed in any tangible shape). The first pools were formed before railway affairs were the 32 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. object of public investigation. The roads, of course, made every effort to keep the facts secret, meagre and indefinite ; the charming frankness which prompted President Thomson, of the Pennsylvania, to openly allude to an agreement in his reports for 1855 and 1858, soon ceased to prevail. Hadley says, "the earliest railroad pools were probably developed in New England, but they were on a small scale, and the whole thing was often so quietly done that their very exist- ence was almost unsuspected." 1 President Fish, of the Illinois Central, in speaking of the trunk line pools said, some years ago, that " the pooling idea is not so recent as might be sup- posed, however. It was introduced into New England and quietly used for a long time." These pools did not have any great influence on railway conditions in New England and they have little more than an historical significance. Pools in the West. — The first great instance of an application of the apportionment idea to competing roads, which has had important history, occurred in the West — on the three lines- running between Omaha and Chicago. In 1 870, the Chicago- Omaha pool was formed by the Chicago & Northwestern, the Chicago, Rock Island & Pacific, and the Chicago, Burlington & Quincy Railroads. In that year these three roads determined that the receipts from through traffic played too important a part in their total revenue to be trifled with, and accordingly made an arrangement whereby each road should be guaranteed its share of such traffic. The three- roads enjoyed practically equal advantages in competition — length, grades, etc., being almost identical — and the agreement provided that each of the three was entitled to haul 33^ per cent of the total through traffic between Chicago and Omaha. The pool established the following arrangement : 2 the through business, without any solicitation on the part of the companies,. 1 Railroad Transportation, p. 91. 5 Annual Report for 1878 of the Iowa State Board of Railroad Commissioners, p. 48. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 33 "was to take any of the three routes, the rates being uniform ; each road was allowed to retain 45 per cent of the passenger, and 50 per cent of the freight gross earnings, the remaining percentages being equally divided among the three companies. Later the agreement as to passenger business was slightly modified, so that all gross receipts from passengers going East and from travelers buying tickets at Chicago going West were equally divided. Although there was a State law x in Iowa prohibiting pool- ing of earnings between parallel lines, this arrangement was not illegal, as the pool applied only to traffic between Council Bluffs and Chicago, which being interstate commerce, was not subject to legislative control by the State of Iowa. This pool was unpopular in the State of Iowa, but the State railroad commission sided with the railroads in the matter. In one of their reports they say, 2 " We look upon the pool as the only agency that can compel the through traffic to bear, as it should, its proportion of the interest on the cost and the expense of maintaining and operating the roads." Later, speaking of the danger of the pools being broken, they said, 3 "The practice that has been so much in vogue, since railroad •competition became strong, of carrying through business at rates that were not remunerative, and making up the losses on local business, is, we think, a mistaken one. We see no simpler method of reaching a fair compensation for through traffic than that adopted by the Iowa pool lines, and we believe that to break the pool and open a warfare would be an unfortunate move." Thus in 1878, we find a State board of •commissioners recognizing the great evil that resulted from place discriminations and the benefit, to at least the local shippers, which resulted from a successful pool. Looking at the situation merely from the standpoint of the inhabitants of » Section 1297, Code of 1873. a First Annual Report, p. 48. ••Ibid., p. 49. 34 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. the State, who were of course only indirectly affected by the pool, they realized 1 that " a wrong is done the producer and shipper if the through business is carried at a loss, and the loss made up from local or Iowa business." The Chicago-Omaha pool continued in operation, on the whole successfully, until 1884, when it merged into a larger association known as the Western Freight Association. I say " on the whole successfully," for there was not a complete harmony in its operations during the fourteen years. 2 In the summer of 1882, there was, according to the report for that year of the Iowa State Board of Railroad Commissioners, 3 a disagreement concerning the distribution of freight, and a war of rates followed, continuing until October. Although this war came to an end in October of the same year, the settlement of the dispute was not finally concluded until the formation of the Western Freight Association. Here were united the several disturbing elements which had prevented a really successful working of the pool since 1880, and a form of organization and government was adopted closely allied to that of the Southwestern Association. 4 This new association included all the roads operating between Chicago, Milwaukee and St. Louis on the east and Omaha and Council Bluffs on the west. Operating immediately to the north, the Northwestern Traffic Association comprised all roads engaged in the trans- portation of freight between Chicago and Milwaukee on the one hand, and St. Paul, Minneapolis and Minnesota Transfer on the other. All roads east of the Missouri River and west of Chicago and St. Louis (excepting the St. Louis & San Francisco) that 1 Report for 1878, p. 49. s Larrabee is accordingly mistaken when he says (on p. 194) that this pool " lasted fourteen years without a break." 3 Annual Report for 1882 (Nov. 30), p. 48. 4 Cullom Com. Rept., p. 231. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 35 carried business destined to or originating in Colorado and Utah, were united in the Colorado-Utah Association. In line with this association, although distinct from it, was the Colo- rado Railway Association, which comprised the roads west of the Missouri River engaged in the transportation of freight traffic to and from competitive points in Colorado. Then there was the Pacific Coast Association, which included all roads east of the Missouri River and St. Paul, and west of Chicago, Milwaukee and St. Louis (again excepting the St. Louis & San Francisco), which carry business destined to or from points on the Pacific Coast, including Oregon, Washing- ton and British Columbia. Immediately west of this compact and fitting into it, was the Transcontinental Association, which included all roads west of St. Paul, Omaha and Kansas City, and a north and south line drawn through the two last named cities on the east and the Pacific Coast on the west. All of these compacts were governed by rules similar to those adopted for the guidance of the Southwestern Railway Asso- ciation, to be later described. At the time of the Cullom Committee's investigation in 1885, the whole of the competitive traffic of the West and Northwest was under the control of some one of the nume- rous traffic associations. An unsuccessful effort had been made in 1878, to unite all of the roads and associations inter- ested in the movement of through Eastbound freights into one gigantic pool. 1 The idea was that Chicago was to be the pooling centre, a schedule of rates fixed for it, and the rates of all the railroad centres in the West and the Northwest dependent upon it. The combination was to comprise more than forty companies, controlling over 25,000 miles of road. The scheme was actually tried for three months, but it was beyond the power of man to harmonize such a multitude of discordant elements. It was after the failure of this gigantic Western pool, which had really been organized under the 1 Larrabee, p. 200. 36 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. protectorate of the trunk lines, that the companies which had composed it formed, as their individual interests dictated, most of the various combinations already described. One of the most instructive parts of the history of railroad combinations to overcome competition is to be found in the history of the struggle between the competing roads connect- ing the Missouri River points with Chicago and St. Louis, respectively. For some years after the roads from Chicago and St. Louis were completed through to the Missouri River, they agreed upon rates of freight, 1 but, as no pledge for their maintenance was given, the rates were not adhered to. Charges of bad faith, denials and counter-charges were of common occurrence. The inevitable war followed, which attained its most severe aspect in the spring of 1876, when rates fell so low that no profit remained in the business. In order to restore rates to a paying basis, the managers of the interested lines met at St. Louis on May 4, 1876. There they entered into an agreement of a twofold nature — to maintain rates and to establish the differentials which should prevail between the St. Louis and Chicago rates to and from the Missouri River points. This effort met with no success, however, because there was no agreement as to the share of the traffic which each road should be allowed to carry. This defect, however, was soon discovered by the managers, and on the twelfth of September following (1876) a division of the earnings derived from the traffic was agreed upon between the several lines. The organization formed for effecting this purpose was known as the Southwestern Railway Rate Association. There was no attempt made to force traffic over a particular line which was not securing its share of the freight ; each road hauled all the freight offered it at agreed rates, then, after deducting 50 per cent from the gross earnings on such traffic to pay 1 All information as to this pool is based on the Report for 1879 on the Internal Commerce of the United States, unless otherwise stated. Chap. VI, Appendix 4, and Part II, p. 174. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 37 operating expenses, the remaining 50 per cent was turned over to a common "pool." This pool was in turn divided among the roads in accordance with a fixed percentage already agreed upon. Later, when the new revised agree- ment went into effect (September 1, 1877) the amount allowed each road for hauling was reduced to 40 per cent. The remaining 60 per cent was divided among the roads in proportion to the business done by the several roads during the past year. One very valuable feature of this association was the clear- ing house under the control of the Secretary, who was required to audit all accounts and settle balances between the roads. Unfortunately this part of the association's organization did not survive the reorganizations which soon followed. On the fourteenth of March, 1878, the association was dis- rupted by the withdrawal of the St. Louis roads, which, having paid $150,000 in balances to the Chicago roads, determined that the large movement of wheat to St. Louis was natural, and so they resolved to pay no more such balances. How- ever, the opening of the Lake navigation soon made the balance the other way, and accordingly on the fourth of May the association was reconstructed. The associated roads were divided into three divisions — the Chicago, the St. Louis and the Hannibal. The division of traffic was as follows : Chicago Division, 45 per cent; St. Louis Division, 45 per cent ; Hannibal Division, 10 per cent. The several roads in each division agreed among themselves what proportion of the share allotted to the whole division should be carried by each individual line. This agreement lasted less than a year, being formally dis- solved on the twelfth of April, 1879. Then followed one of the most severe contests in the history of railroad wars. The rates fell so low that the business carried up to September 1 2, a period of five months, entailed an actual loss in revenue of about two million dollars. 38 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. On September 15, 1879, the Southwestern Railway Rate Association was reorganized, when it took the form to which it substantially adhered up to 1887. This agreement made provision for a resort to arbitration in the event of any con- troversy. A method of securing impartial arbitrators was embodied in the agreement. This pool continued in substantially the same form until 1887, 1 with no little success, although the " intractableness " of the average railroad manager often aroused the ire of their commissioner, J. W. Midgely. In his statement to the Cullom Committee in 1885, he said: 2 Notwithstanding it is to the immediate interest of a road when it becomes party to a pool to adhere strictly to the agreement, such is the weakness of human nature, under the blandishments of shippers, that few are the number who firmly resist. Soon the breach of faith is discovered, whereupon confidence is destroyed, and with difficulty are the others restrained from making reprisals. If the viola- tions are repeated, protective measures are adopted, and the agreed rates are ceased to be regarded. This has been the mortifying experience of all compacts, thus compelling the admission that no means have yet been devised whereby an absolute maintenance of established rates can be assumed. Self interest has failed to effect it, hence compulsory legislation could not be relied on to accomplish it. Yet, despite their imperfections, the fact remains that the pools which have been wisely ordered have approximated the desired results, whereas, all other forms of regulation have failed. In a statement made to the Bureau of Statistics in 1879, 3 this same commissioner explained what was perhaps the greatest cause of the lack of confidence among the members of the pool — that is, the various compacts were always ham- pered by a conscious weakness, arising from the fact that they depended solely upon the honor of the members. The railroad manager knew that he could not go into court and sue for balances withheld from him, hence there was a constant dis- trust lest when any member should be called upon to pay over 1 Cullom Committee Report, p. 230. "Ibid. ' Report on Internal Commerce — Reports of Experts, p. 58. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 39 a large amount he would refuse, and a disruption ensue. It was on account of this that Midgely was in favor of legalizing pooling agreements. Pools in the South. — The really sharp competition between the railroads of the South came later than it did in the North and West, but when it did come (shortly after the war) it came in earnest. As Vigil Powers, later a commissioner of the Southern Railway and Steamship Association, said, "there was not so much business as all could do. Indeed, any of these lines, with a comparatively small output for rolling stock, can do all the business to any, indeed to all, competitive points named in our circulars." 1 The natural result was the presence of the evils of secret rebates, open cuttings and wars, and place discriminations. Rate wars were so severe that Mr. Fink estimated the loss caused by them to be such that gross earnings were 42 per cent less than what they would have been under regular rates. 2 Joseph Nimmo, after reciting the various abuses caused by competition in the South and the evil effects which they had on business in general, concludes his sketch of the conditions which gave rise to combination in the South, as follows : 3 " This condition of affairs not only operated prejudiciously to the interests of trade by breaking down competition, but it also operated detrimentally to the interests of the Southern railroads and of the coastwise steamer lines, by virtually placing them under the control of a few large shippers, whose interest it was, by secret operations, to keep the managers of the various lines in a continual struggle with each other." The railroads of the South made their first effort to over- come these evils by co-operation in December, 1873, when 1 Circular letters of the Southern Railway and Steamship Association, Vol. 3, p. 991 . ( Quoted by Hudson. ) 2 Circular letters, Vol. I, p. 278. Also quoted by Hudson. In fact most of my information in regard to conditions in the South has been derived from his excellent study in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. V. 3 Internal Commerce of the United States, p. 171 (1879). 40 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. four roads connecting Atlanta, Ga., with the seaboard, 1 agreed upon divisions of the cotton business. 2 This, however, cov- ered only the cotton season of that year. In order to bring about some permanent means of settling the difficulties that were constantly arising between the Southern roads, they held a meeting at Macon, Ga., on December 21, 1874. 3 An adjourned meeting was held in January, 1875, when an agreement was signed and a provisional apportionment of the traffic between competitive points was arranged for. 4 For the purpose of keeping the accounts a clearing-house was estab- lished. 5 In September of that year, a convention of managers of Southern railroads and steamship lines was held, at which Mr. Albert Fink presented a paper embodying the principal features of an organization. 6 In October, Mr. Fink was elected gen- eral commissioner, 7 and he immediately set to work to organize and put in motion the pool. The result was the Southern Railway and Steamship Association — the second apportionment scheme of any considerable magnitude and importance estab- lished in this country. The membership of this association comprised the railroads in the States of Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Tennessee and Alabama ; and also the steamship lines connecting these roads with Boston, New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore. 8 In accordance with its plan of organization, the associa- tion held an annual convention composed of one representative from each line. At this convention officers and an executive •Report on Internal Commerce (1879), p. 171. 2 Circular letters, Vol. 22, p. 1619. (Hudson.) 3 Hudson Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. V, p. 72. 4 Ibid. 5 Internal Commerce, p. 172. 6 Internal Commerce, 1879, p. 177. 'Circular letters, Vol. I, p. 18. 6 Internal Commerce, 1879, p. 172. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 41 committee were elected. A general commissioner had general charge of the workings of the agreement, being supposed to refer to the convention any matters with which he was unable to deal. This practice of referring details to the annual con- vention was found to be impracticable, so in 1883 an executive committee was provided for, to consist of the managers of each of the principal lines. This committee was given juris- diction over all joint traffic, but a unanimous vote was required for action. In the event of a failure to arrive at such a deci- sion, it was provided that the matter should be referred to a board of arbitration. The executive committee had subordi- nate to it a rate committee, which had control, subject to appeal, of rates and apportionments. The competitive traffic was apportioned among the rival roads by the executive committee, or, if a unanimous agree- ment could not be reached, by a board of arbitrators. The principle which guided the committee or the arbitrators in the division was that shares should be apportioned as nearly as possible to what each of the roads would get under nominal competitive conditions. Each road was expected to carry, as nearly as possible, its allotted amount. In case a road should carry more than its exact proportion, it was allowed, for the mere hauling, 20 per cent of the gross receipts from such excess, and the remaining 80 per cent was turned into the pool to be divided among the roads which had run behind their proportions. 1 At first the allowance for hauling was one-half cent per ton per mile, but this was abandoned in the later years of the pool, being considered too high. The evil which Midgely complained of so strongly in his Southwestern Association was also present in its Southern neighbor. The roads were slow in paying over the balances to those roads that had run behind. But this abuse was soon corrected by requiring each of the roads to deposit monthly 20 per cent of its gross receipts to the order of the 1 Hudson, p. 74. 42 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. commissioners. Then the commissioner, at the end of the month, paid over to the " short " roads the balance due them out of this deposit, returning the remainder of the 20 per cent to the original depositor. In other words, the association held funds belonging to each road sufficient to remove any temptation to withdraw from the association for the sake of keeping the bal- ance due another road. All danger of fraud, such as secret rebates, under-billing, incorrect classification, etc., was obviated by the complete power of the commissioner to examine all books and bills. The association's greatest source of danger lay in the diffi- culty of apportioning the traffic fairly among the several com- peting roads. 1 For example, in 1883, the East Tennessee became dissatisfied with an agreement which allowed it only 14 per cent of Montgomery cotton traffic ; it asserted that, to avoid paying the heavy penalty of $1.50 per bale for excess carried, they had been compelled to turn over to their com- petitors several thousand bales. In 1883—84, the cotton traffic accordingly was not pooled, and the East Tennessee carried over 27 per cent of the business, even though full association rates had been maintained. The matter was finally settled by arbitration, which gave the East Tennessee 22 per cent. The question of allotments was continually coming up and the number of routes on which the traffic was pooled was steadily increased up to 1887. At Atlanta, for example, the number of pooled routes had grown from 5 to 12. The arbi- trators were generally able to render a satisfactory decision, and where the roads became dissatisfied with a division and went out of the pool, the almost universal experience was that the greatly reduced charges, made during the ensuing rate war, necessitated a larger increase of traffic than could be secured. The result of the pool was not an elimination of competition. The agreement binding the association together was re-enacted every year, at which time were also re-enacted the allotments 1 Hudson, p. 83. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 43 of the traffic to each of the several competing roads. Between the periodical apportionments each road made a strong effort to get as much as possible of the available traffic, so that, even if all earnings on an excess did have to be paid to the other roads, the next allotment would give to such a road a larger share. As Hudson puts it, 1 " Each road tried to carry as much freight as possible, so that, when the next contract came to be made, it might demand with some show of reason a larger share of business. It is competition of this sort that is advantageous, not competition with little Or no regard to the cost of doing the work." 2 The rates made by the association were regulated by certain external competitive forces over which the association had little or no control. It was found that if the rates between Atlanta and New York were increased beyond a certain limit, the trade of Atlanta would be driven to other competing trade centres. Again, sailing vessels competed with the steamer lines of this association between the Northern and Southern ports. Rates by sailing-vessel and rail between the Northern ports and points in the territory of the association had to be met by the association. Besides this there was regulating influence of rates via the Mississippi River, and the railroads extending from that river into the territory of the association. In spite of these influences, however, the association was able to exercise a very large discretionary power over the rates which were to prevail to and from all points within its terri- torial limits in the Southern States. In its dealings with lines that would not become members the association used its powers in an unjustifiable manner. In the revised rules adopted in December, 1876, the following provision occurs : " If any company owning or operating a 2 Larrabee's statement (p. 19S), that there was no inducement for any company to seek to carry more than its allotment " the nominal price allowed for carriage on an excess being so low " is thus not borne out by the facts. 44 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. line of transportation in connection with the roads or lines of companies, parties hereto, shall refuse to become a member of the association, such line shall, as far as practicable, be refused recognition as part of a through line." l In other words, such lines were to be boycotted. This rule does not appear in the later agreements, but, as a matter of fact, I believe the facts would bear me out in the statement that this principle was nevertheless adhered to, though to exactly what extent is of course impossible to determine. 2 For example, in 1877, the steamship lines between the Southern ports and Boston and New York refused to co-operate with the associa- tion in carrying out its rules. The commissioner accordingly authorized greatly reduced rail rates to Boston and New York, as well as to the South Atlantic ports. The result was that in three weeks the refractory steamship lines joined the as- sociation and rates were restored. 3 Another troublesome competition was found in that of the river steamboat lines. Often the differentials between two cities, such as St. Louis and East Cairo, were sufficient to allow the boats to charge under the association rates. To prevent this, in the case referred to, the rates to East Cairo were raised to make them the same as to Cairo, across the river. 4 Rates to Selina and Montgomery from the East were cut in a similar way by the New York and Mobile steamship lines. The association changed their rates to stop this; a few months later, the competition being withdrawn, the rates were restored. 5 The changes in the organization of the Southern Railway and Steamship Association after the passage of the Interstate Commerce Law in 1887 will be considered later. 1 Circular letters, Vol. 2, p. 598. •See Larrabee's " Railroad Question," and J. F. Hudson's "Railways and Republic." * Henry Hudson Quarterly Journal of Economics, p. 86. (Vol. V.) *Ibid. 'Ibid. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 45 Pools in the North. — The history of the attempts of the trunk lines to maintain rates and to overcome the effects of competition has already been considered. The nature of the competition between the rivals was so complicated that the resulting evils could not be overcome by mere agreements between the managers. The lesson had been learned by 1877, that, unless there were some way of removing the temptation to violate an agreement, the agreement might just as well not be made : and it was in that year that the new device for removing the temptation was first put into operation in the North. Agreements to divide the business in order to do away with competition had been used before that time, although with only limited scope. The first important combination of this kind in which the Northern railroads engaged was formed by those interested in the transportation of anthracite coal. The " anthracite coal combination," as it was called, had two distinct objects in view. First, to obtain a remunerative price for the coal by restricting its production ; and, second, to divide among the carriers, who were at the same time those most interested in the production, the total amount of com- petitive traffic according to certain fixed proportions. 1 Ruin- ous competition, i. e., competition in which the parties interested seemed to forget self-interest in a vain endeavor to over- come their rivals, had existed in coal mining and hauling to such a degree that in 1872 the roads entered into a com- pact for self-protection. 2 This compact continued in force from December 1, 1872, to August, 1876. 3 So long as this agree- ment was in force, all went well, but upon its dissolution the price of coal and rates of transportation fell so that several of the companies were obliged to cease paying dividends, one to obtain an extension of time from its creditors, and one to go 1 Ringwalt, p. 273. 'Internal Commerce Report, 1879, p. 179. 'Ibid., p. 180. 46 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. into the hands of a receiver. 1 The roads entered into another agreement on January 1, 1879, which lasted for one year. This agreement went to pieces at the end of the year, mainly because one of the roads refused to accept terms offered by the other roads. 2 From 1878 on to 1887, similar compacts were generally in force and they undoubtedly did much to check excessive competition. They were scarcely ever fully effective, however, mostly because the Pennsylvania refused to enter into a combination which had for its object the restriction of the production of coal ; but there were number- less other dissensions and legal hostilities continually disturb- ing things. 3 The device known as the " evener system " was the form of combination which undoubtedly provoked the strongest public censure and led to the worst abuses. The first appli- cation of the "evener" principle to competitive traffic was made in 1875 to the live stock traffic between Chicago and the East. 4 For this traffic there had been a tremendous com- petition between the trunk lines, live stock being frequently transported at less than cost. 5 The evener plan involved two steps — first, to determine what part of the traffic should be hauled by each of the competing lines ; and second, to enter into an association with certain of the principal shippers, who agreed to divert their shipments over the different lines so as to secure to each road its allotted portion. These shippers were known as " eveners," and in consideration of their services as such, they were allowed a rebate not only on the shipments made by themselves, but also on all those made by other parties. The result was to give them a great advantage over 1 Ringwalt, p. 273. « Hudson, p. 222. 'Ringwalt, p. 273. Consult, also, G. O. Virtue's paper on "The Anthracite Combinations," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 5, for a fall and careful history of the coal carriers' pools. 'Internal Commerce Report, 1879, p. 1 77. * Hepburn Testimony (Blanchard), p. 3316. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 47 their competitors in business, often resulting in a monopoly. According to Ringwalt, 1 the scheme met with such strenuous and determined opposition that it was abandoned by the rail- roads in 1879, si nce which time the transportation of live stock has been subject to regulations similar to the other forms of traffic. The greatest advantages granted to any evener were those given to the Standard Oil Company. This company received as a compensation for so dividing the petroleum traffic between the different lines carrying oil, special advantages, 2 which enabled the company to establish a monopoly of great strength. When in 1 877 there came a cessation of the trunk line wars, whose history we have already considered, the com- panies had learned a very valuable lesson. In order that they might profit to the utmost from their experience, they called Albert Fink to their assistance, the man who had been so successful in the South. The four trunk lines organized July 1, 1 877, 'and established an executive committee, with Albert Fink as chairman. During this year the Westbound traffic from New York was pooled and the traffic apportioned among them according to the following percentages : s The New York Central received 33 per cent, the Erie 33 per cent, the Pennsylvania 25 per cent and the Baltimore & Ohio 9 per cent. If any road received more than its allotted share of the freight, the amount of the excess was to be turned over to a road which was deficient. The conditions involving the East- bound traffic were more complicated, and a division was not completed until two years later. 4 On the seventeenth of December, 1877, the railroads in what is now called Central Traffic Territory — the region between l p- 273- 2 " Railways and the Republic," Chap. III. Also Hepburn Committee Report. 8 Ringwalt, p. 274. 'Hadley, p. 95. 48 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Buffalo and Pittsburg and the Mississippi River — formed an organization and established an executive committee similar to the one that the trunk lines had appointed. The next step was to form a joint organization to supervise the competitive business, in which the trunk line and the roads west of them both participated. An organization was formed similar to the Southern Railway and Steamship Association. This new asso- ciation went by the name of the Joint Executive Committee, and Albert Fink was chairman. This association, according to Hadley, was never so strong as its Southern prototype. There was no clearing-house, and no central authority with power to form pooling agreements — the voluntary action of each road was required in every case. 1 There were three dis- tinct sets of activities assigned to this new body: 1. The decision of what differential should be allowed Phila- delphia and Baltimore, by virtue of their disadvantageous posi- tion, as compared with New York and Boston. 2. What percentage of the traffic hauled should be allowed each of the available roads. 3. Consideration of general business arrangements, matters such as rates, hauling of joint traffic, etc., under the Joint Executive Committee. 2 This arrangement was not satisfactory to the people of New York, who claimed that their city suffered in proportion as its more favored rivals, Philadelphia and Baltimore, became commercially more prosperous than in periods of unregulated competition. Simon Sterne claimed, in a letter published in the Report on Internal Commerce for 1879,* "that the effect was to transfer rental values in New York to Philadelphia and Baltimore." Accordingly in the year 1881, the agreement was violated by the New York Central, which avowed its 1 Hepburn Testimony (Blanchard), p. 3120, I, etc.; also, Fink's Railway Prob- lem and its Solution, 1880. 1 Internal Commerce Report, 1879, p. 165. 'Appendix, No. 2. Co-operation of Competing Railroads, 49 intentions of returning to the status of competition. 1 A fierce war then followed, which lasted for eight months, when the roads decided to put the matter before a board of arbitrators. A board was selected, to consist of Messrs. Thurman, Wash- burn and Cooley. There were no charges of unfairness against these men, who rendered a report on the situation and on the results of their investigation, but the problem was not solved ; they gave an impartial abstract of both sides of the dispute and decided that the existing differentials between seaboard cities were reasonable. At about the same time Albert Fink made his now classic " Report on Adjustment of Railroad Transportation Rates." He showed in effect that the seaboard cities were simply intermediate points en route from Chicago to Liverpool, and argued that the differential rate ought to counterbalance exactly the difference in the cost of ocean carriage, if the problem was to be solved on a theoretically correct basis. Practically, he said, things would quickly adjust themselves to an arbitrary basis, but an effort should be made to fix that basis so as to prevent the instability consequent upon continu- ous readjustments. With Fink's assistance a peace was patched up between the roads on the basis of this principle. But in 1884, war broke out again and assumed a very serious form, although the harmful results to the roads were not so marked because of the large traffic available. In November, 1885, the differences were settled by the adoption of an agreement and code of rules. The combina- tion then formed is important as marking the result of thirty years of experience, and the principles on which the combina- tion was based formed the latest product of that evolution which was so abruptly terminated by the passage of the Inter- state Commerce Act in 1887. Without unduly extending this narrative by including an account of other pooling organiza- tions that were established before 1887, it will suffice to pre- sent the plan adopted by the trunk lines in 1885. 1 Fink, Report on Adjustment of Railroad Transportation Rates, 1882, p. 7. 50 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. The purposes of this agreement are set forth in the following preamble : Whereas, past experience has fully established the fact that the joint action of competing railroad companies in establishing and adhering to uniform rates of transportation for like services to the public is necessary in order to avoid the evils of unjust discrimination and fluctuating rates, so injurious to commercial as well as to the railroad interests ; Therefore the parties above named 1 enter into the following contract for the purpose of jointly establishing tariffs over their respective roads on competitive' traffic, both passenger and freight, and of publishing said tariffs and strictly main- taining the same. This agreement provided in brief, for submitting disputes which could hot otherwise be settled, to arbitration ; for hold- ing Western connections in check by joint action of the agree- ing roads ; for joint schedules and classifications, and finally, for division of the competitive traffic among the several com- peting roads. 2 In order to carry out these provisions a trunk line organ- ization was formed and a body of rules adopted. The organ- ization consisted of a presidents' committee, which served as a court of last resort for the settlement of disputes before an appeal to arbitration ; of an executive committee, which was charged with carrying out the previous committee's orders, and also to settle problems, if possible, without a reference to the higher committee, and of freight and passenger committees,, which had charge of their respective branches of the traffic. A permanent arbitrator was also appointed by the presidents' committee, to whom was " submitted for final decision all questions arising under the contract upon which the parties thereto cannot agree." It was provided that, in case of one road discovering a rival in the violation of the agreement, the executive committee was to be notified and given all possible i Grand Trunk of Canada, New York Central, Erie, Delaware, Lackawanna & Western, Pennsylvania, West Shore and Baltimore & Ohio. 2 Cullom Committee Report, p. 237. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 51 information, but " pending the action of the executive com- mittee, the complaining party shall not meet any alleged reductions in rates or take any separate action whatsoever in violation of the contract, all action necessary to protect the trunk lines and their affiliated roads shall be taken jointly." 1 Under the provision as to dividing the traffic among the several competing roads, all danger of failure to pay over excess balances was obviated by the requirement that balances should be settled monthly, and that each of the roads should deposit with a trustee an amount of money sufficient to enable the drafts for monthly settlement of balances to be drawn upon it. 2 Throughout the whole history of the attempts made by the trunk lines to combine, we find a disturbing factor at work which would often upset a combination almost as soon as it was made. This factor was the competition with the carriers by water, which was an ever potent force and one which could not be restrained. That the effect of the water route by the Lakes and over the Erie Canal and Hudson River was to break down the pools arranged by the trunk lines is brought out very clearly in the evidence before the Hepburn Committee. For instance, a larger shipper in New York, Charles Greiner, 3 who enjoyed a special rate from the New York Central, testified as follows : Q. What ground was there for withdrawing your special rate for a time ? A. There was some understanding between the roads — some pooling arrange- ment, I believe — that they agreed not to give any special rate to anybody ; it was in the winter, and, of course, then we had to pay full rates ; it only lasted for a little while — for a month or two — and we told them that if they did not give us special rates we should not ship by them the following summer, but would use the canal. Q. And they then gave you the special rate ? A. Yes, sir. 1 Cullom Committee Report, p. 240. 'Agreement — Article VII. * Hepburn Testimony, p. 2169. 52 Railroad Co-operation in tJu United States. This single piece of testimony contains in a nutshell the nature of the agreements made by the railroads. In order to do away with the special rate, they combine and agree to give no more, all goes well for a short time, and then there comes in a disturbing factor which cannot be controlled. The com- petition with the canal was one of several influences which rendered any remedy for railway competition so difficult. There was also the competition with other routes ; large por- tions of the crops of the West could be shipped either to the Atlantic seaboard or to the Gulf ports, according to the rela- tive charges. A constant competition prevailed between the two great outlets. Then, in addition to the numerous exter- nal competitive influences that were at work, there was quite a scope for competition to have an influence even between roads which were strictly regulated by pools. There was the constant desire to increase traffic, even if there were no return, in order that at the next periodic revision of the apportion- ment, a larger share might be allowed the road showing an excess. These competitive influences, both external and internal, while they were of course not so potent a factor as absolutely unrestrained competition would have been, were nevertheless of great significance in determining the actual results of the pools. As to the actual course of rates during the ten years in which the traffic on the trunk lines was pooled, it seems from reliable evidence that they were certainly not extortionate ; in fact Blanchard goes so far as to say 1 that " no American pool can be cited which advanced rates unless to restore unjustifi- able rate war reductions." His figures substantiating this statement are certainly reliable, at least so far as they apply to the trunk line pools. When the pool was organized (in 1877) the average of the eastward and westward tariff class rates between Chicago and New York was 71 cents per hundred 'New York Mail and Express — "Railway Pooling," Paper No. 4. Co-operation of Competing Railroads. 53 pounds. When pooling was discontinued in 1886, the rate was under 50 cents. 1 Blanchard's figures 2 as to the actual tonnage transferred from one road to another under the pool, are especially signi- ficant. In the last year of the eastern pools from Chicago, St. Louis, Peoria, Cincinnati, Louisville and Indianapolis, all the tonnage changed from one route to another at all these points was only 22 per cent of the total. The cash paid by the same companies to each other in money settlements did not average nine cents per ton. (The significance of this figure is seen when it is compared with the fifty cent reductions which were usually made during rate wars.) Of about $12,000,000 pooled freight earnings, less than $300,000 changed hands. These figures certainly speak well for the success of those who arranged the apportionments. REVIEW. The pooling system of restraining competition, which grew up after the failure of the simple rate agreements, had its -origin between 1870 and 1880. During those years the idea was planted all over the country and so general was its growth in the next few years that by 1887, nearly all classes of traffic for which a considerable number of railway companies actively •competed, had been pooled. In all of these combinations the principle was the same, although the method of its execution often differed. Several competing roads would determine, as nearly as possible, what share of the competitive traffic fell to each under the nominal conditions of competition, then they would agree that each road should haul as nearly as possible the amount to which it was entitled, and in case a road should receive more business than it was allotted, the matter was easily adjusted either by hauling the freight and transferring the receipts to the road • "Railway Pooling," Blanchard, No. 4. 2 Ibid. 54 Railroad Co-operation in tlie United States. with a deficit, or by transferring the freight itself. Very often there were disturbing factors which the roads could not draw into the combination and which continually interfered with the satisfactory workings of the agreement. The influence of water competition in regulating railroad pools was emphasized by the Cullom Committee ; they say in their report 1 " that their influence (i. e., of the water routes) is not confined within the limits of the territoiy immediately accessible to water com- munication, but extends and controls railroad rates at such remote and interior points as have competing lines reaching means of transport by water. Competition between railroads sooner or later leads to combination or consolidation, but neither can prevail to secure unreasonable rates in the face of direct competition with free, natural or artificial water routes." The agreements and organizations which have been described do not include all traffic associations, but those mentioned are typical. They were all based on one principle, had similar obstacles in their way, and met with more or less success according as they were able to overcome those obstacles. In all associations there existed, even under the strictest arrange- ments, competitive influences which could not be smothered, such as the desire of the individual road to increase its allot- ment; formation of roundabout routes in case of too high rates; presence of water lines, both canal and river, which were difficult if not impossible to harmonize in a pool with railroads ; the rivalry of markets ; these and numerous others which exerted a strong regulative if not actually restrictive control over the operations of the railroads in their pools. 1 p. 170. CHAPTER III. LEGISLATION AND ITS RESULTS. Prohibitive Legislation. PuSIic Opposition. — The early combinations of the trunk lines met with an outburst of popular animosity, the more radi- cal side of which found its expression in the New York and National Anti-Monopoly Leagues that flourished in the sixties. The first really serious opposition arose, however, after the results of the Saratoga conference became known. According to Charles Francis Adams, 1 an " alarm and popular clamor was excited throughout the country. It was looked upon as a movement against public policy, and the plan for operating the combined roads which resulted from its deliberations was denounced as one which, if successfully carried out, must neces- sarily result in the destruction of all competition for carriage between the seaboard and the West, and as consequently turn- ing over to a band of heartless monopolists the vital work of transporting the cereals of the interior to their market. The cry of ' railroad kings ' and ' railroad extortioners ' was at once raised from every quarter." Public opposition to traffic agreements and pools has been of two distinct kinds : First, that arising from those shippers and communities which benefited by the discriminating rates caused by unrestricted competition ; and, second, the more general feeling of fear as to the possible results of a system which placed such power in the hands of a few men and which seemed to undermine the foundation of the industrial system by substituting monopoly for competition. The first form of opposition has had a much greater influ- ence than would at first be supposed. The community which i P . 151. (55) 56 Railroad Co-operation in the United States, was served by only one railroad, instead of encouraging any system which would place it more on an equality with its rival neighbor that happened to enjoy competition, spent its whole energy either in denouncing the local rates as extor- tionate or in attempts to induce another line to build a con- nection. For instance, there was a tremendous opposition in Iowa to the combination arranged by the three great lines running across the State (known as the Chicago-Omaha Pool), and yet their own State commission warned the inhabi- tants of the State that, so far from injuring the local traffic, the real effect of the pool was to make the competitive traffic (in which the inhabitants of the State had no interest) pay its share of the fixed expenses and thus to relieve the local traffic of a proportionate burden. 1 The individual merchants who suffered from personal discriminations, spent their energy try- ing to get a more favorable rate, and in their rage at being baffled they denounced every action of the railroad managers, including the attempt on the part of the roads to eliminate the causes of discrimination. Of course, those merchants and communities which enjoyed the " advantages of competition " would make a tremendous outcry if the roads took any steps to deprive them of what was considered to be their due, viz., discriminating rates in their favor. The more serious, and of course earnest, opposition to the combination came, however, from the great bulk of the com- munity, that large portion of the public not directly affected by the actual discriminations. Of this opposition, we have already noted an instance in the outburst caused by the Sara- toga conference ; the basis of the opposition in this case was typical of the general opposition to pools and agreements throughout the country. This feeling, as tersely summed up by the former Interstate Commerce Commissioner, W. G. Veazey, is that the public has just as much interest in prevent- ing the railroads from forming powerful and overshadowing 1 Iowa State Report, 1883, pp. 4285-86. Legislation and Its Results. 57 combinations as it has in restraining persons engaged in indus- trial pursuits from banding together for purposes of gain. The opponents of pooling say, with reference to the carriers, " you transport our commodities, and we are willing that you should individually fix and charge a fair price for the service, but we are not willing to permit you to combine and by united action so adjust rates, facilities and methods of service over naturally competing lines, so, in fact, conduct the transporta- tion business of the country as to force us, your employers, into positions of subserviency which railway commissions and courts may find it difficult to relieve." l Both of these forms of opposition found expression in the Congressional debate in 1886-87, when the question as to the advisability of prohibiting pooling was decided in the affirma- tive. The arguments against pooling were admirably summar- ized by the Interstate Commerce Commission in its report for 1892. Although not in full sympathy with the views stated the commission gave a very fair and clear statement of the position held by the opponents of pooling. Those opposed to allowing pooling contracts criticised them as conspiracies in restraint of trade, as dangerous monopolies, as "rings" and "corners." They were alleged to have the effect of giving the railroads control of the transporta- tion, commerce, and wealth of the country, and to threaten the liberties of the people by ultimately dominating the measures and policy of the great political parties. It was asserted that such agreements were forbidden by the common law, by the constitutions of many of the States, and by a long line of constitutional decisions, that their effect was to substitute monopoly for competition, extortion for reasonable rates, and discrimination for equal treatment. It was claimed that the publication of tariffs and the uniformity of charges which other provisions of the law made mandatory would be aided in their beneficial purposes by prohibiting pooling rather than by permitting it, that pools had proven to be expensive, troublesome, and demoralizing to operating officials, and that they had often resulted in unre- munerative rates between competing points, the losses from which were recouped by excessive charges at local stations. In short, the belief was entertained that the legalization of these agreements was contrary to the general policy of the pro- posed statute. 1 Interstate Commerce Commission Report, 1893. Appendix D, p. 220. 5 8 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Legal Status of Pooling Contracts. — Under the common law, the pooling contract was treated by the courts as " extra- legal," i. e., while it was not a crime to be a party to such a contract, the courts refused to interfere if the agreeing parties did not adhere to the agreement. The principle on which the courts based their position is brought out by Spelling, in his treatise on " The Law of Pri- vate Corporations," where he says of pooling arrangements : " Courts long ago exercised jurisdiction to regulate rates of quasi-public corporations, and on the same principle will refuse to enforce pooling contracts between railroad and gas com- panies. Such contracts are void as against public policy. There is substantial harmony between the English and Ameri- can definitions of monopoly, the two countries agreeing that contracts entered into by and between two or more corpora- tions, the necessary result of whose performance will crush and destroy competition, are illegal." In spite of the extra-legal nature of the pooling contracts, which rendered them void and unenforcible by the courts, the railroads endeavored to combine. The strong popular oppo- sition to such action caused several of the States and later the United States to pass laws making such contracts criminal. The attitude of the individual States toward these combina- tions is given in Clarke's monograph on State Railway Com- missions, 1 where he summarizes the railroad laws of the various States. 2 In 1891 all traffic agreements between paral- lel roads were forbidden by either the constitutions or the statutes of Iowa, Minnesota, Kansas, Missouri, California, Alabama (when the object of agreement is to defeat com- petition), North Dakota, South Dakota, Oregon, Texas, Nebraska, North Carolina, Arkansas and Nevada. Federal Legislation Prohibiting Pools. — The traffic which was most concerned in the agreements of competing railroads was 1 Publications of American Economical Association, Vol. VI. 2 Table No. 4. Legislation and Its Results. 59 the through shipment which almost always passed through more than one State. In other words, the pool applied mainly to interstate commerce, over which the legislature of the indi- vidual State had no control. Accordingly the assistance of federal legislation was asked for. The Cullom Committee reported in favor of waiting for a recommendation from the proposed commission before any action be taken on so impor- tant a matter as the prohibition of pooling, 1 but the House was opposed to pooling and it carried its point. The fifth section of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 provides "that it shall be unlawful for any common carrier subject to the provisions of the act to enter into any contract, agreement, or combination with any other common carrier or carriers for the pooling of freights of different and competing railroads, or to divide between them the aggregate or net proceeds of the earnings of such roads, or any portion thereof, and in any case of an agreement for the pooling of freights as aforesaid, each day of its continuance shall be deemed a separate offence." The law further provides that any officer of a cor- poration who arranged or aided in forming a pooling agree- ment shall be deemed guilty of a misdemeanor and subject to a fine not to exceed five thousand dollars for each offence. The Sherman Anti-Trust Law of July 2, 1890, provides, in Section I, that " every contract, combination in form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States or with foreign nations, is declared illegal." The status of the traffic agreement under this act was brought out in the case of the Trans-Missouri Freight Association, which elicited from the United States Courts a decision that the agreement of the roads constituting the asso- ciation was illegal and void. The lower courts had upheld the legality of the associa- tion's agreement ; the Circuit Court maintaining : 1 Cullom Committee Report, p. 200. 60 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. An agreement between several competing railway companies and the forma- tion of an association thereunder for the purpose of maintaining just and reasonable rates, preventing unjust discriminations by furnishing adequate and equal facilities for the interchange of traffic between the several lines, without preventing or illegally limiting competition, is not an agreement, combination or conspiracy in restraint of trade in violation of the Act of July 2, 1890. ... It was not the intention of Congress to include common carriers subject to the act of February 4, 1887, within the provisions of the Act of July 2, 1890, which is a special statute, relating to combinations in the form of trusts and conspiracies in restraint of trade. 1 This decree of the Circuit Court was sustained by the Circuit Court of Appeals, that court arguing as follows : The contracts, combinations in the form of trust or otherwise, and conspiracies in restraint of trade declared to be illegal in interstate and international commerce by the Act of July 2, 1890, entitled an act to protect trade and commerce against unlawful restraints and monopolies, are the contracts, combinations and conspira- cies in restraint of trade that had been declared by the courts to be against public policy and void under the common law before the passage of that act. The test of the validity of such contracts or combinations is not the existence of restriction upon competition imposed thereby, but the reasonableness of that restriction under the facts and circumstances of each particular case. 2 The case was carried to the Supreme Court, which reversed the decrees of the lower courts, in a decision delivered March 22, 1897, in which the Court held: The Act of July 2, 1890, covers, and was intended to cover common carriers by railroad. The words unlawful restraints and monopolies, in the title of the Act of Congress of July 2, 1890, do not show that the purpose of the act was to include only contracts which were unlawful at common law, but refer to and include those restraints and monopolies which are made unlawful in the body of the act. The term " contract in restraint of trade," as used in the Act of July 2, 1890, does not refer only to contracts which were invalid at common law, but includes every contract in restraint of trade, and is not limited to that kind of a contract which is unreasonable restraint of trade. The policy of the government is to be found in its statutes, and when they have not directly spoken, then in the decision of the courts and the constant prac- tice of the government officials : but when the law-making power speaks on a 1 From the syllabus of the decision. 53 Federal Reporter. * Syllabus of the decision. Legislation and Its Results. 61 particular subject over which it has constitutional power to legislate, public policy in such a case is what the statute enacts. 1 The point in dispute, in other words, was as to what was included under the term " unlawful combinations in restraint of trade." Did the act declare to be illegal only those agree- ments which had been previously so considered under the common law ? Or did it go further and put under the ban all combinations which had the aim of restraining trade ? The lower courts held the former view, the latter was held by the Supreme Court. This decision decrees, therefore, that " The right of a rail- road company to charge reasonable rates does not include the right to enter into a combination with competing roads to maintain reasonable rates." The Act of 1 8S7 had declared illegal and criminal all com- binations between competing railroads which maintained rates by the " pooling " device. This decision of March 22, 1897, " makes illegal " as Dr. E. R. Johnson says, 2 " all traffic associations formed by railway companies for the purpose of regulating rates charged on competitive traffic." Evolution of Traffic Agreements Since 1887. Upon the passage by Congress of the Interstate Commerce Act in 1887, it was necessary to alter the organization of the numerous traffic associations then in force, in order to bring them into harmony with the fifth section of the law, which prohibited pooling. That the continuance of the rate agree- ment and of some means of enforcing it was essential, had been learned by the roads in their years of bitter experience, with such force that the lesson was not soon to be forgotten. The associations continued in existence, therefore, and, after the 1 Syllabus of the decision. United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association, 169 United States 290. 2 Current Transportation Topics II. Annals of American Academy Political and Social Science, Vol. X, p. 246. 62 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. pool was prohibited, attempted to accomplish the same end by other means. These attempts and their results, with the extent to which the evil effects of competition were obviated by other provisions in the Act of 1887, will form the conclud- ing subject of this chapter. In the East. — After the passage of the Interstate Commerce Act, new articles of association were entered' into by the Trunk Lines. 1 The agreement was signed on the seventh day of April, 1887, and the following preamble was adopted : Whereas, The Interstate Commerce Law, taking effect April the 4th, 1887, requires all the railroads which are subject' to the law to establish, publish, and maintain reasonable and just tariffs of transportation, for both freight and passen- ger traffic ; and, Whereas, The co-operation of the several railroad companies which exchange traffic with each other, and which enter into joint traffic arrangements, is necessary in order to make said tariffs, classifications,' etc. , conform with the law, and to avoid unjust discrimination between localities and shippers ; and, Whereas, On account of the complicated business relations of so many rail- roads whose business offices are located in different parts of the country, it is desir- able, in order to secure this co-operation and bring about a principal organization through which the business between the several railroad companies may be promptly and efficiently transacted, the following named railroad companies, to wit : . . . 2 and such other railroad or transportation companies in the same territory as may hereafter become parties hereto agree to form an association to be called "The Trunk Line Association," for the purpose of facilitating the transac- tion and interchange of business with each other and with their connecting roads, in conformity with the requirements of the Interstate Commerce Law. The agreement thus provided, in much the same manner as had the preceding agreements, for an organization by which the roads could co-operate in the transaction of business. No method, however, was provided for the punishment or dis- cipline of any of the members which should violate the agree- ment. It will be noticed that the Grand Trunk of Canada was not a member. From the date of the execution of the 1 Report of New York Railroad Commissioners, 1887, p. xi. 2 New York Central, West Shore, Delaware, Lackawanna & Western, Pennsyl- vania, Baltimore & Ohio, and the Philadelphia & Reading were the principal parties. Legislation and Its Results. 63 agreement until about the middle of November, the agree- ment was generally observed and rates maintained on the basis of 25 cents per 100 pounds from Chicago to New York on grain. About that time, however, the Grand Trunk Rail- road lowered its rates on dressed beef, and on November 18 all the other roads lowered theirs to meet the cut by the Grand Trunk. In their report dated January, 1888, the New York Commissioners l expressed their " serious apprehension that this will initiate another period of unregulated competi- tion, or, in other words, a railroad war, . . . which will result in great depreciation of property and with no corre- sponding benefit to either producer or consumer." That this apprehension was realized is shown by their report for the succeeding year, 2 when they say that rates " were seriously cut into by the fierce competition between the railroads." 3 This was attributed to five causes, of which the three most important were : " The clause in the Interstate Commerce Act prohibiting pooling ; the reckless efforts of some railroad managers to procure business at any rates, however unprofit- able ; and the building of new roads in advance of any necessity for the same." 4 The commissioners state in their report that " the clause prohibiting pooling has taken away from the rail- roads whatever power they possessed, previous to the passage of the Interstate Commerce Act, to enforce the provisions of their joint traffic agreements as against each other." New articles of association between the trunk lines were entered into to take effect February 20, 1889. 5 They declare in the preamble that " past experience has fully established the fact that the joint action of railroad companies is necessary to establish and maintain reasonable and just transportation tariffs on freight and passenger traffic"; and that such joint 'p. xii. 2 Report for 1888. 3 p. vii. 'p.viii. 6 New York Reports, 1889, p. viii. 64 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. action is also necessary to avoid unjust discriminations in trans- portation charges in conformity with the requirements of the Interstate Commerce Law." The articles were signed by the Grand Trunk as well as by the other roads. This new association seems to have been temporarily successful, if we are to judge by the following sentences from their reports for the two succeeding years, 1889 and 1890 : " It can be said as peaceful relations between the trunk lines and their affiliated connections have been main- tained during the past year as have ever before, or are likely to be hereafter." 1 " The trunk line agreement has been fairly well preserved throughout the year with a correspondingly stable maintenance of freight and passenger rates at fairly profitable figures." 2 The commissioners believed, however, that the diminution of ruinous competition was largely due to : " first, the very great increase of business giving all a share ; and, second, the long and short haul provision in the Interstate Commerce Act." 3 The railroads certainly could not afford to reduce rates on local traffic, " that which is by far the more reliable and profitable," to a war level, and the consequence was, the commissioners argued, that all rates were kept up. 4 The clause in the agreement to which was due the " fairly successful" maintenance of rates was Article VIII, which reads as follows : If the maintenance of uniform tariffs by all lines reduces the traffic of any party below a fair proportion of the traffic in competition, the tariffs may be so adjusted from time to time as to protect such lines from an unjust depletion of traffic ; such adjustment to be made under the rules of this association. The same principle was contained in the revised articles of the Central Traffic Association, which became effective Decem- ber 1, 1893 : "Whenever any party hereto feels that its traffic 1 1889, p. viii. 2 1890, p. viii. 3 1889, p. viii. *l889, p. ix. Legislation and Its Results. 65 is being unjustly depleted, it shall represent the facts in writing to the commissioner, who shall promptly endeavor to secure to the parties hereto their fair shares of traffic." 1 The Trunk Lines were members of two associations : The Trunk Line Association, including the eastern sections, and the Central Traffic Association, including the Chicago connec- tions. For the purpose of establishing joint tariffs, of deter- mining divisions of through rates and fares, and of making other rules and regulations as might be necessary for carrying out the objects of the two associations, the two associations had long had a joint committee. This committee, while it may have been successful in arranging joint tariffs and divi- sions of through rates, had become an inefficient agent for regulating competitive traffic. According to the Articles of Agreement, it could legislate but it could not execute its decrees. The companies composing these two associations had been trying for several years to find a more reliable instrument than the joint committee, but each such attempt was met with failure. No one believed that a permanent agency could be established, and often even temporary arrangements were violated, each road being afraid to trust its rivals. A decided movement to bring about some joint agreement between the two associations was made in the spring of 1894, 2 but without success. Then the evils of competition assumed a more prominent form than ever, until in June, 1895, according to the Railway Guide, 3 there was danger that all American securities held in England would be sold, and that the dimin- ishing profits of the roads would soon culminate in widespread insolvency. This fear pervaded the owners of American rail- road securities, for they brought such an influence to bear on 1 Interstate Commission, 1895, p. 97. 'Railway World, Vol. XXI, pp. 636-7. a Vol. XXVI, pp. 298, 450. 66 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. their directors, 1 that a meeting of the representatives of the railroads was held in the latter part of June, 1895. After numerous meetings during the summer and autumn of that year, the presidents held a short meeting in New York, on November 19, 1895, at which were adopted the Articles of Agreement. This new organization, called the Joint Traffic Association, which went into operation on the first of January, 1896, pro- vided for a board of managers, a permanent board consisting of one representative from each of the nine principal systems of roads. This body had the power of recommending " such changes in rates as may be reasonable and just, and necessary for governing the traffic covered by this agreement." 2 This recommendation was, in effect, an order, since it was further pro- vided that " the failure to observe such recommendations shall be deemed a violation of this agreement." 3 A violation of the agreement was punished by making the offending party forfeit a sum " not to exceed $5000, unless the gross receipts of the transaction in which the agreement is violated exceed that amount." In that case, the forfeiture should not exceed the gross receipts. Each road was required to make an initial deposit of $5000, as well as further monthly payments based upon the gross earnings of each company, for the purpose of providing for forfeitures and defraying the necessary expenses of the association. Another of the duties of the managers was to secure " to each company equitable portions of the competitive traffic so far as can be legally done." 4 In order to accomplish this, it was provided that if the maintenance of uniform tariffs by all the lines reduced the tariffs of any party below a fair propor- tion of the competitive traffic, the tariffs should be so adjusted » "Railway World," Vol. XXI, p. 124. 'Article VII, Section 2. 'Article VII, Section 2. "Article VIII. Legislation and Its Results. 67 from time to time as to protect such lines from an unjust depletion of revenue. Action was brought by the United States in the Circuit Court of the United States for the Southern District of New York to have the contract declared illegal, because, as the District Attorney maintained : 1 . It provided a traffic and earnings pool, and therefore vio- lated the Interstate Commerce Act. 2. It was a combination in restraint of trade and com- merce, and therefore violated the Sherman Anti-Trust Act of 1890. 3. It was an unlawful interference with and an obstruction to interstate commerce, and therefore the United States had a good cause of action in equity irrespective of statute. The Circuit Court and the Circuit Court of Appeals both decided that the contract violated neither the Interstate Com- merce Law nor the Anti-Trust Law. The United States Supreme Court, however, overruled the lower courts and October 24, 1898, decided, in this case, as it had in the Trans-Missouri Freight Association Case, that the contract included an agreement to maintain rates and was a violation of the Anti-Trust Law. In the South. — The Southern Railway and Steamship Asso- ciation, which included most of the roads south of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi, continued in existence after 1887, although the prohibition of pooling required a reorganization. 1 The power of the association was by no means destroyed, however. Pool divisions being no longer legal as a means of maintaining rates, fines were imposed to accomplish the same end. According to Hudson, the association succeeded for some years in maintaining rates and preventing discriminations. During the panic of 1893, however, it became powerless to prevent rate-cutting, and its orders being disregarded it 1 Henry Hudson, Quarterly Journal Economics, Vol. V, p. 90. 68 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. dissolved. 1 In 1895, it was succeeded by the Southern States Freight Association. 2 This association provided that "the principle of a physical apportionment of actual traffic subject to arbitration shall be recognized in the operation of the asso- ciation," and "that the maintenance of rates as established under the rules of the association is of the very essence of this agreement." The agreement also made traffic subject to arbitration, in order to bring it within the rule of physical apportionment. 3 The decision in the Trans-Missouri Freight Association Case compelled a reorganization of the Southern States Freight Association. There are now in existence, January, 1899, two organizations south of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi — the Southeastern Freight Association and the Southern Freight Association. In the West. — Some time after the prohibition of pools, the Western Freight Association and the Western Passenger Association came into existence to control the traffic between Chicago and the Missouri River. 4 The former of these asso- ciations enjoined upon its administrative board "the duty of securing to each party a fair share of the competitive traffic." 6 The declared object of the Western Passenger Association was " to provide for joint instead of individual action in all matters of common interest, and to afford protection against unfair competition, to the end that proper rates of fare may be main- tained." 6 The Trans-Missouri Freight and Passenger Asso- ciations extended from the western limits of the "Western Associations " nearly to the western boundaries of Arizona, Utah, and New Mexico. 7 1 Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. V, p. 91. * " Railway World," 1895, p. 467. 'Interstate Commerce Reports, 1896, p. 90. *A. F. Walker, Forum, Vol. XIII, p. 743. 6 Interstate Commerce Reports, 1896, p. 90. «Ibid. 'A. F. Walker, Forum, Vol. XIII, p. 743. Legislation and Its Results. 69 The traffic to and from the Pacific Coast was controlled by the " Transcontinental Association." ' An account of traffic associations in the West would be incomplete without some mention of the Western Traffic Asso- ciation, which, founded January 31, 1891, embraced most of the carriers west of the Missouri and as far south and includ- ing Arizona, Utah and New Mexico. 2 This association dif- fered from its predecessors in three particulars : First, its authority was derived from the boards of directors, a higher source than the presidents or traffic managers ; sec- ond, it did not directly make or alter rates, but, with functions similar to those of an appellant tribunal, did so through the older associations which were still retained. /The matter of a proposed change of rates by one of the subsidiary associa- tions was taken up by the general organization at one of its regular monthly meetings. Third, where the rate committees of the subsidiary associations were unable to agree, the West- ern Traffic Association afforded arbitration by means of a per- manent board of five commissioners. Mention has been made in this and the preceding sections of this chapter of only the more important associations. There has been no attempt made to discuss all the organiza- tions nor to note all the many and frequent changes which the associations have undergone. It remains only to speak in a general way of the present status of the traffic association and this recital of details will have ended. Present Status. — The decision of the Supreme Court of the United States, in the Trans-Missouri Freight Association Case, made the agreements of all existing traffic associations illegal. Accordingly, with the exception of the Eastern trunk lines, the railroads withdrew from their old associations and recon- structed their agreements in such a way as to make them 1 A. F. Walker, Forum, Vol. XIII, p. 743. »Ibid. 70 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. conform with the principles laid down in the court's decision. 1 They retained the general form of the previous organizations, with the one important exception of reserving to the individ- ual companies the functions of rate-making. 2 An instance of this is to be found in the articles of agreement of the Western Joint Traffic Bureau (which took the place of the old Western Freight Association), where it is provided that the board of commissioners " shall supervise and at its option recommend changes in rates, rules and regulations governing the traffic subject to this agreement." The agreement takes care to pro- vide further, however, that " Nothing herein shall be construed as interfering with the right of individual members to change rates at will, and the board of commissioners shall so exercise the power conferred upon it as to discourage, and, so far as possible, prevent violation of the Interstate Commerce Act, or any other federal or State law, or the provisions of the charter of any member, and it shall, with these ends in view, co-oper- ate with federal and State commissions." Similar provisions are included in the revised agreements of the other freight and passenger traffic associations. 3 The Joint Traffic Association promptly dissolved after the Supreme Court held its agreement to be illegal. Extent of Evils of Competition Under Interstate Commerce Law. Discriminations Prohibited. — Federal legislation for the regu- lation of commerce was first considered in the early seventies, but action was from time to time postponed, on the ground that the affairs of the railway companies should be regulated by their creators, the individual States. In 1886, however, this policy was changed as a result of the decision by the Supreme 1 E. R. Johnson, Current Transportation Topics, Vol. II, p. 98. 2 Ibid. 3 Interstate Commerce Reports, 1897. Legislation and Its Results. J\ Court, in the case of the Wabash Railway Company vs. the State of Illinois. The court declared that a State law against discrimination had no validity in respect to interstate ship- ments, even though Congress had wholly refrained from action upon the subject. 1 In view of this decision an espe- cial significance became attached that year to the report to the Senate of its Select Committee on Interstate Commerce. This report summed up the necessity for federal legislation in a series of "Complaints against the railroad system of the United States." There were eighteen of these complaints, and as A. F. Walker has said, 2 " the bill recommended to the Senate might properly have been named An Act to Prevent Railway Discrimination." Its machinery and details were nearly all directed to the accomplishment of that result. The remedy proposed was the forbidding of unjust discriminations under pains and pen- alties. When the Interstate Commerce Act was finally passed, it contained two additional features added by the House — the long and short-haul clause and the anti-pooling clause. The law undertook to accomplish by legal inhibitions what the railroads had been trying to do by means of pools. A brief review of the extent to which the law has accomplished its purpose of stopping discriminations will constitute the third part of this chapter on legislation. Prohibitions of the Law Evaded. — When the law first went into operation the managers of the railways, so they claim, accepted it as inevitable? and made serious efforts to conform to its provisions. Rebates, drawbacks, and all " other de- vices " whereby a carrier should receive from one person " greater or less compensation for any service rendered " than from another for a like service, were expressly declared 1 Forum, Vol. XI, p. 526. 2 Ibid. 3 That the railroads ' ' accepted the Act of 1887 as inevitable ' ' may seem to be a statement hardly warranted by developments, but the railroads at the time of its passage undoubtedly made serious efforts to conform to its provisions. This is admitted by the Interstate Commission in its first report. 72 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. unlawful and were punishable by a heavy fine. As Walker says, 1 this was just what conservative railway managers desired ; it was not only just but it protected their revenues ; so the new rule was cheerfully accepted and imperative orders were issued for its obedience. This happy condition did not continue. Before the close of the year difficulties began to develop, which in 1888 assumed very serious proportions. Where several roads charged similar rates, the traffic naturally went by the most advantageous]route. The road which pursued a more indirect line, climbed heavier grades, or had less favorable terminal facilities, found that the traffic was going by the route more advantageously situated. Complaint was raised that the law was in effect "a direct interference by the government in favor of the strong roads and against the weak." The weaker roads were not managed by men who were of the kind to sit idly in their offices and lose business. They soon discovered that a commission to a shipper's friend would result in the desired freight, there being nothing in the law to prevent such commissions " to friends." Nor did their ingenuity stop here ; as Walker says, 2 " other kindred devices were sugggested, some new, some old ; the payment of rent, clerk hire, dock charges, elevator fees, drayage, the allowance of exaggerated claims, free transportation within some single State — a hundred ingen- ious forms of evading the plain requirements of the law were in use." Nor was it the minor, unimportant roads alone which thus became demoralized ; shippers were ready to give information to other lines concerning concessions which were offered them, and to state the sum required to control their patronage. " A freight agent thus appealed to might perhaps let the business go at first, but when the matter became more serious and he saw one large shipper after another seeking a 1 Forum, Vol. XI, p. 531, 2 Ibid. Legislation and Its Results. 73 less desirable route, he was very apt to throw up his hands and fall in with the procession." These conditions were largely due to the inadequate methods provided in the original law for its enforcement, and a remedy was attempted in the amendments which went into effect in March, 1889. For a year thereafter there was an almost entire cessation of the use of illegitimate methods of securing business, and until near the close of this period little com- plaint was heard. 1 Then, however, conditions assumed their old form — the malady underwent a serious relapse. Accord- ing to Walker, 2 it became a common statement among shippers and traffic agents that the law was largely a dead letter, as regards the prohibition of personal discriminations, and that its penalties need not be feared. Difficulty of Detection. — The reason for this state of affairs is to be found in the report of the Interstate Commission for 1893, where the commission admits 3 that "the difficulty does not consist in determining what constitutes the criminal act, but in uncovering the guilty transaction and bringing to justice those who engage in it." The report states it to be the belief of many " that the public tariff charges are frequently departed from in particular localities, that rebates are paid, and that other prohibitions of the statute are disregarded." The commission' admits this ; "the legal proofs of these violations may not be obtainable, yet the fact of their occurrence is a moral certainty. How to check discriminations of this kind is a most perplexing inquiry. Unlawful contracts between shipper and carrier are consummated in secrecy, and are all the more harmful on that account. The means for their concealment are practically unlimited ; the mutual interest of the parties compels each to screen and protect the other.; detection is very difficult." 1 Walker— Forum, Vol. XI, p. 532. 2 Ibid. 3 p. 8. 74 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Even roads competing with the road that is offering special rates feel themselves bound to a certain code which forbids their bringing to light the misdoings of their rival. Newcomb shows the truth of this in an articlein the Engineering Magazine, 1 where he quotes " the following extract from an article pub- lished in a periodical of high standing and wide circulation among railway officials": At present no railway man dares to assist the commission to information against another road. No company dares to be the active instrument in bringing com- plaint against another. It has its own record behind it. There would be retalia- tion, and (I say it with sorrow) there is no great company which can face having its record of the past years subjected to investigation. The Interstate Commission expressed this same idea, only more broadly, in their report for 1893 : 2 "The average public sentiment recognizes little moral turpitude in compacts to secure special privileges from railroad corporations and the general refusal to play the role of informer covers the illegal transaction with comparative security." That the law against personal discriminations may be vio- lated and the individual transaction so covered as to prevent any possibility of its discovery, was a fact unexpectedly brought home to the Interstate Commission in 1 894. Accord- ing to Section 20 of the Act to Regulate Commerce, reports are required to be filed with the commission on numerous subjects, among them being the earnings and amounts ex- pended and for what purposes. In response to this require- ment an important railroad system filed with the commission a report, verified by the oaths of its president and auditor, for the year 1893. It subsequently appeared from a statement made by an expert accountant, who made an examination of its affairs and accounts, that during the period covered by the report large sums of money had been paid out by the 1 Vol. XI, p. 1059. a p. 8. Legislation and Its Results. 75 company by way of rebates and drawbacks, but were falsely covered under the head of legitimate expenditures. 1 Under the existing law, no indictment for perjury could be predicated upon such false and fraudulent report, though made under oath. 2 If the examination of this company's books had not been made for another purpose, the existence of the discrimi- nations would have continued undiscovered. It would cer- tainly be impossible for the commission to examine all railroad accounts with the minuteness required to detect false entries, and the only effect of a law punishing the maker of a per- jured report would be merely to make him more careful. In the case just mentioned, the reason why the accountant was able to discover the existence of discriminations, was because no attempt had been made to conceal them, the officers of the road knowing that accounts were almost never so deeply ex- amined and that anyhow no indictment for perjury could be brought. The commission recognized its helplessness in ferreting out evidence of personal discriminations, in its report for 1897. 3 An inquiry was made into certain rates ; the investigation was conducted by members of the commission ; the officers of the accused companies were called and compelled to give evidence under oath. That testimony was, without exception, that the rate had been in all cases maintained. " Neverthe- less," says the commission, "there are strong reasons for believing that the fact is otherwise. Those who are in a position to know say that this is so. Railroad managers themselves, with one accord, declare it to be so. Facts which are morally convincing, although not of a character to secure a legal conviction, lead us to the same opinion. We have no doubt that at the present time very large quantities of com- petitive traffic are carried at other than published rates." 1 Report, 1894, p. 63. * Ibid, p. 64. 3 1897, P- 47- ?6 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Strong Inducement to Discriminate. — That there is a strong motive back of the special rate is doubted by no one. As the Interstate Commissioners say, l " The opportunity of the shipper combined with the carrier's asserted necessity is a constant temptation to bargain for preferential rates." The amount of available traffic varies greatly, while the carrying capacity of the roads is nearly a constant quantity. " Hence at different seasons of the year, or in periods of commercial depression, when the volume of shipments is greatly reduced, the strife to get business is exceedingly fierce. There are occasions where competition is so sharp, where the freight of some large shipper or combination of shippers is so needful to a particular road, that when reduced rates are demanded as the alternative of losing the tonnage the carrier can scarcely refuse." The subordinate agent who in the early days of railway competition created such a disturbance, came to life again, with a restricted field of activities, but with an even greater desire to "get his share of the traffic." Even where the responsibility is placed in higher hands, the official, whoever he may be, is often unable to resist what A. F. Walker calls : "The persistent importunity of patrons, who beg openly, misrepresent unscrupulously, and devise ingeniously, to the end that they may get a trifle, be it ever so small, off tariff, in consideration of their patronage." " In the language of the street, ' anything goes ' with shippers, from a free-pass to a greenback, from the allowance of a bogus claim to free storage, from a clerk on the pay-roll to a dinner at the club. If the facts in respect to the pursuit of personal favors and discriminations by shippers were fully known, all surprise that the law against unjust discriminations has been so extensively a dead letter would disappear." i 'Report., 1893, p. 8. a A. F. Walker, Forum, Vol. XL Legislation and Its Results. yy Present Injurious Effects. — The conditions which give rise to discriminating special rates are such that the results have been and are of an especially unfortunate and injurious nature. The large shipper and the dishonest shipper have been and are the men favored by present conditions. As Newcomb said, in an article in the Engineering Magazine of December, 1897, 1 "There is abundant evidence that concessions are regularly made to those shippers, or combina- tions of shippers, whose enormous wealth, or the extent of whose business operations, enable them to dictate terms to carriers, wherever alternate routes exist." The reason for this is brought out in the Interstate Commission's report for 1897, where they say : 2 " Incidentally this rate-cutting prefers the large to the small shipper. Rebates cannot be given to-day as they were before the passage of this act, nor as they were before the Brown decision 3 even. Various devices are resorted to. Only a few can know of the transaction. The whole matter must be covered up and kept secret, with the result that the large shipper, the trust, the monopoly, is able to secure the concession, while the small shipper is obliged to pay the published rates." Another effect of present conditions which, while it may not be so harmful economically, is nevertheless most outrageous to the more optimistic observer, — the position in which the honest shipper finds himself. " The most unfortunate feature of the whole situation," according to the Interstate Commis- sion, 4 "is the fact that it often prevents the honest shipper from doing business at all. It being a crime to accept less than the published rate, one who believes that the law of the land should be obeyed can not accept a reduction from that rate. It is only the dishonest trader that can and does accept iVol. XIV, p. 473. ' *P- 47- 3 161 U. S. 591. This decision compels a witness to testify even though his testimony may tend to criminate him. «p. 48 (I897)- 78 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. it." The same effect is produced on the carrier — the present situation undoubtedly puts a premium on dishonest and unlawful methods. As the commission says 1 " It is a crime for the agent of the railroad company to give this concession in rates, and no honest man can be, on behalf of the railroad company, a party to such a transaction ; so that the carrier which would obey the law is deprived of the business that legitimately belongs to it." Summary of Present Conditions. — When the Interstate Com- merce Act was first passed, it was believed that the functions performed by pools in preventing discriminating rates as regards both persons and places would be accomplished by the law. This belief, time has shown us, was not well- founded. Personal discriminations are now prevalent, and local discriminations still exist to some extent. I make this statement with great caution, although it may seem a rather sweeping assertion ; the authorities are certainly almost unanimous. That the law forbidding preferential rates has been, and is being, violated, is admitted by all. As the Interstate Commerce Commission says in its latest report, 2 "Railroad men have themselves tacitly admitted that rates were not maintained ; the press openly charges it ; and what inquiries the commission could make led us to the same con- clusion." Yet the commission is unable to prevent these illegal practices. That they exist, the commission says it knows by " facts which are morally convincing." Yet even what it so knows of cannot be eliminated because these facts are "not of a character to secure a legal conviction." 'p. 48- 1 1897, p. 47. CHAPTER IV. Degree and Form of Co-operation that Should be Granted Competing Railways. Public Nature of the Railway's Services. — " A discussion of the present, practical, economic and political question — the extent and form of railway co-operation which, in the light of our past experience, should be granted to competing rail- ways " — should be prefaced with a consideration of the economic and political position occupied by the railroad. While transportation is undoubtedly an industry, its object being the creation of " place value," there is no doubt that its position in the industrial world is exceptional. No other industry bears such important relations to each and every other industry. Transportation figures in practically all production — the commodities in the production of which transportation does not have a share, are, if they exist at all, few in number and without significance. I think the state- ment could be made without exaggeration, that what coal is to the iron industry, transportation is to industry in general. In 1776, Adam Smith told the world that the division of labor, the " greatest cause of improvement in the productive powers of labor," is " limited by the extent of the market." x Upon the industry of transportation rests the task of removing that limitation ; and most ably has that instrument of trans- portation, the railway, performed its task. For the removal of all limitations upon the division of labor, and for the open- ing up of all the resources supplied by nature, the people of the United States depend upon the railroad. The improvement of the old means of transportation has changed the character of the relations of customer and seller ; 1 "Wealth of Nations," Book I, Chap. III. (79) 80 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. the railway is doing on a larger scale what the highway for- merly did in a lesser degree. The railroad is the improved highway — and even if the customer pays for wagon hire as well as for use of road, the principle still remains the same. Now, this connection between the railway and its prototype, the highway, is significant, since it indicates the public nature of the service performed by the railroad. Ever since the establishment of the right of private ownership of land, there has been a public necessity for some common means of going from one place to another without trespassing on someone's property. In recognition of this necessity, the State has reserved to itself what is called the right of eminent domain, in order that when necessity arises the requisite land can be obtained with which to supply such a common means of moving person and property — the highway, in other words. The supply of this highway, in the form in which it must be used, has been long recognized as a function of the State. In this country the State itself does not carry on this public service, but prefers to create an artificial person for that pur- pose. To this creature is delegated a portion of the sovereign power of the State — the right to condemn property and to take possession upon payment of an arbitrated price — and for this service of relieving the State of one of its burdens, the corporation is allowed to charge rates and tolls. Thus the duty of the State in regard to the railway is of a twofold nature : first, to the community at large, that the means of transportation shall be furnished of sufficient quantity and quality and at fair and equal rates to all alike j and second, to those who thus relieve the State of a burden, that they shall receive an adequate remuneration for so doing. Competition Relied on in the Past to Regulate the Railway. — With the exception of certain provisions in the early charters regarding maximum rates, the State did not at first take any legislative steps to fulfill the requirements of its twofold duty. The State relied instead on the force of competition to regulate Degree and Form of Co-operation. 81 the relations of the transportation industry, as it did of other industries. This form of regulation has failed, however, inso- much as it does not secure the execution of either of the two duties of the State ; we have seen that competition resulted in : i. Discriminations, which violate the State's duty of secur- ing to all the use of the public service on equal terms ; and, 2. Rate wars, which injure the roads, by cutting off. the fair remuneration to which we have seen they were entitled, and which injure also the shipping public, owing to the fluctuating and consequently speculative condition of business. Not only have these evils been produced by relying solely on competition as the regulator of the railway, but even this faulty regulation applies to only a part of the traffic of the •country. It is a fact that cannot be denied. Furthermore competition has been found to apply to only a part of the transportation service. Not until every road is paralleled by another can we have the full regulation of competition. That every road should be paralleled would be an absurd require- ment, one that is not to be for a moment thought of, and so we must accept the inevitable, that competition must remain in its present state of partial application to the railway. " Far the greater number of railway stations are dependent upon single railway lines, and the vastly larger portion of railway traffic has no alternative rates available." 1 In other words, competition applies in the first place to only part of the traffic, and in the next place it results in evils where it does apply. The railroads devised a scheme of regulation that they claimed did away with the evils resulting from competition. But the State, fearing that by this new means of regula- tion the duty to see that just rates were charged would not be carried out, has forbidden the roads to make use of their 1 Newcomb in "Engineering Magazine," Vol. XI, p. 1057. 82 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. device. When this prohibition was made other legislation was enacted providing for the prohibition of the evils of com- petition through the punitive machinery of the courts of justice. That this legislation has failed in a large measure has been admitted by practically everyone — shippers, railroads, and the Interstate Commission itself — and the country is to-day faced with the necessity of securing some means whereby the duty of the State in regard to the supply of transportation facilities may be fulfilled. Competition has failed to do so, and legislative prohibition of abuses has not brought about the desired result. The concluding sections of this paper will consider the pub- lic expediency of allowing the railroads to use their means of solving the difficulty. In other words, should competing rail- ways be allowed to co-operate, and, if so, what should be the form and extent of their co-operation ? Competition under the Pooling Agreement. — The evil of per- sonal discrimination undoubtedly arises, as we have seen, from the presence of excessive competition. The force which brings about fluctuating and war rates is likewise the effort of each road to get the better of its rival in order that its rival may not get the better of it. Discrimination between places is some- times due to rate-cutting incident to competition for traffic free to choose between carriers, and sometimes due to the rivalry of roads serving different regions, and even connecting differ- ent termini. The end of the pooling agreement is to eliminate the evils of personal and place discriminations, and this end is to be attained by doing away with one of their causes, the com- petition between several roads struggling for the same traffic. A mere agreement or a mere law was long ago found to be powerless in putting an end to these evils. As we have seen, the relations of rival roads are of such a nature that the only power which can be brought to bear on these evils lies in the railway itself. So long as an individual road cares to give special rates or to declare war on its rival, it is able to do so,. Degree and Form of Co-operation. 8$ and, in spite of legislative enactment, the road will do so unless its own interests require otherwise. Self-interest is man's strongest motive, and the pool recognizes this principle — that the only way to prevent discriminations and rate-cutting is to guarantee to each road its share of the traffic and thus do away, once and for all, with the inducement to discriminate. The argument of the advocates of pools is that competition still remains in force between the several members of a pool even during the existence of an apportionment agreement. They claim that such motives as a desire to increase the allot- ment at the next periodical apportionment, to keep in favor with shippers in case of a break in the agreement, are still present and are an evidence that competition still exists. This contention may violate the principle on which the pool rests. Fink, Midgely and Blanchard said that the pool does away with discriminations, because it does away with the inducement to give special rates. They claim that the only way to prevent the manager of a road from giving a special rate to a large shipper in order to increase the freight hauled by his road, is to remove all incentives to do so by taking away all the advantage of rate-cutting. The advocates of pooling say competition will continue but assert that pools only regulate competition in such a way as to make it possible for the railroad companies to control discriminations. The opponents of pooling say that if competition continues pools will be a failure ; and that if pools do succeed the public will be deprived of the influence of competition on rates. The Interstate Commerce Commission speaks in much the same vein when it says in its report for 1 897 that : It must be remembered that if pooling produces any beneficial result it neces- sarily does so at the expense of competition. It is only by destroying competition that the inducement to deviate from the published rate is wholly removed, and it is only to the extent that competition is actually destroyed that beneficial results can be expected. Notwithstanding the specious arguments of carriers to the con- trary, this is and must be the fact. 84 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. These statements seem hopelessly contradictory. Indeed, neither side is strictly accurate in its assertion, although each is partly correct. The difficulty arises from a misunderstand- ing of the nature and scope of competition, and a use of the word competition in two senses. Undoubtedly the idea at the bottom of all traffic agree- ments is to eliminate the competition between the several members of the pool. But the commission goes too far when it says that "it is only by destroying competition that the inducement to deviate from the published rate is wholly removed." This would require that all competition be destroyed by the pool, whereas in reality the only compe- tition destroyed is that for the traffic that is free to move by way of one or more of the several rival roads forming the association. The force of competition still remains to be reck- oned with. The commission, in throwing aside all competi- tion, has fallen into the error against which we are warned by Dr. Weyl. "They have given to railway competition too local a significance and have laid insufficient, if any, emphasis on its national and international bearings." ' The struggle between several roads for the same traffic is only one of the forms in which competition makes itself felt as a factor in determining railway charges. Dr. Weyl goes so far as to say that such competition can never exist perma- nently, the sole permanent competition being that between roads having no territory in common. In the first kind of competition the struggle always ends in some agreement or at least understanding. Take for example the relations of two rival railways serving the same wheat-field ; the compe- tition between them may be partially or totally stifled in many ways. But the farmers of that field — say Dakota — enjoy no monopoly, and unless they can get their wheat to the world's market at a certain rate, they cannot compete with the farmers of Nebraska and Kansas. The railroad or railroads hauling 1 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, April, 1898. Degree and Form of Co-operation. 85 Dakota wheat to Chicago cannot afford to increase the cost of its production by charging a rate higher than is charged the Kansas or Nebraska wheat ; for if they do, the marginal farmer — the farmer producing at the greatest disadvantage — will be driven out of the market and will consequently trans- fer his energies to the field which enjoys the more favorable transportation rates. This competition of locality with locality — known by the railroad man as "the competition of markets " — is a far more powerful force in fixing transportation charges than are the dicta of railroad officials. 1 This form of competition is not only more powerful than that between several roads in one locality, but it is more permanent, since the industrial condi- tions of the world are far too complicated to admit of any understanding between the transportation agencies of the many productive centres. This competition is national and international in scope ; not only does the wheat of Dakota compete in Chicago with that of Kansas and Nebraska, but the wheat of the United States competes in Liverpool with that of Canada, Russia, Argentine Republic and India. Several instances of this industrial competition are given by Dr. E. R. Johnson. The Pennsylvania and Virginia coal competes in New England with that from Nova Scotia ; the various coal fields in the Alleghenies compete with each other ; the Southern iron and Northern iron are competitors ; in the fruit markets of our Northern States we find California, Florida and the Mediterranean countries striving to outdo, each other. In fact, as Dr. Johnson says, the instances of industrial competition are so numerous and well known that it is hardly necessary to cite special cases. Another phase of this broad form of competition is to be found in the struggle between the various possible routes connecting a given productive centre with the ultimate market of the product. This is a more complicated form of competi- 1 Dr. E. R. Johnson, New York Independent, 1897. 86 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. tion than that between merely two or more practically parallel lines, as is shown by the following illustrations, which, for their aptness, I quote from Dr. Johnson : " Recently, impor- tant trunk lines have been constructed running north and south at right angles to the older routes of traffic, so that now the great region of the Central West will be able to use either the Atlantic or the Gulf ports as gateways for its export and import trade. The consequence will be that rates from the West to the Atlantic cities cannot much exceed those to Galveston, New Orleans, Mobile and other Southern ports. There is a similar instance of this competition in the rivalry of the North Central States and the North Atlantic States in the markets of the Southern States. The Central States, not having facilities for cheap water transportation to the South, are obliged by their rivals on the Atlantic Coast to secure as low rates as possible in order to compete." Acting in conjunction with this species of competition, as an additional stimulus tending to the reduction of railway charges, we find the influence of the principle of increasing returns. This principle is based on the fact that there is no proportionate relation between gross tonnage and gross expenses. To double the gross tonnage hauled by a road means something far different from doubling the expenses. It is usually roughly estimated that the cost of railroading is made up half by fixed expenses on capital and half by operat- ing expenses, and that of these operating expenses one-half do not vary with volume of traffic. In other words, only one- fourth of the total expense of maintaining a road is affected by an increase in traffic. Accordingly there is a strong inducement to charge lower rates if there is any hope that they will cause an increase in the gross tonnage hauled. To understand how this principle of increasing returns works in conjunction with the competition of markets in tend- ing to lower rates, let us consider the position of a number of roads serving a given community. Let us imagine that they Degree and Form of Co-operation, 87 have formed a pool. They see that by charging a certain rate they get a certain amount of freight to haul ; they lower that rate, increase their traffic without proportionately increasing their expenses, and the result is an increase in net earnings. It may be objected that a reduction in rates will not necessarily increase tonnage to an extent great enough to neutralize the reduction in charges. It is in answering this objection that we discover the close inter-dependence of " in- creasing returns '' and " competition of markets." The reason why a reduction in rates will increase gross tonnage is because the industrial activity of the community affected by the reduc- tion is stimulated by its advantage over competing communi- ties. Each set of roads forming a pool is interested in the industrial welfare of the locality served by its members as is each road in its own particular locality. The success of the roads transporting the wheat crop of Dakota to Chicago depends in large measure on the success of the wheat industry in that particular field. It is to the interest of a railroad, or set of railroads, to stimulate as far as possible the industrial activity of that part of the country served by them, and this interest is intensified by the fact that the increase in traffic resulting from increasing prosperity can be hauled at a con- stantly lower rate. It is this competition between communi- ties — a competition which, owing to the complicated character of economic conditions, cannot be restrained by any under- standing or agreement — that is overlooked by the Interstate Commission when they insist so strenuously that the induce- ment to deviate from the published rate is wholly removed "only by destroying competition." Possible Abuse of Right to Pool. — The supposition that com- petition is completely eliminated under the pooling agreement, has been the greatest cause of opposition to the pool. There has been a strong popular fear that the traffic agreement was simply a scheme of doing away with competition in order that the roads might charge extortionate rates. Let 88 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. us glance at "our past experience" to determine how far this objection has been justified by the facts, and how far the joint influence of the two factors, "competition of markets" and "increasing returns" has tended to prevent extortionate rates. Upon an investigation of the actual working of the various pools throughout the country, one is inclined to agree with the Interstate Commerce Commission that " the actual results of the Trunk Line Association and others have been to lower rates." * The commission explicitly states in its first report that pools " have not enabled managers to keep rates up to former standards." That the Trunk Line pool did not keep up rates is shown by some figures gathered by C. C. McCain, for many years the auditor of the Interstate Commerce Commission and one of the foremost authorities on transportation charges in the United States. He says 2 that the average rate per ioo pounds on freight from New York to points west of the termini of the Trunk Lines was 53.7 cents in 1878, the second year of the existence of the Trunk Line pool. In 1886, the year before the Interstate Commerce Law went into effect, the average charge for the same service was 42.6 cents. And in 1892, it was 41.5 cents. Newcomb draws from these figures the significant fact that during the period when this traffic was pooled the charges declined at the rate of 2.59 per cent per annum, but that, after pooling was prohibited, the rate of decline dropped to .39 per cent for each year. 3 However, I do not mean to suggest by. these figures that pools were the only, or the chief, factor affecting rates. The tendency of rates in the South under the influence of the Southern Railway and Steamship Association is described in Hudson's account of that association. Speaking of changes 1 First Annual Report, p. 34. 2 American Statistical Association, Vol. V, p. 65. * American Statistical Association, p. 67. Degree and Form of Co-operaiion. 89 in rates he says, 1 "Such changes as took place have been almost uniformly downward ; and, as reasonable notice of these has been given, there has been no offset to the public's gain such as sudden and fluctuating rates bring. The following figures show the steady downward trend of rates, and prove at least that the effect of the association was not to maintain rates at any fixed high figures." The rates in cents per 100 pounds on Class I from Boston, New York and Philadelphia to Atlanta fell from 170 on Janu- ary 1, 1875, to 114 on January, 1887; on Class VI the fall was from 70 to 49. The decline in rates from Baltimore south was equally great. A table showing the rates charged per ton per mile for all traffic carried by the important roads named during the years 1876, 1886, and 1894, has been prepared by Newcomb. 2 The average rate per ton per mile in cents was as follows : 1876 1886 1.05 0.76 1.03 0.69 0.82 0.64 2.04 1.17 1-95 1. 19 1.91 1.07 1.63 0.96 1.85 1. 10 3-46 1-93 1894 New York Central Michigan Central Lake Shore & Michigan Southern Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Chicago & Northwestern . . . Chicago, Rock Island & Pacific Chicago & Alton Louisville & Nashville .... Southern Railway o-73 0.67 o-59 1.04 1.08 0.99 0.63 0.88 113 The full significance of this table will be seen when we con- sider what was meant by each one of the years selected. In 1876 the Southern Railway and Steamship Association pool was organized ; and the Chicago-Omaha pool had then been in existence for six years, while the year following saw the formation of the Trunk Line pool. The year 1886 was the last in which pooling was legal, and during the ten years' 1 Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. V, p. 93. 2 American Statistical Association, Vol. V, p. 65. 90 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. interval all the companies named were parties, more or less continuously, to pooling contracts covering portions of their traffic. The table not only shows that the average decline was much greater during the earlier than during the later period, but also affords ground for a reasonable inference that the decline was confined to no class of traffic, either competi- tive or local, but was distributed over the entire business of each company. 1 The statement was made in 1 897, by George R. Blanchard, 2 that " no American pool can be cited which advanced rates unless to restore unjustifiable rate-war reductions," and although this may be a little broad, I feel safe in saying this much — that I have been able to find no record of any pool which has done otherwise, and that accordingly the general tendency of traffic agreements has not been, by removing competition, to cause extortionate charges. Objections have been raised to pools on the ground that from their very nature they were only temporary, and that when a pooling contract was broken conditions were rendered more unstable than as if the pool had never existed. J. F. Hudson 3 goes so far as to claim that nearly, if not quite, all railway wars and severe fluctuations in rates are caused by alternating periods of competition and non-competition. First no pool, then a pool, then broken, then reconstructed, and so on — this, he claims, is the very condition of affairs which leads to discriminations, rate-wars and all other evils of com- petition. There may be some truth in this accusation, but we must remember that the pool was never given a fair opportunity to show its efficiency. We have seen 4 that even prior to the passage of the Act of 1887, the pooling contract was not 1 Newcomb, American Statistical Association, Vol. V, p. 63. 1 New York Mail and Express, May 15, 1897. ' " Railways and the Republic." «p. 58. Degree and Form of Co-operation. 91 legal but only extra-legal. The standing of the pool before the common law was similar to that of the gambling contract, while it was not made a crime to agree to such a contract, the courts would refuse to oblige any of the parties to obey its provisions. This being the standing of a contract, there was a constant temptation on the part of one or the other of the roads to violate the agreement ; each road, knowing that the others could break the contract as soon as they so desired and without any penalty for so doing, became suspicious of its rivals and was very hasty in believing reports of such viola- tions. This was the great weakness in the Southwestern Rail- way Rate Association — that, as Midgely testified, 1 it depended solely upon the honor of members. Each manager knew that he could not go into court and sue for balances withheld from him ; hence there was a constant distrust, lest, when any member should be called upon to pay over a large amount, he would refuse, and a disruption ensue. This weakness was also present from the first in the Southern Railway and Steam- ship Association, but there the difficulty was obviated in part by the system of deposits and forfeits which was soon after- wards adopted. Taking into account this extra-legal nature of the pooling contract, one cannot fail to agree with the statement made by Midgely ; when speaking of the necessity of legalizing such contracts, 2 he says : " Until that result is reached, apportionment schemes, however well devised, will have but a precarious existence and an imperfect trial." In fact, the fairness of this position, which Midgely took in 1879, is recognized by the Interstate Commission in their report for 1897 when they say : 3 " Pooling in this coun- try had not been tested previous to the act under such circum- stances as to make its success or failure then a fair criterion of what legalized contracts of that sort might accomplish." 1 Report on Internal Commerce, 1879, p. 58. 2 Ibid. * Report for 1897, p. 49. 92 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. It is obviously unfair to judge of an experiment when made under imperfect conditions. Nor should we judge of the pool by any weaknesses which it may have shown in the early part of its development. Such an authority as Hadley 1 has made the statement that " Pools were better administered in 1880 than in 1877, and better in 1886 than in 1880." This is only natural when we consider that at first pools were only experi- ments. Their natural evolution resulted in an improved form. So to be perfectly just in forming an estimate of the appor- tionment agreement, we should consider it only in its most recent form, and then allow for the weakness due to its unen- forcible character in the courts. There have been certain abuses connected with the pool that have stirred up what is an undoubtedly just indignation. The methods employed by the Southern Association to disci- pline unruly members and to force into the agreement certain recalcitrant roads, were certainly not altogether above-board. One of the roads forming the Colorado pool has become famous for its attempt to prevent the construction of a new road which would compete with another member of the pool ; the method employed was a point-blank refusal to haul the necessary construction material. To permit such action would be most unwise and uncommendable on the part of the com- munity, and, indeed, under existing law, a road which thus refused its services would be promptly set right. Necessity for Regulation of Pools. — Although the objections to permitting pools can be smoothed away, the community should never forget that even in thus allowing the roads to destroy such competition between the several parties to the agreement as a pool can eliminate, a force that has exercised a potent influence in the past on the charges and services of the railways will be destroyed. I cannot agree with the Interstate Commission 2 that " by the legalizing of pooling the 1 New York Mail and Express, May 20, 1897. 'Report, 1897, p. 49. Degree and Form of Co-operation. 93 public loses the only protection which it now has against the unreasonable exactions of transportation agencies," for even under a perfect pool there would exist strong competitive and other influences to prevent extortionate practices. But I nevertheless believe that an important rate-influencing power would be removed by the permission to pool. The history of pools may not show any examples of extor- tion, or of abuses which cannot be accounted for, but that is not a sufficient reason for placing such a vast power in the hands of the railroads as an unlimited right to pool would give them. It was in recognition of this fact that the Interstate Commission said in 1 894 : x " Pooling without other remedial legislation is, we think, unadvisable. Pooling under proper conditions to be approved by the commission and rendered capable of easy and direct regulation, with accompanying effective remedial legislation, we believe might safely be tried." In other words, we find the commission in 1894 expressing itself as in favor of trying pools, if at the same time such legislation were provided as would prevent any of the possible incidental abuses of the right to pool. This same view was upheld by the commission in their report for 1895, when they said : 2 " While the commission is impressed with the evils attending the present system of competition, often resulting in unequal rates and unlawful practices, and concedes that the practical results of that system upon the railroads and the public are unsatisfactory in many respects, it nevertheless believes that the re-establishment of pooling without adequate restrictions and further remedial legislation would be unwise." The commission's reason for believing that to do so would be unwise, was that without such legislation " it would be in the power of the combination to charge excessive rates for the transportation of staple commodities and necessaries of life, and thus to deprive the people of the benefits arising from the 1 P . 63. 94 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. competition which now exists." In their report for 1897, the commission take the same ground, when they say * : "In view of the whole situation, a majority of the commission would be inclined to recommend that the experiment (of legalizing pooling) be tried if suitable safeguards are provided. We are all agreed that the enormous power which such a measure would place in the hands of railroad companies ought not to be granted, unless the exercise of that power is properly restrained in advance." Form, of Regulation. — This certainly seems reasonable enough ; the only difficulty to be solved is in regard to the exact form which regulation should take. It is one thing to say that competition has resulted in evil and therefore we should allow pools, which, however, should be regulated in order to prevent possible abuse, and it is entirely another thing to prescribe the limits within which the regulating is to be applied. In their report for 1895, 2 the Interstate Commission suggest, as an adequate substitute for the safeguards which competition is supposed to afford, the regulation of rates by the commis- sion. To this end, they believed it would be necessary that the rates established by the combination should be subject to effective control by the commission. This exercise of authority would be justified, they claimed, by the fact that it is in the nature of a condition upon which the government grants to certain corporations the privilege of forming a combination or limited monopoly. Such a grant would constitute an excep- tion to the general policy of the federal laws prohibiting trusts and combinations in restraint of trade. Conditions have always been attached to government grants of monopolies and special privileges. The railroad corporations in effect repre- sent that their business is of such a nature that, if subjected to the restrictions upon combination which the policy of the 1 1897, p- 49- Degree and Form of Co-operation. 95 law imposes upon other kinds of business, the result will be destructive to themselves and injurious to the commercial interests of the country ; and they ask to be relieved from the effects of this policy, and that an exception be made in their case because of the exceptional character and relations of public transportation. While regulation of rates by the commission would undoubt- edly be justified according to this line of reasoning, a difficult problem still remains to be solved in determining how this regulation shall be actually administered — what form shall it take and on what principles shall it act ? The Patterson bill, in 1894, answered this question by providing a system whereby all pooling contracts should be obliged to receive the sanction of the commission before becoming legal. This bill proposed to amend Section 5 of the Act of 1887, by declaring pools unlawful, unless they conformed to the follow- ing conditions : " Every such contract shall be in writing and filed with the commission created by this act, and shall become lawful and enforceable between the parties thereto at the expiration of twenty days from the filing thereof, unless the commission shall, upon inspection thereof, make an order disapproving the same : and it shall be the duty of the com- mission to make such order of disapproval whenever, upon such inspection, it shall be of opinion that the operation of any such contract would result in unreasonable rates, unjust dis- crimination, inferior service to the public, or otherwise con- travene any of the provisions of this act." In~other words, a pooling contract was to be submitted to the commission, which had authority to disapprove any contract that would produce undesirable results. Nor did the commission, under this bill, give up its supervision over a pool which had been once approved. It was further provided that the commission should " observe the working, operation, and effect of every such contract upon the transportation and business of the country and of the several contracting parties ; " also that it should 96 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. " investigate all complaints relating to the rates, charges, facili- ties, or practices maintained by or under any such contract," and when any of these were found to be " unreasonable or excessive, or to result in any unjust discrimination," the com- mission was to " issue an order requiring such rates, charges, facilities or practices maintained by or under such contract, to be changed," or, if necessary, to disapprove the contract itself. All findings of the commission disapproving such contracts were to be subject to review by a circuit court of the United States, the burden of proof to fall on the railroad company, while the commission should be a party defendant. This bill, while it undoubtedly covered all the main points, was expressed in general terms and thereby possessed a weakness which might have been cured by a little more explicitness regarding the exact nature of the contracts to be disapproved. Another weakness of the bill was that it did not provide for any appeal in case the commission approved a pool to which individuals had objections. It seems to me to be only just that, if the railroads are to have the right to appeal to the United States Courts from an unsatisfactory decision, the same privilege should be accorded to any who might believe to be objectionable a pool which the commis- sion had approved. The Cullom bill, introduced in the Senate in 1 897, provided that pools should be lawful only after their approval by the commission ; that the contract should be for a term not to exceed five years, and should name the maximum and mini- mum rates to be charged by the common carriers parties to such contract. The duties of the commission as set forth in this bill are similar to those of the Patterson bill, except that the following more explicit wording is used : " to observe the working, operation, and effect of every contract upon the transportation and business of the country, making such examinations and investigations in relation thereto as the commission may deem necessary, and to investigate all Degree and Form of Co-operation. 97 complaints relating to the rates, charges, facilities, or practices maintained by or under such contract." It is further provided that " whenever the commission, after due notice and reason- able opportunity to be heard, shall find that any such rates, charges, facilities, or practices are excessive or unreasonable, or result in any unjust discriminations as between individuals, localities, or articles of traffic, . . . the commission shall issue an order requiring such rates, charges, facilities, or prac- tices maintained under such contract to be changed, modified, or corrected," as maybe necessary, or shall even disapprove and annul the contract altogether. The Patterson clause provid- ing for appeal to United States Courts is practically reinserted in the Cullom bill. The same weakness is apparent in allow- ing only the roads to appeal in case of an adverse decision by the commission. If an amendment embodying the change just suggested were made to the bill presented by Senator Cullom in 1 897, it would, in my opinion, afford the necessary safeguards against an abuse of the right to pool. The shipping public is just as much interested in a decision by the commission as are the railroads, so I would advise that all interested parties be given that right to appeal which Senator Cullom would grant only to the railroads. Of course the idea of the Cullom bill was that the interests of the shipper would be looked after by the commission — that the commission would not approve a pool- ing contract which violated the rights of the shipping public. This, however, gives the investigations by the commission a wrong status, the commission becomes the advocate of the public against the railroad. The status of the commission should be that of an impartial tribunal, looking equally to the interests of all concerned. Both the shipper and the railroad company should be given equal right to appeal from a pooling decision of the commission to a higher tribunal. This amend- ment might secure only negative results, but even as such the results would be of importance. 98 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Summarized briefly, my recommendations as to the form of regulation which should be adopted by this country to prevent any abuse of the permission to pool are as follows : Contracts apportioning traffic among competing roads should be unlawful except when approved by the commission ; that body should have authority to alter or reject altogether con- tracts submitted to it, and an appeal should be allowed from its decision to the United States Courts, such appeal to be taken by either the railroads or any other interested party. Further, the commission should keep a strict watch over the operation and actual workings of the pool, and if any abuse such as discrimination between persons or places should creep in, the proper steps should be taken for their elimination, the pool being utterly annulled if no other way could be found by which to do away with the evil. To adopt such a plan of regulation would undoubtedly put a tremendous power into the hands of the commission, but it seems to me that a safeguard has been provided in the gener- ous appeal-rights given to all interested parties. Some advo- cates of pooling have gone so far as to object to the supervision of such contracts by the commission, because it would give that body too great an influence. As T. J. Greene, one of those who holds this view, has said, the commissioners would be given indirectly " a tremendous power." x But to grant the railroad what he advocates, the right to pool without any supervision, would be a more injudicious step than the adher- ence to our present policy. I heartily agree with the vigor- ous language used by the Interstate Commission in regard to this matter in the report for 1 897 : 2 " The members of the Interstate Commerce Commission wish to say in the strongest possible terms that they are unanimous in the opinion that to overturn the Trans-Missouri decision, to repeal the fifth section and enact in its place a pooling bill, thereby permitting and 1 Nation, December 15, 1892. 2 1897, p. 50. Degree and Form of Co-operation. 99 inviting unlimited combination between carriers, would be little better than a crime against the people of the United States, unless this tribunal, or some other tribunal, is at the same time invested with adequate powers of control.'' To grant the permission to pool, even with a strict system of regulation, may seem to many to be a radical step possess- ing the characteristics of a blind experiment. It seems to me, however, that the radical step was taken in 1887, when, instead of adopting the recommendation of the Cullom Committee that the matter be left undecided until a report could be obtained from the new commission, or instead even of taking the mod- erate step of providing for regulation, Congress blindly pro- hibited all pools. It is not too late now to give the country a fair trial of the pooling system under proper regulations, and Congress should take appropriate action to that end. SOURCES OF MATERIAL AND BIBLIOGRAPHY. The information contained in this paper on " Railway Co-opera- tion ' ' has been obtained in general from three sources : govern- mental and railroad reports, text-books, and periodical literature. The most important source has been the body of reports prepared by the federal and State governments. First in importance come the reports of the Congressional Committees : Windom in 1874 (Sen. Rep. 307, 1st Session, 43d Cong.), Reagan in 1878 (House Rep. 245, 2d Session, 45th Cong.), and Cullom in 1886 (Sen. Rep. 46, 1st Session, 49th Cong.); and the report of the New- York Legislative Committee, the "Hepburn," in 1879 ("Pro- ceedings of the Special Committee on Railroads," New York Assembly, 1879). The Annual Reports, beginning in 1877, on the Internal Com- merce of the United States, prepared by Joseph Nimmo, chief of the Bureau of Statistics, have furnished a valuable contemporary view of the railroad situation as it developed from year to year. The reports of the various State railroad commissions, especially those of Massachusetts, New York and Iowa, have been valuable for a similar reason, though necessarily more local in scope. The annual reports of the Interstate Commerce Commission have formed the best source of this kind since 1887. Under the head of reports would also come those of the individual railroads, of which I have used especially those of the Pennsylvania, the Baltimore & Ohio, and the New York Central. Next in importance to these original sources have been those various .scientific compilations which, for want of a better name, I call the text -books. Under this head I would include a number of works which vary greatly in value and reliability. Those used most frequently have^been Professor Hadley's valuable work on "Rail- road Transportation " (1885), Van Oss' "American Railroads as Investments " (1894), Charles Francis Adams' " Railroads : Their Origin 1 and Problems " (1878), Dabney's " Public Regulation of Railways" (1892), and Stickney's " Railroad Problem " (1893). The less important works consulted have been Hudson's " Railways (100) Sources of Material and Bibliography. ioi and the Republic," Ringwalt's "Development of Transportation Systems in the United States, " McCain's "Compendium of Trans- portation Theories," Larrabee's " Railroad Question," Dos Passos' "The Interstate Commerce Act," and Cook's " Corporation Problem." A very valuable mass of material has been found in the numerous articles in the periodicals and magazines, of which I give a list of the most important : Hudson : " Southern Railway and Steamship Association ;" Quar- terly Journal of Economics, Vol. V. Clarke : " State Railway Commissions ; Publications of the Ameri- can Economic Association, Vol. VI. Hadley : "Railroad Pools;" Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. IV. Johnson : "Industrial Services of the Railways;" Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. V. "Relation of Taxation to Monopolies;" Annals, Vol. IV. " Current Transportation Topics " (I and II); Annals, Vols. IX and X. " Monopoly and Competition in Railway Charges;" New York Independent, second issue of Septem- ber, 1897. Taussig : " Contribution to the Theory of Railway Rates ;" Quar- terly Journal of Economics, Vol. V. Seligman : " Railway Tariffs and the Interstate Commerce Act ;" Political Science Quarterly, Vol. II. Walker: "Western Freight Association;" Forum, Vol. VIII. " Has the Interstate Commerce Law Been Beneficial ?" Forum, Vol. XVII. Newcomb: "Reasonable Railway Rates;" Annals of the Ameri- can Academy, Vol. V. "Railway Competition;" Engineer- ing Magazine, Vol. IX. Also series of articles in the American Statistical Association's Reports, Vol. V. Knapp : " Some Observations on Railroad Pooling ;" Annals, Vol. VIII. Dabney : " Basis of the Demand for Public Regulation of Indus- try;" Annals, Vol. II. Prouty : " Railway Pooling, from the People's Point of View;" Forum, Vol. XXIV. 102 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. Blanchard : " Prohibition of Railroad Pools ;" Forum, Vol. X. Midgely : " Wars in Railroad Rates ;" Forum, Vol. XX. Virtue : ' ' The Anthracite Combinations ; ' ' Quarterly Journal of Economies, Vol. X. In addition to the articles contained in this list, information has been obtained from other less important articles, and also from the newspaper and trade press. The Nation, the Mail and Express, the Philadelphia Public Ledger, the Financial Chronicle, the Official Railway Guide, the Railway World, and the Railway Gazette have been the main sources from which facts, dates and other details have been obtained. The recent history of the traffic associations before the courts has been found in the following legal references : United States vs. Trans-Missouri Freight Association et al. : 169 U. S. 290. Decision of this case by the Circuit Court is in 53 Fed. Rep. 440, and the decision of the Circuit Court of Appeals is in 19 U. S. App. 36 and 24 L. R. A. 73. The Briefs of Counsel in this case contain a valuable discussion of traffic associations and railway co-operation. United States vs. Joint Traffic Association et al.: 171 U. S. 505. Consult also : Decision of the Circuit Court. Decision of Circuit Court of Appeals, and Briefs of Counsel. Numerous other miscellaneous sources have been utilized to a greater or less extent, such as the Congressional debates, and the testimony and investigations of specialists. Under the latter head would come Blanchard' s papers on " Railway Pooling," the Mail and Express (May 8, 11, 13, 15, 18, 20 and 22, 1897); the writ- ings and testimony of Albert Fink in regard to the Organization of Pools, Differential Rates, and Legal Status of Traffic Associa- tions ; and the Thurman, Washburne and Cooley " Report on Dif- ferential Rates to the Seaboard. ' ' Railway Co-operation in the United States* BY WILSON STILZ. (103) CONTENTS. Railway Co-operation in the United States, part first. Evolution of Railway Co-operation. PAOB. I. Co-operation of Connecting Lines to Promote Through Traffic. (i) The beginning of co-operation about 1850 107 (2) Co-operation of connecting lines never a real problem .... 108 (3) Public favor does not stop with a merely negative attitude . . 109 (4) Joint through traffic handled largely by organizations separate from the railroads 112 II. Co-operation of Competing Lines in Restraint of Rate Competition. (1) Introductory Ilj (2) The period from 1867 to 1877 : A. The Granger movement : causes, origin and nature. Granger legislation ; indirect results and the end of the agitation for reduced rates 114 B. Connection of co-operation and the Granger move- ment 123 C. Course of railway co-operation in restraint of competi- tion 125 D. Summary 130 (3) The period from 1877 to 1887 : A. A new phase of the rate question as a leading problem . 131 B. Results of the fact that discrimination had become the leading question. A lessened cause of dispute and a dispute less allied to the problem of co-operation. 131 C. The traditional feeling against restraint pf competition increased 134 D. Experience of pools and rate wars 135 E. Summary of the changes in the pooling situation by 1887 138 F. The growing demand for national regulation .... 139 G. The "Interstate Commerce Act" 142 (4) The period from 1887 to the present : A. Character in general I4S B. Restraint of competition after 1887 147 106 Railroad Co-operation in the United States. PAGE. C. Illegality of rate agreements ; the "Trans-Missouri" and " Joint Traffic " cases 149 D. Attitude of the courts and of the Commission on the question of competition : D 1 . Interpretation of the " long and short haul " clause 156 D 2 . The question of relativity of rates .... 160 D 3 . The Commission on " Pooling " 161 E. Summary of the present situation 162 III. Co-operation to Consolidate Freight Classifications. (i) Introductory 164 (2) History of freight classification 165 PART SECOND. The Present Needs of Railway Co-operation. I. Through Routing and Through Rating. (1) What should be the practice 171 (2) What the present practice is 171 (3) The remedy 172 II. Freight Classification. (1) A uniform classification desirable 173 (2) How to secure a uniform classification 173 III. Co-operation in Restraint of Rate Competition. (i) No a priori conclusion 174 (2) Railway competition not inherently desirable for the railroads . 175 (3) Railway competition not inherently desirable for the public . . 178 (4) Relative merits of different forms of restraint 182 (5) The pool is inherently, as well as relatively, desirable .... 1 83 (6) Pooling should be legalized 187 (7) Precautions against abuse of pooling 189 (8) Brief summary of the situation in the three forms of co-opera- tion hitherto developed in the United States 190 IV. A Railway Clearing- House. (1) England and the United States in the past 191 (2) The need of a clearing-house in this country 192 (3) The necessary preliminaries to a clearing-house system . . . 194 (4) Legalization of pooling the most pressing need of the co-opera- tive situation 194 PART I. The Evolution of Railway Co-operation in the United States. I. Co-operation of Connecting Lines to Promote Through Traffic. § i. Railway co-operation made its first appearance in the United States about the year 1850 as the result of a demand for improved facilities in long-distance transportation. Prior to that time, our railroads had been built mainly to meet local needs, to connect neighboring towns, to tap the coal fields, or to supplement water transportation. The con- cept of long-distance through traffic had not as yet attained dominating importance, and, therefore, though the short, local lines not infrequently formed a continuous series, no need was felt, and no attempt was made, to connect their termini. By the year 1850, however, the social and economic development of the country had resulted in the beginnings of a consider- able through traffic that at once made apparent the defects of existing conditions. Passengers vigorously protested against the inconvenience and delay of having to go from the terminus of one road to that of another. They demanded a rail con- nection and whatever else might be necessary to obviate change of cars and to secure the desired facilities for a long journey. Shippers made a like demand on the ground that freight was lost or delayed in transfer from road to road, to say nothing of the cost of repeated loading and unloading. The smoother and more rapid working of through traffic was, moreover, at least equally desirable from the standpoint of the carriers themselves. Connecting lines saw that they had everything to gain and nothing to lose by developing long-