1 liwifc 'i i'fiiT , ^iili:'. :i;i\"!. i:li I M/!l'i ':;;!':■: ii''!'!!'!' l!iiiillll!!i;iii:i;;i£;''ii ■i ■I ill# j|||ii| BOUGHT WITH THE INCOME FROM THE SAGE ENDOWMENT FUND THE GIFT OF Hetirg M. Sage 1891 .J^....a,.x!..€.o.7..*f... :^M'^-i-''--'i-- Cornell University Library HE2123 .M17 olin 3 1924 032 578 241 Cornell University Library The original of this book is in the Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924032578241 BY THE SAME AUTHOR THE WORKING OF THE RAILROADS an elementary exposition of the devel- opment, the working, and the inter- relation of the different departments of railroad administration Contents I — The Transportation Function 11 — Construction and Operation III— Traffic IV — Accounting and Statistics V — Financial and Executive Admin- istration VI — Correlation VII — Integration VIII — Relations to the Public and the State i2rao, 283 pages. $1.50 net, by mail $1,63 HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY NEW YORK RAILROAD FREIGHT RATES IN RELATION TO THE INDUSTRY AND COMMERCE OF THE UNITED STATES BY LOGAN G. Mcpherson Lecturer on Traosportation, Johns Hopkins University, Author of " The Working of the Railroads " NEW YORK HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 1909 1) Copyright, 1909 BY HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY Published May ^ 1909 A>a^'5o1 M PREFACE Throughout the general discussion of 1905-06 as to additional Federal legislation for the regulation of the railroads became evident the need for a definite, concrete and fairly comprehensive exposition of the effect of the freight rates of the railroads upon the industry and com- merce of the United States. In the desire to set forth the prime factors in this relation, the anatomy and physi- ology as well as the pathology of the freight rate struc- ture, the writer has visited every part of the country, in- terviewing principal shippers, the representatives of com- mercial organizations and the officers in charge of the traffic departments of various railroads. The steps of the development of the freight rate struc- tures have been largely attained through discussions, of which the records have disappeared, and through cor- respondence no longer in existence. They remain in the memory of the veteran traffic managers who have readily imparted much of the information contained in these pages. Their recollection, however, has confessedly not always been exact as to dates, leaving it possible, in parts of the book, to show only the general sequence of the development. The mission has been greatly facilitated by th^ lec- tureship on transportation which the writer holds at Johns Hopkins University, and by an extended experi- ence in active railroad service. Partial results of this research have been embodied in lectures delivered at Johns Hopkins University, Columbia University, Yale University, the University of Chicago and the University of Wisconsin ; in articles that have appeared in the North American Review, the Political Science Quarterly, Rail- way Age, Railroad Gazette, Railway World, and news- papers of various cities. These lectures and articles have been freely used in the preparation of this volume. CONTENTS CHAPTER I Introductory PAGE Division of Labor — Development of Industry and Com- merce — Functions of Transportation — Effects of the Transportation Charge i CHAPTER II The Channels of Traffic Early American Commerce — Its Trend Inland — Railroads versus Canals — Erosion of Traffic Channels by Ex- change of Foodstuffs for Manufactured Products — Movement of Raw Materials of Manufacture — Move- ment of Deciduous Fruits 4 CHAPTER III The Preparation of Foodstuffs The Grain Supply — Machinery Introduced in Harvesting and Preparation for Consumption — The Meat Supply — Beef — Hog Products — Lamb — Poultry — Eggs and But- ter — Truck Farm Products — Orchard Products — Su- premacy of the American Apple — Development of the Peach and Grape — The Melon Tribe — Citrus Fruits — The Canning Industry 15 CHAPTER IV The Distribution of Foodstuffs Involution of Distribution — The Commission Man — Fruit Growers' Associations — The Refrigerator Car — Cold Storage — Elimination of the Broker in Grain Market- ing — Direct Methods of the Packing Houses — Depart- ment of Agriculture and the Handling of Food Ship- ments — Work of State Colleges of Agriculture — The Railroads and the Education of the Farmers — Problem of Car Distribution — Good Roads and the Problems of Distribution ... 28 vi Contents CHAPTER V The Distribution of Raw Material and Merchandise PAGE Elimination of the Middleman — Movement of Cotton,. Iron Ore, Pig Iron, Coal, Petroleum, Lumber, Tobacco, Sugar, Woodpulp, Copper and Lead Ores — Influence of Segregation in Production and Manufacture on Distribution by Rail — Relation of Rates to Character of Freight — Necessity of the Middleman in Distribu- tion of Manufactured Products — The Development of the Main Traffic Channels between Distributing Centers . . . 40 CHAPTER VI The Transportation Charge and Prices The Transportation Charge as Related to the Consumer — As Related to Production — Rates and Prices, Illus- trated by Food Products in New York, by Manufac- tured Products in St. Louis, by Staples in General Use — The Transportation Charge as Related to Materials of Manufacture, Cotton, Wheat, Tobacco, Sugar — Special Instances, Bananas, Hides, Fertilizers, Pulp, and Ores, etc. — Shifting Sources as Influencing Rate Structures — Rates on Foodstuffs not a Factor in Price — A Watermelon Rate Incident — Rates on Raw Material enter Cost of Manufacture— Extensive Transportation makes Low Rates Possible 47 CHAPTER VII The Regional Rate Structures Determining Causes of the Freight Rate Structures: (i) The New England Rate Structure — Preservation of Manufacturing Interests Dictates Adjustments in Rates. (2) The Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory — New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore in their Rela- tion to Chicago — Rate-Cutting — The Trunk Line Asso- ciation — The Evolution of The Percentage System — The Central Traffic Association — The JDifferential — Basing Points — The Interstate Commerce Law, 1887, and the Long and Short Haul — The Percentage Sys- tem_ and Local Rates — Ohio Rates. (3) Trans-Mis- sissippi and Trans-Missouri Territory — The . Missis- sippi River as Basing Line — "^ixed Differences," as Affecting Chicago and St. Louis to Southwest, to Missouri River, to St. Paul, to far West— The Col- orado Common Points Rates — Water Rates and the Denver Differential— " Jobbers' Rates." (4) South of the Ohio and East of the Mississippi — Influence of Water Rates and Water Points — Norfolk Differen- tial—Virginia Cities Rate— Erection of Basing Points —The Atlanta Rate. (5) Texas— Intrastate Maxi- Contents vli PAGE mum Rate — Common Point Territory — Judge Reagan's Theory of Distribution for Texas — Houston Differen- tial — The Water Rate Again — Texas Railroad Com- mission — Weakness of the Common Point System and effects of Decentralization of Distribution — The Emergency Rate and the Texas Commission. (6) The Pacific Coast and Trans-Continental Traffic — Exports to the Orient — General Character of Trade with the East — Clipper Ships and Trans-Continental Rates — Effect of Mode of Transportation on Mer- chants' Stocks — Development of the Trans-Conti- nental Rate — Back Traffic in Fruits, Fish and Lumber — The Interstate Commerce Commission and the Lum- ber Rate — Inter-Regional Traffic — Regional Gateways and Proportional Rates 67 CHAPTER VIII Commodity Rate Structures (i) Grain and Grain Products — Export Trade and the Through Rate-^Attitude of Boston and the Differen- tials — Duluth in the Grain Trade — Competition for Back Traffic in Wheat — Grain Export by the Gulf and Resulting Rate War — ^The Gulf Ports Differential — Flour Rates. (2) Livestock and Dressed Meats Rates — Transportation " on the hoof " and the Cattle Rate — Rates on Livestock and Packing House Products. (3) Cotton — Development of Cotton Milling and Elimination of Excessive Rates — Texas Rates — Com- pressing in Transit and the Compress Fee. (4) Lumber — Shifting Rates due to Shifting Sources of Supply — Effect on Manufactures. (5) Types of Com- modity Rate Structures — Adjustment Necessary be- tween Production and Consumption — Difficulties of this Adjustment Illustrated by Coal, Brick, Glass, Cement. Import and Export Traffic — Through Rates — Insta- bility of Steamship Rates — Ruling of Interstate Com- merce Commission 117 CHAPTER IX Early Tariffs and Classifications The Wagon Toll the First Basis of the Railway Rate-r Rates in the South Carolina and Georgia Charters — The "Distance" Tariff— Bulk and Weight Merged in Classifications — Classification in South Carolina, 1855 — Diversified Manufacture Separates Tariff and Classifi- cation — Freight Charges Finally Based on Weight, According to Class — ^Carload Rates 148 CHAPTER X Early Rivalries and the Beginning of Through Service Modification of the Distance Tariff— Introduction of the viii Contents PAGE " Basing Point " — Military and Postal Necessities Pave the Way for Interstate Traffic — Removal of State Restrictions and Allowing Act of 1866 — Development of Fast Freight Lines and General Through Traffic . 156 CHAPTER XI Rate Wars and Traffic Agreements Water-Forced Rates — Multiplicity of Junctions — Excess of Transportation Facilities — Competition for Traffic — Resulting Rate Wars — Growth of Rebating — Pooling Traffic — Adoption of the Trunk Line Percentage System — Beneficial Effects of the Traffic Associations — Freight Rate Structures Given Form by Develop- ment of Freight Traffic 165 CHAPTER XII Secondary Freight Services Switching — Spurs — " Belt " Lines — Lighters — Private In- dustrial Tracks — Tap Lines — Elevation and Warehous- ing — Special Equipment Cars — Private Car Companies — Refrigerator Cars — Icing — Palace — Livestock Cars — Tank Cars — Coal Gondolas — Mileage on Private Cars 174 CHAPTER XIII Incidental Developments of the Freight Service Bill of Lading, Ordinary and at Carrier's Liability — De- murrage — " Reciprocal Demurrage " — Track Storage Charge — Reconsignment — Diversion en route — Milling in Transit — Carload and less than Carload Rates — Effect of Enlargement of Freight Cars — Rate Basis Established on the Hundredweight — The " Spread " in the Carload Rate — Increase in number of Carload Ratings — Resulting Decentralization of Distribution — Increase in " Jobbing " — Origin of the Chain Stores . 188 CHAPTER XIV The Freight Traffic Department of Railroad Administration Association of General Freight Agents — Freight Solicitors and Rate-Cutting — Freight Traffic Managers — Indus- trial Agents — Pernicious Legislation — Healthy Effect of Law Against Rebates, Passes, etc. — Freight Officers and Extension of Markets — The Claim Agent — ^Joint Weighing and Inspection — Bureau of Explosives . . 206 Contents « CHAPTER XV The Basis for the Transportation Charge PAGE Primitive Tolls, for Use of Road and Motive Power — ■ Cost of Roadway and Maintenance — Of Equipment and Administration — Consumption of Fuel, etc. — Cost of Transportation — The Ton Mile — Heterogeneity of Freight Traffic — The Classification Basis — Experi- mental Rates — Raw Material Rates for Back Traffic — " What the Traffic will Bear " — Relation of Capitaliza- tion to Rates — The Cape Cod Ship Canal Project as Illustrative — Current Valuation and Rates .... 216 CHAPTER XVI Public Sentiment and Legislation to 1887 The Passing of the Canal — Encouragement of the Railroads — Early Traffic Small in Volume and Variety — Evils of too Rapid Construction^Rate-Cutting and General Business — Progress Toward Uniformity of Rates — Long and Short Haul Rates — The Granger Laws — The Birth of the Railroad Commission — Interstate Commerce Demands Federal Supervision — The Cul- lom Report — The Interstate Commerce Law, 1887 . 235 CHAPTER XVII The Interpretation of the Interstate Commerce Law Provisions of the Law — Proscription of Pooling — Selig- man's Prophecy of Railroad Amalgamation — The In- terstate Commerce Commission and the Long and Short Haul — The Supreme Court and the Commis- sion's Ruling in the Summerville Hay and Danville Cases — The Import Rate Decision — The Freight Bureau Cases — The Rate-Making Power — Judge Cooley on Large and Small Shipment Rates — Failure of the Commission to Abolish Rebates 250 CHAPTER XVIII Further Development in Public Sentiment and Legislation The " Midnight " Tariff — Traffic Agreements — Advantages of Pooling and the Evils of Unrestrained Competition — The Anti-Trust Law — Dissolution of the Trans- Missouri Freight Association — Procedure of the Joint Traffic Associations — The Elkins Act, 1903. Effect of Panic of 1893 on the Railroads— The Unpreparedness X Contents FAOE for Demands of Sudden Prosperity of 1899— Amalga- mation of Railroads — " Community of Interests " — Cassatt Employs this Agency in Abolishing Rebates — The Carnegie Steel Co. and the Pennsylvania Lines — Renewed Prosperity and Congestion of Traffic — Improper Use of Freight Cars a Primary Cause — In- creasing Revenues of the Railroads and the Senate Investigation 261 CHAPTER XIX Public^Sentiment and the Hepburn Bill Reviev^ of Cases Before Interstate Commerce Commission — Prominence Given Rates in Senate Doc. 257, 1904 — The Esch-Townsend Bill — The Hepburn Bill — Its Pro- visions — The Commission and the Rate-Making Power — Complaints to Commission Based on Hepburn Bill — Classification of Hay — Grouping of Cases and Decisions of Commission — Brick Rates — Emergency Coal Rate and Indiana Commission — Oil Rates — Car Distribution, Bituminous Coal, Citrus Fruits — Switching Charges and Elevator Service — Carload Rates — Community Complaints — Review of Number and Character of Complaints 275 CHAPTER XX The Influence of the Commission Toward Uniformity of Procedure Accounting Systems — Association of American Railway Ac- counting Officers — The Statistical Difficulty in Uniform Accounts — Uniformity of Classification — The Official, Southern and Western Classifications — Efforts Toward a Practical Uniform Classification — State Classifica- tions — Federal versus State Rate Regulation — Develop- ment of Interstate Traffic and the Freight Rate Struc- tures — The Correlation of Rates — Local Interests and Interstate Rates — Conflicts Between State and Federal Authority .... .... ... 301 CHAPTER XXI Traffic Experts in the Employ of Shippers Development of the Intermediary — Far-Reaching Effects of a Rate Change — Sensitiveness of Rates on Com- modities — Necessity for Specialization in _ Rates Af- fecting a Corporation or Firm — City Freight Traffic Bureaus — Traffic Representatives, Good and Bad — Im- proper Exploitation of " Paper " Rates — Railroad En- couragement of the Expert Traffic Representative^ Traffic Clubs— Beneficial Effects in Service . . . 314 Contents xi CHAPTER XXII The Commerce of the Cities PAGE Production, Consumption, and Distribution in Cities Af- fected by Rates — North Atlantic Seaboard, Boston — Buffalo — Pittsburg— Cleveland and Columbus— South- eastern Rates Complaint — Cincinnati — Louisville — Chi- cago — St. Louis— Kansas City— St. Paul and Minne- apolis — Denver — Helena and Butte— the South and Southeast, Richmond, Charleston, Memphis, Mont- gomery, Mobile, and New Orleans— Oklahoma — Texas, Dallas, Ft. Worth, Galveston— Pacific Coast, San Francisco, Spokane — The Situation at Indian- apolis 325 CHAPTER XXIII A Comparison of the Railroads with the Agri- cultural AND Manufacturing Industries Capital, Profits, Expenditures Compared in Agriculture, Manufactures and Railroads — Wages Similarly Com- pared 374 CHAPTER XXIV The Progressive Achievement of the Railroads Operating Revenues, Expenses, and Income of Railroads — Capitalization — Mileage and Equipment — Traffic — Ratios of Increase, 1875 to 1905 — Intensive Growth — Progressive Efficiency — Over-capitalization and the Interstate Commerce Commission's Report on Inter- corporate Relationships — Traffic Conditions as Ex- planatory of Popular^ Criticism — Problems in Demand of Future for Increase of Facilities — Probable In- crease in Capitalization .... 384 CHAPTER XXV Conclusion Lack of Precedent in Construction of Freight Rates — The Freight Rate Structure Complicated by Multi- plicity of Products and Manufacture — The Competition for Capital — Rate Criticism Coincident with Inter- state Traffic — Complaints of Conditions, 1886 and at Present — The Existing Freight Rate Structure a Resultant of Needs of Industry and Commerce . . 397 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTORY As we are told, even in the schoolbooks used by chil- dren, our present civilization could not have been at- tained except through the division of labor. In the typi- cal early community the tailor made the clothes, the carpenter built the house, and the smith fashioned the tools, each with his own hands from material obtained near by. Each exchanged his handiwork for the prod- uct of the other and with the farmer for the product of the soil. In time, perhaps, the tailor, the carpenter, the smith, the other artisans of the community, and, likewise, the farmer, enlisted the help of one or more apprentices, or wage workers, as the case might be. Then it was not a simple exchange of the direct handiwork of one workman for the direct handiwork of another. The men employed by each artisan had to be supplied with portions of the products of the others. At a later stage the material used by different crafts was brought from distant places, often passing through more than one process before reaching the artisan who wrought it into its final form. The development of these processes has resulted in the industry and commerce of to-day. The food, the clothing, the implements, the buildings, of every com- munity are of material that may have been brought frbm the field or mine or forest within a dozen miles, or it may have been conveyed a thousand or two thousand miles or more. It therefore follows that there must not only be mechanism for carrying raw material from the source of supply to the various places where, through various processes, it is finally wrought into ultimate form, but there must be mechanism for conveying these finished 2 Railroad Freight Rates products to the widespread communities where they are consumed. Broadly speaking, the processes through which material passes from the source of supply into the finished prod- uct are those of industry; and the processes through which the finished product passes into the hands of the consumer are those of commerce. There is, of course, much buying and selling of material as it is transformed from one phase of manufacture to another, and, there- fore, the function of the merchant is still prominent in industry, but this is apart from distribution to the final consumer. Throughout all industry and all commerce the func- tion of transportation is conspicuous. Products may be carried by dray or wagon for short distances from the field, or merchandise of various kinds to and from the factory, the warehouse or the retail store, and cer- tain of the waterways take part in this function ; but the overwhelmingly preponderating transportation agency in this country is the railroad. The railroads carry raw material from farm and forest and mine to the places of concentration, to the places of preparatory process, to the places of intermediate process, to the places of final process. They carry products from these places of final process to the warehouses in the great distributing cen- ters, to the storehouses in the smaller cities and towns, to the shops of the retail merchants, and, in no inconsider- able degree, to the homes wherein they are used and consumed. Entering thus into every process of every industry, and into every process of distribution, the transportation function affects every person who is concerned either in the production or the consumption of any commodity of industry, of any article of commerce. That is, it affects the entire population. The charge for transportation en- ters into the cost of production of every article; the charge for transportation enters into the cost of distribu- tion of every article. A survey of the effect which the charges for trans- Introductory 3 portation have upon the various industries and the varied commerce of this country must, therefore, include a study of the extent to which they further or hinder the movement of the materials and the products of industry ; of the extent to which they advance or retard the prog- ress of commerce. Those immediately engaged in indus- try are the producers of raw material — the owners of and workers in the fields, the forests and the mines, the owners of and workers in the factories and the mills ; those immediately engaged in distribution are the own- ers and salesmen of the mills and factories, the wholesale merchants and their employees, the retail merchants and their employees. As every farmer and farm-hand di- rectly or indirectly consumes the products of mill and factory, and every manufacturer and worker in mill and factory consumes the products of the farm, and so on throughout industry and commerce, every producer is a consumer and every consumer is a producer. The work- ers in the arts and the professions, while not engaged in material production, consume material products. It is also necessary to consider the effect of the trans- portation charge upon the maintenance of the railways and upon their capacity for extension and enlargement to meet the needs of the industry and commerce of the future. The railroads must adequately perform their part as an integral factor in the material activities of the nation, and they must receive the consideration and the support which will enable them adequately to perform that part. As the first subject to be considered is the relation which the railroads bear to the movement of commodities, there must be a clear comprehension of that movement and the directions which it takes. CHAPTER II THE CHANNELS OF TRAFFIC The colonists who settled on the Atlantic seaboard were dependent for many generations upon the father- land for all manufactured articles except the crudest handiwork. The commerce which slowly developed was in the products of agriculture taken by wagon or by stage to the seaboard to be sent to Europe by the sailing vessels, which, in return, brought fabrics, firearms, house- hold utensils and even brick and other building material. The more important settlements were naturally, there- fore, on the harbors, Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Baltimore, Richmond, Wilmington, Charleston, Savan- nah. Even until the time of the Revolution there was very little commerce between one colony and another, but the area from which agricultural products were re- ceived for export and throughout which manufactures from Europe were distributed increased as the pioneers fought their way into the interior. During later years, as they penetrated beyond the mountains, at places nat- urally adapted to become bases of supplies, arose clusters of cabins that formed the nuclei of the present cities of Buffalo, Cleveland, Detroit, Milwaukee, and Chicago, on the Lakes; of Pittsburg, Cincinnati, Louisville, St. Louis, St. Paul, and Memphis, on the rivers; Mobile, New Orleans, and Galveston, on the Gulf; of Los Angeles, San Francisco, and Portland, on the Pacific. The domestic tranquillity and solidarity of interest brought about by the Revolution gave a stimulus to do- mestic manufacture and to the interchange of products between the colonies. Although this was enhanced by the War of 1812, and it was recognized that there was need of an extension and enlargement of the means of 4 The Channels of Traffic 5 communication between the Atlantic seaboard and the interior, the situation had not greatly changed within the dozen years that elapsed before the time when ex- periments were made with the building of roads of rails. The first railroads led from the seaports into the interior for but short distances, but they extended the area tribu- tary to each seaport, bringing products of the soil over greater distances to the seaboard, and furnishing a regu- lar and certain means by which the residents of the interior could obtain the supplies which they did not produce. That is, an early result of the building of the railroads was a furthering of the division of labor, the residents of the towns giving less attention to the grow- ing of food, and the farmers not being obliged to turn their hands to the making of so many things. The period from 1830 to i860 was one of contest be- tween the railroads and between the canals which had been built largely by aid of the various States. Toward the close of this era the superior efficiency of the rail- roads was generally recognized, and the canals, with but few exceptions, gradually lapsed into disuse. The railroads that had been built westward from Massachusetts Bay extended through Massachusetts and Connecticut to Albany and to New York. Lines from New York had extended to Buffalo ; from Philadelphia to Pittsburg; from Baltimore to the Ohio River. By the time of the Civil War certain of these railroads had reached Chicago, St. Louis, and Cincinnati, and from these cities other lines had been built radiating, not only throughout the interior States, but reaching toward the West and South, the Northwest and the Southwest. The lines from the ports on the South Atlantic and on the Gulf had penetrated to junctions at various places in the southern interior. There was direct communication by rail between Chicago and New Orleans, and lines of rails extended from the Gulf toward the interior of Texas. Along these various routes traffic had increased both in volume and in diversity. The Civil War, interrupting the industry and commerce 6 Railroad Freight Rates of the country in general, naturally brought a cessation in railroad building. Immediately after its close, how- ever, construction was resumed and railroads were rapidly extended. They wound a network over New England, the North Atlantic and the Middle States: they stretched farther into the West, sending out branches that covered the region from Missouri and Kansas to Minnesota and the Dakotas ; they reached down into Texas from St. Louis. In 1869 was driven the golden spike that marked the completion of the first through rail route from the Missouri River to the Pa- cific Coast. The railroads of the States south of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi Rivers had resumed active operation and were also iDcing extended, although less rapidly than in the North. Every section of the country was thus connected by rail with every other section and the main channels of traffic were then outlined. In the last forty years rail- road building east of the Missouri River has been inten- sive rather than extensive ; sections that theretofore were not supplied with railroads have now been traversed by these agencies until it is an exceptional State of which every county is not crossed by one or more lines. Instead of one rail route to the Pacific Coast there are now half a dozen, and cross lines are gradually extending over vast areas of a once barren West that irrigation has coaxed into fertility. The stimulus to manufacture given by the Revolution naturally made Boston the early industrial center. The commercial currents set in motion by the exchange of the handiwork of the domestic artisans for the products of the soil deepened the traffic channels already grooved by the barter through the seaports of the products of the soil for the manufactures of Europe. A pronounced step in this development occurred many years later when the building of railroads throughout the Ohio and Mis- sissippi Valleys led to grain from those regions being brought to the East in exchange for the diversified manu- factures of industrial centers that increased in the North The Channels of Traffic 7 Atlantic States. This exchange of food products for manufactured products is the primary force that has eroded the traffic channels of to-day. This force, mani- fested in diverse ways, has led to a multiplying and rami- fying of the channels. Foods of various kinds are brought from remote sources of supply to widespread markets. Raw material of one kind may be obtained at the factory's door, while another must be brought from across the continent. As the population has spread' throughout the country, the industrial area has extended, certain manufactures tending to segregate at a feW' centers, while others have become more widely diffused. Central and southern New England, southern New York, eastern Pennsylvania, and northern New Jersey,; are still the principal places of manufacture of the finer fabrics and articles of apparel, of carpets, rugs and vari- ous wares, of the smaller tools and more delicate bits of mechanism, and of countless articles of personal use and adornment. From this region this merchandise flows not only to the communities of the New England and North Atlantic States, but throughout the interior, the South, the Northwest, the West and Southwest, and up and down the Pacific Coast. This merchandise goes through Buffalo or Pittsburg to the interior States of Ohio, Indiana, Illinois, and Michigan, and by way of Chicago or St. Louis to the valleys of the Mississippi and the Missouri. It goes over the rail lines that extend from the Northern Atlantic seaports throughout the South and is also carried to this region by the coastwise steam- ers that connect at the South Altantic and Gulf ports with the railroads leading from these ports into the in- terior. This merchandise goes by rail to the ports on Lake Erie, thence by vessel to the head of the Lakes, and thence by rail throughout Minnesota, the Dakotas, Montana and Wyoming; or, it may go to this section over the all-rail routes via Chicago or St. Louis or through Canada. To the region between the Missouri River and the Rocky Mountains that lies to the south of these States this merchandise may go by all-rail routes 8 Railroad Freight Rates via Chicago or St. Louis; or via coastwise vessels to Norfolk, Newport News, Savannah, New Orleans, or Galveston, and thence by rail. To the Pacific Coast this merchandise may go over the rail lines through Canada, by way of St. Paul, or Chicago, or St. Louis, or Memphis; or it may go by vessel to Norfolk, Newport News, Savannah, or New Orleans, or Galveston and thence by rail ; or it may go by vessel to Tehuantepec or Colon, thence by rail across Mexico or Panama, and by vessel up the Pacific Coast; or it may go by vessel over the entire route through the Straits of Magellan, or* around Cape Horn. This merchandise not only may go from the Atlantic seaboard to these various regions via any one of these routes, but it does go in large vol- ume over every one of them; except that the all- water route around the Cape to the Pacific Coast is fall- ing into disuse. In reverse direction the grain and grain products of the Mississippi Valley flow throughout the East and Southeast. From the Dakotas and Minnesota they go to the East, either entirely by rail, or across Lake Michigan by car ferry; or via Duluth and vessel to the Lake Erie ports, and thence by way of the railroads or by way of the Erie Canal. From Nebraska, Kan- sas, Iowa, Missouri, Wisconsin, these products move by way of Chicago or St. Louis ; from the region south of Kansas by way of St. Louis, Galveston or Memphis or New Orleans. Livestock and meat products move to the East and the Southeast, over the same all-rail routes as the grain, from the ranches and farms that reach on the north to the Dakotas and on the south to Texas. This does not mean that all of the grain and all of the meat come from this western interior. Wheat is raised in nearly every State, and corn in many of the States of the Union, but in quantities that, except in these surplus grain-growing States in the Mississippi and Missouri Valleys, are usually not more than adequate for home consumption ; and so, also, with cattle and hogs. Those who Hve on the farms, in the villages, and in The Channels of Traffic 9 nearly all of the smaller cities and towns, obtain butter, eggs, milk, cheese and chickens from near by. But the growth of the larger cities has compelled their inhabi- tants to draw upon more remote sources for these foods which, in commercial parlance, are known as dairy prod- ucts. Eggs are shipped in carloads from as far as Texas and Arkansas on the south and the Dakotas and Minne- sota on the north, from Wisconsin, Tennessee and the Middle States to St. Louis, Chicago, Pittsburg, and the populous seaboard. Butter, cheese and chickens come from an area almost as extended. These products, of course, are supplemented by the surplus production of near-by farms. The larger cities draw milk from con- siderable distances, the milk trains that supply New York starting as far as four hundred and even four hundred and fifty miles from that city. The concentration of population in the large cities has also necessitated the going far afield for fruits and vegetables, and therefore has led to the production of these edibles on a large scale on truck farms and in or- chards. The populous region from Boston to Washing- ton obtains vegetables, not only from near-by gardens, but from great truck farms in western New York, east- ern Maryland and southward along the Atlantic Coast to Florida. From the Southeast and from the lands along the Gulf, and even from Utah and California, vegeta- bles and melons are sent in the spring to Pitts- burg, Chicago, and St. Louis; while in the autumn this southern region obtains vegetables from Wisconsin, Michigan, and other parts of the North and from Cali- fornia. Akin to this widely originating and widely circulating traffic is that in berries, peaches, apples, and oranges. Seafood enters largely into the traffic of the railroads. Special fish-trains are run on express time daily from Boston to New York, from New York to Philadelphia; fish- and oyster-trains from Philadelphia and Baltimore to Pittsburg, Cincinnati, and Chicago. Fish is also car- ried from the ports of the Southern Atlantic States into 10 Railroad Freight Rates the interior, and from New Orleans to St. Louis and Chicago. Special trains with halibut and salmon run directly through from the fisheries in the far Northwest to the Atlantic seaboard. The great source of supply of the raw material of leather is naturally identical with the cattle-raising re- gion of the West. The hides from the great packing houses and from other places of slaughter throughout the States are sent to the tanneries, of which the greater number are in the East, although a few in recent years have been built in the Middle West and in California. The greater portion of our wool is clipped from the sheep that graze to the east of the Rocky Mountains, but large quantities also come from Wyoming, Utah, Idaho, Oregon, Nevada, and California. It is sent to scouring and carding mills in the East and woven in the looms of the North Atlantic seaboard. Seventy-five per cent, or more of the cotton, — the raw material that forms the basis of by far the greater part of the clothing worn by the men, the women, and the children of every civiHzed nation, — is grown in the States of the South. It moves from the plantations by rail to the mills of Alabama, Georgia, and the Carolinas, to the mills of the North Atlantic seaboard, and through the ports of the South Atlantic and the Gulf also to the markets of New England and to those of Europe. From Texas and Oklahoma quantities are shipped as well to the Pacific Coast and to the Orient. Conspicuous channels of traffic are those of iron ore from the mines along Lake Superior by lake vessel to the furnaces near Chicago; and by lake vessel to the ports of Lake Erie, whence it is carried by rail to the furnaces of southern and eastern Ohio, northern West Virginia, Pennsylvania and western New York. The pig-iron into which the ore is converted at these fur- naces is taken to adjacent mills, where it is transformed into rails, beams, and angles that go to all parts of the United States, and into iron and steel ingots, blooms. The Channels of Traffic ii bars, billets, and sheets that are manufactured into ma- chinery, the smaller tools and countless devices. In Colo- rado are iron and steel mills that obtain ore from the Wyoming and Lake Superior mines, their products find- ing markets principally in the West. Mills in Alabama utilize the ores and coal of the South in the fashioning of products that penetrate the South and even to the north of the Ohio River. Before the invention of the modern blast furnace and of the processes that have so radically cheapened the manufacture of steel, virood was, even to a greater degree than at present, an indispensable and all-pervading sub- stance of general use. As the forests of New England and the East were cut away, this region was supplied with lumber that was brought down the Lakes and from Canada to Buffalo. Then the furniture factories mi- grated to the vicinity of the Michigan forests, and fac- tories for the manufacture of wagons and other vehicles, agricultural implements, and the various kinds of wood- enware, sprang up in Ohio, Indiana, and Illinois, which remain to-day the principal seats of this manufacture, whence these products radiate throughout the entire country. Michigan is still the leading center for the manufacture of the finer furniture, but excellent grades are made in Chicago, St. Louis, and other places in these interior States, and furniture factories are prospering in the Carolinas and other parts of the South. The lumber used in the Middle States is, however, no longer secured from adjacent forests, for they have been cut down and wasted by flood and fire. Yellow pine is now obtained from the South and the Southwest; pine, fir, and hem- lock from California and the far Northwest between the Rocky Mountains and the Pacific Ocean. Other commodities that are conspicuous in transpor- tation have various sources of origin and radiate through divers channels to places of need. From the Rocky Mountains, — from Utah and Nevada, Oregon, and New Mexico, — from the northern to the 12 Railroad Freight Rates southern national boundary, come the greater portion of the lead, copper, and silver that are wrought into the familiar forms of daily use. Material, other than iron and steel, that is used in building and other heavy construction is secured ordi- narily in the vicinity of the various places of use. There are brick kilns and lime and cement kilns adjacent to every large city. The finer kinds of brick and of cement, however, are marketed within radii that extend for hun- dreds of miles from the places of manufacture, moving, for example, from the Missouri River even to the Pacific Coast. What the age of electricity may yet have in store no one can tell, but everyone knows that steam has been the source of the power most used by man during the past one hundred years, and that it is coal that has generated steam. The abounding prosperity of the United States is due to no other one cause so much as to its plentiful supply of coal. Hundreds of thousands of acres of this fuel underlie the lands on either side of the Appalachian range almost continuously from the southern borders of New York to central Alabama. There are coal fields in eastern and southern Ohio, central Michigan, south- em Indiana, central and southern Illinois, in parts of Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, Iowa, Missouri, Kansas, Oklahoma, Washington, Colorado, Wyoming, Utah, Ari- zona, and New Mexico. There are but few cities of prime importance east of the Missouri River that are not within two or three hundred miles of a coal field. Many of them have coal mines at their portals, and a great many have the choice of coal of different grades from different fields. Although this oncoming era of electricity has largely displaced oil as an illuminant in practically all of the cities and many of the towns, there are still countless thousands of homes in these cities and towns, as well as in the villages and on the farms, in which the day is prolonged by the burning of the petroleum-saturated wick. Thousands of gallons of petroleum oil are used The Channels of Traffic 13 daily to lubricate valve and gear and journal, and it serves many other purposes in the industries and in the arts. Crude oil, that is, the mineral, as it flows from the well, is found in western Pennsylvania, Virginia, and Ohio, in Kansas, Oklahoma, and Texas. It is transported principally through underground pipes to the refineries, whence it is distributed by rail. This catalogue-like array gives but a broad indication of where the principal products of general use and con- sumption have their origin, and whither they are taken. There has been no word as to coffee, which is imported through San Francisco, New Orleans, and New York, and thence distributed throughout the United States; of cane sugar, which likewise radiates chiefly from San Francisco, New Orleans, and New York ; of beet sugar, which is distributed from Colorado, California, Utah, and Idaho throughout the Missouri Valley ; of rice, which in largest m.easure now comes from the lowlands of Texas and Louisiana. From the vicinity of every truck farm canned fruits and vegetables flow to wide markets. From Virginia, the Carolinas, Kentucky, and Tennessee, as well as from parts of Pennsylvania and Wisconsin, to- bacco is sent, not only throughout the United States, but over all the world. To emphasize a most wonderful achievement mention has been reserved to the last of the flow of deciduous fruits, of citrus fruits, and of dried and canned fruits, from California. Train-loads of peaches, apples, pears, and plums, oranges and lem.ons, go from the orchards, fields and groves of this rare land of fruits and flowers to distributing centers throughout the country, whence they find their way into every nook and corner of the United States. This summary gives no adequate idea of the actual handling of two million freight cars that are in service day in and day out; of the tens of thousands of freight trains that are moving by day and by night, carrying foodstuffs to markets, material to mills and factories, and finished products to warehouses and retail dealers. This 14 Railroad Freight Rates is the function of the railroad. Upon its successful per- formance depends the material welfare of the country, and its successful performance in turn rests, upon the prompt and efficient conduct of the processes of agricul- ture, of industry, and commerce, to which some attention must now be given. CHAPTER III THE PREPARATION OF FOODSTUFFS Inasmuch as over one-half of the industrial and com- mercial energy of the civilized world is expended in the provision and preparation of food, reference is here made to various phases of the food supply by way of intro- duction to the service performed by the transportation agencies, the processes of production and the processes of distribution being closely interwoven. Bread is the staff of life, and, therefore, the grains doubtless are entitled to first consideration. It is the wheat-grain that contains starch and gluten, the nutri- tious elements that are ground into flour. The larger and the more numerous the grains on the stalk of wheat and the more abundant the stalks to the acre, the more valu- able the farmer's crop. Expert wheat-growers take the trouble to find the individual plants that yield the largest and heaviest grains and use these for seed. In the agri- cultural colleges and schools of the West new varieties are being bred by the cross-fertilization of the wheat blossoms. This delicate operation consists in the careful removal of the stamens from the wheat flower and the dusting or brushing of the pollen from another plant upon its pistils. Durum wheat, a variety with a hard grain that grows in the hot, dry regions of Russia, has been introduced into this country, making productive the semi-arid belt to the east of the Rocky Mountains. It is especially adapted to the manufacture of macaroni, of which there is a growing consumption, and is largely exported. Both with oats and with barley experiments have also been made in cross-fertilization. Although the com crop is more important than that of wheat, less than twenty-five per cent, of the corn is shipped out of the county where it is grown; that is, it is not shipped out as corn : transformed into beef and IS i6 Railroad Freight Rates pork it goes to the ends of the earth. The quality of corn has also been improved by selection. The yield has been increased, the stalks and roots strengthened. It is not the tallest and the most beautiful stalks that produce the best grains : the sturdy stalks of medium height bet- ter support the ears and give them more nutrition. The development in the physical handling of the grains is especially marked by the advanced use of machinery. On the largest western farms, some of which are thou- sands of acres in extent, the planting of grain is by plows and drills driven by steam, the harvesting by steam reap- ers and threshers. From the threshers the wheat falls into wagons, which take it to the railroad station, where it is loaded into cars that take it to the great elevators at such primary centers as Omaha, Duluth, Chicago, Kansas City, and St. Louis. At some stage of its trans- portation grain destined for the table is milled. That is, wheat is ground into flour, corn into cornmeal, and other grains pass through similar processes, which become the more complicated in the case of breakfast foods and kin- dred preparations. Many of the modern flour mills have a capacity of a million barrels of flour a year, working with machinery so perfected that the wheat is not touched by hand from the time it is placed in conveyors, which take it to the top of the mill and start it through the first set of rollers, until, after six alternate grindings and boltings, the flour drops into sacks or barrels. The grain of this country is usually transported in bulk; that is, it is loaded directly into cars and vessels without being enclosed in sacks or wrappings. The great packing houses of the Middle West are the sources through which is obtained the greater portion of the meat that finds its way to the tables of this meat- eating nation. Beeves can maintain a livelihood without other food than that gotten by grazing, but to be properly fattened for market they need careful attention. This accounts for the fact that cattle by the thousands, after they have grown beyond calfhocd on the Texas ranches, are transported to New Mexico, Colorado, Kansas, Ne- The Preparation of Foodstuffs 17 braska, and even to Wyoming and the Dakotas, where they are fed on a mixture of corn, oats, alfalfa, and cot- tonseed. With the development of Texas, however, this end is accomplished on its farms to a greater degree than before, and of late years packing houses have been established within the State. Cattle are also sent by the thousands to be fattened on corn in the " feed lots " of the corn belt, and to the towns near the oil mills where they are nourished on cottonseed products, undue rations of which sometimes make them blind. The quality of beef has been improved by feeding and caring for the cattle on the farms and ranches during the winter instead of allowing them to run wild as formerly, and both by selection and breeding has been developed to a degree of juiciness and of tenderness unknown not many decades ago. The transition in the source of the beef supply, that was first marked by the herds of the western grazing grounds supplanting the cattle raised by farmers and sold to the local butcher, would seem to be on the verge of a new phase. The increasing population of the country demands larger crops of grain, and, therefore, vast areas, from Texas to the Dakotas, that have been used as grazing grounds, are being cut up into farms, the culti- vation of grain being more profitable than the raising of cattle. This means that the unoccupied ranches of Mex- ico will be used for grazing to a greater degree, and also a certain reversion to the old-time practice of every farmer raising a few cattle — a hundred or more — as many as he can properly feed and take care of. Indeed, the methods of feeding have been so developed and are so widely understood that even now cattle from Texas are sent for feeding, not only to the areas first named, but to farms as far east as Ohio, where they are fattened and shipped to the packing houses. The advancing cost of corn and other grains is so increasing the cost of feeding that it will be necessary to devise a cheaper diet as well as to utilize new grazing land. Attempts are now being made to restrict the quantity of corn in the 1 8 Railroad Freight Rates beeves' ration, its exclusive or excessive use being inju- rious to the health of the animal and to the quality of the meat. The farmers of southwestern Virginia have for many years grown and fattened entirely upon grass some of the choicest beeves known to the market, and the Blue Grass region of Kentucky is almost as fa- mous for the quality of its cattle as for its horses. Although we hear far more of beef, it is really the hog that supplies the greater quantity of the meat eaten in this country, either as plain pork or as bacon, ham, or sausage. There is scarcely a farmer, from Maine to California, or from St. Paul to New Orleans, who does not raise hogs as a by-product. They are produced in large numbers in Kentucky, Texas, and Ohio, but the greatest density of the cultivation is in the State of Iowa and the immediately contiguous portions of Illinois, Wis- consin, Nebraska, Kansas, and Missouri. Here the rais- ing of the hog is becoming as much of a science as the raising of a steer. His food is practically the same mixture and as carefully prepared. This greater care has been forced partly by the necessity for avoiding cholera and tuberculosis, which appears to be very prevalent when hogs are allowed to feed on the refuse of the stables and barnyards. It has also been necessary to improve the meat of the hog in order to extend the market for bacon. As it is now, England does not regard American bacon as the finest which reaches her market, paying far lower prices for it than for that received from Ireland and Denmark. It has been ascertained that an exclusive diet of corn is as bad for the hog as for the steer. A regimen of peas, oats, and barley, or of corn mixed with skimmed milk, produces better bacon. This is marked in the products of the San Luis Valley of California, and in many regions of the South where an abundance of vegetables, especially of peas, afford a proper diet. The famous Smithfield hams of Virginia are said to owe their superior quality to the fact that the hogs are fattened on peanuts. The sheep of the United States are descended from a The Preparation of Foodstuffs 19 flock of Spanish merinos brought to New Mexico in 1540, and the sheep of the Western States are still of the merino type, while those grown east of the Missis- sippi River, especially in Ohio and Michigan, are of the English breeds which have been imported within the last twenty-five or thirty years. The greatest number of these animals, however, at this time come from the west- em grazing grounds which they share with the cattle. Like calves, the lambs are permitted to roam on the pas- tures, principally between New Mexico and Colorado, Utah and Idaho, until they have attained a degree of strength, when they are removed to the feeding grounds in Colorado, Nebraska, and Kansas, where they are nourished with a mixture of alfalfa and refuse of the beet. Then they are taken to the Missouri River to be fattened with hay, prior to consignment to packing houses. In the great packing houses the carcasses of cattle, hogs, and sheep are whirled through different depart- ments by machinery which disembowels, washes, skins, and cuts them up for the market. When the meat is intended for sale by the butchers, each carcass is cut into two pieces, the " sides," which are hung in the railroad cars. Ham, bacon, and other products are packed in barrels or boxes. Of our edible fowl, the wild duck and the wild turkey are indigenous to North America, the name of the latter being due to the fact that Cortez and his followers thought they had rounded India and reached Turkey in Asia. The chicken, the universal fowl, had to be im- ported. The first settlers brought small flocks which, it is to be presumed, multiplied upon the face of the earth, although their descendants have faded into obscurity. When the Brahmas were brought from the Brahma- putra region in India, the Cochins and Langshans from China, the Leghorn from Italy, the Minorcas from the Island of Minorca, the Black Spanish and Andalusians from Spain, the bird with the indefinite name attained high standing in the United States. The barred Ply- 20 Railroad Freight Rates mouth Rock is the most popular breed in this country, being prized both for its flesh and its eggs. Great attention of late years has been paid to the feeding of chickens ; an improved method being to scatter a part of their food in straw or hay so that they will have to scratch for it, — exercise being as good for them as for the other bipeds that do not wear feathers. In the West, speaking generally, no particular care is given to the feeding and raising of chickens; they are simply allowed to grow. The great packing houses tried in vain to enlist the interest of the farmers in im- proved methods, and finally were obliged to establish poultry fattening stations where they prepare for market chickens bought from the farmers. These are the choice fowl which, in exception to American poultry in gen- eral, can be marketed abroad. The truth is, that although each of the varieties has been developed by breeding and selection until everyone of them is superior to the fowl of the same family in the country of its ancestry, America is not, as yet, in the front rank as a producer of table poultry. The statement of King Edward's poulterer that our best hotels tolerate poultry which would not be accepted in the establishments of epicurean resort in Europe is quite correct. As a rule the poultry of the market has been killed and dressed by the packing houses which buy it from the farmer, who no longer kills and dresses it himself, — a conspicuous exception being in southern New Jersey, where the old custom of farm preparation still prevails. From the great ranches of Texas, where they are raised by the thousands, turkeys are often driven like cattle to the marketing centers, whence they are taken to the packing houses. Chickens, developed for egg production, are carefully selected from the broods of mothers who lay the largest eggs in greatest numbers, a device having been invented that records the weight and measurement of each egg laid by each hen. Foods and methods of feeding have been devised for the production of the richest colored The Preparation of Foodstuffs 21 yolks. These developed methods are, however, not gen- erally followed by the farmer, who, moreover, is not al- ways careful to collect eggs promptly. Often they remain in the nests for several days, sometimes for a week or more, and when gathered are well on the way to decay, although they may pass the test at the primary markets. In England, where the henneries are not so widely dis- tributed, each egg is stamped, under the co-operative system adopted by the British producers, with the num- ber of the farmer and the date received from him. It is thus made possible to trace bad eggs to their sources and repeated carelessness is punished by expulsion from the association. A comparatively recent development is the practice of certain large dealers to remove the shells from the eggs, freeze the whites and yolks together, or separately, in cans of one or more gallons, which they keep frozen to be furnished to such bakeries, hotels, and restaurants as may care to buy them for cooking pur- poses. Eggs are probably as little amenable to handling by machinery as anything imaginable, but still there are mechanical devices for testing their quality. They are packed for shipment in light wooden cases, cross lined with pasteboard so that there is an apartment for each egg. The butter on the tables of the residents of the larger cities is not now made by the farmer's wife or daughter in the dairy on the farm. In the dairy States a creamery receives the milk from the surrounding farms, and makes butter of uniform grades under modern conditions. The cream is now removed from milk by a machine called a " separator " ; butter is churned and worked into prints by machinery. There is the farmers' co-operative cream- ery, the creamery owned by an individual, and the large corporate creamery, the industry having reached such a development that one factory often produces fifty thousand to seventy-five thousand pounds of butter in one day. Sometimes the cream is taken from the milk at the dairy and the skimmed milk returned to the farmer ; sometimes the cream alone is delivered by the farmer. 22 Railroad Freight Rates The raising of fruits and vegetables was once a part of farming in general. The origin of market gardening, the raising of garden truck on small tracts for sale, can- not be traced. It probably arose in the vicinity of each city with the growth of the population of that city. Truck farming, the exclusive raising of the smaller fruits and vegetables on large areas, became conspicuous not more than twenty-five or thirty years ago. It fol- lowed the demand of the enormously increasing popu- lation of the great centers for such food, and was made possible by the coincident development of transportation. The first truck farm region to become conspicuous was that near Norfolk, Virginia, from which the first ship- ments by rail were made in 1885. Truck farming on a large scale has developed in western New York, on Long Island, in New Jersey, on the eastern shore of Maryland, and Virginia, and the extension of the industry has been made picturesque by its expansive inauguration along the Atlantic Coast from Florida northward through the Carolinas. Of recent years the southern portions of Alabama, Mississippi, and Louisiana, and eastern Texas have been devoted to this purpose. Potatoes and cabbage are not grown exclusively on truck farms, but in many States are rotated on the farms with corn, oats, wheat, and clover. The seed for onions, lima beans, and many other an- nuals, is now produced principally in California on seed farms in the irrigation land where the growers can bet- ter control the elements than where the weather is spasmodic. Operators of the great truck farms in all parts of the country draw upon these Californian farms for seed. The principal tree fruits of the United States, with the exception of the native plum, are descendants of Euro- pean varieties, seedlings having been grown by the early settlers by the thousands. Thus, all of our multiple kinds of apple trees trace their pedigree back to the European wild apple. The American varieties have re- sulted more through accident than design, a seedling The Preparation of Foodstuffs 23 here and there developing a juicier fruit or a better flavor which, by careful culture, has been preserved until it has become a fixed type. It was found, for instance, in an early year of the nineteenth century, that a particular apple tree on the farm of Colonel Loami Baldwin, in Massachusetts, yielded unusually palatable apples. Scions cut from that tree and its descendants have been grafted so widely that the Baldwin apple is produced almost wherever there is an apple orchard. Throughout the northern United States this designation of the Baldwin apple, as that of other varieties, does not, however, mean the same thing at all times and in all places. Apples are grown very generally along the Atlantic seaboard from Maine to North Carolina, Georgia, Alabama, and throughout the entire region extending from the Lakes southwestward and westward to the Arkansas and the Missouri Rivers. The production of the States of Arkan- sas and Missouri has in recent years become conspicuous, several of the counties having five hundred thousand trees and over. The finest and most carefully handled apples come from the far Northwest, — from Washington, Oregon, Colorado, and California. These, although they seem to be of widely different origin, have been developed from scions transplanted from the orchards of the East. The Oregon Spitzenburg is the Spitzenburg of Esopus on the Hudson, and the Newtown Pippin of the North- west is the Newtown Pippin of Long Island's colonial days. The drier air of the Rocky Mountain region and the far Northwest develops a firm texture in the fruit, and the growers of these regions take unusual pains to keep the trees free from fungi and insects. The result is that the choicest grades of these apples bring inordinate prices. Shipments are made to the Russian nobility through Vladivostock, to the " crowned heads of Europe," and they are sought by the wealthy of all lands. These apples have brought, by the box at the orchard, as much as fifteen cents apiece, which is equivalent to a retail price in New York of from twenty-five to thirty cents. It is not at all necessary, however, to pay any such price 24 Railroad Freight Rates for excellent apples of delicious flavor. Even Spitzen- burgs and the Newtown Pippins often retail from the fruit stands at five cents each, and superior grades of various kinds can be purchased by the quantity for much less. Throughout the summer of 1900 there was a con- tinuous exhibit of American apples at the Paris Expo- sition. Since that time the European demand has steadily increased and has frequently exceeded the supply. In Great Britain, as on the Continent, however, American apples find competition late in the spring with the apples of Tasmania and New Zealand. Although the peach originated in China, was taken to Western Asia and to Europe, whence it was brought to the United States, it is significant that the Chinese gov- ernment is obtaining from this country seedlings of peaches and other fruits to investigate the possibility of their propagation in China. Anyone who has visited a chop suey restaurant knows the difference between the little wizened peach of China and the luscious product of our home orchards. Peaches are not nearly as hardy as apples, and do not grow under as great a variety of conditions of soil and climate. They ripen in the Georgia and Texas orchards in June and July; come later from Arkansas, Missouri, Maryland, Delaware and New Jer- sey; in the early autumn from the mountains of West Virginia, from New York State, and Michigan ; and very fine peaches are obtained from California. Peaches in appreciable quantities are also now received in New York from South Africa, where they ripen during what is our winter. Our choicer varieties of pears, such as the Bartlett and Flemish Beauty, are mostly of European origin, though some of the very best in quality, such as the Seckel and the Sheldon, have been developed in this country from the European stock. More recently an- other type has been introduced from China and Japan. Pears grow in about the same localities as peaches. The plum is an own cousin to the peach, but the most of its several species are much hardier. It grows The Preparation of Foodstuffs 25 throughout the temperate belt, and has attained high development on the Pacific Coast. Here certain varieties of the European species are manufactured into prunes that have gained the ascendancy in the markets of this country and are largely exported. The grape of our eastern vineyards is conspicuously a fruit for vi^hose successful development the American growers are little indebted to Europe. Although, of course, the grape was known to the Hebrews and the Egyptians, the discoverers of America found it on this continent. There was in later years a determined effort to supplant the native with the European grape, but this failed utterly, our grapes of to-day being descendants of the early American type that triumphed over the European varieties through sheer fitness. The fruit was originally of inferior quality, — widely different from the Catawba, the Concord, the Delaware, and the Niagara grape of to-day, all of which differ from the grapes of Europe. These statements, however, apply only to the grapes that are grown east of the Rocky Mountains. In California the European grape found a congenial home, and its culture has attained marked success. The familiar pictures of the darky and the watermelon indicate no recently acquired fondness of the colored race for the refreshing fruit, for we are indebted to Africa for both the fruit and the race, and they have both spread pretty thoroughly over the United States. A generation or so ago we ate muskmelons for two or three months of the summer ; now we have the cantaloup in abundance from April until October. It comes from Florida and California from April until July, from Texas, Georgia, and the Carolinas, during June and July, from Idaho, Utah, and Colorado from the middle of July to the mid- dle of October. A well-known and highly prized variety is the Rocky Ford melon, which comes from Colorado, beginning the latter part of August and continuing until frost. The Rocky Ford is simply the old Netted Gem melon, which was first planted in the Rocky Ford region fifteen or twenty years ago by settlers who wanted to see 26 Railroad Freight Rates if melons for their needs could not be raised at home: the soil and climate did the rest. The popularity of the Rocky Ford is now such that Georgia growers go to Colorado for the seed. As the melon has to be annually planted afresh, and in Georgia will retain the Rocky Ford flavor and consistency for but one generation, it is necessary .to obtain the seed anew each year. Therefore, in Colorado, acres and acres are planted for the seed, the melons being fed to hogs and cattle. One acre will produce melons yielding two hundred pounds of seed, and it is not uncommon for one Georgia buyer to take half a ton of seed at a time. As a pound of seed will plant an acre, such a purchase provides seed for one thousand acres. In certain regions of Canada these de- licious melons are literally hand raised and milk fed, an incision being made in the stem, during the period of growth, into which milk is injected. The citrus fruits are not native to the United States. It has not been more than thirty or forty years since practically all of the oranges used in this country came from the shores of the Mediterranean. The orange is grown with complete success in Florida, where it was probably brought by the early Spanish explorers, and in California, where it was likely introduced by the mission- aries. The oranges of southern Florida are the sweetest, but the crop of California now largely supplies the mar- ket, the navel orange, which had its origin in some young trees brought under the auspices of the Department of Agriculture from Bahia, Brazil, about 1870, now fur- nishing from eighty-five to ninety per cent, of the annual consurnption. The lemon has been propagated from trees obtained from Sicily. It is now produced in California by the hundreds of thousands of dozens per annum, and is ap- parently destined to drive the Sicilian lemon from the American market. The European fruit is still received in quantities at the Atlantic seaports and the dealers of these cities sell it in the interior without a great deal of effort as far as the Alleghany Mountains. The Cali- The Preparation of Foodstuffs 27 fornian lemons have the entire field as far east as the Mississippi River. In that portion of the Mississippi Valley which lies between the river and the Alleghany Mountains the citric cousins are at bitter warfare. Everyone knows that things that our grandmothers used to put in cans and jars for winter use are now pre- served by the large canning establishments, some of which own farms of from five thousand to eight thou- sand acres. The canned products embrace tomatoes, beets, string beans, lima beans, corn, spinach, a dozen varieties of peas, squash, asparagus, dandelion, rasp- berries, strawberries, blackberries, huckleberries, pine- apples, pears, plums, apples, figs, quinces, gumbo, and a combination of gumbo and tomato. The canned goods, however, that enter most largely into consumption are tomatoes, corn, and peas. There are great canneries in Indiana, Ohio, and Illinois, in Delaware, Maryland, and New Jersey, in Connecticut, New York, and Massachu- setts. Corn is also canned in Maine, Wisconsin, Michi- gan, and Kansas. The canneries of California annually send canned fruits and vegetables in greater volume and of great variety throughout the country. There are other articles of food, nuts, spices, and tea, to specify no further, consumed by thousands of tons every year. But it is the grains, the meats, the fruits, and vegetables that form the major portion of the diet of every person of this country who has passed infancy. Every day of the year they are in movement, in hundreds of thousands of freight cars, from the fields to the ele- vator, the pasture to the packing house, the truck farm and the orchard to the produce house. CHAPTER IV THE DISTRIBUTION OF FOODSTUFFS It is evident that if everything that serves as food were produced in the locality where it is consumed the trans- fer from the producer to the consumer would be an easy matter, especially if the production were all the year round in the quantities desired from day to day by the consumers. This condition is approximated in the vil- lages where the dairyman drives his wagon in from the farm each morning and around to the houses of his cus- tomers, leaving with each the milk for the daily need. When the place of production is remote from the place of consumption the producer cannot sell in person to the consumer, and this is clearly all the more out of the question when the production is on a very large scale, sufficing for the needs of a multitude of consumers. Even if the production were in the same locality with the consumption, but were restricted to a brief period, the consumption would either be restricted to that period, or either the purchaser or the consumer or some interme- diary agency would have to store the food during the al- ways limited period of production to be disposed of during the more extended period of consumption. Where the consumption of the product is so vast that one inter- mediary cannot know all the consumers and their desires, there is necessarily a number of secondary agencies, each in a position to know and to provide for the wants of a limited number of consumers. That is, in the case of production on a large scale in a region remote from the place of consumption on a large scale, there must be a wholesale receiver of the product and retail distributors who obtain their stocks from him. Fruits and vegetables that do not quickly perish, such as potatoes, cabbage, and apples, were formerly consigned 28 The Distribution of Foodstuffs 29 by the growers to dealers at the great market centers, who sold them and remitted the proceeds of the sales to the growers, charging commission for the service. Sale on commission, however, has been subject to such abuses that it is becoming more and more the custom for these products to be sold outright on the farm or at the ship- ping station to the large dealers. The apple industry, for example, has become so concentrated that a dealer may directly own orchards in each of the great apple- growing regions, and may contract for the entire crops of many other orchards to which he sends his own em- ployees to pick and pack the fruit. Not only because of the exigencies of the markets, but in large measure because of the evils of the spirit which man has not entirely outgrown, the disposition of the quickly perishable fruits and vegetables under the com- mission system has been especially pernicious. Growers distant from the markets have not always hesitated to include products of inferior quality and not of the highest degree of soundness in their shipments to the dealers. The commission man remote from the farmer, who had no means of inspecting his methods, would sometimes re- port to the farmer that his shipment had arrived in bad condition and unmarketable, and perhaps even ask him to remit for the freight charges. There have been in- stances in which the commission dealer has done this, notwithstanding the fact that he had sold the consignment at good prices. He has also been accused of selling con- signments to himself and thus turning the profits of a good market to his own pockets. These evils still exist, but they have been greatly diminished. In that they must be promptly disposed of, the pro- ducer of quickly perishable fruits and vegetables who is distant from the markets is under another disadvantage : the vagaries of the sun and the rain sometimes delay the ripening of his crop until it comes strongly into com- petition with the crops of other regions and a glut ensues in the markets. A glut is also often caused by the hasty consignment of superabundant shipments to a de- 30 Railroad Freight Rates nuded market. If shipment has been on consignment to a commission merchant the loss falls on the grower. Better adjustment is being reached through two causes : the development of means of preserving the products for longer periods ; the formation of associations of growers having similar shipping and marketing interests, and the appointment of representatives on behalf of such associa- tions to look after these interests of their members. The most efficient of these organizations is the Cali- fornia Fruit Growers' Exchange, representing the citrus fruit producers of California. There is a manager in Los Angeles and an agent in each of the large cities of the United States. The manager receives reports from the local exchanges and packing houses of the quantities of fruit available for shipment, and from the agents tele- graphic reports of the prices in various markets, the stock on hand, and the extent of the demand. The man- ager is thereby enabled to direct shipments to the best advantage, and to this end is permitted by the railroads to divert shipments while en route in accordance with the telegrams showing the requirements of the markets. The agents in the various cities inspect the shipments upon receipt and oversee their disposition. There are associations, in greater or lesser degree re- sembling this organization, in the Georgia fruit district, in the Norfolk truck region, and in other localities of great production. Their formation, however, has been retarded. The grower does not like to have the details of his business and the names of his customers dis- closed to his neighbor and competitor. If he can now and then, by individual dickering, get a somewhat better price than his neighbor, he may transgress his loyalty to the association even at the risk of losing the higher aver- age price obtainable through its services. The development of truck farming on a large scale in regions remote from the markets compels transportation facilities through which the truck products, even the quickly perishable, may be transported from the farms to the markets. The retention of perishable food products, The Distribution of Foodstuffs 31 in order that they may be available over extended periods, necessitates storage facilities by means of which decay is arrested. JThe transportation mechanism that has made possible tlie shipment over great distances, and the storage mechanism that makes possible this retention for pro- longed periods, are practically the same device. In con- nection with transportation it is designated as refrigera- tion ; in connection with preservation in warehouses it is known as cold storage. Organic matter quickly decays if allowed to remain without special attention in an or- dinary atmosphere. The decay is hastened if the ex- halations from the product are not withdrawn from the compartment; meats, fruits, and vegetables, like the living body, all needing fresh air to keep them from suffocating. If such products as fruits and vegetables are warm when packed they part with their heat but slowly; the ripening processes proceed with undue ra- pidity, and the result is premature decay. The knowledge of this led to the leaving of holes in barrels and apertures in boxes, and to the provision by railroad companies of ventilator cars. The early types of these were simply box cars with slats instead of boards around the upper sides. The first refrigerator car was placed in service in 1868. It had galvanized iron tanks so arranged along the sides that they could be refilled from the top with a freezing mixture of ice and salt. In this car shipments were made of strawberries and of peaches which re- mained in sound condition during ten days in transit. A successful consignment of dressed beef made to Boston in this car in September, 1869, is credited with being the beginning of the great industry. Various types of refrigerator cars were devised, and in 1887 began the through shipment of fresh fruits and vegetables from starting point to destination in the same refrigerator car, which was iced as often as necessary. The system of transportation under refrigeration quickly developed. Inasmuch as the need for such trans- 32 Railroad Freight Rates portation from any truck or fruit region is limited to the brief period during which the crop ripens and is gathered, very few railroads have found it profitable to include refrigerator cars in their equipment. When required they are obtained from the private car companies, any one of which may own hundreds or thousands of these cars, sending them to this region in the spring, to that region in the summer, to another in the autumn, and likely to California or Florida during the winter. This adjust- ment of the refrigerator car supply to the demand can- not be made by a railroad company for itself, except, perhaps, by a very few of the great systems whose lines, extending to regions that are widely separated by dis- tance and by characteristics of soil and climate, can give practically continuous employment to such cars. The great packing companies needing transportation under refrigeration for their meat products all the year round were the first to construct and maintain refrigerator cars in considerable numbers. This quickly led to these com- panies furnishing the greater number of these cars re- quired for the transportation of poultry, butter, and eggs, fruits and vegetables. The ownership of the vast ma- jority of the refrigerator cars also led to these companies being in a position to dictate over what railroads the traffic should be sent, and therefore they obtained a certain control over the transportation charges. The icing charges were levied at the will of the refrigerator companies, and, as they had a practical monopoly of the service, such charges were often exorbitant and became the basis of many complaints. It would seem, however, that the enactment of Congress compelling the charges for icing to be definitely fixed and published in the same tariffs with the transportation charges has largely, if not entirely, removed the cause for such grievances, and that the useful functions of the system of transportation under refrigeration are becoming generally recognized. As the first transportation under refrigeration was di- rected to the conveyance of perishable articles of food to Chicago, so also did the system of cold storage attain The Distribution of Foodstuffs 33 its first conspicuous development in Chicago, which is to-day the principal cold storage center of the United States. Cold storage buildings of the latest type have thick walls of concrete lined with air chambers through which fresh air is continually fanned. Each chamber is encircled with pipes, through which ammonia or chilled brine is driven, keeping the temperature at freezing point, at zero or lower if desired. At the time of the most abundant supply thousands of barrels of apples, thousands of tubs of butter, thousands of chickens and turkeys, and thousands of cases of eggs, may be placed in any one of these cold storage houses. They are also used for the storage of chilled beef and mutton and, to a more limited extent, of frozen beef and mutton. Prac- tically all of the fish carried over long distances are frozen, and large quantities are carried in cold storage houses. There has been much discussion as to the kind and extent of the change in the quality of articles of food while they are in cold storage. Critics of the system vigorously assert that deterioration begins from the time they are placed in cold storage and continues in ac- celerating degree throughout the period during which they are kept there. Those who have developed the sys- tem state that if a product is originally sound there is no deteriorating for an extended period so long as it is kept frozen — weeks in the case of some products, months in the case of others, and a year or m.ore in the case of poultry. It would seem that a necessary step toward the ef- ficiency of cold storage and the safety of the cold-stored products is an extension of preparation by freezing or cooling the products before they are placed in storage. It has been the custom to gather some fruits before they have ripened that they may ripen in transit and in storage. There is no question that the quality and even the wholesomeness of such fruits is inferior to that of those which have been allowed to ripen on the tree or the vine. A process of freezing in advance has lately 34 Railroad Freight Rates been applied to strawberries, with the result that they can be kept in good condition in storage for five or six weeks. The extension of this process is one of the problems which the Department of Agriculture is endeav- oring to solve, with every prospect of success. In the marketing of the quickly perishable foodstuffs that are produced by countless growers and consumed by a multitude of consumers, there is not the pronounced tendency toward the concentration of handling that is marked in the case of foodstuffs not so quickly perishable, and conspicuous with the more durable products of other kinds. As fruits and berries, vegetables and melons must, as a rule, be quickly sold to avoid loss, and as there is no change in their form between the time of ripening and the time of disposition, it is but natural that there should not be many changes of ownership as they pass from the grower to the consumer. The development of the associations of producers, through which it is en- deavored to direct the distribution according to the requirements of the markets, has been the'only noteworthy step in the way of centralization. A half century ago grain was marketed in much the same manner as fruits and vegetables are now. It was sent by the farmers to the elevators at the larger mar- kets, consigned to commission men. It was to the inter- est of each railroad to provide elevators as a receptacle for the grain brought from the fields over its lines, and it became the custom for the railroads to lease these ele- vators to men who operated them simply as storage houses and derived their compensation from the charge for storing grain in them. It naturally being the desire of the lessees to keep their elevators filled that they might be in receipt of continuous revenue from the storage charge, it became their practice to buy grain. They sent their representatives out in the farming lands to dicker with the farmers, and sometimes erected smaller elevators at various places in the country in which the neighbor- ing farmers were allowed free storage. The men leasing The Distribution of Foodstuffs 35 the elevators thus became the principal intermediaries between the farmer and the miller. Certificates repre- senting the grain in the elevators were bought and sold by brokers. With the expansion of the milling interests, however, it became more and more the custom for the owners of the large mills to buy grain directly from the farm.^ The complexity of the export business has tended to place the purchase of grain for export in the hands of the great grain firms having widespread cor- respondents who keep them informed of the supply of grain in all producing centers, and the demand for grain in all markets. These firms have the facilities for char- tering vessels and negotiating with the great steamship lines, and the capital requisite for purchasing and carry- ing the vast quantities of grain needed in their operations. The purchase of grain direct from the farmer by these large milling companies and exporting interests tends to- ward the elimination of the broker. In Chicago, for example, instead of the dozens of brokers who once prospered by buying and selling grain on commission, the vast bulk of the business is now done by a very few firms of large capital, whose information as to crops and markets is obtained from worldwide sources. In the transfer of those foodstuffs that undergo various processes of manufacture before they are ready for the market, the elimination of the broker is still more marked. A half century ago men known as drovers used to buy Hvestock from the growers and drive it on foot to central markets, where it was disposed of through brokers. Transportation by rail has transformed the caretaker of livestock from such a man, who walked or rode across the plains in the rear of a drove of cattle, into a hostler who accompanies them by train to see that they are properly watered and fed. The perfecting of the refrigerator car that made possible the develop- ment of the great packing industry has caused the pur- chase of livestock used in the packing houses to be made in the main by their representatives, who are located throughout the cattle-raising regions, and keep continu- 36 Railroad Freight Rates ously informed as to the condition of the cattle supply. The great packing houses buy the live animals from the farmers who have fattened them, and send the meat products to their branch houses in various cities, whence they are distributed to the local butchers. To every one of the phases of the problem presented by the production and preparation for shipment of the food supply, the ofificers of the Department of Agriculture are giving close and continuous attention. These men, each an expert in his particular field, obtained their ap- pointments through fitness and, entirely removed from political influences, conduct their work with the earnest enthusiasm engendered by a well defined desire for a definite achievement. The efficiency of the Bureaus of the Department is enhanced by the work of the sixty-one experiment stations under their direction. The ascertainment and the diffusion of accurate and advanced knowledge in regard to the production and handling of the food supply is furthered by the State colleges of agriculture endowed by the government under the enactment for which Senator Morrill, of Vermont, worked unceasingly for a number of years, and the re- sults of which are a monument to his memory. Many of the States in recent years have introduced courses on agriculture in the high schools and many of them have established specialized dairy schools. Under the auspices of the State schools are held the farmers' in- stitutes, gatherings here and there for a limited time of the farmers of one or more counties, which are at- tended by lecturers and demonstrators, who advise the farmers as to the characteristics of the best products, as to seeds, soils, fertilizers, and the best methods of plant- ing; and the breeding and care of livestock and poultry. The railroads of the country have co-operated with and furthered the work of the Department of Agricul- ture, and of the colleges and schools. Many of the railroads, especially those in the South and West, have demonstration cars stocked with samples of the best The Distribution of Foodstuffs 37 seeds and products. These cars are attended by lectur- ers and demonstrators who are employed by the rail- roads, and who are often accompanied by delegated mem- bers of the faculties of the State institutions. They are sent to the farmers' institutes and taken throughout the length and breadth of the region which the lines of the railroad penetrate, diffusing among the farmers the information collected by the expert investigators. The railroad companies render this service entirely at their own expense. Increase in their traffic naturally follows the development and prosperity of the country, which it is to their interest, as well as that of the government, to promote. It is not always an easy matter for the railroad com- panies to distribute their cars in accordance with the demands of traffic. If the different commodities moved at regular periods one year after another, it would be difficult enough to provide just the right number of cars at the right time and move them promptly ; but when, as has happened, on account of strikes, unfavorable con- ditions of the weather, and other causes, great crops of grain, an unusual tonnage of bituminous coal and ex- traordinary quantities of merchandise, all pressed for shipment at the same time that fruits, delayed in ripen- ing, demanded to be hauled to the markets before they perished, the already badly hampered railroads were simply overwhelmed. The railroads endeavor to obtain as accurate informa- tion as far in advance as possible of the demands that may be made upon them from divers sources. As the grain is ripening on the western fields, the station agents along the various railroad lines send frequent reports of its condition to the general offices, and men of experience are periodically sent out from these general offices to go through the grain territory. Upon the information thus obtained the western railroads estimate the number of cars that probably will be required and endeavor to collect them in the grain districts. The movement of 38 Railroad Freight Rates meats, poultry, butter, and eggs is more nearly regular and the car distribution can be made with a greater degree of certainty. The greatest diiBculty, however, in estimating and ar- ranging the car supply, as has been intimated, is in connection with the quickly perishable foodstuffs. In the summer of 1907 the railroad company leading there- from was advised that the peach crop of the Delaware and Maryland Peninsula would require five hundred cars. That number was fitted with the racks needed for peach crates, but by the time they were ready a turn in the weather had reduced the peach crop, which, at best, had likely been overestimated, to but little more than fifty cars. All the time that these cars had been assigned for what must necessarily be a prompt move- ment of the peach crop, they could have been used to excellent advantage in the grain movement. This chapter ought not to conclude without reference to the heaviest handicap under which the farmers of this country labor in moving their produce from the farms, and that is the lack of good country roads. In the Report of the Industrial Commission, Vol. VI, page 446, appears the following paragraph: "It has been shown, after careful inquiry, that the average haul of the American farmer in getting his produce to market, or to the nearest shipping station, is 12 miles. The average cost per ton for hauling over the common country roads is 25 cents per ton per mile, or $3 per ton for a 12-mile haul. Care- ful estimates, also, place the total tons hauled at 300,000,000 per year and the average haul at 12 miles, making the total cost of getting the surplus products of the farm to the local market or to the railroad $900,000,000. This figure is greater than the operating expenses of all the railroads in the United States, which for the year ending June, 1898, were only $818,000,000. In other words, it cost $82,000,000 more to haul farm products to the local points where they enter the distributive system than it does to operate our entire railway system, comprising nearly half the mileage of the world." The vast improvements of the country roads in nearly every section of the United States, and the adaptation The Distribution of Foodstuffs 39 of trolley lines to the use of the farmer during the period that has elapsed since the year referred to in this report have much facilitated the initial movement of produce. These are but the first steps in the line of se- curing the better conditions that are essential to the highest economy and efficiency in the distribution of farm products. CHAPTER V THE DISTRIBUTION OF RAW MATERIAL AND MERCHANDISE In this time of the large industrial corporations the purchase of raw material from the producers is very generally effected without an intermediary. It was once the universal custom for cotton to be hauled by the plantation owner to the general store, where it was purchased by the storekeeper, sometimes for cash, but oftener taken as an offset to the supplies that had been furnished during the period of growth. The storekeeper disposed of the cotton to dealers in the various cities, and it was bought and sold by brokers on the floor of cotton exchanges. This is still largely the custom, but of late years it has become more and more the practice of the great cotton dealers, the owners of the great cotton mills, and the great cotton exporters to make purchases of the crop through their representatives direct from the plantations, and there has been the en- deavor, through cotton growers' associations, to give the plantation owner opportunity to hold his cotton through the seasons of low prices in order that he may obtain the benefit of an advancing market. Even so recently as a score of years ago the trans- fers of iron ore from the mine to the furnace, of pig iron from the furnace to the mill, and of the merchantable iron or steel from the mill to the user, were effected through the agency of brokers. At the present time each of the great iron and steel companies owns beds of ore ; many of them own both steamboats and railroads whereby the ore is transported to their own blast fur- naces, and thence to their own mills. It has likewise been but a score of years or so since coal brokers flourished in great numbers. Now each of the iron and steel com- 40 The Distribution of Raw Material 41 panics either uses coal from its own mines or purchases direct from the great coal-mining companies, as do the railroads and other large coal consumers. In many places the large coal companies own the retail yards through which coal is sold to the consumer. Some years ago certificates covering crude petroleum were bought and sold by brokers on the floor of ex- changes, the price of oil thus being fixed. Nowadays the great oil companies either directly control the wells, or purchase the oil directly from their owners at prices adjusted by the oil interests. There is not the same degree of concentration in the distribution of lumber, owing to the wide diffusion of the forests, and the comparative simplicity of the process of sawing the timber into the elementary shapes, which are marketed among a vast number of widely diffused users. There are lumber associations, however, which endeavor to harmonize the interests of different dealers. Tobacco grown in Virginia and the Carolinas is taken in wagons to the various towns where there are ware- houses, through which the farmers negotiate the sale directly with the buyers, who are, in the main, the repre- sentatives of the great tobacco companies. In Tennessee and Kentucky the tobacco is " prized " into hogsheads by the farmer and shipped to primary markets, such as Lexington, Louisville, Cincinnati, and St. Louis, where it is sold through warehouses by commission merchants, the larger portion here also being purchased by the great tobacco companies. The custom is growing, however, for these companies to purchase the tobacco of these States directly from the farmers, their representatives often times negotiating for the crop of an entire plan- tation while it is still in the leaf. The sugar cane of the United States is grown prin- cipally in Louisiana. It is taken by the farmer, usually by wagon, to the " central," the local and crude refinery, whence it passes into possession of the buyer, who, in this case, is nearly always one of the great sugar re- fining companies. The beet sugar industry has obtained 42 Railroad Freight Rates its principal development in California, Colorado, and Utah, where the sunshine, the semi-aridity, the suscep- tibility to irrigation which permits the application of water at intervals as desired, has caused the peculiar adaptation of the soil to the production of beets con- taining a large portion of sugar. These beets are de- livered by the farmer to the factories, whence the sugar is sent to the principal places of storage, such as Kansas City, Omaha, and St. Louis. The tanning industry has been concentrated into the hands of two or three companies whose representatives are located in the vicinity of the large packing houses, and the other places throughout the country where hides are obtainable, where they bargain directly for them. The greater portion of the paper used in this country is that which passes over the presses of the great news- papers. It is made largely of fir and spruce obtained in the Canadian forests, vast "areas of which are owned by the great paper manufacturing companies. Lumber- men deliver the logs at the cutting up-mills, numbers of which are situated on streams down which the logs are floated. From such mills the cut lumber is transported to a pulp mill or, where it is necessary that the lumber be transported from the forest by rail, the pulp mill is generally adjacent to the cutting-up mill. The pulp is taken to the paper mill whence the paper is consigned directly to the newspapers, to whom it is sold by the representatives of the great paper manufacturing com- panies. The copper and lead ores found in the far Western States are transported from the mines to the smelters, at various places between the Pacific Coast and the Mis- souri River; the bullion is taken from these to other smelters, or to refineries, many of which are as far East as the Atlantic seaboard. The several chains of smelters and refineries are under the control of the great smelting and refining companies, who sell the refined copper and the refined lead to the mills through which it is wrought into articles of use. The Distribution of Raw Material 43 As the places of production of many of the principal raw materials are comparatively few in number and fairly well segregated, and as the places of manufacture in each of many lines of industry are comparatively few in number and fairly well segregated, the problems of transportation are not so difficult and many sided as these connected with the conveyance of the perishable foodstuffs. As ventilated or refrigerator cars are not requiied, and as delay in transit does not result in de- terioration to, or total loss of, the shipments, there is not the necessity for the immediate furnishing at one place and at one time of a great number of cars to move products that will decay if the car supply be delayed. Each car may be loaded more nearly to its capacity as there is not the necessity for leaving space for venti- lation as in the case of some organic products, or for carrying vast quantities of ice as with others. The greater the proportion of the weight of a loaded car which yields revenue to the railroad company, the lower the rate, other things equal, at which the freight con- tributing such large proportion of weight can be carried. That is, the weight which the locomotive hauls, and, therefore, for the hauling of which the railroad com- pany has to pay, is that of the load and of the car com- bined. A car will hold a heavier load of some commodities than of others. A high rate on a carload of a bulky commodity may yield a lesser rate per hun- dred pounds if applied to the total weight of load, of car, and of ice or other non-paying adjunct, than a lower rate on a carload of a heavier commodity applied to the weight of load plus weight of car, especially if it be not accompanied by ice or other non-paying adjunct. Attempts have also been made to eliminate the middle man in the distribution of various products from the factory to the consumer, but they have met with only a partial success that has affected only a limited number of commodities. The wholesale dealer is acquainted with the conditions of the region which he supplies and gauges 44 Railroad Freight Rates the needs and the credit of the retail dealers to whom he sells. The retail dealer gauges the needs of the com- munity which he serves, and the credit of his customers. These functions will usually be more carefully performed by a man whose business life directly depends upon his success in their performance than by the agent of a manufacturer. The wholesale and retail dealers, by trading in a variety of commodities, distribute the cost of their handling over a wider range than the exclusive agent of a particular line of manufacture, the handling cost per unit therefore being less. The wholesale dealer also usually maintains a store of goods from which the retail dealer can replenish his supply more promptly than from a remote place of manufacture. The distributive flow of products is, therefore, in greatest volume from the factory to the wholesale merchant and from the wholesale merchant to the retail merchant. Opposed to the various steps from the producer of raw material to the final manufacturer — that is, from the producer to the con- centration point, from the concentration point to the place of the first process of manufacture, and then to the place of the next process of manufacture, and so on — there are but three steps in the case of the distribution from the manufacturer to the consumer, namely from the manufacturer to the wholesaler, from the wholesaler to the retailer, and the retailer to the consumer. This is not without variation. The wholesale dealer will often order a consignment to be shipped direct from the fac- tory to the retail dealer without its passing through his warehouse at all, and the retail dealer, particularly if he can afiford to buy a full carload at a time, will often purchase directly from the manufacturer. There are a variety of different relations that may exist between the manufacturer, the wholesale merchant and the re- tail dealer, but they do not change the general form of the distributive structure in which the wholesale dealers and the retail dealers play the principal part. While there are comparatively few places of production The Distribution of Raw Material 45 of many kinds of raw material, and comparatively few manufacturers of each of many kinds of products, there are innumerable distributing centers at which there are wholesale merchants, and there are retail dealers in every city, town, village and hamlet in the United States. This cursory review of certain of the principal com- modities that enter into the traffic of the United States, and of the commercial mechanism through which they are distributed, leads to further contemplation of their movement over the railroads. In the great channels of traffic "the great staple commodities move in train loads ; raw material to the mills, and finished products from the mills to the distributing centers; foodstuffs move from the sources of supply to the distributing centers. Radiating from these centers are trains composed of cars, some laden with this commodity and some with that, or some of the cars may be each laden with a variety of commodities. This loading of various com- modities in the same car is conspicuous in the case of local freight trains that go from station to station, un- loading at each the small shipments consigned to it. In a great traffic channel of any particular commodity an entire train may be run through over two or more rail- roads to some point of manufacture or to some place of distribution. A solid carload of a commodity may be transferred at a junction point from the incoming train of one to the outgoing train of another railroad. Through consignments that occupy less than a car are often vm- loaded at the junction point transfer depot from the car of one railroad and loaded into the car of the other. Thus a main traffic channel is broken up at a princi- pal distributing point into secondary channels which, through the retail dealers, are broken up into still smaller channels, just as the great artery of the body breaks into secondary arteries that split again into smaller arteries. The flow of the blood of the body, however, is always in the same direction, through the same arteries, and the volume of the blood is substantially the same day after 46 Railroad Freight Rates day ; while the great traffic channels of the United States extend in various directions, crossing and recrossing. The volume of the commodities varies from week to week, from month to month, and from year to year, as there are variations in supply and demand, as there are fluctuations in production and distribution due to divers causes. CHAPTER VI THE TRANSPORTATION CHARGE AND PRICES Vastly the greater proportion of the commodities moved by the railroads are in the processes of commerce ; that is, the conveyance from the place of consignment to place of receipt in the majority of cases is sequent to a transfer of ownership. The seller cannot continue in business unless he obtain a market for his material, or his merchandise, and the purchaser cannot continue in business unless he secure the material, or the merchan- dise, which he needs. The margin within which the added charge for transportation may be adjusted is therefore limited in one direction by the amount which the seller of a commodity will accept and the purchaser will pay and continue in business. If the seller or the purchaser cannot make a profit at least approximately as great as from other operations in which it might be feasible for him to engage he will, other things equal, change his business, and the railroad will no longer have the trafific that flowed from his operations. A railroad, therefore, must adjust its transportation charges that pro- duction may continue. This includes the adjustment of rates that products may be sent to markets, that the products of the region tributary to one railroad may reach markets in competition with similar products of other regions, and in competition with other products that will answer the same purpose. The wider the markets that the producers can reach, the greater is the encouragement to production. The more numerous and varied the sources of supply of which the purchaser has choice, the more likely that his requirements will be met to his satisfaction. This is the case whether the sale and purchase be of food, 47 48 Railroad Freight Rates whether it be of raw material to feed the processes of mill or factory, whether it be of wares for wholesale distribution, or whether the purchase be of merchandise by the retail dealer, or the final consumer. It has long been claimed by the railroads of the United States that their rates of freight are lower than those of any other country, and that the nation's progress in industry and commerce has in large measure been due to the cheapness and the efficiency of its transportation service. By way of proof has been instanced the proportion that the transportation charge bears to the selling price of the staple commodi- ties. It is said that the rate charged for the transporta- tion of food products does not affect their selling price in any market of the United States — that price being fixed by the processes of supply and demand which the amount of the freight rate does not influence. In the spring of 1907 inquiry was made upon this point among the produce dealers of the city of New York, who gave the information contained in the following paragraphs. The price paid by the housekeeper per dozen for eggs during the season of shipment seldom exceeds by more than five cents the price received by the Western farmer who takes them to the country store. That is, the rail- roads bring eggs a thousand miles to New York for a cent or a cent and a half a dozen, and two thousand miles or so for about two cents and a half a dozen, the dealers taking the remainder of the five cents as pay- ment for handling. The net difference between the price paid per pound for butter at the creamery, whether in New York City or in the Mississippi Valley, and that paid by the New York retail dealer averages about one and one-half cents for commission and one cent for freight. In December, January and February turkeys are taken from the Texas ranches to marketing centers, the transportation charge on ten birds weighing 'one hun- dred and twenty pounds being about 25 cents. After these ten birds have been dressed and packed they weigh Transportation Charge and Prices 49 about one hundred and two pounds, and the freight rate from Texas to New York is $1.50 for 100 pounds. That is, a Texas turkey that retails in the New York market for 20 cents a pound will have paid one and three-fourths cents per pound to the railroads that took it from the ranch to the concentration point and thence to the market. The farmer in Texas received about nine cents per pound, leaving a trifle over nine cents to be divided between the packing house, the produce' merchant and the retail dealer. Chickens and other dressed poultry that come from Chicago pay a freight rate of about three-fourths of a cent a pound, the railroad company supplying a refrigerator car, and keeping them iced while in transit. The rail rate from Chicago to New York on grain and grain products for domestic consumption has been about 17J cents per 100 pounds ; that is, a bushel of oats or corn or wheat, that may bring in New York anywhere from 40 cents to $1, has been brought from the western farm for from eight to fifteen cents. Hay that has yielded the farmer $i8 or $19 a ton and sells in New York at about $24 has paid the railroads somewhere from $3 to $5 per ton, according to whether it came from the meadows of the Ohio or the Mississippi Valleys. A bullock that weighs 1200 pounds will, at Chicago, bring on an average $5.50 per 100 pounds, which in- cludes an average of five cents per 100 pounds for freight from the grazing grounds. Its total value at the stockyards, therefore, is $66. When it has passed through the packing house its weight will have been reduced to 700 pounds. From Chicago to New York it will pay 45 cents per 100 pounds freight or, in other words, the 700-pound carcass, which, if retailed at an average of 15 cents a pound would bring $105, has paid the railroads between $3.50 and $4 from the far West to the metropolis. On potatoes the freight rate per barrel containing about two and a half bushels is $1.05 from Florida, 65 cents from South Carolina, 45 cents from North Caro- 50 Railroad Freight Rates lina, 30 cents from Virginia, and from this 12 cents per bushel the rate scales down to five or six cents per bushel from near-by regions. The freight rate on tomatoes from Florida is 25 cents per package of six baskets, from Texas 15 cents for twelve quarts, from Mississippi 76 cents per 100 pounds and from the near- by farms eight cents per bushel of twenty-eight quarts. The freight rate on cantaloups to New York ranges from less than a cent for a melon from the Carolinas to about two and a half cents for that from California. Oranges from Florida to New York pay the railroads from four to nine cents a dozen, and those from California six to twelve cents a dozen, as they may be large or small. A three pound can of tomatoes from Maryland pays the railroad about one-half cent per can. The freight rates to New York on foodstuffs have been selected as typical of the transportation charges applying on such commodities in the main channels of traffic from the West to the East ; and, in so far as fruits and vegetables are concerned, from the South to the East. The transportation charge per consumer's unit on these foodstuffs is a trifle less to Philadelphia and adjacent Delaware and New Jersey; another fraction lower to the great Pittsburg district, and still lower to the cities of the West and South that are nearer the places of production. As prices of food products fluctuate within a fairly wide range and freight rates also fluctuate, though within but a very narrow range, the rates and prices specified in the foregoing, as well as in the suc- ceeding paragraphs of this chapter, cannot be considered as of specific application at any given time in the future. They were exact at the time they were collated and will very closely approximate accuracy at any period. As New York may be considered representative of the places to which edible products of the West and South are consigned, so also may St. Louis be considered a typical center of reception of the manufactured prod- ucts of the East. The information given in the im- Transportation Charge and Prices 51 mediately following paragraphs was obtained from mer- chants and manufacturers of that city. The transportation charge on the material entering into a pair of shoes made in a St. Louis factory averages one and one-quarter cents. The transportation charge required to place that pair of shoes in the hands of a consumer in any part of the United States averages be- tween two and three cents. The material entering into an ordinary bedstead, such as retails in St. Louis for $8, will have paid the railroad about 40 cents. From ten pounds of nails made in Pittsburg and retailed in St. Louis the railroad will have obtained a trifle over two cents, and from ten pounds of wire two and one-half cents. An axe made in the Pittsburg district that retails in St. Louis for $1 will have paid the railroads one and one-fourth cents. At Kansas City that same axe will have paid freight of a fraction over four cents and at Denver, where the retail price will have advanced to $1.30, it will have paid 14 cents freight. A padlock re- tailing in St. Louis at 50 cents will have paid the rail- roads a little more than one-half cent; at Kansas City it will have paid one cent, and at Denver, where the re- tail price advances to 75 cents, it will have paid two cents to the railroads. An eighteen gallon galvanized iron tub that retails in St. Louis at 80 cents will have paid the railroad from place of manufacture two and three-tenths cents ; to Kansas City the freight rate will have been six and one- fourth cents and to Denver 15 cents, but here the retail price of that tub is $1. A stove that weighs two hundred pounds and retails in St. Louis for $18 will, in carload lots, pay 44 cents to Kansas City or Omaha, and retail there for $22 ; $1.48 to Denver and retail there for $25 ; $2.50 to Seattle, and retail there for $30. When a housewife of St. Louis buys a dozen clothespins she has paid the railroad five ten thousandths of a cent. If she buys a washboard at 50 cents she has paid the railroad forty-two one hundredths of a cent. In Denver she would pay for that washboard 60 cents, of which the railroad would have received two cents. The 52 Railroad Freight Rates higher rates and prices that have been specified as apply- ing in Kansas City and Denver may also be taken as applicable to cities in the interior South and Southwest, such as Oislahoma, Forth Worth and San Antonio. In response to inquiries made concerning certain staple articles of daily and general use in various of the smaller cities and towns extending from Massachusetts to Georgia and Illinois, and from Michigan to Missis- sippi, it has been ascertained that throughout this region the transportation charge on such articles ranges as fol- lows: On a man's suit of clothes from two to eight cents; on calicos and ginghams from one-fiftieth of a cent to one-fifth of a cent a yard; the freight charge paid on the entire apparel of a fully dressed man or woman in this section would range perhaps from six or seven to i6 or i8 cents. The rate on an ordinary dining-room suite consisting of table, sideboard, six chairs and a china closet, would average from 75 cents to $5, on a parlor suite of sofa and four chairs from 50 cents to $4, on a bedstead and its equipment from 75 cents to $1.50, in each case from the factory to the home. The lumber used in the ordinary eight-room house will have paid the railroads from $35 to $150, and the brick from $6 or $8 to $50 or $60, as the kiln may be near or remote. A fifty pound sack of flour from the mill, even at Minneapolis, in but a few cases has paid a freight rate of over eight or nine cents to the consumer. Products of the beef or the hog are carried from the western packing houses throughout this terri- tory at rates that vary from a fifth of a cent to not exceeding a cent per pound. It has not been difficult to secure such information as applies in the main to the transportation charge borne by a manufactured article from the place of making to the final market, or on foodstuff from the place of growth to the place of sale to the consumer. Data as to the amount of transportation charge carried by the vari- ous kinds of raw material entering into a manufactured product has not in many cases been so easy of ascer- Transportation Charge and Prices 53 tainment. A principal reason has been that the manu- facturers ■ in numbers of instances do not know what it is themselves. Many kinds of material are bought at a price which includes delivery at the factory, the freight rate not coming under the cognizance of the purchaser. The different materials used in a product may have come from such diverse sources, and paid such varying rates of freight, that the ascertainment of the total freight charge in any given unit of manufacture would be too difficult to be worth while. In numerous other cases the freight charge is confessedly so small an item that no attempt is made to apportion it as an item of expenditure per unit of product, the total simply being grouped in the aggregate of expense. The statement that the transportation charge borne by the material entering into an ordinary pair of men's shoes averages one and a quarter cents is the result of a definite calculation made by one of the largest shoe manufacturers of the country. A leading woolen manu- facturer estimates that the price of wool at Boston will average perhaps 30 cents a pound " in the grease," in- cluding a transportation charge that will average one cent a pound. The loss in cleaning and scouring is about forty-five per cent, and the price of a pound of scoured wool will average about 63 cents at the mill. Of this about two cents is chargeable to transportation. One hundred pounds of wool will make about seventy pounds of straight woolen cloth, on which the transporta- tion charge has therefore been a fraction less than three cents a pound. On cloth that is mixed with cotton the transportation charge is less. The rates on woolen goods from any of the New England mills are so low that a yard of cloth which will sell from $1.50 upwards in any of the western markets will not have paid the rail- roads more than five cents from the sheep's back in Colo- rado to Massachusetts and back again to the Mississippi River. The following information as to the extent of the transportation charge borne by divers materials of vari- '54 Railroad Freight Rates ous industries has been obtained in each instance from an authority in that industry. The transportation charge on raw cotton to the mills in Massachusetts will average from one-half to two- thirds of a cent a pound, not exceeding one cent per pound even from plantations so remote as those of Texas. Cotton loses from fifteen to twenty per cent, in the clean- ing, one hundred pounds of cotton making from eighty to eighty-five pounds of cotton goods. As ordinary calico will run about six yards to the pound and sell for about five cents, the cotton that has paid a freight rate of from 50 cents to $1 is woven into $24 worth of calico. The transportation charge on a pair of rubber over- shoes, including the rubber from South America, the cotton stock, and the shipment to the western markets, averages about two and one-half per cent, of the cost of those markets. That is, a pair of rubber overshoes re- tailing for 75 cents will have paid for transportation, all told, less than one and nine-tenths cents. In no one of these examples, which, perhaps, are typical of the entire clothing industries in so far as the use of leather, wool, and cotton are concerned, is the transportation charge an appreciable factor in the price either of the material to the manufacturer or of the finished article to the consumer. A barrel of flour made in Minneapolis and trans- ported to Boston is sold at the time of this writing by the milling company to a dealer of that city, or any other place in New England, for $6. Of that $6 accrues to the transportation agencies, for carrying the wheat of which that flour was made from the Western farm to the Minneapolis mill, and for carrying the flour from the mill to Boston, an amount that averages 85 cents. The proportion of the transportation charge to price at different markets varies with the freight rate. At New York the milling company would sell that barrel for $5.95, which would include a total transportation charge of 80 cents; at Philadelphia the selling price would be $5.90, the transportation charge 75 cents ; at Buffalo or Transportation Charge and Prices 55 Pittsburg the selling price $5.80, and the total transpor- tation charge 65 cents; at Atlanta the price $6.20, the transportation charge $1.05 ; at New Orleans the price $6.10, the transportation charge 95 cents. Typical rates on leaf tobacco, averaging in value $13 per 100 pounds from plantation to warehouse in Vir- ginia and the Carolinas, are from 15 cents to 21 cents per 100 pounds; on the smoking tobacco into which this leaf is converted, and which sells at $48 per 100 pounds, from Richmond, Virginia, to New York City 30 cents, to Chicago 59 cents, to Kansas City $1.16. Rates from the plantation to the warehouse on the leaf tobacco of the Kentucky and Tennessee region, which also brings an average of $13 per 100 pounds, are from 5 cents for short to 20 cents for longer distances. The plug tobacco into which this leaf is converted is sold at $28 per 100 pounds, being distributed on such rates as these: St. Louis to Louisville, 25I cents, to New York City 58^ cents, to Kansas City 35 cents, to Seattle $2.20. Manufactured tobacco in all cases is sold at a price which includes delivery from the factory to the place of consignment, wherever it may be, in the United States. The freight rate on cane sugar from the " central " in the Louisiana district to the final refinery ranges from 5 to 10 cents per 100 pounds, the refinery paying from $3.50 to $4.50 for the sugar. Sugar that is sold by the refinmg company at 4^ to 5^ cents a pound retails at 6 cents, the dealer making little or no profit. As a town of five to ten thousand people at the average per capita consumption of seventy-five pounds a year will consume a carload of sugar in about a week, the jobbing of sugar is greatly decentralized. Contrasting with this retail price of $6 per hundred pounds typical distributive rates are, from New York to Chicago 25 cents, to St. Paul 30 cents, to Kansas City 42 cents; from New Orleans to Chicago 25 cents, to Atlanta 24 cents, to Kansas City 34 cents. The freight charge on sugar beets raised in Colorado 56 Railroad Freight Rates and Utah from the farm to the refinery is always paid by the sugar company. It averages from 30 to 40 cents per ton, or for a distance of fifty miles is as much as 50 cents. A ton of beets contains about three hundred pounds of sugar which, allowing for an average loss during extraction, would produce two hundred and forty pounds of refined sugar. This is sent from the factories to the principal places of storage, Kansas City, Omaha and St. Louis. The aggregate freight charge from the farm to St. Louis on these two hundred and forty pounds is about $1.70, and the aggregate revenue to the refinery at five cents a pound, $12. While the price of bananas is subject to great fluctua- tion, a fair average at New York, Philadelphia, Balti- more, Charleston, Mobile and New Orleans, the ports of import, is $1.75 per 100 pounds. The average rail charge for carload lots from port to market is from 30 to 50 cents per 100 pounds. About one-third of the bananas consumed in this country are received at the North Atlantic ports, whence they are distributed throughout the Eastern and Middle States. The remain- ing two-thirds, which supply the South and West, are received at the Southern ports. Immediately upon re- ceipt at New Orleans, for example, shipments are made to the North in train loads that they may be taken out of the warm climate before they spoil, and cars are re- consigned en route at the instance of the company which has very thoroughly organized the banana business, an allied company having about sixty agencies with men who devote their entire time to extending the sale of the fruit. For hides that pay a freight rate from the packing houses at Chicago to New York of 30 cents per 100 pounds, the butcher receives, according to quality, from $6 or $7 to $11 or $12 per 100 pounds. The butchers remote from market have the freight rate deducted from the price paid them for hides, but it is a trifle, seldom exceeding five cents per 100 pounds. The hide loses from twenty-five to thirty-five per cent, in the process of tan- Transportation Charge and Prices 57 ning; the price of leather is fixed by measure and not by weight. The rate on tanned leather, however, be- tween Chicago and Boston is 39 cents per 100 pounds. The railroads make low rates on fertilizer to encourage its use by the farmers, it being, of course, to the interest of a railroad to encourage the production of larger crops that its traffic may be augmented. Fertilizer of different grades brings from $18 and $20 to $55 and $60 a ton. Typical rail rates from the places of manufacture are from Jersey City to Trenton, New Jersey, $1.10 per ton, and from Boston to Portland $1.20 per ton — ^both rates applying in carload lots. In the South, where fer- tilizer is extensively utilized, representative rates are, from Atlanta to Thomasville $2.50, from Charleston to Columbia $2.00 per ton. When allowance is made for the elimination of water from pulp and the shrinkage in its manufacture into paper, the average freight rate borne by the material entering into paper at the northern New England mill is about 13^ cents per 100 pounds. The manufacturers consider 17 cents per 100 pounds to be the average freight rate on the paper from the mill to places north of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi Rivers. The aggregate freight charge borne on the average by the 100 pounds of paper which sells at the factory for $2.50 is therefore 30 cents. As with all things else, the rates on the ores of the far western region have been adjusted under the necessity of the transportation agencies to so serve the mines that their products may be marketed. The rate upon the ore from the mine to the smelter, upon the metal from the smelter to the refinery, and upon the refined lead or refined copper from Chicago to the seaboard market, are all determined by this prime factor. The freight charges, for example, from the Coeur d'Alene district in northern Idaho on the ores from which the extra- neous material has been roughly separated, to the Puget Sound refineries, reach a maximum of $6 per ton for a distance of four or five hundred miles, and the rate from 58 Railroad Freight Rates Puget Sound to New York is $14.50, the average trans- portation charge, therefore, being about $20 per ton. The value of a ton of copper at 12 cents a pound is $240, and a ton of lead at four cents a pound is $80. Copper passes through manifold and expensive processes and its extensive consumption has followed the development of electricity. Lead does not require so many or so expensive workings, and it has long been a great staple of general use. The mine farther from a smelter natur- ally has to pay a higher rate of freight than a mine nearer to it, receiving, therefore, a lesser net price for its product, but the railroads are obliged to so adjust rates that practically every mine can reach a market. The rate on refined petroleum between New York and Chicago is 2.j\ cents per 100 pounds, the average rate paid north of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi Rivers being from eight to ten cents per 100 pounds. From To- ledo to Atlanta the rate is 48 cents, from Whiting 46J cents, from New Orleans 35 cents. The rate from Chicago to the Missouri River is 22 cents, to St. Louis ten cents ; while the rate from the Kansas field to St. Louis is 17 cents. One hundred pounds of refined oil contain ap- proximately sixteen gallons which, at an average price of \2\ cents a gallon at the refinery, would aggregate $2. The price per gallon to the consumer is increased one cent with each increment of seven cents in the freight charge. The principal biscuit company receives from $8 to $16 per 100 pounds for its crackers and cakes, averaging $10 per 100 pounds for its leading brand. From its New York plant to Boston the freight rates are 19 cents per 100 pounds, to Atlanta 62 cents. The rate from Chicago to Montgomery is 69 cents, to Houston 81 cents, to Denver 97 cents. From either New York or Chicago to the Pacific Coast the rate is $1.60. These rates apply to carload lots, all goods being sold deliv- ered, the company absorbing the freight. The retail price is the same all over the United States as it is with shoes, cigars, soap, proprietary medicines and dozens of other familiar articles. Transportation Charge and Prices 59 On cotton, the great staple product of the South, the freight rate structure has been in process of develop- ment even a longer time than that affecting the move- ment of grain from the West. From the plantation into Memphis, the largest inland cotton center of the United States, a typical rate is 30 cents per 100 pounds for one hundred and fifty miles. From Memphis to Boston the rate is 57^ cents, and from Memphis to the Gulf 30 cents per 100 pounds. From Augusta, Ga., a central market of the Eastern cotton growing district, the rate to Charleston and Savannah is 21 cents, to Brunswick 23 cents and to Norfolk 26 cents per 100 pounds. A bale of cotton contains five hundred pounds and is therefore worth, at II cents a pound, $55. The aggregate trans- portation charge on this bale from the plantation, one hundred and fifty miles from Memphis, to Boston, is $4-27-_ Mainly because of the rapid shifting of the sources of supply, there has not yet been developed a stable struc- ture of rates for the movement of lumber in all parts of the United States. By way of illustration, however, it may be said that a fair average rate on lumber into Memphis from the forests of Arkansas is six cents per 100 pounds, or $2.40 per 1,000 feet. Lumber going from Memphis to New Orleans for export will pay $4.80 or a total transportation charge from the forest of $7.20 per 1,000 feet. A fair average rate to the markets in Ohio and Indiana is $8 per 1,000 feet, a total transporta- tion charge from the forest of $10.40. This is on the kind of lumber that in 1905 and 1906 sold at about $40. The rate on yellow pine from New Orleans to Chicago is 24 cents per 100 pounds. There is an equalization of rates on the iron ore from the upper lakes in that the rates of the boat lines from the ore mines are the same to each of the Lake Erie ports. From thence to the furnaces they are adjusted under the policy of the railroads to make the transporta- tion charge on the raw material required to make a ton of pig-iron approximate the same amount at each of the competing furnaces of southern Ohio, Pittsburg, Wheel- 6o Railroad Freight Rates ing, in the Mahoning and Shenango Valleys, and even as far as the Schuylkill Valley. How closely this equal- ization is effected is shown by the fact that the trans- portation charge on the ore, coke and limestone required to produce one ton of pig-iron is as follows in these respective districts: At the furnaces on the Mononga- hela River in the Pittsburg district, $5.82 ; at the furnaces of the Mahoning and Shenango Valleys, $5.57; at the furnaces of the Wheeling district, $5.78. These charges compare favorably with those at the furnaces on the Lake Shore in the Chicago district, which aggregate $5.63 per ton of pig-iron, but are higher than at the fur- naces on the Lake Shore in the Cleveland district, where they aggregate but $4.72. The rates on coal, which gives return loads to the cars that take the ore south from the Lake Erie ports, are maintained at established differences between the coal fields of Ohio, Pittsburg and West Virginia. The rates in effect in the spring of 1908 were $1 per ton from southern Ohio, 90 cents from southeastern Ohio, $1 per ton from the Pittsburg field and $1.15 a ton from West Virginia. The claim of the railroads that the rates on foodstuffs are not high enough to enter as a factor in fixing the selling price is fully substantiated by the statements of the dealers in such products. That is, the conditions are, with negligible exceptions, such that if the price ob- tainable in the markets be sufficient to encourage the growing of livestock, grains, dairy products, fruits or vegetables, the rate of freight, from whatever locality to whatever market, is sufficiently low to allow the pro- ducer to enter that market. His profits are, however, as a matter of course, diminished by the amount of freight which he pays, and, as a rule, the farther the place of production from the markets the greater is the freight charge. The differences in the net return to the producer are almost invariably reflected in the value of the land, which is lower as the distance from the mar- kets is greater. Largely because of the defective sys- tem of mercantile distribution the grower of produce Transportation Charge and Prices 6i obtains a smaller proportion of the price paid by the consumer than accrues to the grower of any other agri- cultural product. Where, as in this country, the oppor- tunity for the extension of cultivation is practically un- limited, a good market one season leads the farmers of any district to increase their production up to the point of minimum profit and the railroads are then besought for lower rates : when unfavorable weather or other con- ditions reduce their output they are also disgruntled. It therefore rarely happens that the grower, especially of the quickly perishable foodstuffs, is entirely satisfied with the freight rates. A controversy, that it is scarcely an exaggeration to designate as typical, occurred several years ago between the growers of watermelons in a Southwestern State and the railroads conveying the melons to the primary mar- kets. In comparatively a few years that region had be- come so productive that the shipments of watermelons over one road alone ranged from 1,400 to 1,800 cars during a watermelon season, deliveries being made all over Ohio and Indiana through dealers from those States who came down and bought the melons at the farms. The contention for lower rates had waxed so warm that a reduction in the watermelon rate became the issue upon which a legislative campaign was fought. The candidate pledged to secure a reduction in the rate was elected, and introduced a bill, which was enacted by the legislature, making the rate to the nearest primary market 7^ cents per 100 pounds. The railroad companies put this rate in effect and used it as a basis for the lowering of rates to the territory beyond. During the year of this rate reduction the trafific department of the railroad company referred to sent word to the farmers that the company had handled 1,500 cars of melons that season, the prompt shipment of which had been highly satisfactory to the growers. It furthermore said that the movement of these melons from that territory was a one-way traffic entirely, it being necessary to send special cars empty for the crop. These were necessarily stock cars that 62 Railroad Freight Rates there might be ample ventilation, but they had to be sup- plied with extra slats in order that the melons might not fall out. It was necessary for them to be switched in requisite number on side tracks especially built adjoining the farms where the fruit was grown ; that switching en- gines be kept at work, putting cars in and taking cars out all night and all day. The cars of melons, moreover, had to be hauled on special trains at a high rate of speed to get them to the markets before they spoiled. This reduced the tonnage per train fifteen or twenty per cent. below the maximum that could be hauled at the normal freight train speed. A car with the average allowable load of i,ioo watermelons would contain but about twelve tons, although its capacity would be eighteen or twenty tons : the weight of the car exceeded the weight of the load. The switching and other special movements necessitated the employment of night telegraph oper- ators and other extra help at the melon fields. All of these conditions led the assistant to the general manager of the company to make an analysis of the ex- penditure as compared with the earnings. Way bills were abstracted and the receipts listed. A tabulation was made of the revenue tonnage, the gross tonnage, the tare weight, and the expenses incurred in behalf of the traffic. He found that the handling of the 1,500 cars of watermelons involved a loss to the company of $12,000 if the expenses of operation alone were considered. The results of this investigation were brought to the attention of the traffic department and the next spring it sent a circular to the farmers in the truck region urg- ing that the watermelon acreage be reduced, as the rates on that business were not remunerative, and stating that the railroad would not undertake to handle it except in the regular cars that were brought into the territory in the ordinary course of traffic ; that there would be no special trains, nor special service of any character. The melon growers at once notified the State Railroad Com- mission, which, in turn, requested the railroad company and the melon growers to attend a meeting to discuss the Transportation Charge and Prices 63 whole subject. When the meeting convened the chair- man called upon the railroads to say why they had caused so much trouble. The railroad representative, who was the aforesaid assistant to the general manager, stated that as he had been invited to attend the meeting it might be proper for whomsoever had instigated it to open the discussion. Several shippers made statements of their complaints, all admitting, however, that the melon business had become very profitable, — one grower saying that $300 to $500 per car was being made out of a crop. The railroad representative then made reply, showing the loss to the company from handling the business for the previous year, and stated that unless cost for the handling and something by way of profit could be obtained, the company would prefer to move other crops. He showed that it had been necessary to park 350 to 400 especially prepared stock cars in the melon territory ; that it had taken a month or six weeks to gather these cars, which had to be hauled empty to the melon fields. He then pointed out that the rate per melon was less than a cent and a quarter, whereas it had cost the farmer four or five cents per melon to bring it by wagon the one or two or three miles to the railroad track. The chairman objected to some of the analyses, espe- cially to this contrast of four or five cents per melon for the wagon haul from the farm with the cent or a cent and a half per melon for the railroad haul of two hun- dred miles. When the railroad man had finished, farmers from all over the room began to ask questions directly of him. They wanted to know how much they should pay to afford the railroad some slight profit. They were told 12 or 12J cents. The chairman said : " The rate cannot be changed. It has been fixed by law at 7^ cents and that is the rate. I am here to protect the people of these counties." The railroad man suggested that his company might be willing in addi- tion to affix the necessary slats to the stock cars and perform the switching for $5 to $6 per car. The farmers were willing to accept this, but the chairman insisted that 64 Railroad Freight Rates it was contrary to law, and finally said in his wrath, " If you men here are going to deal with the railroad company you can do it without me. This meeting is adjourned." With one exception the farmers remained in the hall and expressed a willingness to pay a rate of 12 cents per 100 pounds. Returning to the main discussion, we have found that the rates on raw materials are so adjusted as to per- mit the manufacture of any staple article at any logical place of manufacture. On the raw material of wearing apparel the freight rate is entirely unimportant. On the lumber that enters into building material, on the ore, coke, and limestone used in the manufacture of iron and steel the freight rate is sufficient to become an appreci- able factor in the cost of manufacture. On brick, coal and cement the selling price is the higher by the amount of the freight charge, which for distances sometimes not considerable exceeds the value of the commodity at the place of production. The freight charge, even on these heavier commodities, however, is far less in propor- tion to the wage of the day laborer as well as to the in- comes and salaries received in the United States, than in any other country. This is obviously a better test of comparison than that based upon rates of freight as expressed in money. To say that a specific rate is twenty cents in the United States, a shilling in Great Britain, a franc in France, or a mark in Germany, conveys an in- adequate idea. When it is ascertained that the average wage of the day laborer in the United States is higher in comparison with the average rate of transportation than in any other country, the comparison is significant. In this country a continually increasing amount of rail- road transportation can be purchased with the wage of the day laborer. With the sum of money representing the value of a given unit of any of the staple commodities of commerce, also can a continually increasing amount of railroad transportation be purchased. That which makes possible the low freight rate of the American railroads is the magnitude of the scale upon Transportation Charge and Prices 65 which the transportation is conducted. The large cars, with a capacity of from thirty to fifty tons, and the pow- erful locomotives that draw a score or more of these loaded cars in one train, permit an almost infinitesimal freight charge per pound or per yard that, however, yields by the carload or by the trainload no inconsiderable rev- enue. For example, the average weight of the carload of food products is about 30,000 pounds. If the freight on such a carload be $300 the rate per pound would be only one cent, and there is scarcely a commodity upon which a freight rate of one cent per pound makes any difiference in the retail price. As a matter of fact a carload of food products does not bring to the railroad so much revenue as $300 unless it has been moved from a far region; for instance, from the Dakotas or Texas to New York. Specific complaint in regard to the freight rates of the United States for many years has not, except in a small minority of cases, been based on the ground that they have prevented foodstuffs from finding a mar- ket, raw material from reaching places of manufacture, or finished products from distribution. While the differ- ence of a cent or two in the rate of freight may not in the least interfere with the conduct of industry or com- merce in the aggregate, such a slight difference may perhaps determine whether a manufacturer obtain his raw material from this or that source of supply, whether a wholesale dealer obtain his stock from the manufac- turer in one, or the manufacturer in another city, whether a retail dealer make his purchases from the wholesale dealer in this city or in that city. That is, for example, the prices of the products at the sources of supply being equal, a difference in the rate of freight may determine whether Cleveland, Ohio, obtain potatoes from Michi- gan or from upper New York; whether a factory in Louisville obtain coal from the fields of southern Indiana or central Kentucky. A carpenter in Des Moines may perhaps pay a dollar for twenty pounds of nails without knowing or caring what the freight rate may have been, OT where they may have come from. A difference, how- 66 Railroad Freight Rates ever, of a few cents a hundred pounds in the rate of freight may have led the hardware dealer to have pur- chased the nails in Chicago or St. Louis or even directly from Pittsburg. As the purchase of raw material tends toward the prosperity of the region where it is produced, as the operation of a factory tends to the increase of popula- tion, to appreciation in the value of real estate and the augmentation of business at the place of its location, so also does the growth of a wholesale business or of a retail business aid in the development of its surround- ings. Producers, manufacturers, wholesalers and re- tailers naturally all desire to extend their sales, to reach further markets in competition with their rivals, and are supported in this desire by the communities to whose welfare they contribute. Any difference in freight rates that gives a producer of raw material, a manufacturer, a wholesale distributer, or a retail merchant an advan- tage over a competitor of another locality is therefore promptly made the subject of complaint. The pressure brought upon the railroads by such com- peting producers, manufacturers and dealers has been a very important factor in the development of certain arrangements of freight rates, which we shall term the Regional Rate Structures, each of which has grown out of the various characteristics of a traffic region and has become adapted to those characteristics. Other arrangements of freight rates which have grown out of the needs entailed by the production and marketing of certain of the principal articles entering into commerce we shall designate as the Commodity Rate Structures. CHAPTER VII THE REGIONAL RATE STRUCTURES An examination will disclose that the freight rate structure of each section of the country has been de- termined by its geographical situation, its material re- sources, its material needs, its physical relation to sources of supply and to markets, its transportation facilities both by rail and by water, and its position in the aggre- gate of these relations with respect to other sections of the country. The problem forced by these relations upon the railroads has been to develop that adjustment of rates which serves the economic needs of each section. In the solution, which has in every case been through long struggles and compromises between competing railroads and competing communities, the distance over which commodities are carried — that is, the length of the haul — is always a large and often the chief factor in determining the rate. Frequently, however, the length of the haul is subordinated by other factors. This is conspicuously the case with (l) THE FREIGHT RATE STRUCTURE OF NEW ENGLAND At the close of the Revolution the commerce of Boston exceeded that of New York. When the merchant marine of the United States was foremost on the ocean, the shipping and shipbuilding interests of Boston were the greatest in the country. Throughout a large part of the nineteenth century the city was noted for the manu- facture of iron, the smelting of copper, the making of furniture and various wares from wood. That this condition no longer exists was sharply brought to the attention of the people of Massachusetts by Governor Russell, who presented, in 1892, during 67 68 Railroad Freight Rates the term of his administration, a list of one hundred and thirty iron mills and factories that had gone from the State. Weymouth is now at the beginning of an effort to resurrect the shipbuilding industry that likewise had died. The smelters have migrated to the ore beds. Su- premacy in the manufacture of furniture passed long ago. The prestige in grain export is maintained only by a continual struggle against advancing odds. The gain in the total imports and exports of Boston does not keep pace with that of the other Atlantic ports. It is natural that with the development of the country in- dustry should pass to the source of raw material; that as the grain regions pursue the star of empire their prod- uct for export should go by the short and level routes to the outlets on the north and on the south. Yet it must be remembered that while New York was forging great lines of communication with Chicago, the surplus wealth of Boston was not being used to establish similar channels to that gateway to the West, but in building railroads from the West tributary to that gateway. The eastbound traffic of these western roads has been poured in increas- ing measure into the channels that lead to New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore. While Boston was most ac- tive in financing these lines beyond Chicago, she permit- ted her own direct connection with the West to consist of a single track railroad which remained a single track railroad for thirty years. There was once a project for a great and direct through line to the West, but the State laws governing investments in railroads killed it in its birth. Boston still, however, maintains an indus- trial and commercial eminence ; the manufacturing towns of Massachusetts, southern New Hampshire, northern Connecticut and Rhode Island are prosperous. This entire section is in the same general traffic district as Boston, sharing in its advantages and disadvantages. It is pre-eminent in the manufacture of boots and shoes, cotton, woolen and worsted goods, leather articles of all kinds, paper, rubber goods, and other manufactures that require delicate and skilled workmanship in mills The Regional Rate Structures 69 and factories of elaborate design and expensive con- struction. A foremost requisite for the continuance of this prosperity is therefore the perpetuation of the skilled labor. That the people of these States are awake to this necessity would appear from the propositions for the establishment of industrial schools and from the atten- tion being given to sanitation and other phases of indus- trial welfare. Only to a negligible extent does New England pro- duce the raw material of any of her industries ; her popu- lation furnishes a market for but a fraction of the prod- uct. Therefore the transportation agencies must not only furnish the facilities for bringing in raw material and taking out the finished product, but the rates must be so adjusted that the raw material may be profitably brought in, and that the products may be advantageously sold in the widest markets. This is the governing consideration, because of the necessity for maintaining the manufactures of New England in competition with those of the principal competing region — that ter- ritory which extends from New York and Brooklyn through central New Jersey into southern Pennsylvania and northern Delaware. The railroad adjustment fostering this purpose is that under which the rates on the raw material of manufac- ture,- coming from west of a line drawn from Buffalo through Pittsburg and Wheeling, are the same to every point in New England, and but a trifle, from 2 to 7 cents per 100 pounds, higher than on that material to New York. The rates on all of the manufactured products going out of New England to west of a line drawn from Cleveland to the Ohio River are the same as the rates from New York to the region west of that line. That is, for the purpose of reaching the markets of the popu- lous regions that lie to the north of the Ohio and west of the Mississippi River, not only is every place of pro- duction in New England placed on a parity with every other place of production in New England, but every place of production in New England is 70 Railroad Freight Rates placed on a parity with the great metropolis of the United States. The same rates spread, Hke a blanket, over the entire region. It is also to be remembered that to but a small extent does sterile New England now produce the food required within her confines. Here again there is dependence upon the rail- roads which bring in foodstuffs from the West and South at rates so very little higher than the rates to New York that the transportation charge upon the consumer's unit of meats, dairy products, grains, fruits or vegetables, is practically the same as in the metropolis. The rates governing the interior traffic of New Eng- land are embodied in local tariffs which are issued by each road for itself and are ordinarily on a mileage basis. Along the Atlantic Coast, however, the steamboats keep the rates of the railroads between Boston and the ports of Maine to a somewhat lower level. The steamboat rates between Boston and Portland, for example, range from 20 cents on merchandise of the first class to 6 cents on that of the sixth class. The railroads meet these rates, observing the mileage basis, however, to inter- mediate stations, even though the rates be higher than to the further station having water communication. Thus the rail rate from Boston to a station immediately south of Portland is 2i cents on merchandise of the first class and 7 cents on that of the second class. (2) THE TRUNK LINE AND CENTRAL TRAFFIC TERRITORY New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore, each a sea- port and the metropolis of its respective State, naturally became commercial rivals as their means of communica- tion extended further into the interior. The Erie Canal, connecting New York with the Lakes, led Pennsyl- vania to devise the State Line of Public Works for the purpose of giving Philadelphia direct means of com- munication to the west of the Alleghany Mountains, and in turn Maryland chartered the Baltimore and Ohio Railroad Company to connect the City of Baltimore with The Regional Rate Structures 71 the Ohio River. The intense rivalry between the cities was in evidence in 1854, when the President of the Balti- more and Susquehanna Railroad, extending from cen- tral Pennsylvania toward the South, vowed that freight would never be carried more cheaply to Philadelphia than over his line to Baltimore. The main stems of the first lines from the East led, one from New York City through the central part of the State to Buffalo, and one through the southern tier of counties to Salamanca ; one from Philadelphia to Pittsburg; and one from Baltimore to Parkersburg. These were designated as the Trunk Lines and the region between the seabpard and their western termini as the Trunk Line Territory. From these western termini of the Trunk Line rail- roads, lines, radiating like branches from the trunk of a tree, were built across Ohio, Indiana and Illinois toward the West: transverse lines were also constructed con- necting the interior of these States with the Lakes on the north and with the Ohio River on the south. Even in the days prior to the railroads the water communication and other advantages of location had caused Chicago to become the gateway to the West and Northwest, St. Louis to the West and Southwest, and Cincinnati to the South. These three cities, each an immediate market and a distributing center of impor- tance, naturally, therefore, were the goals of the lines that were stretching from the Atlantic seaboard, and each of the four westward trending companies gained access to these cities over the rails of directly connecting roads. Each of these lines continually strove to carry augment- ing quantities of merchandise to the West, and its en- deavors were seconded by the merchants and manufac- turers who sought to extend the markets of their respec- tive cities. Eastbound the rivalry was for the shipments of grain, of which the greater portion, even until the close of the decade beginning with 1870, came from the farming lands between the Alleghany Mountains and the Mississippi River. 72 Railroad Freight Rates The competition inevitably became bitter between the railways and between the termini which they served. One railway would cut the tariff rates to the East, the others would meet the cut and perhaps make a deeper cut. The rates would be cut on traffic to the West. There would be retaliation and retaliation in return. The weakest and worst situated lines naturally had to fight the hardest and were the first and most persistent rate cutters. Throughout this period the rebate spread like a fungus: a railroad company, desiring to obtain the traffic of a heavy shipper, would offer him a secret rate ; other railroads would offer secret rates to other ship- pers, until neither railroad nor shipper knew what rates were being paid other railroads by other shippers. In- deed one shipper would not know what rate a compet- ing shipper on the same railroad was paying. Rate wars, beginning not long after the close of the Civil War, were almost incessant during the following decade. They ap- plied to traffic, not only between the three great west- ern cities and the seaboard, but developed on traffic be- tween intermediate cities. They not only afifected the through eastern and western lines, but involved the transverse lines leading north and south. These trans- verse lines carried traffic to the Lakes, whence it was sent east in competition with the railroads ; they car- ried traffic to the Ohio River, whence it was sent west in competition with the railroads. Any one of these north and south lines found it profitable to compete in its north- ern territory with the Trunk Line leading to the East from that region by taking traffic to a junction in the South and delivering it to the Trunk Line leading east from that region, or vice versa. It could use the east- bound Trunk Line at the North, or the Trunk Line at the South, as a leverage wherewith to obtain return traffic from these lines and induce them to make arrange- ments in its interest. Through these various causes the rates of this entire territory between the seaboard and Chicago and St. Louis and Cincinnati fell into chaos. The shippers of The Regional Rate Structures 73 neither Baltimore nor Philadelphia were willing to pay as high a rate to the West as applied from New York, nof did they regard as satisfactory the application to their cities from the West of the same rate as to New York. The main contention was that the shorter dis- tance between their cities and the West entitled them to lower rates. After long continued conflict an arrange- ment was reached whereby Philadelphia was granted lesser rates than to and from New York and Boston, and Baltimore a lower rate than to and from Philadel- phia: these are the Baltimore and Philadelphia differen- tials. Although the specific rates applying on eastbound traffic and on westbound traffic to and from these cities under this arrangement have been changed several times, the principle is still recognized and differential rates still exist. Their establishment was but one step toward bringing harmony out of chaos. The bitterness of the rivalry was in some further degree ameliorated by the fact that the growing importance of New York led the lines that originally terminated in Philadelphia and Bal- timore to obtain entrance to the metropolis. The complexity of the situation to the west of the Trunk Line termini led to conflict after conflict between the rail- roads there that devastated their revenue : agreement after agreement, entered into for the maintenance of rates, was broken almost as soon as it was made, with re- sulting demoralization. This region between the western termini of the Trunk Lines and Chicago, St. Louis and Cincinnati was designated as the Central Traffic Terri- tory. As a Trunk Line Association had been formed for the purpose of bringing about and maintaining har- mony between the railroads in the Trunk Line Terri- tory, so also was a Central Traffic Association formed to the same end. There was, however, not only difficulty in the way of maintaining rates, but the different rail- roads had so interlaced throughout the territory that it was difficult to determine what rates should be main- tained. For example, freight between Columbus and the seaboard could be sent by way of Cleveland and Buffalo, y4 Railroad Freight Rates by way of Pittsburg, or by way of Wheeling or Parkers- burg. How the rate from Columbus to the seaboard should be made and how it should apply is but one iHus- tration of the perplexities that existed over the entire region, and they were aggravated by the part taken in the east and west traffic by the north and south lines. A long step toward the solution of this phase of the problem was taken in 1876 by the device of the Trunk Line Percentage System. The rate between Chicago and New York, whatever it might be, was designated as 100 per cent. The rate to or from certain principal in- termediate points that were common to two or more railroads was made a fixed percentage of the rate to or from Chicago ; that is, the rate from New York to Pitts- burg became 60 per cent., to Cleveland 71 per cent., to Detroit 78 per cent., to IndianapoHs 93 per cent., and to Peoria no per cent, of the New York-Chicago rate. The rates from the West to the East were also determined by these percentages from common points. That is, the rate from Indianapolis to New York was fixed at 93 per cent, of the rate from Chicago, from Detroit 78 per cent., from Cleveland 71 per cent, and from Pittsburg 60 per cent. It should be said that at first the percentages applying to the East and from the West, or vice versa, were not identical at every common point. The adjust- ment which the system obtained throughout succeeding years finally brought about this result. The percent- ages fixing these rates at the common points were origi- nally nearly, if not exactly, the ratio borne by the dis- tance over the shortest " worked and workable route " between a common point and either Chicago or New York, to the short line distance between those points. The rates to and from stations intermediate to the com- mon, or " basing points," were made by adding the local rate to or from the intermediate point to the basing point rate. This method of construction frequently led to the rate at an intermediate station being higher than the rate at either the basing point to the east or the basing point The Regional Rate Structures 75 to the west of that station. A north and south line would still take through east or westbound traffic, for example, from a station on the southern part of its line at the through rate applying from that station, and de- liver it to an eastern or western Trunk Line at a junc- tion on the northern part of its line even although the through rate from that junction were higher than the through rate from the station at which the traffic origi- nated. When the Interstate Commerce Law became effective in 1887 the railroads of the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory, in their zeal to comply with its provisions, at once set about a general revision of their tariffs in order that no rate might be lower from a far- ther than from an intermediate station on the same line, or, in other words, that traffic might not be hauled over a longer distance at a lesser rate than for a shorter dis- tance over the same line, and in the same direction. The Trunk Line Percentage System was so revised that all rates eft'ective thereunder were based exactly upon dis- tance — due allowance being made for a loading and an unloading charge — and in no case, under its most strict construction, was the long and short haul clause of the Interstate Commerce Law violated. This abolished the method of making rates from intermediate stations in the way theretofore customary, and it also minimized such carrying of east and west traffic, as violated this clause, over the roundabout routes formed by the north and south lines. This arrangement worked badly from the first, dis- turbing industrial and commercial conditions at many places. Shippers, whose business had developed under the previous rate status, found themselves handicapped by having to pay higher rates than competitors at other places with whom their rates had theretofore been on a parity: the north and south lines chafed at being de- prived of a goodly share of traffic; established chan- nels of trade in many instances were dislocated. In 1892 a further revision of the Percentage System was begun that took into account these commercial and industrial 76 Railroad Freight Rates conditions, and it resulted, in 1896, in the adjustment which, with a few changes, is in effect at present. Rates for the eastern and western traffic are applied to groups of stations, each focused more or less directly upon a central basing point, but the rates as a whole bear only an indirect relation to distance. The long and short haul principle is still, however, rigidly observed in this terri- tory; that is, on interstate traffic. Under the present grouping, for instance, the 100 per cent, rate from and to Chicago applies throughout a belt of Indiana, extending southward to Louisville: the 87 per cent, rate applies throughout a " shoestring district" extending from above Ft. Wayne on the north down through Cincinnati and almost to Parkersburg on the south. One cause leading to such a northerly and southerly prolongation of a group has been the demand of a north and south line that it be not absolutely prohibited from engaging in east and west traffic in conjunction with an east and west line. This has been met by the applica- tion of the same rate throughout the length of the north and south line, thereby permitting it to take traffic at the same rate from any point of origin on its line by way of any of its junctions with an east or west line. The Percentage System has not been strictly observed throughout the territory in that here and there rates are made by the application of specific instead of percentage differences above or below the rate from a basing point. For example, as a result of many years of controversy between competing iron manufacturers and conflict be- tween the railroads serving the several districts, the rates to the East from the Mahoning and Shenango Val- leys have been made 2 cents per 100 pounds higher than from Pittsburg, from the Cleveland district 3 cents higher than the Pittsburg rate, and from the Johnstown district i| cents less than the Pittsburg rate. The grouping under the present percentage adjust- ment, in combination with the Philadelphia and Balti- more differentials, has carried the rates applying to these respective cities for considerable distances back into the The Regional Rate Structures ^^ interior, thus forming a Baltimore group, which includes an area extending northward through Maryland and a considerable section of southern Pennsylvania; and the Philadelphia group, which includes the stations within a radius of two hundred miles or so to the north and east of Philadelphia. The rate, for example, from the West to Altoona is the same as to Baltimore, to Wilkesbarre the same as to Philadelphia. It will be perceived that the Trunk Line Percentage System determines the rate to or from a percentage point only after the basic rate between Chicago and New York has been established. When that rate has been determined, whether upon the traffic that moves under the class tariffs or that which moves under commodity tariffs, the rates for all intervening stations, and sta- tions as far west as the Mississippi River crossings from Cairo on the south to Dubuque on the north, are auto- matically adjusted by the percentage of the basic rate applying to the group to which any particular station is assigned. All of these rates, therefore, change auto- matically as the basic rate changes. The Trunk Line Percentage System affects in the main the rates upon the commodities that flow in the main traffic channels to and from the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Association Terminals. It does not determine the rates upon which the merchandise is carried in this region from the distributing centers to the retail dealers, or upon the merchandise which, originating at one, is shipped to another place in its interior. Although it often happens that such rates are influenced by the Trunk Line Percentage rates, they are primarily and in the main determined by each road for itself, subject to such over- sight as may have been delegated by a State to a Public Service Commission or to a State Railroad Com- mission and to such modification as may be caused by one or another phase of competition. In the Central Traffic territory maximum local rates for the State of Ohio were specifically fixed by the State Legislature many years ago, and have the distinction of being lower than 78 Railroad Freight Rates any similar rates in any other portion of the United States that has population and traffic of a corresponding density. In 1896, when the revised Trunk Line Per- centage System was made effective, a scale of minimum rates governing local traffic was also adopted by the lines of the Central Traffic Territory. The tariff promulgated by the Ohio Legislature restricts the local charge on commodities of the first class to 5 cents per 100 pounds up to thirty miles, but allows a handling and a terminal charge in addition, of which the railroads have not availed. This Ohio scale was extended into Indiana by some of the lines traversing both States, but has not been generally adopted by all the railroads of that State. The local rates of the railroads in Illinois are fixed by the Illi- nois Railroad and Warehouse Commission. The manner in which the Trunk Line Percentage System affects the interior rates in the Central Traffic Territory is instanced by the following example: The distance from Chicago to Toledo by the short line is two hundred and thirty-four miles, the rate being determined by the Central Freight Association tariff of 1896. The short line from Chicago to Detroit is two hundred and seventy-two miles, but as Detroit takes the same New York percentage as Toledo it is accorded the same rate from Chicago in competition with Toledo. Port Huron, three hundred and twenty-five miles from Chicago, takes the same New York percentage as Detroit, and the lines leading from Chicago to Port Huron insist that its rates from that city shall be no higher than the rate to Detroit. (3) THE TRANS-MISSISSIPPI AND TRANS-MISSOURI TER- RITORY The fan-like opening out of the channels of traffic from the East at the western termini of the Trunk Lines, broadens through Chicago and St. Louis into a rim that extends from the boundary of Saskatchewan to the line that separates New Mexico and Arizona from the Mexi- can Republic. The Regional Rate Structures 79 As the lands to the west of the Mississippi River were attaining a population, Chicago and St. Louis were the principal sources of supply of the staple articles of use, and they continued to be the main distributing centers as the frontier moved beyond the Missouri River. North- ern lUinois and central Iowa were naturally tributary to Chicago and southern Illinois, and central and south- ern Missouri to St. Louis. Throughout central Illinois, southern Iowa, northern Missouri, Kansas and Nebraska the merchants of the two cities and the railroads serv- ing them came into competition, which waxed fully as bitter as that which had earlier developed between the great cities of the North Atlantic seaboard. There was then no common interest between the railroads extending from Chicago to the Missouri River and the railroads ex- tending from St. Louis to the Missouri River. A succes- sion of rate wars entailed losses of millions of dollars to their revenues and led to the formation of associations through which it was endeavored, as through similar associations in the East and at about the same time, to bring about agreement as to rates and the elimination of friction. The cutting of rates during these wars had affected to an extent the revenues of the lines east of Chicago and St. Louis, which frequently were obliged to partici- pate in the low through rates made by their western connections, but the adoption of the Trunk Line Per- centage System protected them in great measure, as the making of the rate between New York and St. Louis 116 per cent. — originally it was 129 per cent. — of the rate between New York and Chicago determined the relative proportions that the eastern lines would accept on trafific via those cities. It devolved upon the lines leading to the West from Chicago and St. Louis to fix some basis for the adjustment of the respective rates from those cities into the competitive territory. After much contention the lines from St. Louis were accorded differences under the lines from Chicago to St. Joseph, Atchison, Leavenworth, and Kansas City, the lower Mis- 8o Railroad Freight Rates souri crossings and to the Southwest generally, which, ranging higher at first, were reduced to the gradation from 20 cents per 100 pounds on merchandise of the first class to 5 cents per 100 pounds on that of the fifth class. Rates from the East were then made the same to Omaha and Kansas City, because of the competition of these cities as Missouri River distributing centers. It will be perceived that no device similar to the Trunk Line Percentage System was applicable. That system was made feasible by the definite base line which rested upon a populous New York at the one end and a populous Chicago at the other; and also by its especial adaptabil- ity to a territory comparatively narrow in width through which the flow of traffic was in fairly direct channels. Analogous conditions did not exist in the trans-Missis- sippi and trans-Missouri territory; hence the system of adjustment by " fixed differences " instead of per- centages. By the time of the adjustment of the differentials be- tween Chicago, St. Louis, and the Missouri River, other complications had arisen through the building of lines that, without passing through either Chicago or St. Louis, traversed Illinois from the east, crossed the Mis- sissippi River at such places as Dubuque, Davenport, Buriington, and Hannibal, and thence continued west. At an early stage in the development of the Trunk Line Percentage System the rate from New York to certain of these Mississippi River crossings was as high as 122 per cent, of the Chicago rate. The 116 per cent, rate to St. Louis, plus the rate from there to Kansas City, made the lowest rate from New York to the Missouri River. The greater proportion of this through traffic under such an adjustment would go by way of St. Louis to the detriment of lines crossing the Mississippi River at the other points. These other lines naturally would not tolerate such an arrangement, but by making rates as low or lower than those via the St. Louis route would secure a portion of the traffic. To eliminate the ensuing contentions, the proportional rates on through westbound The Regional Rate Structures 8i traffic to all the Mississippi River crossings, as far north as Dubuque, were made the same as to St. Louis; and the rate via any line from the Mississippi to the Mis- souri was made the same as the rate between these rivers over the short line between St. Louis and Kansas City. The effect of this was to make the through rate from the East the same via any of the Mississippi River crossings, from as far north as Dubuque, and as far south as St. Louis, to any of the Missouri River points, from as far north as Omaha to as far south as Kansas City; and to make the rate the same from any one of these Missis- sippi River points to any one of these Missouri River points. It should be remembered that in the earlier days it was the policy of the United States government to keep the navigable rivers free, as far as possible, from obstruction by bridges, and the construction of a railroad bridge across a great river was relatively by far a more difficult and expensive enterprise than at present. There- fore many a railroad terminated at one bank of a river, and if there were rail connection from the opposite bank transferred its traffic by ferry. Such great rivers as the Mississippi and the Missouri became the natural dividing lines between different groups of railroads, and also the basing lines from which rates were calculated. That the Mississippi River was made a basing line, how- ever, was largely caused by the necessity for making the crossings from Dubuque to St. Louis common points from the East. St. Louis was thus on this basing line while Chicago was not. The rate from the East via Chicago to Omaha, for instance, was not made by adding the rate from Chicago to Omaha to the rate from the East to Chicago, but by adding the rate from the East to Dubuque to the rate from Dubuque to Oniaha. This is a cumbersome arrangement and the railroads are grad- ually so altering the tariffs that the dividing line ex- tends from Chicago through Peoria to St. Louis. This is an illustration of the " sloughing off " of a rate ad- justment made under conditions that have become ob- solete, the railroads that once started from the western 82 Railroad Freight Rates bank of the Mississippi River having been absorbed by the lines that formerly terminated at the eastern bank of the river. Many of the through lines thus formed cross not only the Mississippi, but the Missouri River, and extend to Colorado and the farther West. The conflicts between the lines extending from Chicago to the Missouri River were essentially duplicated by conflicts between lines reaching from Chicago to St. Paul. Here the all-rail lines from the East via Chicago to St. Paul were obliged to take cognizance of the rates from the East to St. Paul via the Lakes and Duluth. The rates between these cities from 1870 until along in the next decade underwent frequent change and were finally fixed by specific agreement between the lines in interest at 75 per cent, of the rate from Chicago to Omaha. There was also trouble in the adjustment of the rate from St. Louis to St. Paul. Lines reaching St. Paul by a St. Louis connection only, were in opposition to the lines reaching St. Paul by a Chicago connection, claim- ing that the St. Louis to St. Paul rate should be little if any higher than the Chicago to St. Paul rate. They urged the competition of the Mississippi River between St. Louis and St. Paul in support of this contention. This was opposed by the Chicago lines, but after a long struggle the rate was made 105 per cent, of the rate from Chicago to St. Paul. The development at Kansas City and the growth of traffic between that center and the Twin Cities — the rates to and from St. Paul and Min- neapolis are always the same — introduced another ele- ment into the problem which was disposed of by making the rate between Kansas City and St. Paul 25 cents higher on merchandise of the first class than between Chicago and St. Paul. Other adjustments have been made to points in the interior of this triangle ; for exam- ple, the rate from St. Louis to Des Moines is a percent- age of the rate from St. Louis to St. Paul ; the rate from Chicago to Des Moines is a percentage of the rate from St. Louis to that city ; and the rates from Chicago to in- The Regional Rate Structures 83 terior points in Iowa, sucii as Cedar Rapids, Ottumwa and Marshalltown, are in fixed relation to the rates from Chicago to Des Moines. The rate from Chicago to Sioux Falls is 104 per cent, of the rate to Sioux City, and to Mankato a fixed amount higher than St. Paul. That is, while in the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory the rates are mainly adjusted on a percentage basis, fixed differences being used where the percentage system is not entirely suitable, in the trans-Mississippi territory the rates are mainly adjusted by fixed differ- ences, percentages being applied in a minority of cases where their use is preferable. In either territory a change in a rate between two commercial centers results auto- matically in the changing of many other rates between many other centers. As the traffic developed between the lower Mississippi region and the Missouri River, the rates from Memphis to Kansas City were made 2 cents less than to Omaha, and from Paducah, Columbus, Cairo, and Evansville 2 cents less than from Memphis. The adjustments under the system of fixed differences have resulted in the grouping of stations, just as the adjustment under the percentage system resulted in groups in the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory. The Burlington rate, for example, applies to Davenport, Moline, and other stations in the Burlington group; the St. Louis rate to Alton, and other stations in the St. Louis group; in eastern Kansas and western Missouri the Kansas City rate applies at many stations ; and on many kinds of traffic the Omaha rate applies to Lincoln and intermediate stations. The rates from the commercial centers to the station's beyond the Omaha group in Nebraska, and beyond the Kansas City group in Missouri and Kansas, are in some instances made by adding the local rate from the Mis- souri River to these stations to the rate to the Missouri River; that is, by a combination on the Missouri River. In many cases, and especially to the principal towns, such as Wichita and Wellington in Kansas, the rate from 84 Railroad Freight Rates St. Louis is made a percentage of the combination rate, 95 per cent, perhaps, or, in some cases, as low as 80 per cent, of the combination on Kansas City. The lower percentages usually apply to points to which there is a line from St. Louis that does not pass through Kansas City. Rates are thus made either on the Missouri River combination or a percentage of that combination as far west as Colorado. The far-reaching effect of the rivalry between Chicago and St. Louis is shown by the fact that the rates are the same from these cities to Butte, Helena, Anaconda, and Great Falls, the Montana Common Points. That is, a through rate is common to each of these cities and there- fore is the basis for rates to points beyond. Denver, Colorado Springs, Pueblo, and Trinidad are the Colorado Common Points to and from which the rates on through traffic are the same. This has come about because one system of railroads passes through each of these points from the north to the south, and another passes through each of these points from the south to the north, it therefore being impossible for either line, in competition with the other, to charge a higher rate to one of these points than to another. Denver is the first city of importance in the direct westerly trend in whose commerce the Atlantic coast- wise lines are an important factor. To secure traffic in competition with the direct rail lines by way of Chicago and St. Louis, the coastwise steamers from New York to Savannah, in connection with the railroads leading west from Savannah, established differentials under all-rail rates ranging from 39 cents on merchandise of the first class to 10 cents on that of the fourth class. This dif- ferential was met by the vessels running from the At- lantic seaboard to Galveston in connection with the rail lines from Galveston to Denver, and is still in effect both by way of Savannah and by way of Galveston. Rates to stations beyond the Colorado points are made by adding the local rates from the common points to these stations to the rates to the common points. This The Regional Rate Structures 85 method applies as far as Salt Lake City, to which the rates from the East are affected by the vessel rates from New York to San Francisco. The rates to stations in Wyoming and Montana are so adjusted that they may obtain merchandise from either Denver or Salt Lake City on a parity, so far as rail rates are concerned. The rates from the East to Santa Fe and Albuquerque are determined by the vessel rates to Galveston, plus the rail rates from that port. The rates to the further in- terior stations of New Mexico and eastern Arizona are made by adding the local rates from Albuquerque to the through rates thereto. Throughout the entire region west of the Missouri the railroads have endeavored, by making " jobbers' rates," which apply on merchandise distributed by whole- sale merchants, to permit each distributing center to reach the markets it could fairly expect to reach in rea- sonable competition with another distributing center. The rate structure outlined in this section is that ap- plying in the territory to the west of Chicago and St. Louis, for the greater part on through westbound traf- fic; that is, on the merchandise consisting largely of manufactures of the various kinds that flow from east of the Mississippi River for distribution among the popu- lation in the Mississippi Valley and to its west as far as the Rocky Mountains. The products that flow to the East from this vast territory are principally grain and grain products, livestock, and meat products, wool, lum- ber, and bullion. Each of these great staples of traffic moves under a special freight rate structure that has developed to meet the peculiar requirements arising out of the conditions of its production and distribution. (4) SOUTH OF THE OHIO AND EAST OF THE MISSISSIPPI In the Southeast problems of rate adjustment presented phases still different from those of the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory, or of the trans-Mississippi and trans-Missouri region. The flow of the traffic is neither 86 Railroad Freight Rates predominantly east and west nor north and south, and the competition of water craft affects the making of rail rates at more points than in any other section of the country. From Virginia to Florida the lands that slope from mountain to savanna are washed by the Atlantic Ocean, and the westward continuation of this lowland belt by the Gulf of Mexico. Before the days of the rail- roads there was communication by the Ocean and the Gulf between the North Atlantic cities and Norfolk, Richmond, Wilmington, Charleston, Savannah, Jack- sonville, Pensacola, Mobile, and New Orleans; there was communication by river between the Ocean and Co- lumbia, S. C, Augusta and Macon, Ga. ; between the Gulf and Columbus, Ga., Montgomery and Selma, Ala. A very large proportion of the wearing apparel of the people of this section — the fabrics and the made-up garments, the hats, and shoes ; and nearly all of the smaller manufactures, the more delicate appliances and bits of mechanism — come from the New York and the New England district. The effect of the communication by coastwise vessels between the northern and the south- ern seaports keeps down the rates of the railroads, not only to the ports, but to the interior stations which can be reached by the rivers or by the rail lines extending from the ports toward the interior. The rates are the same to-day via rail and via water from the North Atlantic ports to Norfolk, the rate from New York on freight of the first class being 32 cents per 100 pounds. From New York to Brunswick the all-rail rate is 85 cents, the all-water rate 65 cents ; to Savannah the all-rail rate is 82 cents, all-water rate 55 cents. To Augusta and Columbia the all-rail rate is $1.08, and to Macon $1.14; while the water and rail rates are, to Augusta and Columbia 96 cents, to Macon $1.02. The all-water rate to Mobile and to New Orleans is 70 cents ; the all-rail rate to Mobile 75 cents, to New Orleans 95 cents. To Savannah, Mobile, and New Orleans prac- tically all of the traffic from the North Atlantic seaboard is carried by water. The Regional Rate Structures 87 The railroads are obliged to make approximately the same rates as the water routes to the points having water communication if they desire to carry any of the traffic. To make the same rates to the intermediate stations would be to reduce the revenue from the rail traffic to a water basis, which the railroads cannot by any means afford to do. The rate to an intermediate station is, therefore, in many cases, made by adding the local rate from the water point to that station, even though this make a higher rate than to a water point beyond. That is, the water point is a basing point, and rates to points beyond are made by combining the local rate from, with the water forced rate to, the basing point. An exception to this practice lies in that adjustment of rates which followed the completion of railroads leading from the Central Traffic Territory to Norfolk and to Newport News, harbors through which it was desired to do an export business in grain and grain prod- ucts, meat and meat products from the West. That they might share in this traffic in competition with the ports to the North, these lines made the rates from the West to Newport News and to Norfolk the same as the differential rates from the West accorded by the Trunk Lines to Baltimore. The rates via these lines for local shipment to the interior of Virginia, because of the sparse population and the scant traffic, were so much higher than the low differential rate to Baltimore that their rates from the West to stations far back in Vir- ginia exceeded that rate which they had applied on traffic to their termini. When the Interstate Commerce Law took effect these lines, like their neighbors in the Trunk Line Territory, hastened to observe the strict construction of the long and short haul clause, and, there- fore, to all intermediate points to which the rates from the West had exceeded the rates to their termini, they reduced the rates to a level with those at the termini. This has made the rates from the West the same to Roanoke, Lynchburg, Richmond, Petersburg, and Nor- 88 Railroad Freight Rates folk, which, in the parlance of the traffic officers, are known as the Virginia Cities. Rates from Chicago to points immediately south of the Virginia Cities make by combinations on those cities, while rates from Cincinnati and Louisville are lower than from Chicago by fixed differences; lines from the West that reach these cities over the more southerly and longer routes are obliged to carry traffic at the rates thus made. Basing points also arose through the extension of the early railroads. These, at first, in the Southeast, as else- where, were short local roads, taking the place of the stage and wagon lines in the carrying of traffic between the seaports and the adjoining territory. That they might serve a wider area these local roads were ex- tended ; every here and there a local road extending from one distributing center, would cross a local road extend- ing from another distributing center. Not only the roads, but the respective distributing centers, would compete for the business of the point of intersection and its vicinity. For instance, as the line from Augusta reached Athens, the line from Macon reached Athens, and lines from Richmond and Norfolk, each of these cities and each of these lines would compete for the trade of Athens. Competition would make the rates to Athens, which would, therefore, become a basing point. The rate to a point beyond would be made by combining the competitive rate to Athens with the local rate from Athens to that point. The rate to an intermediate point was also made in this way when the back combination on Athens was less than the normal rate to the inter- mediary point. Yet again, in some cases, as a railroad extended to a town in the proximity of another town served by a com- peting railroad, it has had to make the same rates to it that its competitors have made to the other, in order that its merchants may be placed on a parity with the mer- chants of the other town in supplying merchandise to the consumers in the intervening country. Such com- petition, in many instances, has made a basing point of The Regional Rate Structures 89 such a town, although it may be served by but one rail- road. These factors in the adjustment of rates in the South- east, while unlike, are entirely analogous to similar factors which produce like results in many parts of the North and West, and the rates to and from the basing points of the South facilitate the distribution of merchan- dise just as do the jobbers' rates in the West. Here, as in the West, there is the continual pressure of smaller towns that are not basing points for rates that will en- able them to do a jobbing business. Although it has been severely criticised, this system of basing points could not have developed solely for the benefit of the railroads. The railroads must serve the needs of com- merce; no artifice of man can stem the working of economic law for any considerable time throughout so considerable a territory. It was once universal in the South, and still is customary at many places, that the wholesale dealer allow credit for a long time to the re- tail dealers in his vicinity; that is, that he carry them. If the basing points be abolished and a scale of rates fixed that uniformly increase with distance, the source of supplies will be driven back to the source of production. The retail dealer will no longer be able to keep as great a variety of merchandise on the same capital, and as he will not be able to so promptly replenish his stock, it will no longer be so fresh. The development of the interior portion of the South, the region between the Ohio and Mississippi Rivers and the mountains, naturally was but in its early stages when the seaboard had attained a considerable population. Before railroads were built into this interior region mer- chandise was brought from the East via Pittsburg and the Ohio River, and distributed by means of the wagon routes and the smaller rivers from Cincinnati, Louisville, and other distributing centers that had grown at points of natural advantage. Here, as elsewhere, the first railroads were short local lines, extending from the distributing centers and charging local rates. As they were con- 90 Railroad Freight Rates structed southward their rates were held down by the rates of the boats on the Mississippi River, in much the same manner as were the rates of the lines along the Atlantic Coast by the rates of the coastwise vessels. This affected the rates not only to Memphis, New Or- leans, and Mobile, but to Montgomery and Selma, to which there is navigation by river from the Gulf. Indeed, the rates even from Louisville to Nashville were modi- fied by the Cumberland River, which is navigable from the Ohio to Nashville. The rail rate on merchandise of the first class from Cairo to New Orleans, determined by watef competition, is 75 cents. The competition of the river is now effective only upon such low class freight as coal, cement, brick, and various iron articles southbound; and northbound, on lumber and molasses ; but the potential competition still influences the rate adjustment. The line to New Orleans is paralleled by a line to Mobile, which, to protect the interests of that city, and consequently its own traffic in competition with New Orleans, keeps the rate to Mo- bile the same as the rate to New Orleans. The river- compelled rates are not used for traffic to intermediate stations, but, as in the Southeast, the rates to competitive water points are used as bases for rates to local points beyond, notwithstanding that rates to such local points may be higher than to a farther point having water com- petition. For example, the rate from Cairo to Jackson, Mississippi, is higher than to New Orleans, and rates to intermediate points are fixed in relation thereto. Upon the rate from Cairo to New Orleans the rates from the cities to the north of Cairo are determined by fixed differences, St. Louis being 15 cents higher than Cairo, or 90 cents, and Chicago 20 cents -higher than St. Louis, or $1.10. As the area nearer the mountains attained some de- velopment, particularly after the utilization of the iron and coal deposits, the railroads extended eastward from the Mississippi region and the Ohio Valley, finally through Chattanooga, Knoxville, and Asheville, leading The Regional Rate Structures 91 up to connection with the railroads that penetrate the Southeast. These railroads across the mountains had, from the start, scant traffic, but their connection with the southeastern systems permits them to carry grain and grain products, meat and meat products from the West and Northwest, not only into the Middle South, but into the far Southeast. They also opened channels for the manufactures in the production of which Chicago, St. Louis, Cincinnati, and Louisville were developing. Thereupon ensued complications. Grain and grain prod- ucts, meat and meat products had previously reached the Southeast by way of the North Atlantic seaports and thence by the coastwise transportation via the southern ports. The low Trunk Line rates and the coastwise ves- sel rates made lower through rates to the far Southeast than would be accorded on a normal rail basis across the Ohio River and over the mountains. To take such products to the seaboard these rail rates had to be ad- justed to meet the Trunk Line and coastwise rates to the far Southeast. To the interior, however, normal and, therefore, higher, rates were charged. These lines from the Ohio River were not obliged, under any stress of water competition, to make as low rates upon manufactured articles to this southern in- terior as the coastline railroads from the Northeast were compelled to make by reason of the coastwise competi- tion. The manufacturers and wholesale dealers of Chi- cago, St. Louis, Cincinnati, and Louisville have, however, continually besought the railroads to make the same rates per mile to this territory as are made to it by the lines from the East. The railroads responded by making the same rates in the aggregate from Louisville to Atlanta as are made from Baltimore to Atlanta. The situation is still the cause of bitter contention. Atlanta being the great commercial center of the interior South, is the focal point of rate adjustment from every direction from which traffic reaches this southern interior. The customary era of conflict ended in the rates being made the same to Atlanta from Cincinnati, 92 Railroad Freight Rates Louisville, Evansville, and Cairo. St. Louis is 23 cents, and Chicago 35 cents higher than Cairo, traffic from these cities passing at the same rate through any of the Ohio River crossings. The rate from Memphis is 4 cents less than Cairo, and from New Orleans the same as from Memphis. The rates to and from other cities in this central part of the South are adjusted in relation to the rates to and from Atlanta. (S) TEXAS Even had the Lone Star State formed part of the original Union, it is doubtful whether railroad building within its borders would have proceeded along different lines. The first settlements, naturally, were along the Gulf; of the original ports of entry, two or three were literally blown away, and because of its excellent harbor, Galveston outstripped the others. Merchandise brought by vessel from the East to Galveston was distributed by wagon, and then there was the tendency to shorten the wagon haul by sending the boats up the Bayou to a landing within but a few miles of Houston. The first railroad construction was of the familiar local line leading from the seaport. It took away from the Bayou the traffic in high grade merchandise and car- ried it into the interior from Galveston and from Hous- ton. Traffic was of small volume, and rates necessarily high. For distances of forty or fifty miles the railroad could not charge more than the tolls of stagecoach and wagon, or rates that would preclude the farmer from using the railroads in preference to his own conveyance. The rates from Houston, therefore, were scaled for shorter and rather sharply advanced for longer distances, until was reached the limit that the traffic could pay and find a market. As the railroad was extended the appli- cation of this rate was extended, it thereby becoming the maximum rate charged to any station beyond that to which it first applied. The designation " maximum " is here used in accordance with the Texan usage to indicate The Regional Rate Structures 93 the highest rate charged for a commodity for any dis- tance. Ordinarily a " maximum rate " in railroad no- menclature means the highest rate that can legally be charged between any two places, the railroads being free to charge a lesser rate at their discretion. In Texas the maximum rate for intrastate rate traffic is fixed by the State Railroad Commission as the specific rate that must be charged. As St. Louis progressed as a distributing center, rail- roads were built from that city toward the Southwest. The government decreed that one railroad might be built across Indian Territory from the east to the west and another from north to south. There was a race; the first line to cross the Territory from the north con- nected at Denison with the line that had been extended from Houston, but soon continued its own rails to the southern and southwestern part of the State. Other railroads from St. Louis passed through Missouri and Arkansas into Texas. The merchants of St. Louis de- sired to distribute and these railroads to carry merchan- dise into Texas. The merchandise sold by the St. Louis jobbers, as well as that obtained via the Gulf, came al- most entirely from the East. To enable her merchants to reach the Texan territory it was necessary that the southwestern railroads make rates which, in conjunction with those applying over the Trunk Line from the East, at least approximated the through transportation charge to the Texas interior made by the vessel rate to and the rail rate from the Gulf. Rates from St. Louis to the northeastern corner of Texas were also held down by the sum of the water rates from St. Louis to New Or- gans via the Mississippi, from thence via the Gulf and the Red River, along which steamboats then ran to Shreveport and beyond. In other words, a line from St. Louis could not compete in central or southern Texas at a higher aggregate rate than applied via the Gulf, and a railroad from the Gulf could not compete in central and northern Texas at a higher aggregate rate than applied over the route by way of St. Louis. There was 94 Railroad Freight Rates a period of struggling between the diflferent interests, of rebates, stealthy cutting of rates, and open fighting. The result was, that the lines from St. Louis made the same rate to all stations south of the Texas border. This, of course, was in competitive relation with the maximum rate applying over much of the line leading from the south. As railroads were built and extended, one line would reach station A by passing through station B, and an- other line would reach station B by passing through station A, and so on throughout a ramifying network. The result was the application of the same rates to the stations in the entire area covered by the network of the lines that extended from St. Louis. These various causes worked together to produce what is known as the Texas Common Point Territory, the very considerable area to all stations in which the rate from St. Louis is the same ; to all stations in which the rates from Kansas City, Memphis, Chicago, and other cities in the central territory and in the East are respectively the same, and to all stations in which the intrastate rates of Texas are the same after they have attained the maximum. This situation was found in existence by the Texas State Railway Commission at the time of its inauguration in 1890, and has been developed and modified by that body in a way especially to conserve what it considers to be the interests of the citizens of the State. It was the idea of Judge Reagan, in his time the dominant statesman of Texas, that it would be inimical to the welfare of the State to have its merchandise distrib- uted from one or two great distributing centers. He believed that, as it is by nature an agricultural State and, therefore, of a diflfused population, the needs of that population could be better supplied from a considerable number of small commercial centers so distributed that there would be no large area without such a center within its limits. The adjustment of rates under the Texas Common Point System is eminently adapted to the furtherance of The Regional Rate Structures 95 Judge Reagan's desire. Long distance traffic from any place outside of the State pays the same rate to any place in the Common Point Territory and, therefore, in so far as railroad rates are a factor, any town in this territory is as well qualified to be a jobbing point as any other. As a matter of fact, jobbing centers have arisen every forty or fifty miles, the controlling cause that has led to one town instead of another attaining this dignity frequently being the conjuncture of two or more rail- roads. The point of juncture being both able to obtain and to distribute merchandise over a variety of routes has developed a greater number of mercantile establish- ments which have attracted an increasing population. Such centers are Ft. Worth and Dallas in the northern part of the State, Waco in the center, and San Antonio in the south. A principal mercantile city in the State, however, is Houston, which began to outstrip Galveston as a commercial center when freight was first carried from Galveston via the Bayou. Its use made Houston the city, Galveston the seaport. Houston became the market of concentration for the products of the State, whence they were taken in barge-loads to outside the bar at Galveston and loaded into vessels. The railroads cut the cotton rate in competition with the Bayou, but a charge in all cases was made for the carriage from Houston, in competition with the Bayou, in addition to the rate from the plantation to Houston. Although this rate from Houston has fallen from $3.00 or more per bale to but 30 cents, the tariffs are still constructed on the basis of a separate charge between Galveston and Houston. It is at Houston, therefore, that the gradation that leads to the intrastate maximum rate to the interior begins and where the application of the maximum rate from the interior ends. The building of a railroad from Galveston to the Southwest complicated the situation by the application of the Houston differential to the rates from Galveston along this road. The State court has held, however, that if such traffic does not pass through Houston the differential does not apply. 96 Railroad Freight Rates Not only does the common point rate system put all distributing centers on a parity, in so far as the procuring of merchandise over long distances is concerned, but, through the scaling up of the intrastate rates to a maxi- mum, it practically puts every distributing center, in so far as the distributive rates are concerned, on a parity with every other distributing center. It gives each center the advantage of distribution in the radius of the gradu- ated rates, but in the region beyond, that is, in the region to which the maximum rate applies, each distributing cen- ter is on a parity with every other distributing center. To illustrate. Ft. Worth and San Antonio obtain mer- chandise at the same rate from St. Louis, and San An- tonio and Ft. Worth obtain merchandise at the same rate from Houston. Assuming that the radius of the scaling rates averages two hundred miles, the mer- chants at Ft. Worth naturally command the trade within a radius of two hundred miles of that city, and the mer- chants at San Antonio the trade within a radius of two hundred miles of that city. But at any point farther than two hundred miles from either city, no matter in what part of the common point area it may be, the mer- chants of Ft. Worth and San Antonio compete on a parity, in so far as the freight rate is concerned. It will be perceived that the competitive factors af- fecting the rates on through traffic from the Atlantic seaboard to Texas are very much the same as those af- fecting the rates on through traffic from the Atlantic seaboard throughout the Southeast. In the latter case the railroads extending through Virginia, the Carolinas, and the farther South are not remote from the ocean which they parallel: their rates are held down not only to such distant points as Mobile and New Orleans, but to intermediate points along the coast and in the interior to which there is direct water or rail communication from the coast. This condition accounts for the generally low level of rates and the numerous basing points through which the distribution of merchandise is highly decen- tralized. In the former case it is the rail lines far to the The Regional Rate Structures 97 inland, those by way of Pittsburg or Buffalo or Wheel- ing and St. Louis, that compete for the traffic of Texas with the water lines that ply around the Floridian penin- sula. The high level of rates that originally existed in Texas led to the formation of the Texas common point system, which has also led to the numerous jobbing cen- ters through which the distribution of merchandise is highly decentralized. One point of resemblance to the situation in the Southeast exists in the fact that the rates from the North to Houston and Galveston are lower than to the intermediate Texas points. This exception to the common point system was originally made because of the water rates down the Mississippi River and via the Gulf of Mexico. The original high level of the intrastate rates has been modified, in some cases radically, by the Texas State Commission, which has absolute power over all rates within the State. It has reduced maximum rates on both classes and commodities, and has, in many cases, modified the distance throughout which the rate is scaled before reaching the maximum. This distance, with certain ex- ceptions, is two hundred and forty-five miles on mer- chandise taking the class rates ; one hundred and sixty miles on cotton ; one hundred and forty miles on flour, grain and hay; seven hundred and ninety miles on coal; one hundred and eighty miles on fruits, melons, and vegetables; and so on, through the list of commodities that move in any considerable volume. Where it is necessary that a shipment pass over the lines of two or more railroads a small additional charge is allowed, except that when the common point distance is reached the rates are the same over a single as over two or more lines. The area embraced in the common point territory has changed from time to time, the desire of the rail- roads being to contract it, the pressure of commercial conditions to enlarge it. At present it extends from the Gulf to a line drawn from Amarillo in the Pan Handle of Texas, through Big Springs, San Angelo, Brady, 98 Railroad Freight Rates Llano, San Antonio, Laredo, and Corpus Christi. It in- cludes the population that represents about eighty-five per cent, of the consuming capacity of the State. The maximum rates apply from all points within to the boun- daries of this area. To points in the narrow belt lying beyond these boundaries the rates are made by adding rates that increase with distance, to the maximum rates. Of recent years the growth of the cities in the Missis- sippi and Ohio Valleys and their progress in various lines of manufacture has led to their supplying Texas with an increasing proportion of its manufactured articles. The rates from the various cities have been placed at certain fixed differences above or below the rates from St. Louis. The rate from Kansas City is the same as from St. Louis; from Louisville 11 cents higher; from Cincinnati and Chicago 20 cents higher; from Detroit and Cleveland 40 cents higher, and from Pittsburg 50 cents higher : the rates from Memphis and New Orleans are each 10 cents lower than from St. Louis. It will be perceived that the application of the same rates on interstate traffic to and from all places in the Texas common point area creates a situation resembling that under which the railroads serving New England make the same rates on raw material to all places, and the same rates on manufactured products from all places in that section. In this case the railroads are forced to the sacrifice entailed by extending the application of a low rate over a considerable area by the necessity for supporting the New England industries. There is no corresponding pressure upon the railroads of Texas and their traffic, as yet, is but scant in comparison with that of New England. Moreover, the local rates of New England bear no analogy to the intrastate rates of Texas, which are no longer at the level which led to the adoption of the intrastate maximum rates. The increase in the traffic into the State from the North is leading to doubt whether the railroads are justified in the continuance of the common point sys- tem. It is argued that the equalization of a distant dis- The Regional Rate Structures 99 tributing point with a nearer distributing point in the rates on inbound traffic works an injustice both to the railroads and to the nearer distributing point; that the equahzation at the distributing points, in any event, is obtained at the expense of the railroads, which are no longer forced, by economic stress, to maintain such equalization. It is argued that the development of the industries and commerce of the Middle West, and the increasing population of Texas, justifies the railroads in making lower rates to the cities at the northern border than to those in the interior of the State, and lower rates to the interior points than to those in the south, and that, therefore, there should be some arrangement that will permit the roads from Chicago and St. Louis to have the traffic destined to the northern part of the State and the roads from the Gulf to have that destined to the southern part of the State. A tendency in this direction is already manifest by the establishment of rates on grain that apply in fifteen groups throughout the State. The difference in the rate from Kansas City is so slight that San Antonio, three hundred miles further south, pays but three cents per 100 pounds more for flour or grain than Ft. Worth. Grain, however, comes into the State only from the North, The lumber rates are also adjusted to apply to groups that range from the East to the West, the Texas lumber largely coming from Louisiana mills. The breaking up of the common point system would doubtless be vigorously resisted by the distributing cen- ters which are farthest from the sources of supply, and doubtless, also, by the Texas Railroad Commission, in that, by causing a redistribution of the wholesale trade of the State, the various distributing centers would no longer be on an equality. That excessive degree of decentralization of distribu- tion, however, which prevents any distributing center from attaining marked growth, rather restricts such small distributing centers as exist to dealing in the more staple merchandise. This tendency is conspicuously manifest in loo Railroad Freight Rates Texas, no one of the towns being a market adequate to carrying the finer manufactures and higher grades of miscellaneous products. The Texas Railroad Commission vigorously upholds the interests of the Texas jobbers and uses its power over the freight rates of the State to that end. For exaijiple, because of the restricted markets, neither dry goods, hats and caps, boots and shoes, nor carpets are purchased in carload lots by any wholesale merchant of Texas, ex- cept, perhaps, by a firm or two in the very largest cities. The jobbers, however, persuaded the Commission to make a carload rate of 49 cents, which was 38 cents lower than the less than carload rate. By combining their shipments at New York the jobbers use this carload rate from Galveston, thereby obtaining a through rate 38 cents lower than by paying the 87-cent rate, which properly applies to what, in reality, are their less than carload shipments. Another example is offered by an occurrence of a year or two ago, when the railroads in the Central West found that because of the exceptionally low rates prevailing from the eastern seaboard by water to Gal- veston on wire and nails, the manufacturers of the eastern cities had an advantage over the manufacturers of the Central West. The rail lines from Ohio, Indiana, and Illinois and St. Louis, to retain a portion of this traffic, reduced the wire-nail rates from 55 cents to 43 cents — that is, 12 cents — per 100 pounds. The Texas Commission thereupon immediately reduced the intrastate rates 12 cents per 100 pounds. The railroads were, there- upon, confronted with the identical situation that had faced them before. They pointed out the situation to the steamship lines, who agreed to make an advance in the rates from the East to Galveston that would permit the restoration of the rail rates previously in effect. This was done, and the Commission requested to restore the intrastate rates to the former basis. The Commission, however, said that the rate as reduced gave the rail- roads sufficient compensation for handling the wire and nail traffic, and refused to make the restoration, the re- The Regional Rate Structures loi suit being that the especially reduced rates on wire and nails continue in effect. Some years ago, prior to the passage of the Elkins Law, the steamship lines were asked for a lower rate on canned goods by canneries of the East, who produced the greater portion of that merchandise used in Texas. Upon being refused a concession in the rates, these Eastern canneries chartered schooners to handle the canned-goods traffic, the rates via schooner to Galveston, and from Galveston by rail, aggregating less than the rates from the canneries of Illinois, Indiana, and Ohio. The railroads engaged in the traffic from this region im- mediately reduced their rates to permit these establish- ments to continue to market their goods in Texas, When the attention of the Commission was called by Texas local shippers to the reductions from the Central West, it established an intrastate rate of 3 cents per 100 pounds as a maximum on canned goods. This aggregated a revenue of $6 per car of 20,000 pounds on canned goods between any two points in the State, even although the movement be over two or three, or more railroads, and for a distance of from 400 to 600 miles. These reductions were made under an Emergency Act whereby the Texas Railroad Commission is empowered to set aside any local rates in the State, and to substitute emergency rates at its discretion, without giving the railroads a hearing or any reasons for their action. The result is that the railroads often do not make temporary concessions for the benefit of particular movements of traffic, in the fear that the temporary basis will be used by the Commission as a standard for the permanent ad- justment of local rates. That is, if an interstate rate should be so reduced as to give the shipper of another State an advantage in reaching the Texas markets, the Commission would reduce the intrastate rate to a point that would offset that advantage and restore it to the dealer in Texas. When various increases in the inter- state rates from the Middle States were made effective August 10, 1908, the Commission considered offsetting 102 Railroad Freight Rates them by reductions in intrastate rates. One commissioner favored such action, but the other two, restrained only by the fear of a federal injunction, voted against it. In other words, it is the avowed policy of the Railroad Commission of Texas to so adjust the freight rates of the State that the citizens of the State to the greatest possible extent shall be the beneficiaries of its commerce. In short, it uses the intrastate rates of Texas as a protective tariff in the interest of its shippers, and it has so used them at times in apparent disregard of the effect upon the revenue of the railroads. It states that the local graduated rates are so high that the railroads can afford to apply the maximum rate to the innumerable stations in the thousands of square miles included in the common point area. The Texas Railroad Commission, when it holds a hear- ing, sits as a court before which witnesses appear for and against the railroads. Unlike a court, however, their testimony is not taken or made a matter of record by the Commission, that body rendering its decision as the evidence or other considerations may have affected their minds at the time of hearing. (6) THE PACIFIC COAST AND THE TRANS-CONTINENTAL TRAFFIC That portion of the United States which lies between the Rocky Mountains and the Pacific Ocean, in its cen- tral and southern reaches produces both citrus and de- ciduous fruits, nuts and raisins, prunes and figs, melons and vegetables. Deciduous fruits are also grown in the northern sections of California, in Oregon and Wash- ington, as are wheat and other grains in large quantities. Formerly wheat from California was exported to Europe, sometimes to the extent of one miUion tons in one year. Lately, however, the production of wheat in this State has only exceeded its increasing consumption by a sur- plus which is exported to Central and South America, and to the Orient. Oregon and Washington produce not The Regional Rate Structures 103 only large quantities of fine deciduous fruits, but wheat, which is principally converted into flour and exported to the Orient, although more or less of the 'grain is for- warded direct from North Pacific Coast ports to Europe. The timber of California, Oregon, Washington, Idaho, and even western Montana, is unexcelled in quality and would seem to be almost inexhaustible. Large deposits of petroleum oil have been found in California, com- pensating in large measure for the lack of coal. This oil is used for fuel, and a considerable quantity is re- fined, which, in part, is exported to the Orient. Hops, wool, hides, and leather are all produced in these States for market in the Eastern States and in Europe. Cali- fornia was one of the first, if not the first State, to suc- cessfully produce sugar from the beet, and there are now large beet-sugar refineries in the southern and central parts of the State, whence hundreds of thousands of tons are annually shipped to the territory east of the Rocky Mountains. California also refines and ships to the east cane sugar from the Hawaiian Islands. The wine-mak- ing industry of this State produces large tonnage, the wines being marketed throughout the United States and even in Europe. Aside from these products, the Pacific States do not produce very many of the things needed to satisfy the ma- terial wants of its population. Of the articles usually in- cluded in the terms " general merchandise " and " manu- factures," such as clothing, furniture, tools, and mechani- cal appliances in general, machinery and implements, per- haps 75 per cent, or more are supplied by the States lying east of the Missouri River. Before the completion of the Pacific railroads these supplies were received almost wholly from the territory lying east of Pittsburg and Buffalo, but since then the sources of supplies have been drifting westward, and to-day perhaps 75 per cent, of the goods that used to be supplied by the territory east of the Alleghany Mountains is now supplied from the terri- tory lying between that range of mountains and the Mis- souri River. Dressed meats and some grains are obtained 104 Railroad Freight Rates from the Missouri Valley, as well as a very large propor- tion of the dressed poultry-and of the butter, eggs, and cheese. The problem of the railroads serving the Pacific Coast is, therefore, to provide that adjustment of outbound rates which will stimulate the consumption of her prod- ucts, and of inbound rates that will bring to her people the commodities which they require without undue en- hancement of the price. To the former end the rates of the railroads on the products of the soil are kept at a low level by the fact that they are in competition in every market at one time or another with products of the soil of other sections, and by the fact that at no time in any market can a price be obtained for them that will enable the railroads to charge a high rate and yet yield sufficient return for the growers to encourage them to continue in production. To the latter end the railroads have been forced to make low rates because of the com- petition of the vessel lines from the Atlantic seaboard. The water competition, which forces low rates on the merchandise brought from the East, had its roots in the service of the clipper ships which supplied the wants of the straggling settlers before there were railroads on the Pacific slope. These ships sailed from New York around Cape Horn to San Francisco, — the pioneers taking their cloth, bacon, axes, and saws by the water- ways as far as possible, thence by wagon to the far interior. Thus the fact that Sacramento, on the Sacra- mento River, was the nearest, or otherwise most favor- able point of distribution to the mining regions which, at that time, constituted the most populous section of the State, accounts for the first railroad in California being built toward the interior from that city, instead of from a seaport. This first railroad, completed in 1856, ran from Sacramento to Folsom, in the direction of the gold fields. The next railroad, which was opened early in 1869, extended from the port of San Pedro to what was then the adobe village of Los Angeles. Long before the road from San Pedro was constructed, however, men The Regional Rate Structures 105 of enterprise had pondered over an all-rail route to con- nect California with the East. The first through trans- continental line was completed on May 10, 1869, and immediately entered into competition with the vessel routes for the traffic between the Atlantic and the Pacific Coasts. The rate per 100 pounds on first class merchandise from New York to San Francisco was, at first, $8.00, but was very soon reduced to $6.00. In entering the field of transportation these so-called transcontinental lines and their connections encountered the competition of sailing vessels following the route via Cape Horn, and of the long-established steamship and rail line by way of the Isthmus of Panama, the former consuming an average of 120 days, and the latter from 26 to 45 days in performing the service from New York to San Fran- cisco. The means of transportation available previous to the completion of the Pacific roads concentrated the merchandise business into the hands of a few firms with large capital, because it was necessary that large stocks be carried to San Francisco and large stocks kept on the sea. The California jobbers who bought their goods in the East were termed importers. The completion of the Pacific Coast roads thus found the business of the importer in few and very strong hands. It did not take long to demonstrate that whatever rates were made for the transportation by the all-rail routes, the rates by sea, owing to the much lower cost of the service, could be and were made very much less. It naturally became the practice of the importing merchant to divide his bus- iness*between the three available routes — via Cape Horn, via Panama, and all-rail. He was relieved, to an extent, from the necessity of carrying large stocks. That relief was not welcomed, because of the opportunity afforded the small merchant, who, by the use of the railroad, could carry adequate stocks on smaller capital. In di- viding his business, the importing merchant would obtain the goods peculiarly needed for a particular season, and such goods as were necessary to promptly replenish his io6 Railroad Freight Rates stocks, by rail. These, however, did not amount to more than 20 per cent, or 25 per cent, of his total importation. Another 25 per cent, he would obtain by the next shortest route, that via Panama, but his staple goods, his large tonnage, aggregating at least 50 per cent, of his total receipts, he continued to obtain via Cape Horn. The rail carriers could not overcome this practice by open tariffs. Whenever the railroads reduced their rates the steamship lines and the clipper ships reduced theirs, so that there still remained the inducement of the im- porter to divide his tonnage, obtaining the largest share by sailing vessel. He believed that his interests com- pelled him to continue this practice, because the railroad rates were the same to all shippers, while there was considerable discrimination in the rates by sea. To over- come these conditions the Pacific railroads finally hit upon what is known as the Contract Plan. They solic- ited the total business of these large importing merchants at San Francisco, and, in consideration of a contract whereunder they agreed to obtain their goods exclusively by rail, guaranteed rates which were supposed to ap- proximate the merchant's average transportation charge by using all three routes. This arrangement was the be- ginning of a large movement by rail. It was found to be objectionable in many respects and did not continue very long, but it did furnish the foundation for all of the tariffs which have since been constructed to apply to the transportation by rail of freight from New York to San Francisco and other Pacific Coast terminals. Competition of the clipper ships around the Horn ceased some years ago, but competition of the- steam- ship lines by way of Panama, and by Tehuantepec, is still active and potent. Vessels of this service not only carry merchandise from the Atlantic Coast, but solicit shipments from the interior, making through rates low enough to favor the use of these vessel-routes as against the all-rail lines, after allowing for the cost of carriage from the interior point to the ship's side at the Atlantic port. The Regional Rate Structures 107 The railroads at one time discussed making the all-rail rates from the stations interior to the Atlantic seaboard, and in the Middle States to the Pacific Coast, by adding the local rate from such a station to the Atlantic port to the vessel rate from that port. Under this plan the rates to the Pacific Coast would have gradually risen from the Atlantic seaboard to that point in the interior from which the normal rail-rate to the Pacific Coast would be equal to the rail-rate to the Atlantic, plus the vessel-rate thence to the Pacific Coast. The interior points thus paying higher rates than the Atlantic ports would have been handicapped in competition with those ports for the trade of the Pacific Coast; the rate, for example, from Chicago to San Francisco, would have been higher than the rate from New York. These in- terior cities and the railroads taking Western traffic therefrom would not tolerate such an adjustment. The vessel-forced rates from the Atlantic Coast were there- fore " blanketed back " to those points, whence the rates under the normal rail adjustment were no higher. Un- der this arrangement, which is now in effect, the rate from New York, speaking generally, applies from every point between that city and Chicago. That is, on trans- continental traffic there is between these limits a rate plateau which descends from Chicago westward. To the foodstuffs from the Missouri Valley rates are applied that permit them to be sold in the markets of the Pacific slope. As different railroads have reached from the East via different routes to the various harbors on the Pacific Coast, the competition of one railroad with another and of one harbor with another has compelled the making of the same rates to the different terminals that have water communication. Therefore, in so far as the trans- portation charge on merchandise from the East is con- cerned, San Diego, Los Angeles, San Francisco, Port- land, Seattle and Vancouver are on a parity. In no case is the ratio of the transportation charge to the price of the consumer's unit materially greater than it is at io8 Railroad Freight Rates the Missouri River. That is, for example, although the rate on merchandise of the first class from Boston and New York is more than twice as much to San Francisco as to Kansas City — being $3 in the one case and $1.48 in the other — the difference in the case of drygoods amounts to but a fraction of a cent a yard. On the heavier commodities, such as machinery and wooden- ware, which largely come from the Ohio and Missis- sippi valleys, the transportation charge bears a somewhat higher ratio, but it very seldom, if ever, will justify more than an insignificant addition to the retail price of any commodity. These terminal rates, in the days prior to the time when the railroads had attained their present efiSciency, were also made applicable to, and still apply to, the cities having direct water communication with the coast, such as San Jose, Stockton, Sacramento and Marysville. Such cities had become centers of dis- tribution for the surrounding territory, before the Pacific Railroads were constructed, receiving their sup- plies by water. The local rates upon which merchandise is dis- tributed throughout the interior of California are also affected by the waterways. The rail rates from the coast to Stockton, to Sacramento, and to Marysville are less than the rail rates made on the basis that applies throughout the State in general, because of the boat lines on the rivers that are navigable to these points ; while the rates to stations beyond are made by adding the local rates from these stations to the competitive rates thereto, or sometimes upon a lower scale. Rates for the north and southbound traffic along the Pacific Coast are made in like manner. The steamboats between Portland and San Francisco, between San Fran- cisco, Santa Barbara, San Pedro and San Diego, keep down the rail rates between those cities, while the rates to intermediate stations are the lowest that can be ob- tained by adding the local rate from one or from another point. That is, rates between the Pacific Coast ports, The Regional Rate Structures 109 and throughout the valley that lies between the mountains and the Pacific Ocean, are made in the same manner as the rates from the cities of the North Atlantic sea- board to the ports and to the river towns in the South- east that are upon or adjacent to the Atlantic Coast and the Gulf of Mexico ; and in the same way that rates are made over the railroads that lead, in com- petition with the Mississippi River, from Chicago, St. Louis and Louisville into the South. Were it not for the products of the soil the railroads connecting California with the East would have little eastbound traffic. Were it not for the general consump- tion of those who grow, and in one way or another are dependent on, this produce, these railroads would not carry much traffic from the East. It is therefore to the interest of the railroads to co-operate with the farmers in extending the cultivation of the farms, the orchards and the groves, and, consequently, in extend- ing their markets. To do this it is necessary that the railroads leading from California obtain the partici- pation of practically all the railroads of the United States in the through rates that are necessary to market the Californian products. Their traffic managers are in continual communication with the traffic managers of the other railroads to this end. This is, of course, in order that their lines may secure an increasing traffic, but it is also an inestimable benefit to the Californian pro- ducers. The result is that their oranges, lemons, peaches, pears, plums, grapes, apples, celery, cabbage, cauliflower, potatoes, raisins, prunes, figs, English walnuts, dried fruits and canned fruits, olives and wines, find markets from Denver to Boston and Montreal, and from St. Paul to New Orleans. The rate on oranges is $1.15 per 100 pounds from the Californian packing houses to every place east of Denver, as far as the remotest corner of New England. The rate on lemons has been made 15 cents per 100 pounds lower than on oranges to aid the industry in its rivalry with the lemons of Sicily. During about one half of the season no Railroad Freight Rates refrigeration is necessary, which adds from $50 to $110 a car to the transportation charge. To be more ex- pHcit, the unit of transportation is the box, which weighs 72 pounds and contains on toe average twelve dozen oranges. During a period of normal production and prices the average cost delivered in New York was $2.72 per box, the freight and the refrigeration costing about 95 cents, or 8 cents a dozen. The other expenses of mar- keting and the picking and packing in California ran from 50 cents to 60 cents a box, leaving about 10 cents a dozen to the grower. This is approximate and there- fore but an indication. The prices in the East and the return to the grower fluctuate within a considerable range, and the number of oranges in a box varies. The vegetables of California move by the carload, with a minimum of 20,000 pounds, at a rate of $1 per 100 pounds to Chicago, $1.15 to Buffalo and Pittsburg, and $1.25 to New York. There is also an icing charge of $55 a car to the Missouri River, which approximates 23 cents per 100 pounds ; and $67.50 to New York, which approximates 25 cents per 100 pounds. On deciduous fruits, which come mostly from the central and the northern parts of California, and from Oregon and Washington, the rate to all points between Colorado and Chicago by the carload, with a minimum load of 24,000 pounds, is $1.25 per loo pounds. The rate to Cincinnati and Pittsburg is $1.40 and to New York and Boston $1.45. There is, in addition, a re- frigeration charge. This is $70 per car from Sacra- mento; and from Portland, Oregon, where ice is more readily obtained, but $45 per car to Chicago, and in proportion to other markets. The wide fluctuation in the prices obtained for fruits of the various kinds and grades at different times and places precludes any definite statement as to the return to the grower. The current statements as to the enor- mous profits per acre would indicate that the transporta- tion charge is a negligible factor either with the con- sumer or the producer. The Regional Rate Structures iii In 1908 grapes that paid the railroads, all told, about $400 a car, brought from $1,200 to $1,900 a car in the Eastern markets; the grower of cherries received an average of perhaps 8 cents a pound. In this year, however, because of the abundant crops elsewhere, peaches brought only $20 a ton at the orchard, although they had brought $70 a ton during the previous year. A box of pears, selling in New York for $3.20 for the 42 pounds, yielded the grower about $2.20, out of which he had to pay for the picking and the packing. Apples net $500, strawberries $800, vegetables $300 and up- wards an acre. The extent of California is comparable to a reach from Savannah to within a few miles of Boston, and its soil produces as varied products. On Mt. Whitney is eternal snow, while oranges and lemons are ripening in the Riverside region, strawberries and raspberries in the low- lands, and vegetables and deciduous fruits farther north. The production of deciduous fruits in Oregon and Washington is not as large as that of California, with the exception, perhaps, of apples, which are firmer in texture and juicier. Owners of apple orchards in these States have refused $1,200 and even $1,600 an acre for their fruit bearing lands. The halibut and salmon fisheries are also a source of great revenue to these States. The rate on canned salmon and halibut is the same as the rate on canned fruits and vegetables, 85 cents per 100 pounds from the Pacific Coast to any place in the United States east of the Missouri River. This rate, although nominally lower, is really more remunerative to the railroads than the rate on the ripe fruits. A car can be filled with canned goods from top to bottom and from one end to the other, the load aggre- gating more than 40,000 pounds. A car cannot be thus filled with citrus fruits, the heaviest load not exceeding 26,700 pounds with safety, and, in addition, during the period of refrigeration, it carries 8,000 pounds of ice, for the transportation of which the railroad makes no 112 Railroad Freight Rates charge. Moreover, the refrigerator car needed for the fruit weighs 8,000 pounds or so more than the box car which is adequate for canned goods ; and canned goods can be moved on regular trains under a normal schedule, while citrus fruits are forwarded on special trains at accelerated speed. That commodity which at this time is of the greatest importance to the far Northwest is the output of the forests, about two-thirds of the total value of the prod- ucts of the State of Washington being composed of lumber in one or another of its forms. When the newly built railroads into this region were seeking re- turn loads for the cars bringing rherchandise from the East, they made a rate of 40 cents per 100 pounds on lumber from the Northwestern forests to St. Paul. Under the stimulus of this low rate markets for the lumber were found in the Missouri Valley, even in the farther East for the choicer woods, and the industry developed until in 1907 it employed, in the State of Washington, 101,000 men, who received $70,000,000 in wages. In the dozen or more of years following the inauguration of the low rates, the development of the fisheries and the orchards and of other traffic in general made it not so imperative for the railroads to secure return loads of lumber. The markets had been estab- lished and lumber had so greatly advanced in price that it seemed to them justifiable that the rate should be advanced. It was endeavored to increase the rate to St. Paul from 40 to 50 cents, and to Omaha from 50 to 62^ cents. This was vigorously resisted by the lumber- men, who brought action before the Interstate Commerce Commission, which practically restored the old rates. The matter was then taken to the courts by the railroads, who claim that they are entitled to adequate com- pensation for transporting the lumber, especially in view of the fact that the advance in lumber prices is rapidly enhancing the fortunes of the lumbermen. These gentlemen held that while there is a secure market for their finer grades, the knotty interiors of the logs, which The Regional Rate Structures 113 could be used for various staple purposes, had to be thrown away, as they cannot be marketed in competition with similar lumber from the South, which has an advantage of 40 cents or more a thousand feet in the cost of production, and an advantage of about $9 a thousand in the freight rate. The lumbermen state that because of this inability to market the inferior grades, over 53,000 carloads, to the value of over $15,000,000, were destroyed in one year. The railroads reiterate that they are entitled to fair remuneration for the lumber haul, and intimate that if the lumbermen were not so zealous in pushing their finer grades at this time they would, in but a few years, as the country places more and more reliance upon the Northwestern forests, be enabled to market not only the superior but the inferior grades at prices still further enhanced. This contention not only affects the carriage of lumber from the far Northwest to the Missouri and Mississippi Val- leys, but its transportation from the Willamette Valley of Oregon to the markets of California. Here the rail- roads increased a long standing rate of $3.10 a ton to $5, which was reduced by the Interstate Commerce Commission to $3.40, whereupon the railroads took the matter into the courts. INTER-REGIONAL TRAFFIC The boundaries of the regions, for which the rate structures described in the foregoing pages were de- veloped, are indicated by no artificial lines. The cities that are the leading industrial and commercial centers of the United States to-day, with but two or three ex- ceptions, were the chief commercial centers before the days of the railroads, principally because of their water comrnunication. It was for the benefit of the railroads to seek to share in the rnovement of the commerce of these cities, and for the benefit of these cities that they should have railroad communication. Therefore, as we have learned. New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore 114 Railroad Freight Rates on the east, and Buffalo and Pittsburg on the west, became the termini of the Trunk Lines. Merchandise changed ownership at these termini. When the Trunk Lines gained access to Chicago and St. Louis the merchandise brought from the East changed owner- ship therein before distribution in the territory beyond, and commodities from the West almost invariably changed ownership here before further consignment to the East. The line of division between the Trunk Line — Central Traffic Territory — and the trans-Mississippi- trans-Missouri region was therefore due to the location of Chicago and St. Louis, which in turn was due to their advantageous sites, which naturally made them the first and the most important gateways between the two regions. The trans-Missouri region, representing the broad end of the fan, was naturally limited by the Rocky Mountains. The Pacific slope, by reason of its natural boundaries and peculiar characteristics, became a well- defined region. For reasons similar to those which made Chicago and St. Louis gateways between the East and the West, Cincinnati, Louisville, Memphis and New Orleans be- came gateways between the Southeast and the Central Traffic Territory on the north and the trans-Mississippi territory on the west. The railroads of the respective regions terminated at these gateways, and nearly all of the merchandise consigned from or to the Southeast changed ownership therein. It was therefore entirely logical that a freight rate structure should develop within the limits of each region, and be moulded by the characteristics of its commerce. As with the growth of commerce shipments were forwarded from a point in one to a point in another region, the rate for the through shipment was made by adding the rate from the place of consignment to the regional gateway, to the rate from that gateway to the place of destination. The next step was the making of inter-regional rates from a competitive point in one region, the same via different gateways to a competitive point in another region. The Regional Rate Structures 115 The rates for the distributive flow of the merchandise of the higher classes from the East and from the Cen- tral Traffic Territory into the Southeast, and into the trans-Mississippi and trans-Missouri regions, are still largely made by combinations on the regional gate- ways, although the ownership of the merchandise does not in these days change in nearly so large a proportion at those gateways. Kansas City and Denver, for example, as well as Atlanta and Birmingham, buy directly from either Chicago or New York. In the reverse channels of traffic, those in which the grains and grain products, meats and meat products of the West, and the fruits and vegetables of the South, flow from one into another region, the rates are also still frequently made by combinations on the regional gate- ways. To an increasing degree, however, inter-regional shipments of such commodities do not change owner- ship between the place of concentration in one region and the place of destination in another. The tendency in the adjustment of such rates is, therefore, to take less account of the regional boundaries and to be governed in greater degree by the conditions existing at various markets throughout the country, or throughout the world, the competitive relations between those markets, and the transportation agencies leading thereto. This tendency has been enhanced by the increasing number of railroad companies that have established through lines, either under direct ownership or immediate con- trol, between one region and another, and the multipli- cation in the number of gateways as these through lines have crossed the regional boundaries at different points. Inter-regional rates, in common with long distance rates in general, are, as a rule, lower than the sums of the separate rates applying between intermediate points along the through line formed by the various railroads. The division of such a rate between the different lines, therefore, gives to each line less than it obtains on a shipment originating at the point at which it receives the long distance shipment and consigned to the point ii6 Railroad Freight Rates at which the long distance shipment leaves its line. That is, the " proportion " accruing to a railroad on a long distance through rate is, as a rule, less than its regular rate between the receiving and the delivering point. To facilitate the making of such through rates many rail- road companies publish from their junctional points " proportional " rates, which are simply the pro- portions they receive on through traffic. For ex- ample, the lines leading east from St. Paul and Minneapolis publish a proportional rate from those cities on bullion, although no bullion originates at either of them. This proportional rate is used by the lines west of St. Paul and Minneapolis in making through rates on bullion to the East in competition with the Eastern routes via Omaha or Kansas City. The most conspicuous example of an inter-regional rate adjustment is that arising out of the needs of the transcontinental traffic in either direction between California and the East; this has been sufficiently de- scribed. Other inter- regional adjustments are those affecting the staple foodstuffs and the staple raw ma- terials of manufacture. These will now be briefly considered. CHAPTER VIII COMMODITY RATE STRUCTURES A COMMODITY rate is applicable to a particular com- modity, thereby being distinguished from a class rate which is applicable to any of the many articles that are grouped in the same class. Commodity rates are usually specified for each of the great staple materials, which move in large quantities under conditions peculiar to themselves. There are many of these commodities. In this chapter will be indicated the conditions that have affected the rates applying on a few of the more im- portant. (l) GRAIN AND GRAIN PRODUCTS Wheat is the accepted type of the grains, and flour of the grain products. The rate structure which has de- veloped to meet their needs is similar to that which char- acterizes corn and cornmeal, oats and oatmeal, and the other grains and their products. As the population east of the Alleghany Mountains began to draw upon the Ohio Valley for part of its grain supply, Detroit, Toledo, and Cleveland became places of concentration for that which was sent east by way of Lake Erie and the Erie Canal. The competition between this water route and the various rail routes was stead- ied by the adoption of the Trunk Line Percentage Sys- tem. With the increase in the production of grain to the west of Chicago, radical competition broke out be- tween the boats running from the Lake Michigan ports to Buffalo, and the all-rail lines. The rates of the lake vessels were subject to wild fluctuation, the necessity for a boat to obtain a cargo determining its charge for carry- ing such grain as was ready for shipment. To meet this competition the rates of the railroads also underwent rapid and radical changes during the season of naviga- 117 ii8 Railroad Freight Rates tion, causing losses which they tried to recoup by ad- vances during the winter when the waterways were closed. Although this rivalry between the water route and the rail routes for the carriage of grain to the East has continued to this time, there has been such a progressive decrease in the margin between the rates of the boats and those of the railroads that there is no longer such violent oscillation. \ The establishment of fast trains to move flour in train loads from the great mills of the Northwest to the seaboard is relieving the mills of the necessity for keeping vast quantities of flour in storage at Chicago for future shipment to the great eastern markets. These trains are run on quick time to a cen- tral point, such as Bufifalo, whence the cars radiate to their destinations. The millers prefer to pay 2 cents per 100 pounds higher than the lake charge for this special service, and they are also led to give their traffic to these fast trains in summer in order that the service may be continuous, thus assuring a supply of cars in the winter. When the grain from the western fields so exceeded the requirements of the United States that it was feas- ible to dispose of the surplus in Europe, another factor entered into the old time rivalry between the ports of Boston, New York, Philadelphia and Baltimore, and the respective lines serving them. Each city strove to handle and each railroad to carry an increasing proportion of the export grain. This was a foremost element in the rate wars that began in the early seventies. After various attempts at settlement, adjustment under the auspices of the Trunk Line Association decreed in 1877 that the rate on grain from the West should be the same to Bos- ton and New York, 2 cents less than New York to Philadelphia, and 3 cents less than New York to Balti- more. The shorter distance from Boston to Liverpool was held to offset the longer rail haul, and therefore to justify Boston being placed on a parity with New York; the lower rates were accorded to Philadelphia and Bal- timore because of their shorter distance by rail from Commodity Rate Structures 119 the West and their irregular and less efficient vessel service. The general intention was that the through rate via rail and steamship should be the same from the in- terior to Liverpool through either of the competing ports. The basis on which the differentials were awarded hav- ing been questioned the matter was referred in 1882 to a Board constituted of Allen G. Thurman, Elihu B. Washburn and Thomas M. Cooley, who decided that the competitive relations between the cities were justly to be regarded as the principal factors in determining the differentials, and that the differentials then in effect were fair under the conditions then existing. These differentials, fixed in 1877, never satisfactory to Bos- ton and not entirely so to the other cities, were reduced one-half in 1899. At a later date the matter was brought before the Interstate Commerce Commission and that body, in the capacity of an arbitrator, finally decreed in 1905 that this adjustment should stand; that is, that the rate to Philadelphia should be one cent and to Baltimore one and one-half cents less than to New York. This applies to grain moving entirely by rail. On that which has come by lake to Buffalo the export rate to Baltimore and Philadelphia is six-tenths of a cent less than to New York and Boston. This decision is still unsatisfactory to Boston. That city holds that while the basis of the original award was to secure an equal through rate from the western primary markets through each of the various ports to Liverpool, the lowering in recent years of the ocean rates from Philadelphia and Baltimore practically establishes a lesser rate to Liverpool through these ports, and that, therefore, the exports of grain and grain prod- ucts through Boston are decreasing, notwithstanding her better steamship facilities, while the exports through Baltimore are increasing. The all-rail rate upon wheat from Chicago to New York per 100 pounds, that had fluctuated between 50 cents and $1.60 from 1864 to 1867, was 25 cents in 1882, and has ranged around 16 cents in recent years. At this writing it is 13 cents. 120 Railroad Freight Rates The extension of the grain culture from the upper Mississippi Valley throughout the West naturally gave rise to rate problems in that region that had to be fought to a solution. The railroads leading into Mil- waukee and into Chicago brought grain into those cities at local rates. As the first railroads from upper Wis- consin led through Milwaukee into Chicago, the rate was naturally lower to Milwaukee than to Chicago, and Milwaukee became the first great primary grain market of the West. The development of Chicago as a railroad center attracted a greater number of boats, because of the opportunity for the exchange of traffic with the rail lines, and pressure was brought to bear upon the rail- roads to make the grain rate the same to Chicago as to Milwaukee. This Milwaukee resisted, but as railroads were built from the grain fields to Chicago without pass- ing through Milwaukee, it became imperative that the rate via these lines to Chicago be no higher than that to Milwaukee; for, otherwise, the lines reaching Mil- waukee at a lesser rate would have a vital advantage. As the growing of grain pursued its way through Wisconsin into Minnesota, Duluth became the nearest lake port to a portion of the grain region. The en- deavor of the railroads leading toward that city to in- crease their traffic created competition between them and the lines serving the ports on Lake Michigan. Wheat was handled through Duluth at 2^ cents less per loo pounds than through Chicago: this made the Zenith City the great grain port of the Lakes. In those days there was not enough business from the West to fill the cars that had taken merchandise from the East. Competition focused upon the grain and especially upon wheat, the great staple. There were attempts to ap- portion the traffic between the diflferent lines, but each of these pools had only a short existence. A difference of opinion between the lines leading from MinneapoUs to Chicago as to the division of the wheat traffic led to the great rate war which began November 19 and con- tinued until December 14, 1882, and incidentally resulted Commodity Rate Structures 121 in the company owning one of the Chicago Hnes obtain- ing a majority of the stock of one of the Duluth Hnes. At about this time the milling interests in Minne- apolis, at the Falls of the Mississippi, that were on their way to pre-eminence, began to intercept a great part of the grain shipments that formerly would have gone East by way of Duluth. Indeed, the capacity of these mills soon outstripped the supply of wheat from the tribu- tary farming land then under cultivation, and this led to more extended cultivation. Under the ensuing rate adjustments, while the rate on wheat is still lower to Duluth than to the Lake Michigan ports, the rate on grain products from Duluth is one-half cent per one hundred pounds higher than from the Lake Michigan ports to the seaboard territory. Duluth, therefore, has not maintained pre-eminence as a port of grain shipment, its greatness now depending upon the com- merce in the ore, for which it is a concentration point for shipment down the Lakes, and in the coal which comes up the Lakes for distribution throughout the Northwest. (See Milling in Transit.) When the first elevator was built at Chicago — not long before the Civil War — it was thought that sufficient grain to fill it would never come to the city. A typi- cal rate on wheat at that time was 28 cents per 100 pounds from Champaign, Illinois ; it is now 5 or 6 cents. At the time of the great grain rate wars between the lines in the Northwest there were at least one or more elevators at the terminus of every line entering Chicago from the West. They received grain not only from Wisconsin, Minnesota, and the Northwest, but from Iowa, Kansas and Nebraska. As grain was grown in Missouri and Arkansas, elevators were erected in St. Louis, and, as the production west of the Missouri River became extensive, at Omaha and Kansas City, which became primary markets that have increased in impor- tance. (See Elevation.) The competition that arose be- tween the various markets and the railroads serving them led gradually through the years to a general equalization 122 Railroad Freight Rates of rates to the East. That is, broadly speaking, the rates are so adjusted on grain from an initial shipping point of the West that the local rate to Kansas City, plus the through rate from Kansas City to the East; the local rate to Omaha, plus the through rate from Omaha to the East; the local rate to Chicago, plus the through rate from Chicago to the East; and the local rate to St. Louis, plus the through rate from St. Louis to the East, shall aggregate the same total rate. This equalization of the grain rates, so that the total shall be the same or approximately the same from any place of production via any primary market to the same Eastern market, is general through the grain regions. The re- sult is that the grain freight rates form a delicate struc- ture which may easily be disturbed by this cause or that. A disturbing factor of the first magnitude arose through the revival in recent years by the railroads leading to ports on the Gulf, of the carrying of grain for export to those ports. Many years ago attempts ■were made to take grain to New Orleans by boat down the Mississippi River, but in the warm climate it be- came saturated with moisture in the vessels' holds. The endeavor of the railroads extending to the Gulf to build up their traffic in grain began anew with the large crops of 1900, and made considerable progress during the two or three subsequent years. At first these railroads made rates far below those in effect to the Atlantic seaports. The railroads serving the Atlantic seaports retaliated, and in natural course there were rate wars, disastrous to the revenues of the railroads and unsettling to the grain business. After a test of strength by the fight- ing railroads the subject of an equitable differential be- tween the ports of the Atlantic and those of the Gulf was taken up for mutual serious consideration and dis- cussion. The Gulf railroads claimed that because of the shorter distance to their ports from the grain fields, their low grade lines upon which the expense of handling was not so great ; because of the moisture that accumu- Commodity Rate Structures 123 lated in the grain, impairing its quality so that it brought lower prices in the European markets ; small elevator facilities; the longer water route to Europe and higher vessel rates; irregular and less efficient vessel ser- vice, and higher marine insurance, they should have a differential of from 6 to 8 cents per 100 pounds under the Atlantic rates. The Atlantic railroads replied that by means of recent inventions the Gulf grain can be thoroughly dried at little ex- pense; they produced certificates -from European deal- ers that grain from the Gulf ports averages as high in quality as that from the Atlantic ports ; claimed that the difference in time between a trans-Atlantic voyage from the Gulf ports and from the Atlantic ports was not of great importance; that while the regular steamship sailings are not so frequent the Gulf ports are well supplied with tramp vessels ; and on account of these and other considerations urged that the differential should not exceed 3 cents under Baltimore, which would be equivalent to 4 cents under Philadelphia and 4^ cents under New York. There was finally a compromise. At this writing the rate on wheat per 100 pounds from Kansas City to Baltimore is 26^ cents; to the Gulf 22^. cents. The proportional rates for export are, from Kan- sas City to Baltimore 23^ cents, to Galveston 18^ cents. Before the development of the grain traffic between Kansas City and the Gulf the rates on grain for ship- ment through Kansas City were made by the combina- tion of the local rate from the grain fields of Kansas and Nebraska to Kansas City with the through rate from Kansas City to the East or Southeast or to the Gulf. The increase in the grain traffic by the direct lines from Kansas City to the Gulf led to lines not so direct enter- ing into competition for this traffic. The rate on grain for export from Wichita and the surrounding territory, that had been made by adding the local rate from Wichita to Kansas City to the rate from Kansas City to the Gulf, thus came to apply from Kansas City to the Gulf by way of Wichita. That is, a lower charge was being made for 124 Railroad Freight Rates the longer haul from Kansas City through Wichita than for the shorter haul from Wichita to the Gulf. This naturally awakened the antagonism of the growers and dealers in grain of Wichita and thereabouts, who sought larger reductions than the railroads were willing to make. The matter was finally taken to the Interstate Commerce Commission, which so reduced the rates from Wichita to the Gulf that the rates from a considerable area of the grain region to its north and west make on Wichita instead of Kansas City. Grain from this region is nat- urally seeking the gulf ports without going through Kansas City, and the importance of that city as a primary grain market is consequently impaired. The development of the transportation lines of Canada has brought another factor into the export grain traffic. In the summer of 1908 the Canadian steamers and rail- roads took grain from Port Arthur and placed it along- side steamer at Montreal or St. Johns for 3^ cents per bushel. The rate of the American railroads on wheat from the vessel at Buffalo was s| cents per bushel to New York and Boston, and the grain merchants of those cities complained that the American lines were depriv- ing them of traffic because they would not lower their rates to meet those via the Canadian route. These lines stated that if they were to reduce the rate by way of Buffalo I or 2 cents they would still get none of the Canadian wheat, but would ruinously sacrifice their rev- enue on such wheat as came to them. They suggested to the New York and Boston shippers that inasmuch as the Canadian government supports the Welland and Lachine Canals it might .not be improper for them to secure lower rates by bringing their wheat East by the Erie Canal. That the mills near the farms and those near the places of consumption may be upon an approximate parity in so far as the transportation charge is concerned, it has been the general policy of the American railroads to make the rates upon wheat the same or very nearly the same as upon flour. This is not always easy of accom- Commodity Rate Structures 125 plishment even in the domestic trade. It is still more difficult to maintain such a close relation between the rates for export traffic as will protect the American miller. At the time of the introduction of the roller ground patent flour, about 1880, the profits of the mills were from $1 to $3 a barrel. These have now fallen to 5 or 6 cents a barrel, the millers regarding a margin of from 2 to 3 cents per 100 pounds of flour as a good profit. If the rate on wheat for export is lower than the rate on flour for export by greater than this amount, there is consequently a tendency to export wheat, which is ground into flour in the countries where it is consumed. Wheat rates, however, have undergone wider fluctua- tions than those on flour, to the frequent grievance of the American millers. The railroads have claimed that the rates on wheat have been subject to more intense com- petition than those on flour; that wheat can be carried in bulk in heavier loads per car, at a lower cost for loading and unloading, and that a sudden demand will bring forth far more wheat for shipment than flour ; the former flowing out of elevators in bulk, while the latter can only be produced from day to day in such quantities as the capacity of the mills will permit. The Interstate Commerce Commission has decreed that the rate to the seaports on flour for export must not exceed the rate on wheat by more than 2 cents per loo pound's. The general effect of the grain rate structure of the railroads of the United States is summed up in volume VI of the Report of the Industrial Commission, pub- lished by the Government Printing Office in 1901. It states that while it is a fallacy to assume that grain rates all over the country have fallen anything like the rate on grain from Chicago to New York, there has been " great gain in the past fifteen years to the consumer by the elimination of numerous charges at the central markets by concentrating the trade, and to the producer by the competition of these central markets themselves, whereby the price tends to be kept up to a higher level than other- wise." It further says that " the competition of car- 126 Railroad Freight Rates riers and the rivalry of markets, in their constant efforts to control freight movement from grain territories, suc- ceed in steadily lowering railway rates." The diagram accompanying this statement shows that the prices of wheat oscillated between 135 per cent, in 1867 to 68 per cent, in 1896; of corn, between 116 per cent, and 45 per cent. ; while railroad rates steadily declined from 105 per cent, to 45 per cent. This report gives table after table showing the declines in grain rates which, on cer- tain roads, have ranged as much as 74 per cent., and states that " the American product meets the world's competition in foreign markets on favorable terms and usually with great success, with the result that, because of the cheapness of transportation and the acumen of the grain merchant, the American producer gets very much more for his labor than the inhabitant of any other country on earth." In brief, competition of the primary markets — St. Paul, Omaha, Kansas City, Chicago, St. Louis, etc. — keeps up the price to the producer: the competition of car- riers and markets keeps down the price to the consumer : both forces tend to reduce the cost of distribution, in- cluding the rate of transportation and the charge for handling. (2) LIVESTOCK AND DRESSED MEATS As the lands to the west of Chicago were brought under tillage the prairies that intervened and stretched to the farther West were used for grazing. Hundreds of thou- sands of cattle feed on the ranches that spread from the Dakotas to Texas. As the railroads desired to increase their traffic by carrying cattle they met a kind of compe- tition other than that of one railroad with another and different from the struggles with the wagon or the water- way, a kind of competition the motive power of which was furnished by the animals 'themselves. They could be and were driven from the plains of Texas to the feed- ing grounds of the North, they could be and were driven from the far West to the stockyards at primary markets. Commodity Rate Structures 127 It was necessary for the railroads, therefore, to make the rates for the carriage of livestock not greatly to exceed the cost of transportation " on the hoof." The general freight agent of the first railroad to cross the Texas border obtained from the stock drovers themselves a statement of the cost of transportation by the drove. They admitted that they would rather pay a trifle more by rail, and the rates were accordingly fixed a little in excess of the cost of driving. That phase of competition which makes it requisite for a railroad to make the rate from a station on its line the same as that from a correspond- ing station on another railroad in order that it may share in the traffic of the intervening territory was particularly effective in the case of cattle which could readily be ranged over the two or three hundred miles that sep- arated the railroads of the frontier. Upon these founda- tions developed the tariffs on livestock. The first channels of this traffic were from the Middle States to the stockyards and thence to the slaughter houses of the large eastern cities. During the first years of grazing in the farther West, the greater quan- tities of livestock were also shipped through to the East, but the development of transportation under refrigera- tion led to their being killed nearer the sources of sup- ply. Chicago was the first of the great packing centers where cattle are turned into dressed beef. As grazing grounds still farther to the West were extensively util- ized, packing houses were erected at Omaha, Kansas City, and, in recent years, at Denver and Ft. Worth, not to mention Oklahoma City, which is on the way to real- izing its ambition to become a packing center. This does not mean, however, that slaughtering is not still conducted in cities along the Lakes and in the Ohio Val- ley, any more than that the enormous development of mill- ing in the West and Northwest has destroyed the flour- ing industry in these cities. Cincinnati, which was the first conspicuous pork packing center, is still the seat of a large packing house industry and there are large pack- ing houses at Buffalo, Cleveland and Indianapolis, 128 Railroad Freight Rates which draw their supplies of livestocii principally from Ohio, Indiana, Illinois, Kentucky and Tennessee. When the slaughter of cattle and hogs on an extensive scale began in the West everybody assumed that the rate on dressed beef and dressed pork should be higher than that on cattle and hogs, manufactured products al- ways commanding a better price in the markets than the raw material out of which they are made, and therefore paying a higher rate of freight. Moreover, the cars in which livestock was shipped were not of expensive con- struction and frequently secured return loading from the East. Refrigerator cars, on the contrary, are costly. They have to be provided with facilities for carrying and must carry ice at the same time as the beef, and they do not al- ways find loads for the return to the West. Competition engendered by the packing houses, after a long and bitter contest between the interests involved, forced the west- ern railroad companies to make the rate on dressed beef and dressed pork the same as on cattle and hogs. In- cidentally it was necessary to decide such questions as to whether slaughtered hogs that were not salted until placed in the cars should be considered as salt meat or a packing house product, the latter taking a lower rate. This status in the West continued for several years. It was overthrown through the action of a railroad company whose lines, extending between Kansas City, Omaha and Chicago, had been unable to obtain an appreciable share of the traffic in packing house prod- ucts. The president of this company invited the heads of the packing house companies to a conference in which he agreed to cut the rate on their output from the Missouri River centers to Chicago from 23J to 18^ cents per 100 pounds, if the packers would guarantee to his company a certain percentage of the traffic. The packers accepted the offer and entered into the contract, with the result that the other lines were obliged to meet the cut rate, and the packers have given them the bulk of the traffic, preferring to make up to the road that brought about the reduction, by a cash Commodity Rate Structures 129 forfeit, the amount of revenue due under their guarantee. A demand of the Livestock Association that an equivalent reduction be made in the rate on Hve cattle and live hogs w^as contested by the railroads and made the subject of litigation. The lower court decided that as the compe- tition did' not apply to cattle and hogs the railroads were not obliged to lessen the rates to the level of those on dressed meat. The case was appealed to the Supreme Court of the United States which sustained the lower court. The natural result has been to give the packing houses a tremendous advantage over the livestock shippers. As the shipments of cattle from the West to the pack- ing centers have increased, as the railroads have had to provide better and larger loading pens, improved water- ing facilities, and to move livestock from the ranges or the fattening grounds in quicker time, — that is, as their advanced methods have brought about the movement of livestock not only more speedily, but with far less de- terioration to the animal than would be possible under the old time transportation on the hoof, — they have from time to time advanced the rates above the level upon which they were first fixed to meet that competition. Although they claim that the original rates were ab- normally low, and that even under the highest level which they have sought to establish, the carriage of livestock yields less revenue per ton per mile than that of almost any other commodity, certain of the livestock associations have contested the advances before the Interstate Com- merce Commission and in the courts. The railroads also call attention to the fact that improved feeding condi- tions on the ranges make it less necessary than dur- ing previous years to transport cattle to fattening grounds, and that as the prices for both cattle and hogs have radically increased the livestock dealers in all fair- ness should pay higher rates for the superior transporta- tion service. The Report of the Industrial Commission presented to Congress January 15, 1901, shows that horses, marketed in St. Louis at from $75 to $100 each, had paid freight 130 Railroad Freight Rates from the breeding farms of from $3 to $6 each. The deduction of this and other expenses of distribution left the producer from $67 to $93. Cattle weighing from 1,200 to 1,500 pounds, for which the consumer paid on an average $5.35 per 100 pounds, paid freight that ranged from 19 to 36 cents. The deduction of this and other expenses of distribution, yielded the producer from $4.88 to $5.15. As the advance in the price of livestock has greatly exceeded the advance in the rates of freight, the ratio of the transportation charge at this writing is still lower. The struggles between the western railroads as to the relative rates on live animals and on meat and meat products did not extend in the same degree to the eastern lines, which have preserved a higher rate on the manu- factured product than on the raw material, the rate for many years from Chicago to New York on dressed meat having been 45 cents, the rate on hogs 30 cents and on cattle 28 cents per 100 pounds. The difference between the dressed beef and the livestock rates is thus preserved substantially in accordance with the report of Elihu B. Washburn, to whom the matter was referred for arbi- tration. After a thorough investigation and analysis he rendered an opinion that in fairness the dressed beef rate should be 170 per cent, of the livestock rate. (3) COTTON As grain was a prime cause of conflict between the seaports of the North Atlantic and the railroads serv- ing them, so also was cotton the bone of contention be- tween the seaports of the South Atlantic and the Gulf and the railroads respectively serving them. As with the grain traffic, there was the giving of secret rates, the open cutting of rates, and rate wars that continued with but short intervals until an adjustment of rates that fairly satisfied the export dealers of the rival ports and the competing railroads was brought about in the early sev- enties through the Southern Railway and Steamship Commodity Rate Structures 131 Association. The damage to their harbors during the Civil War took away much of the cotton trade from Charleston and Mobile, the cities of Wilmington, Savan- nah and New Orleans each profiting thereby. The rates are now delicately and by almost unanimous consent so equitably adjusted that each port draws cotton from the territory tributary to it; and in the competitive ter- ritory farther in the interior each port can compete on a fair basis with its rival. The development of the cot- ton milling industry in the Carolinas, together with the censorship of the State Commissions, has resulted in an adjustment of rates to the milling points that is elimi- nating the old time criticism of excessive local rates. When the producer east of the Mississippi River re- ceives 10 cents a pound for his cotton it is computed that the freight charge averages 2.5 per cent, of his receipts. In Texas the State Railroad Commission has graded the rates on cotton for 160 miles from Houston and estab- lished a maximum rate of 49 cents for any greater dis- tance. The rate to Galveston is 6 cents per hundred pounds more, which has the effect of making a rate of 55 cents per hundred pounds for all distances 210 miles or more from Galveston. About 25 per cent, of the cotton which moves through Galveston is grown within 210 miles of Galveston, so that this basis means that 75 per cent, of the cotton produced in the State is carried to the Gulf at the same rate — the rate to New Orleans, for export, being 56^ cents, which is the Galveston rate plus i^ cents, the amount of the wharf charge at Galves- ton. The plantation owner several hundred miles in the interior therefore receives as much for his cotton as the grower within 210 miles of the Gulf. This policy tends to give the grower the benefit of the competition engen- dered by the primary markets, Houston, Galveston and New Orleans. He can ship his cotton to Houston on the basis of 49 cents, and when it is sampled and pre- pared for market the purchaser at Houston pays the rate of 6 cents from Houston to Galveston. If the pro- 132 Railroad Freight Rates ducer would sell to a Galveston merchant he would pay 55 cents for the initial movement ; the present basis there- fore provides that a bale of cotton shipped to Houston, thence reshipped to Galveston, pays exactly the same freight rate as a bale of cotton shipped direct to Galves- ton. The rule of the Texas Railroad Commission re- quires that railroads shall compress all cotton, if desired by owner, at the nearest compress in line of movement, and pay for this compression the amount of 10 cents per one hundred pounds. The railroad company, there- fore, receives 39 cents per hundred as net revenue for hauling a bale of cotton from the initial point to the compress, thence to Houston; and 45 cents from the initial point to a compress, thence to Galveston. This regulation of the Commission has had the effect of stimulating the construction of compresses in the inte- rior so that the compresses at Houston and Galveston are used only to a small extent and by small shippers who forward their cotton to factors at Houston and Galveston to be compressed there and placed on the market when market conditions are favorable. Of the entire average crop of Texas of over 3,000,000 bales, only about 10 per cent, is thus handled. In other parts of the South the railroads likewise pay the compress fee because the compress reduces the baled cotton by about 75 per cent, in bulk, thereby en- abling a far greater tonnage of compressed than uncom- pressed cotton to be loaded in a car. The fee, however, ranges as low as seven cents, in but few places being as high as the ten cents stipulated by the Texas Commission. The rate from Oklahoma to the Atlantic seaports on cotton going to Europe is naturally higher than from the other cotton producing sections. By way of compensa- tion the rate to the Pacific Coast for export to the mills of China and Japan is lower than from any other cotton raising district of the United States, except Texas. Cot- ton from Oklahoma, therefore, seeks the Pacific and the Oriental markets. Probably no other agricultural product of the United Commodity Rate Structures 133 States is so slovenly handled as cotton. The farmers often leave it exposed to be damaged by rain and infil- trated with mud; it is loosely baled and inadequately marked. That which is sold to Japan, however, must meet the requirements of the Japanese, who insist that it be carefully packed, that it be clean, and bound in white cloth, which must be marked in indelible ink. (4) LUMBER The shifting of the source of the lumber supply has prevented the lumber rate structure from ever attain- ing a condition even approaching stable equilibrium. Sixty years ago the lumber used by nearly every town and city in the country was obtained from adjacent for- ests, and shaped in near-by mills. Timber is still cut in New England, New York and Pennsylvania, but in quantities that are no longer adequate to supply local needs. As the vast forests of these States were destroyed by the woodman's axe, and by fire and freshet, and the ravages of insects and fungi, Buffalo became a great headquarters of dealers who brought lumber down from the Lakes and across the border from Canada. Then the main source of supply shifted to the West and to the South, and finally to the Southwest and the far Northwest. The lumber dealers whose business was once almost entirely done through Buffalo, in common with lumber dealers who have headquarters in other cities," have established offices at Memphis, through which they direct shipments from the Southwestern forests. Lum- ber, and especially shingles, also come in great quantities from Oregon and Washington to the far East. For instance, the coal companies of Pittsburg that send coal down the Ohio and Mississippi Rivers in the light wooden shells known as coal boats, once obtained the hemlock of which these boats are made from the banks of the Allegheny River. Now it comes in large quantities from the forests along the Columbia, Oregon, and Willamette Rivers and their tributaries. 134 Railroad Freight Rates The shifting status of the lumber rates is shown by the changes that followed the depletion of the North- western forests. Logs from the timber land along the lake shore were once taken by water to Buffalo and Chicago, where they were milled for further use. Even the lumber used in Omaha and eastern Nebraska came from the Lake forests by water to Chicago and by rail from the Chicago mills to Omaha. As the forests were cut away from the lake shore sawmills were built in the interior, it being more economical, in the absence of immediate water transportation, to saw the timber at the forest edge. Competition arose between these interior mills and those at Chicago for the trade of Omaha. The matter was referred to arbitrators who established the rate adjustment, based on fixed differences as from the respective milling districts, that is in effect to-day. At this time, however, the requirements of the Omaha sec- tion are met principally with pine from the South and from the States of Idaho, Oregon, Washington and Cal- ifornia, the Wisconsin mills finding a more profitable market in Ohio and Indiana. These white pine forests of Wisconsin and Minnesota have been so depleted that large distribution of lumber no longer takes place through the ports on Lake Michigan, Lake Superior and Lake Erie. When lumber was forwarded by water the various sizes were loaded in the boats as they came from the mill, and were assorted and prepared for specific mar- kets as they were rehandled from the boats to the rail- road cars at the lower ports. At present the lumbermen find it more profitable to fill specific orders directly at the mill by loading the sizes and shapes desired on cars that go through to destination. In the proceedings of the traffic associations whose formation was brought about by the excessive railroad competition of the Northwest the lumber rates were a source of unending complications. Adjustments were required between the rates on hardwood logs and hard- wood lumber, on softwood logs and softwood lumber, and between the rates on lumber and those on its various Commodity Rate Structures 135 products, such as telegraph poles, beams, shingles and girders. The railroads of the interior Northwestern States en- deavored to protect the trade of their lumbermen as long as the white pine forests provided abundant traffic. They thus facilitated the conversion of the timber districts into farming lands, and the lumber afforded return loads for the cars that brought the supplies to the lumber camps. It was their fixed policy, therefore, to make lower rates on this white pine than on the yellow pine from the South which was then seeking a market, the dis- crimination being furthered by the fact that there were no return loads to the South for the cars that brought up the yellow pine. As the Northern forests have been denuded, the rates on the Southern pine have been reduced. The following example is but one of the very many that might be cited to illustrate the complications arising from such a change in the source of supply. During the availability of the Wisconsin forests ex- tensive and expensive plants were established in Osh- kosh for the manufacture of sash, doors and blinds, which supplied large markets in Chicago, Cincinnati, Toledo, Indianapolis, and other cities of the interior. As the lumber supply moved toward the South similar plants were erected at Muscatine, Iowa. Both cities are now forced to bring lumber from the Southwest, the haul to Oshkosh being considerably longer than to Mus- catine. The Oshkosh plants are under a further handi- cap in reaching the markets at Indianapolis, Columbus and Cincinnati by the fact that the rates from Muscatine, a Mississippi River point to the south of Dubuque, are largely controlled by the rates from St. Louis, and the direct route is to the south of Chicago, whereas Osh- kosh is almost due north of that city. A similar illus- tration is furnished by the vehicle factories that were located at Pontiac, Wayne, Jackson, South Bend, and Franklin, because of contiguity to the Michigan lumber supply, which has also been exhausted. They must now 136 Railroad Freight Rates obtain lumber from the South and Southwest, and they likewise complain because of the rates on vehicles to the West and Southwest. That is, these industries, which in previous decades paid remunerative rates to the railroads, now seek unremunerative rates to enable them to con- tinue in competition with rival industries that, situated nearer the present sources of lumber supply, not only secure their raw material more cheaply, but have lower rates on their products to the region to which they are a long step nearer than the earlier located factories to their north. South Bend, for example, clamors for the same rates to the West as from Chicago, although she is 86 miles to the east of that city. This and the foregoing example are reciprocal in that to sustain the sash, door and blind factories of Oshkosh the roads to the west of Chicago are obliged to ask concessions of the railroads leading from that city through the Central Traffic Ter- ritory ; while to protect the vehicle industry of northern Indiana and southern Michigan the railroads leading therefrom to Chicago are obliged to seek concessions from the lines leading to the West from that city. While the railroads of the Northwest were making low rates on white pine to give the lumbermen of that section an advantage in the markets, the railroads that had been constructed into the South, and especially into Arkansas, Louisiana and the Southwest, were attempting to increase their traffic and develop the territory which they served by encouraging the cutting of and helping to market the yellow pine and the other woods of the South. They made low rates and still lower rates, and finally began to obtain traffic from the lumber which at last was gaining a foothold in the northern and west- ern markets. As the northern forests were exhausted the lumber from the South and Southwest came more and more into demand at higher and higher prices ; stumpage that had sold as low as from 10 to 20 cents an acre had risen to $5.00 and upwards, and the land itself, for which there was not a purchaser at $5.00, easily brought from $25.00 to $50.00 an acre. The railroads endeavored to Commodity Rate Structures 137 advance in their rates, claiming a right to share in the increased prosperity of the region; the lumbermen con- tested these advances before the Interstate Commerce Commission and through the courts, which upheld the Commission in nullifying an advance of two cents per 100 pounds. The prosperity of the lumber industry to the westward of the lower Mississippi has extended to the remote Southwest, timber that a score of years ago could not find a market now being the basis of profitable operation. When its timber in Michigan was nearing exhaustion, a lumber company of that State, about the year 1891, invested in white pine timber in New Mexico, erected a sawmill and built a logging railroad. It struggled for several years to find a market, but almost entirely without success. The lumber was full of knots and pitch, and could not be sold in competition with that of the Pacific Coast, or even that of Colorado. The railroad on which the enterprise was located made very low rates to aid in the disposition of lumber in Colorado and Kansas, but the lumber company ultimately abandoned the project, dismantling the sawmill and taking up the logging railroad. The property laid idle until about 1904, when another company purchased the timber rights, and built a mill at a point where there was better water supply. This company cut the trunks in short lengths for the market, into material for sash, doors, boxes, bar- rel heads, and into lath. It is now shipping the material to the sash and door factories at Muscatine, Oshkosh, and Chicago, and even sends doors to Scotland, making a fair return on a very large capital. These results have fol- lowed the great advance in the prices of lumber, coupled with the intelligence of the operators. The rates on lumber from the South and Southwest that is destined to the markets north of the Ohio River are adjusted under fixed differences. The rate by way of St. Louis is 2 cents higher than by way of Cairo ; to many points in Indiana it is but i cent higher Reference has been made to the freight rates as af- 138 Railroad Freight Rates fecting the lumber industry of the Pacific Coast in that part of the previous chapter devoted to the freight rate structure of that region. As the traffic problems of the Pacific Coast are in large measure peculiar thereto, it has seemed advisable to include mention of the commodi- ties constituting that traffic in the outline of those prob- lems. (5) THE DIFFERENT TYPES OF COMMODITY RATE STRUCTURES On the great staple commodities it is necessary to so adjust rates as to maintain equilibrium between the places of production and the various markets. In the case of grain and grain products flowing in the great channels of traffic from one region to another this is accom- plished, as we have seen, by an equalization through dif- ferent gateways. The solution of the problem is similar in the case of livestock and dressed meats. These com- modities are all produced throughout a widely extended area, and are marketed in an area that is also widely extended. In the case of such commodities as wool and bullion, while the production is over a widely extended area, their flow is along converging lines to places of final manufacture comparatively few in number and in an area limited in extent. The rate adjustment, therefore, is more especially concerned with the establishment of an equilibrium between the places of production. The adjustment in the case of cotton is in a measure akin to that on grain and grain products, although the cotton mills are not nearly so widely distributed as the flour mills. In the case of lumber, of which the sources of supply are no longer so numerous as in former years, the crux of the adjustment lies in the contest between the railroads and the lumbermen as to whether the rate shall be higher or lower within the margin that the traffic will readily bear. In the case of fruits and vegetables is approached another type of structure — that which has to take into Commodity Rate Structures 139 account the necessity for such an adjustment as will maintain an equilibrium in common markets between products from widely divergent sources of supply. In Chicago and the cities of the Atlantic seaboard, and in the intervening cities, for example, the vegetables of Florida compete with those of MissiS'Sippi, and the oranges of Florida with those from the Pacific Coast. The maintenance of the equilibrium in common mar- kets on a product that comes from widely divergent sources of supply is, perhaps, the more difficult in the case of coal than of any other commodity. Practically the entire supply of anthracite coal comes from north- eastern Pennsylvania, whence it is distributed for con- sumption throughout the North Atlantic States, and, to a lesser degree, in the West and the Northwest. Bitu- minous coal fields, supplying the North Atlantic States, extend from the Clearfield region in Pennsylvania down through Maryland and the Virginias. The competition between these fields and the lines serving them for the seaboard trade was so continuous and unrelentingly bitter through a long series of years that it was a principal factor which led to the " community of inter- est " between the lines extending from these coal fields to the East. The coal fields of western Pennsylvania, eastern and southern Ohio, of West Virginia, and to a limited ex- tent, of Virginia, are in competition for the lake trade, that which is carried by rail to the lower ports of Lake Erie and thence by vessel to the ports of the upper lakes, as far as Duluth, where it is distributed through- out the Northwest. The adjustment of rates to maintain equilibrium between these competitors has been a per- plexing problem, the quality of the coal, as well as the conditions of transportation, needing to be taken into con- sideration. Coal from these fields also competes through- out Ohio, Indiana, Michigan, and Illinois, also con- testing these markets with the coal of southern Ohio, northern Kentucky, central Michigan, central and southern Indiana, and of central and southern Illinois, 140 Railroad Freight Rates this multiplying competition leading to further compli- cations that make the rate adjustment all the more difficult. At different places along the Mississippi Val- ley there is competition between the coal that comes from Illinois, Arkansas, Missouri, and Iowa, and to a degree the coal from these fields is in rivalry in the Northwest with that which has come up via the Lakes. In the trans-Missouri territory the coal from Iowa, Mis- souri, Arkansas, and southeastern Kansas competes, certain markets also being entered by coal from Okla- homa and Colorado. In the Rocky Mountain region there is competition between the mines of New Mexico on the south, and those of Colorado, Wyoming, and the Crow's Nest field of Canada to the north. The Southeast is supplied with coal from the Virginias, Kentucky, Ten- nessee, and Alabama. The fact that the operators of each field continuously desire to increase their output and extend their markets leads to constant pressure upon the railroads for reductions and readjustments of rates, the freight rate on coal always being a considerable element in its price. The competition between manufacturers of brick and cement in nearly all respects is similar, except that or- dinarily it does not apply over such extended areas. For example, in the Clearfield district of Pennsylvania vast quantities of fine fire clay underlie the coal seams. Not many years ago the practicability of manufacturing fire brick from this clay in this district was investigated, but on account of the locality not being in the main channels of traffic, the rates then in effect would not let the brick enter the markets in competition with the fire brick from the Pittsburg and Johnstown districts, or compete in wider markets with the brick manufac- tured in southern Ohio or New Jersey. A fire brick plant at Pittsburg, of course, had the Pittsburg district market at hand throughout which its delivery cost was low; this gave it an advantage over the plant 150 miles away in the Clearfield district, which, however, was favored Commodity Rate Structures 141 by being nearer the source of raw material. In adjust- ing the transportation charge on the fire brick from the Clearfield district and on the raw material from the Pitts- burg district, there was the endeavor to place the competing districts as nearly as possible on a parity so far as their cost of manufacture is concerned. Deposits of glass sand that are abundant in the center of the State of Pennsylvania have been developed by the adjustment of rates so that it may be shipped to plants near a fuel supply, where the manufacture of glass is practicable. For instance, the enormous glass plants along the Allegheny River and in the Pittsburg district must compete with those at Kane and there- abouts, where there is both sand and fuel-gas, and also with the glass plants of Indiana. To these various places the railroads must so fix their tariffs on the various materials that the plants may continue in operation. Cement is produced in various locahties in this eastern portion of the United States, the plants in each locality being designated as the Pennsylvania group, the New Jersey group, the Hudson River group, the Virginia group, and the Ohio group. To protect the cement industries on its lines, each railroad company has been obliged to make such adjustment of rates on coal to the cement plants as will permit a cost of manufacture enabling their product to be sold in as extended a market as can be maintained. The Lehigh district of Pennsyl- vania is so abundantly supplied with cement rock that it would seem to be the natural place for the manufacture of cement, but the railroad company has been obliged time and again to adjust its rates to the needs of the industry, and the situation will be the more complicated as the manufacture of cement from furnace slag is still further developed. Cement from this region was once extensively shipped to the Middle West, but these mar- kets have been absorbed by plants erected in recent years in the Mississippi Valley. It goes without saying that the adjustment of rates 1421 Railroad Freight Rates between competing districts is not always effected with- out friction between the producers of one district and those of another, or between one and another producer of the same district. Every producer is at nearly all times trying to extend his market, and he besieges the railroad company for rates that will make possible that extension, even although the concession which he seeks will work to the injury of a competitor or of a com- peting region entitled to as much consideration. A pro- ducer is prone to regard the market in his vicinity as belonging to him by natural right, and to regard sales in a distant market as so much extra gain. This ten- dency is especially manifest in times of great pros- perity, when there is on every hand the stimulus to exertion. Other kinds of complications that beset the railroads are indicated by the following examples. In northern Indiana a great many roads are building for which can be used either crushed stone from various quarries that are respectively in the vicinity of Chicago, Toledo, and Milwaukee, or gravel from gravel pits within a few miles of the roads. To enable the quarry owners to com- pete with the gravel pits, it has been necessary for the railroads to make a very low rate on crushed stone for use in the country roads, and they have been forced to apply the low rates made because of this contingency as the basis for rates on crushed stone employed for other purposes throughout a considerable section. Along the south shore of Lake Michigan are sand dunes hundreds of feet high bordering the tracks of the railroads for thirty-five miles or more. The railroad company naturally desired to rid its track of this menace, and when demand arose for sand for use in the embank- ments made by the railroads upon which to elevate their tracks in Chicago and its vicinity, this company made rates of $4.00 and $5.00 per car on fifteen-ton cars, and $7.00 and $8.00 per car on fifty-ton cars for distances of thirty and forty miles into Chicago. This rate was profitable enough for cars that ran with full loads in Commodity Rate Structures 143 long trains at frequent intervals. Other sand shippers insisted, however, that correspondingly low rates be made on sand sold by them for various uses, although moved in but one or two carloads at a time and from sand banks as remote as St. Joseph and Michigan City. Lime of fine quality is made at Mitchell, Indiana, on a railroad leading into Chicago, and also at Marble- head, near Burlington, Iowa, which is much nearer than Mitchell but on another railroad leading into Chicago. It has been necessary for protection of the lime kilns of Mitchell that the railroad therefrom make the same rate into Chicago as applies from the nearer kilns at Marble- head. Iowa is a competitive market for salt from Kansas, from Manistee and Ludington, Michigan, and from De- troit, Toledo, and Cleveland. The conflict between these divergent sources of supply and the railroads serving them finally resulted in rates on salt that are practically the same from these various points to the Iowa mar- kets. In like manner the rates on ice from Michigan to Chicago are influenced by the rates from Wisconsin. This rivalry is especially marked in the case of such a large market as Chicago, the population of which is approximately the same as that of the entire State of Wisconsin. When there is but one source of production of a com- modity that commodity is in competition with substitute commodities only ; the price, including the transportation charge, is limited by the point at which there will be the substitution of another for that commodity. When there are numerous sources of production there is a greater number of markets which are interwoven by the working of competition. There must be maintained a certain equilibrium for the interest of everyone con- cerned, and the burden of its maintenance often falls upon the transportation lines. Their traffic officers be- come the umpires between contending interests, and not infrequently receive the buffeting that is the umpire's usual fate. 144 Railroad Freight Rates IMPORT AND EXPORT TRAFFIC Through the various ports of the United States are imported in large quantities the materials and products of other countries, and are exported the materials and products of this. The through route formed by a ves- sel line from a foreign country, through a particular port, in connection with a railroad line from that port to a city in the interior is in competition with a through route formed by a vessel line through another port, in connection with a railroad line leading from that port to the same or to a rival interior city. For example, traffic from Liverpool to Denver may go through either Montreal, Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Baltimore, or Norfolk, and thence by rail to Denver; or it may go through New Orleans or Galveston and thence by rail to Denver. In the case of export traffic the same conditions exist in reverse direction. As stated on a previous page, the differentials on export grain via the different North Atlantic ports to Liverpool were originally established with the intent of making the through rate from the grain fields to Liverpool the same via any of these ports. The adjustment of the grain export rates via the Gulf also had to take into account the through rate to Liverpool via the Atlantic ports. The endeavors of different ports and of the railroads serving them to secure either import or export traffic, or both, have obliged the railroads at times, indeed, at nearly all times, to make inland rates on certain traffic far lower than those accorded on similar traffic between the same points that is entirely do- mestic. This practice has been held to be justi- fiable by the Supreme Court of the United States. The railroads have also claimed that they have been compelled to rapidly change their rates in accordance with the fluctuations of steamship rates, which often go up and down from day to day as the offering of loads i for cargoes are heavy or light. Indeed, the vessel rates Import and Export Traffic 145 have been known to vary from hour to hour. For ex- ample, a ship with two-thirds of a cargo may make a substantial reduction to stimulate the shipment of ad- ditional merchandise sufficient to make a complete cargo. This condition has frequently obtained at the southern ports with steamships seeking full cargoes of cotton and naval stores. It is also evident that a port through which exports naturally flow desires to offer rates to the interior on imports that will attract vessels with inbound cargoes in order that there may be adequate facilities for the out- bound traffic. Conversely, it is desirable that a port naturally attracting imports should have favorable rates on export traffic in order that it may have full cargoes for the vessels outbound. The Interstate Commerce Commission has ruled that the inland rates for both export and import traffic shall not be lowered or advanced, except upon due notice, as provided in the Interstate Commerce Law, and it has also ruled that either the through import or export rates, or else the inland proportions thereof received by the rail lines, shall be published and posted the same as rates on domestic traffic. That is, the Commission states that while it has no jurisdiction over the vessel rates or over the through rates made by the railroads in combination with the vessels, it has jurisdiction over the rates of the railroads between the interior and the ports, and decrees that these rates shall be filed and pub- lished the same as other rates applying on interstate commerce. The lines engaged in transcontinental traffic state that this ruling is especially burdensome to them. For ex- ample, to participate in traffic from the Orient to New York they are obliged to accept the agreed percentages of such rates as the steamboats are obliged to make from the Oriental ports. The traffic from Australia and China, for instance, may come to New York either via the vessel routes by way of the Suez Canal, or by way of the vessel and rail routes through San Francisco, or 146 Railroad Freight Rates other of the Pacific ports. The vessels that sail from these lands eastwardly around the globe to the Pacific ports, and the vessels that sail half way around the globe to the west on their way to the American me-' tropolis are in vigorous competition for this traffic. Those that sail toward the East are obliged to rely upon the transcontinental railroads to accept the stipulated percentages from the Pacific ports to various destinations in the United States of such rates as they are obliged to make to secure traffic that otherwise would move in the opposite direction through the Suez Canal and through the ports of the Atlantic to these destinations. Likewise, the traffic from New York or the interior may go either from the Atlantic ports by way of the Suez Canal, or by rail to the Pacific ports and thence by vessel. The vessel lines from New York via the Suez are under no obligation to publish their rates and are not under any jurisdiction of the Interstate Com- merce Commission compelling them to maintain rates. On the contrary, the transcontinental lines which, in connection with the Pacific vessel lines, compete for this traffic to the Orient, are obliged to publish and to adhere to the published proportions that accrue to the rail lines on this traffic. These proportions, in any event, are so much less than they receive on domestic shipments that the railroads fear their publication will lead to demand for a reduction of their domestic rates, and, at the time the Commission made its ruling, stated that they could better afford to withdraw from this traffic, which, al- though large in the aggregate, is of small consequence in comparison with the aggregate of other shipments, rather than take the risk of having the rates on the domestic traffic reduced. In consideration of these peculiar con- ditions affecting the transcontinental traffic of the Pa- cific ports the Commission has reduced the time within which notice of a change of rate may be given to ten days in the case of advances and three days in the case of reductions. The decision of the Supreme Court permitting the Import and Export Traffic 147 railroads to charge on import and export traffic lower rates than apply on domestic traffic between the same places is in entire accord with the practice of the state- owned railroads of Germany, which are obliged by the government to encourage the German manufacturers to seek foreign markets by making lower rates on export than on domestic traffic ; and that of the National Rail- road of Mexico, which contains a stipulation in the con- cession that it must, in the interests of the Mexican producers, make one-half rates on export traffic. While the American producers are entirely content with the application of this principle on export traffic, they resent its application to import traffic, claiming that thereby the intent of the custom duties is subverted. CHAPTER IX EARLY TARIFFS AND CLASSIFICATIONS No one of the factors entering into the formation of the existing rate structures has been constant. As the railroads have extended, as traffic has developed, as the localization of industries and the currents of commerce have changed, as State and Federal legislation has im- posed its decrees, these varying influences have acted and reacted upon the rate adjustments. When railroads were first projected in the United States, there was no definite basis upon which to estab- lish their tarififs. Costs of maintenance and operation were of uncertain estimate and the economic relations of the transportation function were simple. Certain of the State legislatures, at the time of granting charters, assumed, as a matter of course, that a railroad could furnish transportation at a lesser price than the wagons along the turnpike, and, therefore, arbitrarily decreed that the freight charge should be a greater or less pro- portion of that customary by wagon. In some parts of the country the wagon toll was 20 cents per cubic foot for articles light in weight, and $1.00 per 100 pounds for articles heavy in weight, per 100 miles. The mini- mum charge was for twenty miles, because twenty miles was a day's work, and a lesser haul spoiled the day. A wagon of the kind in general use had a capacity of 200 cubic feet, and four horses could haul 4,000 pounds, or 2 tons. As the charge for 200 cubic feet at 20 cents amounts to $40.00, and the charge for 4,000 pounds at $1.00 per hundred weight amounts to $40.00, the mini- mum charge for the wagon load was fixed at $40.00 per hundred miles. The charter granted by South Carolina, in 1827, to the South Carolina Railroad provided that the freight charge 148 Early Tariffs and Classifications 149 should not exceed 10 cents per cubic foot for articles light in weight, and 50 cents per 100 pounds for articles heavy in weight, per 100 miles, thus arbitrarily making the railroad tolls one-half the wagon tolls. The rail- road accepted this to mean that the usual railroad charge should be one-half the wagon charge : it divided its extent into lengths of ten miles, one-half of the distance for which wagons made a minimum charge, and adjusted its rates at 100 pounds per ten miles. In a charter granted by Georgia, in 1837, it is " Provided, That the charge of transportation or conveyance shall not exceed 25 cents per 100 pounds on heavy articles, and 10 cents per cubic foot on articles of measurement for every 100 miles." The provision as to the rates that generally appeared in the early State charters, however, specifies that there may be charged " such rates per mile as may be agreed upon and established from time to time by the directors of said corporation." Under this discretion various tariffs in divers parts of the country were adjusted to different proportions of the tolls that had been charged by wagon, or by stagecoach, or by canal or other water- way. A's the first railroads were built from one or another seaport for but short distances into the interior, there was nothing to prevent the charge for any given distance being the amount obtained by multiplying the rate per mile . by the number of miles. That is, a " distance tariff " prevailed. As the railroads extended, however, it quickly became the practice to accord relatively lower rates for long than for short distances, that is, to make " tapering rates." The practice of the wagoners to charge by the cubic foot for articles light in weight, and by the 100 pounds for articles heavy in weight was continued by the rail- roads; but it quickly developed that it was not easy to assign certain articles to one or another of these broad classes. This difficulty was enhanced by the fact that the railroads brought about an increase not only in the volume but in the diversity of commodities offered 1^0 Railroad Freight Rates for transportation ; things differed, not only in bulk and weight, but in value, and the way in which they were packed, while many articles were not packed or wrapped at all. A more elaborate grouping — such as had been used by canals both in Great Britain and the United States before there were railroads — was obviously neces- sary. The initial steps of this development, as it pertains to the railroads of the United States, are lost to record, but that much progress was made within thirty years is manifest from a document issued by the South Carolina Railroad in 1855, copies of which are extant. At the top four classes of articles are specified, the first including " hats, bonnets, saddles, furniture, pianos, tea, and other light articles," for which the charge was made per cubic foot, ranging from 4 cents for 7 miles to 10 cents for 136 miles. As furniture and pianos are not exactly light in weight, they were probably placed in the first class because of their high value. The second class included " dry goods, shoes, glass, paint, glassware, drugs, gensing, pinkroot, confectionery, raisins, figs, dates, camphine, spirits, turpentine, feathers, stoves, hollow ware, bows and shafts, pepper, spice, gin- ger." For these articles the charge applied per 100 pounds, ranging from 25 cents for 25 miles, to 50 cents for 136 miles. Here, again, the inclusion of feathers and stoves in the same class implies that commercial as well as transportation conditions received consideration. The third class embraced " butter, peas, lard, rope, to- bacco, leather, dry hides, tin, copper, cast steel, hoop and sheet iron, machinery in boxes, coils of wire, carriage springs and axles, rice, soap, candles, hardware, guns, bagging, tallow, beeswax, oil, white lead, wool, dressed marble, mahogany bedsteads, old furniture, crockery, doors, sashes and blinds, hubs, spokes, chair stuff, mel- ons." The charge applied per 100 pounds, ranging from 18 cents for 25 miles to 40 cents for 136 miles. The fourth class comprised " bacon, coffee, sugar, nails, spikes, mill gearing, ice, steel — other than cast — pig and bar iron, bundle iron, grind and mill stones, coal, Early Tariffs and Classifications i^i green hides, hair and rags, potash, soda ash, german clay, iron railings, shot and lead, mineral paint, undressed marble, stone, hay, moss, tar, pitch, crude turpentine, cotton yarn and domestics, down, paper down, tanbark, stoneware, cottonseed, dried fruit, railroad wheels and axles, car springs, copper ore." The charge applied per 100 pounds, ranging from 15 cents for 25 miles to 30 cents for 136 miles. The inclusion of cast steel, hoop and sheet iron in class third, while other kinds of steel and pig and bar iron were placed in class fourth shows a variance in the tariff on similar articles intended for different purposes. In addition to the articles ranged in these classes espe- cial listing is made of agricultural implements, molasses, liquor, barrels, lime, flour, cotton, grain, salt, chairs, carriages and livestock. Under these headings the charge is so much for each agricultural implement, vehicle, bar- rel, cask, hogshead, pipe, tierce, kit, sack, bale, as the case may be of fish, beef, pork, bread, crackers, fruit, oysters, shoe pegs, beets, potatoes, onions, apples, ce- ment, plaster, lime. Flour was charged so much per barrel or so much per sack; cotton so much per bale, not exceeding 400 pounds; grain so much per bushel; chairs so much per dozen; horses, mules, cows, or oxen so much for one, so much for two or three, so much for four, for five, for ten ; sheep, deer, lambs, goats, pigs, calves, dogs, were carried for so much apiece; turkeys, geese, ducks, and fowls, for so much per dozen. Pro- vision was made for a rate by the carload of any one kind of livestock with one passenger in charge, the load not to exceed 16,000 pounds. A list of special rates specified the transportation charge for wood by the cord, lumber and bricks by the thousand, the rate being 20 per cent, or more higher in the winter than in the summer; and for resin, tar, and crude turpentine, staple products of the region, a rate per barrel much lower than for other articles packed in barrels. This document was both a tariff and a classification. 1^2 Railroad Freight Rates Various articles taking the same rate were grouped in a class and the rate applying to the class was specified on the same sheet. For articles which, because of volume or value or peculiar conditions, such as vitriol, gunpow- der, eggs, and spice, could not well be grouped in any of the classes, " miscellaneous rates " were specified. This sheet named, all told, fewer than 300 things as taking the rate specified for any one of the four classes, or special or miscellaneous rates. Before many years a more varied agriculture, and particularly a more varied manufacture, caused a vast increase in the number of the articles of traiiSc. It therefore was no longer feasible for the classification and the tarifiF to be issued in one document. The articles were listed alphabetically, with indication of their respective classification in one docu- ment, and the rates as they applied for the different classes in another. By 1880 the number of articles necessary for inclusion in the various groups exceeded one thousand. At the present time each of the principal classifications contains nearly 6,000 items, and there are numerous articles moving at commodity rates which are embodied in special tariffs. It is noteworthy that, while this early Southern classification contained four classes, the classifications used in New England indicated rates for a " first class," for " special commodities belonging to the first class," and for various other " special " articles. The original tariff of the Louisville and Nashville Rail- road included but three classes, the first being rated by bulk, the second by weight, and the third containing livestock. As late as 1873 this railroad rated poultry by the dozen, charging more for Muscovy than for ordi- nary ducks. The principle primarily underlying classification is the endeavor to apply — without listing a separate rate for each article — to each of the articles of commerce that rate which it should equitably pay, and which will cause the revenue derived from the aggregate quantity of that article transported to be in proper proportion to the total revenue derived from the conveyance of all articles. Early Tariffs and Classifications 153 The original simple distinction between articles light in weight and those heavy in weight has been complicated by such considerations as, to quote from the Eleventh Annual Report of the Interstate Commerce Commission, " Whether commodities are crude, rough, or finished ; liquid or dry ; knocked down or set up ; loose or in bulk ; nested or in boxes; or otherwise packed; if vegetables, whether green or dry, desiccated or evaporated ; the mar- ket value and the shipper's representation as to their character; the cost of service, length and duration of haul ; the season and manner of shipment ; the space oc- cupied and weight; whether in carload or less than car- load lots; the volume of annual shipments to be calcu- lated on ; the sort of car required , whether flat, gondola, box, tank, or special ; whether ice or heat must be fur- nished; the speed of trains necessary for perishable or otherwise rush goods ; the risk of handling, either to the goods themselves or other property; the weights, actual and estimated ; the carriers' risk or owners' release from damage or loss." The classification of commodities according to such varied considerations made possible the abandonment of the charges based upon such heterogeneous units as a cubic foot, an agricultural implement, a vehicle, a dozen, a barrel, a cask, a hogshead, or a cord. The assign- ment of divers commodities to different classes, in each of which the especial characteristics of one commodity were weighed against those of another, permitted the adoption of 100 pounds as the basis for the transportation charge on all, except the heaviest commodities, for which the ton is the unit. That is, the 100 pounds became the common denominator of all commodities, and the class rate the numerator of the commodities included in the class. Certain exceptions to this basis endured for several years. Foremost of these was the charge per carload — that is, upon the carload as a unit — for livestock. This was because the early cars in which this could be shipped were of about the same size, the load of any 154 Railroad Freight Rates particular kind of livestock averaging about the same in number and weight, and it not being practicable to establish scales adequate for the weighing of such heavy shipments at all places where livestock was loaded. For somewhat similar considerations rates for lumber by the carload endured for many years. It became customary to accord what were designated as carload rates — based upon the hundredweight as the unit — on many other commodities when shipped in car- load lots, the prime distinction between carload and less than carload shipments being that the former are loaded by the shipper and unloaded by the consignee, while the latter, as a rule, are delivered at the freight house by the shipper, unloaded and placed in the cars by the em- ployees of the railroad: at the place of consignment they are likewise unloaded from the cars and placed in the wagons by the employees of the railroad. The lower cost of handling freight that moved thus in car- loads, together with the assurance of a full load per car, led to the making of a lower relative rate for a car- load than a less than carload shipment. The carload rate upon such commodities was not only specified as so much per loo pounds, but to insure that it would not apply upon less than a reasonably full load, the minimum load for which that rate would apply was also specified. Such carload rates were at first granted upon cordwood, coal, lime, cement, and such other commodities as could be loaded by a shipper in an empty car placed for his exclusive use upon a " team " track. Later, as spur tracks were built from the railroad tracks to mines, mills, and warehouses, it became customary to make lower relative rates for carload than for less than carload ship- ments on the commodities loaded into the empty cars placed upon such spur tracks. Thus it came about that tariffs contain two columns, in one of which is listed the LCL, or less than carload rate per lOO pounds, and in the other the CL, or carload rate per loo pounds, with the minimum carload weight. To find the freight charge on an article offered for Early Tariffs and Classifications 155 shipment, a freight agent, therefore, looks first at the classification, where he finds in what class it is grouped ; then from the tariff he ascertains the rate applying on commodities of that class, and if the offering be of a carload, finds out whether or not a rate by the carload is designated. The development of the classifications and rate ad- justments outlined in this chapter is that which took place, speaking broadly and generally, between the build- ing of the first railroads and the development of through traffic succeeding the Civil War. During the initial steps of this development, the practices of one railroad had no immediate and direct effect upon those of an- other; competition was remote; each railroad developed its classifications and rates for itself. CHAPTER X EARLY RIVALRIES AND THE BEGINNING OF THROUGH SERVICE By about 1850 many of the railroads extending into the interior had penetrated territory whence traffic could move via either one or another railroad to the coast, and, indeed, at many places railroads reaching from different and naturally rival seaports had met at junction points in the interior. The rivalry of the seaports necessarily implicated their respective railroads and thus arose kJaUctloa competition between them. Contiguous stations, on rival railroads, through either of which traffic to and from the intervening region could flow without physical in- convenience to shippers or consignees, in many cases were given the same rates to and from the seaboard. Between the seaboard and an interior junction it was necessary that rates by competing lines be the same. 156 Beginning of Through Service 157 Thus arose modifications of the " distance tariff," similar to those that doubtless had previously been ef- fected by competition between a railroad and a river or canal. If the longer line between the seaboard and the junction did not make the same rate as the shorter line it would carry none of the traffic. To make the rate equal to that by the shorter line meant to abandon the distance basis of multiplying the rate for one mile by the number of miles. In making the same rate from its sea- port to the junction point as applied by the shorter line from its seaport, the longer line was compelled, in many Jnactioji JkEeonedlate ^ Point ' cases, to make a lower rate to the junction point than it had theretofore made to stations not so far away. Therefore, if it continued to charge the former rate to an intermediate station, it would carry traffic for a longer distance at a lower rate than for a shorter distance. If it reduced the rate to the intermediate station the revenue secured on traffic to and from that station would be diminished, even if the traffic to a,nd from that station was not directly affected by the competition of the shorter line. The managers of the longer railroad could not but reflect that inasmuch as the rates to the intermediate 158 Railroad Freight Rates stations were those that had normally been charged theretofore, there was no reason that their revenue, al- ready diminished by the reduction forced in the rates between the junction point and the seaport, should be the further lessened by a reduction which they were not obliged to make in the rates to and from the intermediate stations. The residents, and particularly the merchants, at the intermediate stations naturally reasoned that if the railroad company could afford to reduce the rate on traffic between the seaport and the farther point, it could afford to make at least the same rate to the inter- mediate stations to and from which the haul was not so ■ — = JnnctionS Inleisnediate* Station Seapor^^^ ^ Seaport^^^^^^^^ ^^P % ==!^^^^^^5S^ ■- 3 El "5 -T /5 ■- t« '-I => rt O o w <: w u CO t— I gg S 2 2 ^js O O o «-' aJl3 O O t, a .2f rr O Public Sentiment and Hepburn Bill 287 tablished lower than local rates that the corporate cream- eries may draw cream from wide areas. The complaints as to fruits and vegetables in Group V are largely as to peaches to the North from various points in Georgia, as to the rates on citrus fruits from Florida to the North in competition with similar fruits from California, and as to the rates on vegetables in competition with the vegetables from Mississippi and Louisiana. The Commission found the rates on oranges and pineapples to be reasonable, except that it estab- lished certain carload rates to the Northeast. It reduced certain rates on vegetables to the northeastern markets, but found other rates on fruits and vegetables to the cities of the Northeast and north of the Ohio River to be reasonable. Miscellaneous Raw Materials (see Table I). — No one of these complaints is of more than minor importance. It is especially noteworthy that cotton, the great staple of the South, produces but two complaints, both of which were dismissed. That in Group V is as to the rates from Lorman, Miss., to New Orleans and to Boston as compared with the rates from Port Gibson, a trifling matter that was adjusted and set aside. The complaint in Group VIII is as to the rates on raw cot- ton from points in Texas, and Oklahoma, to Kansas City, as compared with the rates on cotton fabrics; but the Commission held that the existing rates were not unreasonable. Miscellaneous Manufactures (see Table II). — The only comiplaint of passing importance was caused by different rates being charged on different kinds of brick. The Commission ordered that rates on firebrick, building brick and paving brick be the same, stating that from a trans- portation standpoint the value of the brick or the purpose for which it would be used would not be considered. This decision is contrary to the widely applied principle of charging according to the value of the service which, in the case of other commodities, has been directly recognized by the Commission. The brick manufac- 288 Railroad Freight Rates S. ■d Q •UAiBjpmiAl puB pasiui -ojdmoD JO p3;sn[pv •p3uod;sod iCpjiuyapu; jouMBjpqjiA ■psssiuisiQ luBupiduiog JO ' JOABJ ui pappaQ & O O 3 o H Id i3 o XJ X C/2 W O w <; w (_> § S fO to M o « o o o o o o o -^-^ \0 O O ''d* O CO CO O O 11 fO o »o O O O Tf o « y^ O O O O O M h-i »o O O O M O t^ o o o o o o o O O O •-< O »Ov£) ro M CO t^ lO CO W O iH « rO O O O O O O O O O w -^ lO 0m 1^.00 o o o o o o o o CLi CI c =^ o i2 S o o o -r-H ra a = 3 2 H-1 o u CA o H JUOH o o'C " f-* I^ l-l ^-» •^ 4-1 ^ m" C.S e H - I— I o ™ n) j; o O G CJ ^ •4-1 '^ rt •^ c_ HmKo •~ — ■« Is CD « 3^ . g S c •u) - a,_,fH _g cdP5 4;;=: rr; -— to at 3 ' ft tH «S i-* ■ti ii 2 i; n! ■^D if" (J ft"3S cow %Qi Public Sentiment and Hepburn Bill 289 turer, who was the complainant in the particular case that brought forth this decision, subsequently pro- tested that it worked injustice to his business and the case was opened for further argument. An example of the application of the principle which the decision in this case ignored is that which arose in Indiana at the time of the waning of natural gas in the district to which glass and tinplate factories had been attracted by the presence of this fuel. These industries made "an ex- position to the railroads showing that they would not be obliged to remove to other locations if they could ob- tain coal to take the place of the disappearing natural gas. The price which they could afford tp pay, however, would necessitate the transportation charge being mate- rially reduced. The railroads, to enable the factories to continue in operation, that they might obtain the traffic in their finished products and in the supplies used by the communities dependent upon them, materially reduced the rate upon coal for their consumption without re- ducing the rates upon the same coal from the same fields to the retail dealers who sell it for domestic consump- tion or to the companies operating the trolley and elec- tric light lines. The latter consumers at once made com- plaint, but the Indiana State Railroad Commission finally upheld the discrimination on the part of the railroads as justifiable. The complaints as to the rates on cotton piece goods in Group VIII are from merchants of Wichita, who seek concessions that will enable them to extend their wholesale markets. The two complaints as to rates on furniture are from a new factory in Mississippi that de- sires to extend its markets. lumber, Coal, and Oil (see Table II). — Lumber is really the only article of commerce upon which the rates of freight are in turmoil. The rapidly changing sources of supply, necessitating a continual readjustment of the freight rate structure, will account in a great measure for this instability. Although substantially the same number of complaints 2 go Railroad Freight Rates nS ( o3 wow OOwOO OOw t Q »H •UMBjpqjIM. puB pasiui -OJduiob « w rt OWOOO OOw JO psjsnfpv < •pauodjsod Aiajiugaput £ O O O JOUAVBjpqjIM H rn 'passixusiQ laBUIBjduiOQ JO JOABJ wow ui pappaa -3 o rj* w lo CIC4C4WM «ww H X O C OOwOO OOw X O w 1- ONOOO oo« 1— < t> 1 , o >— ( • 1-H > O O C OOOOO OOO > O o c wOOOO «o« > O c OOOOO OOO H > o o c w o O O OOW 1— 1 O c OOOOO OOO t— 1 GOO OOO*-""-* OOW H- 1 DOC OOOOO OOO co -a ■ • • 1 W 13 • ■ w H m t^ : '. ^ O t3 o "S : : t— ) o o ^ o • • ►— 1 o eJ O tfl Pi ■ w p^ ^ : £S w Si S'S : ►J to o o > ffi o < < > o c Q < a c L 1 i, w. 1 c Between S Electric Cotton Se Public Sentiment and Hepburn Bill 291 have developed on coal as on lumber, they have not nearly so great an effect upon the coal rate structure, as a whole. Certain mines in Maryland claim that they are charged a higher rate to the seaboard than certain other mines in Pennsylvania which are farther away. The Commission ruled that a lower rate should be applied on thin vein than on thick vein coal from the same dis- trict or even the same mine. Exception is taken in Group III to as high a rate on cannel coal as on ordi- nary bituminous coal. Several complaints in Group VIII have arisen from the rapidly shifting competition of coal fields in this region. One dealer complains that a reduction of 50 cents per ton, made during July and August to stimulate shipment and storage during the dull season, discriminates against the small dealers, as the dealer with capital can accumulate coal at this rate which he can sell at a later period at 50 cents a ton lower than the man whose capital will only permit him to pur- chase coal for immediate sale. The complaints as to the rates on oil are of the National Petroleum Association, and applied as to the rates in general on petroleum and its products, especially in the region north of the Ohio and east of the Missouri Rivers. They were dismissed by the Commission as being too sweeping, not sufficient evidence being presented to en- able it to pass upon any specific rate. Animal Foods (see Table III). — The complaints on hay are as to the rates on that commodity from various points in Kansas to Kansas City. Through Koutes and Through Rates (see Table III). — The one case of interest is that of the electric railway company, which endeavors to establish through rates and through routes in connection with a steam railroad. The Commission ordered one of the railroads extending to the Hudson River to stop discriminating in favor of the Standard Oil Company by refusing to take oil in tank cars from Titusville to Brooklyn. The railroad claimed that, as the oil had to be delivered direct from the cars, its handling at that terminal was exceedingly hazardous and has appealed the case. 292 Railroad Freight Rates 00 P •UMBipqjm puB pasiui -ojduiob JO pa^snfpv •pauodjsod Ap;iuif3pui JOUAl'EjpqitM 'passimsiQ li") « *^ in M o w iuBureiduioQ JO ' JOABJ u; pappaQ K) M Tf " o o o w (1. § O ij < 3 o H 2 w H 3 o a VO to M 00 1-1 to X IH o o o o O 11 X O o o o o o o 1-1 M to > VO Ci M >o lO M to tOM M 00 > « M CO w O O t^ > fo t^ C4 o o to O M VO M > to o M " M M M 00 > M M o o O O M t-H 00 o o « o « toi/» M 1-H VO M VO o o M o M r^ (— ( o o o o o O o o > Pi W w < IS W Q u 2 a :tA ■ d • : g :« :u :-y .2 c ■ "u U w !/3 M :c« "'II "" : Su rtw : §^H>4-i ■ U. rti a c g rt -ert^ Si^ o m C cj 13 o -S i5 n »j ° 4j rt rt o, o Public Sentiment and Hepburn Bill 297 the absence of nearly all of the great commercial centers of the country. It includes Indianapolis, New Orleans, Minneapolis, Denver and Kansas City, but even in these cases, with the exception of Indianapolis, it is certain particular rates that are complained of and not the gen- eral rate structure affecting the commerce of the city. The list does not include Boston, New York, Philadel- phia, Pittsburg, Baltimore, Richmond, Savannah, Atlanta, Cleveland, Cincinnati, Chicago, St. Louis, Galveston, San Francisco, Portland. It embraces a dozen or so of the smaller towns and cities of the South and West, but not one of the thousand or more towns of similar or greater importance in various parts of the country. Throughout the tabulations the earlier developed re- gions of the North and East show the effect of the wars of rates and treaties of peace which led to the exist- ing rate adjustments that are of great stability and give general satisfaction. The region from Maine to Illinois produced fewer than one-fifth of the total number of these complaints, although its railroads move more than one-half of the tonnage of the country. That Group VIII should have produced the greater portion of com- plaints is logical, as it includes the new State of Okla- homa and the surrounding States where activity in gen- eral is still at the boiling stage. Here the railways have been extended and intertwined in the last dozen years with a rapidity so great that the exact adaptation of their freight rates to the developing commerce of the region is still in process. Although the total number of complaints in a way rep- resents the measure of the grievance felt by the ship- pers against the railroads, it is the measure in which these complaints are adjudged to be well founded that more nearly tests their reasonableness. It is therefore significant that on April 11, 1908, of the formal com- plaints filed with the Commission during the sixteen months ending December 31, 1907, the number disposed of in favor of the defendant railroads exceeded by more than 33 per cent, the number decided in favor of the 298 Railroad Freight Rates t HI o ■S Q CO to OvOMMrorN.'«tTf « ^ CO lOCO ■UMEjpqilM puB pasi'ui -ojdmob JO p3;sn[pv lO M Tj-VD eo M N 00 < •p3uod}sod Apjiuyapui J0UAVEJpq}I/VV 'passiuisiQ «o « COtOONOt^iOtO WW M TOM Ht juBure[duioo JO ' JOABJ m pappsQ VO w MM M CO »< P o o < 3 O H S 3 o 00 M IOC30 M -<:J- M N IH M C* CO X M ^COOtHiOMW « x: CO 1-1 MCOi-iMlOcO"^ W t— 1 t— 1 > ON CO v£> t^ Tt Tj- M VO 00 VO - M CO -^ lO t 1— t > o OMOONt^C 1- c > O M vo t^ o CO Tj-^O r- M H 1/ 5 CO ' M 6 > M W COCNOOOOOVC MM M \£ > o O mw^OmOWO « 1=1 CO lOt^OOI^iO*^ M C^ l-H ON O OOlOOWOt^M M ^ t— 1 Ht N OOOOOOC > W ►J I2 C < < C U P :> H H H H -4 t; J i it t: c c O u terial Miscellaneous Manufac- tures Lumber, Coal and Oil. . . Animal Foods Community Complaints. . Incidental Service Totals 1 c 1 c c 1 Ci Express and Sleeping Car Companies, Passenger Fares, etc Public Sentiment and Hepburn Bill 299 complainants. If the same ratio of disposition holds throughout the cases not then decided, the greater part of the 425 complaints will have gone against the complain- ants. The considerable number of cases remaining unde- cided at the date of the examination indicates no lack of industry on the part of the Commission. The complaints listed in the tables are those entered upon the docket and not those submitted for decision. After the mak- ing of the complaint an extended period often unavoid- ably elapses before the hearings are held, the evidence and arguments presented, all of which constitute a neces- sary preliminary to the formal submission to the Com- mission for its decision. A great deal of the work is done not directly by members of the Commission, but by " special examiners," men of comparatively small salary, who are sent to different parts of the country to hear cases, and they often write the decisions, the Commissioners being so pressed with work that every case cannot fully receive their direct attention. It is not intimated that the efficacy of the Commission as a tribunal for the adjustment of complaints between shippers and the carriers is disclosed in its entirety by the foregoing analysis. As an intermediary and con- ciliatory agency it brings about an agreement in many cases where there has been a difference of opinion before that difference assumes the character of a dispute. This analysis of the complaints made to the Commission dur- ing a fairly extended period in which there was every reason to expect that every formidable or longstanding disagreement would be presented to it, certainly does not indicate any radical fault in the freight rate structure of the railroads of the United States. Even when there is a difference between a shipper and a railroad as to what constitutes a proper rate, the margin of difference is usually narrow. These differences, when applied to all the shipments which they concern, may aggregate, in the course of a year, a large sum, and the sum total of the differences arising throughout a period of years 300 Railroad Freight Rates a sum that, although enormous, is an infinitesimal frac- tion of the aggregate payments made by all of the ship- pers to all of the railroads. The proportion borne by the complaints made to the Commission to the aggregate transactions "between the shippers and the carriers is no more than the proportion borne by the cases that come before the justices of the peace to the conduct in general of the inhabitants of an orderly community. Even in an orderly community, however, it cannot be said that justices of the peace are not essential to its well-being. That there should be a tribunal to which a shipper may have recourse as a last resort goes without saying. Its very existence tends toward a diminution of injustice, to the exercise of greater care on the part of the transportation companies in adjusting their charges. A most useful function of the Commission, acting as an impartial body, has been to disabuse the mind of many a. complainant that he had a real griev- ance. Another function of inestimable value to the rail- roads is that the Commission can settle a contention, such as not infrequently arises, wherein they are between the upper and the nether millstone of opposing interests, and powerless to effect an adjustment without bringing upon them the ill-will of one or the other party and often a consequent loss of revenue. CHAPTER XX THE INFLUENCE OF THE COMMISSION TOWARD UNIFORMITY OF PROCEDURE THE SYSTEM OF ACCOUNTS Although the main items of a balance sheet of one railroad company are necessarily very much the same as those of another, there is room for difference of opinion, sometimes even as to what constitutes an asset and what a liability, as to whether one amount is properly charge- able to profit and loss, or another to surplus. In that classification, whether of receipt or expenditure antece- dent to the aggregation of similar accounts, there is often room for wide difference of opinion as to whether a given sum should be included in this account or that. The great number and variety of purposes for which a railroad company is obliged to expend money, and the great number and variety of sources from which it receives money, necessitate a great number and variety of main accounts, each divided into secondary accounts, which are subdivided into minor accounts, which are again subdivided. Both receipts and expenditures of even a comparatively short railroad are so large that un- less the system of accounts be of logical construction and its keeping be subjected to thorough tests there is the opportunity for manipulation on the part of a skill- ful and unscrupulous accountant, which, in not its most objectionable aspect, may take the form of covering over illicit or surreptitious expenditures by their inclusion under accounts to which they bear no relation. The separate development of the railroads of the United States led to a wide diversity in their accounting systems. Through the examination of experts at the de- mand of bankers whose offices have now and then been 301 302 Railroad Freight Rates invoked for the purpose of securing additional capital, or at times of reorganization, the accounting methods of at least the principal railroad systems have been brought into such form that serious manipulation is not facile, but it is difficult, without constant supervision, to prevent the possibility of the concealment of illegitimate expenditures. From the time of its original organization, the Inter- state Commerce Commission has insisted that the pay- ment of rebates, or of commissions and gratuities to se- cure traffic, could not be absolutely prevented until all railroad companies were obHged to adhere to a uniform system of keeping accounts, and the Commission, through its authorized agents, was allowed to inspect those accounts. The Association of American Railway Ac- counting Officers, formed in 1888, throughout its various discussions has led toward uniformity in many phases of accounting, but it remained for the Hepburn law, au- thorizing the Commission to prescribe a uniform sys- tem of accounts and enforce its adoption, to bring about absolute uniformity. Immediately after the enactment of the law the Statistician of the Commission, in con- junction with the Association of Railway Accounting Officers, gave to the matter of a uniform system dis- cussion and consideration which resulted in the adop- tion, on July I, 1907, of an approximately complete ac- counting system which is now being perfected for use by all of the railroads of the United States. There is one phase of the authorization of the Hep- burn law and the action of the Commission thereunder with which the administrative officers of many of the railroads are not content. The Act specifies that not only shall the Commission prescribe a uniform system of accounts which shall be obligatory upon all of the railroads, but that no railroad shall keep any accounts or memoranda other than those prescribed by the Commis- sion. These administrative officers state that an ac- counting system under which every item of receipt or of disbursement shall be so allocated that any erroneous Influence Toward Uniformity 303 disposition may be detected, while it answers the original bookkeeping requirement of checking income and outgo and arriving at a knowledge of profit or loss and present worth, does not meet the purpose entailed upon a thor- oughly comprehensive accounting system by the develop- ments of recent years. With the extension of the rail- roads into large systems, each under centralized control, it has become impossible for any managing or directing officer to know by personal oversight that the various operations are properly and economically conducted throughout their minutiae. It is, therefore, necessary for him to have reports showing the application of material and labor for various purposes, showing the cost of each of various details of operation apportioned by units of this kind and that kind in order that expenditure for a specific purpose at one time may be compared with the expenditure for that same purpose at another time, in order that the expenditure on one division may be com- pared with the expenditure on another division, the ef- ficiency of various officials in the economical performance of their functions thus being brought to definite record. This is the statistical as contrasted with the book- keeping phase of accounting. That is, the entries of receipts and expenditures are so arranged as to afiford a test of the efficiency of operation and not alone to serve the primary purpose of an accounting system de- signed to see that all revenue due to a company is received by it, that disbursements are made only upon proper authority, and that the balance sheet is properly arrived at, which, alone, have been the points of interest to the Accounting Officers' Association and to the Com- mission. These administrative officers claim that not only is the statistical system still in process of develop- ment, but that different statistical records are needed by different railroads to meet peculiar conditions; and that a managing officer, in order to make use of statistics in the directions of greatest service to him, should be allowed to arrange and rearrange them as he may think will best suit his ends. In other words, they claim that, 304 Railroad Freight Rates as statistical systems have not, as yet, completely ma- tured on any railroad, that as they need to be varied to meet peculiar conditions, and, above all, that as they are instruments in the hands of particular men, their varia- tion to meet the requirements of those men is essential to furthering the development of efficient administration w^hich would be hampered by the crystallization of sta- tistics at this time along the lines of a prescribed and uniform code. A UNIFORM CLASSIFICATION The separate classifications, developed each for itself by the different railroads, were not the source of marked inconvenience during that period when there was little or no interchange of traffic. As through bills of lading were issued, and it became necessary to quote through rates of freight, it was a nuisance for an agent of one railroad to be obliged to trace an article on which a through rate was desired through the different classes to which it might be assigned by different railroads. Just prior to the enactment of the original Interstate Com- merce Law there were over 130 different classifications in the territory east of the Mississippi and north of the Ohio Rivers. There were not only different classifica- tions for different railroads, but an eastbound classifi- cation different from the westbound, and special classi- fications for use in different sections of this region. The ascertainment of through rates was about as perplexing an undertaking as was pecuniary adjustment in Central Europe in the days when there were approximately lOO different monetary systems in that region. The insistence in the debates in Congress and on the part of the Interstate Commerce Commission that the inconvenience and possibilities of abuse growing out of this medley of classifications should be reduced, led the railroad companies operating in the great traffic sections to take steps toward the unification of the classifications. The 130 or more separate classifications in the Trunk Line and Central Traffic Territory were merged into Influence Toward Uniformity 305 one, the Official Classification. In like manner the South- em Classification was arrived at for the railroads south of the Ohio and east of the Mississippi Rivers, and the Western Classification for the railroads west of Chicago and the Mississippi River. The adoption of the three principal classifications vastly simplified the quoting of rates and the interchange of traffic between the railroads in the respective territory in which each classification was effective. There re- mained, however, a certain confusion in the ascertain- ment of rates and the through billing of traffic between the territory of one and the territory of another classi- fication, and a perplexing variance in the incidental rules of the different classifications. These are still the source of annoyance, especially in the territory contiguous to a classification boundary. From parts of the State of Illinois, for instance, on traffic destined beyond the Mis- sissippi River, an article has to be shipped either under the Official Classification to the river and the Western Classification beyond, or by way of exception one classi- fication must apply from starting point to destination. In such cases, on traffic destined to a considerable distance beyond the river, the Western Classification is applied from the starting point. Likewise, on southbound traffic from some places in Ohio and Indiana the Southern Classification applies from the shipping points, and there are similar overlappings of the classifications at other places. At a commercial center on the boundary between classification areas there is the perplexity caused by the use of different classifications for shipments in different directions. For example, the freight agents of St. Louis use the Official Classification for eastbound, the Western Classification for westbound, the Southern Classification for southbound, and the Transcontinental Commodity Tariffs for Pacific Coast shipments. Throughout its existence the Interstate Commerce Commission has persistently called attention to the de- sirability of a freight classification that shall be uni- form for the entire United States. In 1890, as the result 3o6 Railroad Freight Rates of conferences extending- over two years between repre- sentatives of the railroads of the different sections, a uniform classification was drawn up, but not adopted, because of the belief that a sudden attempt to enforce the same rules, classes and rates throughout the different traffic regions of the United States would be injurious, not only to the railroads, but to commerce and industry. At divers times since then the railroads have discussed the feasibility of such a classification, but there have been such wide differences of opinion between the traffic officers of the different railroads as to the practicability of its formulation and possibility of its application that little has resulted from the negotiations except a realiza- tion of the difficulty. The classifications of the various sections have developed along the lines characteristic of their respective traffic. Commodities that are staple and enter largely into the traffic of one region are of minor volume in the traffic of other regions, and, there- fore, have been placed in different classes ; the railroads of one section have restricted and those of another have extended the number of carload ratings ; while difference in local practice or in the workings of many minds have resulted in certain articles being placed in one class in one section and in another class in another. The com- merce of the respective sections has, however, become adapted to the respective classifications, and the railroad companies are still fearful, not only of the effect upon their revenue, but of the disturbance to business that would follow the changes necessary to make a classifi- cation uniform for the entire country. In numerous instances an article would have to be advanced to a higher class in one section or reduced to a lower in another, often with a corresponding change in the rate. There are cases, however, in which the different as- signment of the same commodity in different classifica- tions is without apparent justification. For example, the produce dealers of New Orleans obtain dairy products from the farms along both sides of the Mississippi River. These products are differently classified in the Western Influence Toward Uniformity 307 Classification, which applies in Louisiana, and the South- ern Classification, which applies in Mississippi, with the result that butter and eggs and chickens pay different rates into New Orleans from farms that are similarly situated in all respects except that they are on different sides of the river. Almost immediately subsequent to the enactment of the Hepburn law the Interstate Commerce Commis- sion renewed its effort to bring about a uniform classi- fication, and a bill was introduced in Congress author- izing the Commission to formulate and enforce the adoption of such a classification, if this were not done by the railroads themselves within one year. The measure was not passed, the Commission and the rail- roads agreeing that the latter would make a further attempt to arrive at a practical solution of the difficulty. To this end a committee, composed of five representa- tives each, from the respective regions in which the Official, the Western, and the Southern Classifications now apply, held protracted sessions during 1907 and 1908, checking each item of the various classifications seriatim in order to arrive at a thorough understanding of the changes, concessions, and compromises that would be necessary to bring about uniformity. The committee reported that in the Southern Classi- fication there are thirteen classes, six designated by numbers and seven by letters. In all thirteen classes there are less-than-carload ratings, the total number of less-than-carload ratings being 3,503, the total number of carload ratings jy^i^ o^ 22.1 per cent, of the less-than- carload. It reported that the Official Classification has six classes designated by numbers and two classes gov- erned by rules, a total of eight classes, in seven of which are less-than-carload ratings. The total number of less- than-carload ratings is 5,852, and of carload ratings 4,235, or 72.4 per cent, of the less-than-carload. It re- ported that in the Western Classification there are five classes designated by numbers and five by letters, and that in four of the ten classes are less-than-carload rat- 3o8 Railroad Freight Rates ings. The total number of the less-than-carload ratings is 5,729, and of the carload ratings 1,690, or 29.8 per cent, of the carload. It further reports that in the South- ern Classification 33.92 per cent, of the less-than-carload ratings are in the fifth, sixth, and lettered classes; that in the Official Classification only 1.25 per cent, of the less-than-carload ratings are below the fourth class; while in the Western Classification there are no less- than-carload ratings below the fourth class. The Committee reports that it believes a uniform classification can be arrived at in time, although it can- not be foretold what the effect will be upon the revenue of the railroads or upon industry and commerce until such classification and ratings are made and placed in effect. It is certain that numerous advances, as well as numerous reductions, will be necessary to bring about uniformity, and that, as they cannot but have a great and far-reaching effect upon industry and commerce, the readjustment must be gradual and each step the result of thorough consideration. Just one example of the great number of difficulties encountered has been instanced as follows : ' It is not reasonable, for example, to expect that a condition will be easily reached in which the rate on cattle shall bear the same relation to the rate on shoes from the western ranges to Chicago, as the rates on the same commodities bear to each other be- tween New York and Boston. The comparison of the present status is as follows: Cattle, Montana to Chicago 75 cts. per 100 lbs. Shoes, Chicago to Montana $2.85 per 100 lbs. Cattle, New York to Boston 19 cts. per 100 lbs. Shoes, Boston to New York 25 cts. per 100 lbs. The rate on cattle in the one case is but one-fourth of the rate on shoes, while in the other the difference is an inconsiderable trifle. The conditions of the mar- kets demand a low rate on cattle from the ranges, but such conditions do not exist between New York and Boston, where but few cattle are shipped. Influence Toward Uniformity 309 It would seem that at the best there will need to be so many exceptions to a uniform classification as to seriously mar its uniformity. There is no doubt that the railroads are seriously at work upon the problem, their desire to solve it, if possible, being indicated by the appointment of a permanent com- mittee to work to that end. A classification, however, will not be uniform unless it is uniform in fact as well as in name. This means that if the railroads and the Commission agree upon a classi- fication and decide to make it efifective, the modified classifications adopted by several of the States for intra- state traffic will have to be withdrawn. Virginia has such a modified classification, as have Iowa, Nevada, South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, and other States. Il- linois has a published classification different from all others. The State Railroad Commission of Texas has made exceptions to the Western Classification as it ap- plies upon traffic within the boundaries of that State, and exceptions have also been made by other State legislatures and commissions to the classification apply- ing in the general traffic region of which they are part. This leads to consideration of the broad question of FEDERAL VERSUS STATE RATE REGULATION Even before the formation of through lines conse- quent upon the authorizing Act of 1866 it had become evident that the commerce of the United States, both in volume and characteristics, was becoming widely dif- ferent from that of the time when the nation was founded. The rapid development of both railroad lines and traffic has led to the present status whereunder main traffic channels, secondary, and minor traffic channels inter- lace over the entire United States, carrying raw material and finished products, and merchandise of all kinds, from sources of supply often to far-distant places of manu- facture and through widely separated centers of dis- 310 Railroad Freight iRates tribution. These traffic channels have formed under the working of the economic processes which are in no wise affected by State boundaries. In their develop- ment to meet the pressure of this traffic for movement, and to develop new traffic, the railroads have extended without regard to State boundaries. The development of through freight rate structures has, likewise, been without relation to State confines. The blanket rates of New England depend upon no State lines; the rates between the North Atlantic sea- board and the Mississippi River are centered upon a traffic base line wrought by the flow of traffic which knows not State boundaries in its course; the rate ad- justment to the west of Chicago and St. Louis has evolved out of the contention between commercial cen- ters regardless of what States they may be in. In the Southeast the action and interreaction of rail and water communication is irrespective of the lines dividing the States, and the flow of traffic to and from the Pacific Coast takes no heed of such lines. In Texas the freight rate structure has developed under the limitations pre- scribed by the State, which, however, are based upon political, rather than upon economic, foundations, and is possible because of its great size and isolated position. The development of the freight rate structures, as set forth in previous chapters, discloses how close may be the relation that one rate bears to another. It is evident that a change in but a single one of the rates that is a thread in the woof into which the freight rate structure of a region is woven, or under which moves any one of the great staple commodities of commerce, may, in its ramifications, affect every other rate in that regional structure or in that commodity rate adjustment. A rate so changed may be an interstate rate or it may be an intrastate rate. A change, for example, in the intra- state rate between St. Louis and Kansas City would change the rates between any other point on the Mis- sissippi as far north as Dubuque and any other point on the Missouri river as far north as Omaha, and, by so Influence Toward Uniformity 311 doing, would change the rates on all through traffic from points east of the Mississippi to points west of the Missouri River. A reduction in the rate on coal from Dulutli to interior points in Minnesota forces a reduction, not only from Superior, Wisconsin, but from Milwaukee, whose coal dealers compete with Duluth in the Minnesota markets. The change in a rate on grain between a station in Kansas and Kansas City may affect the rate from that and contiguous stations to Omaha, and the rates from a number of stations in Kansas to Galveston. The change in a rate between Savannah and Augusta, Ga., may change all rates between the North Atlantic seaboard and the southeastern interior. A rate adjustment, working with satisfaction over an extended area and of proved stability under test of the Interstate Commerce Commission or the courts, may be overthrown by the action of a State legislature or State Commission desiring to obtain a local advantage for the shippers of that State. A change in the local rate between a distributing center and local points in the same State may nullify an adjustment of through rates from various cities supplying those points with mer- chandise. No one of these cases is merely hypothetical. The legislature of Minnesota did make a reduction in the coal rate from Duluth. Legislatures of Kansas and Nebraska have made reductions in the State grain rates. The State Railroad Commission of Texas has offset through rate adjustments by prescribing intrastate changes. The State rates of Arkansas, and of Georgia, have, in instances, been modified to give shippers of those respective States advantages over the shippers of other States. The Railroad Commission of Oklahoma, by establishing a low tariff on lumber within the State, forced heavy reductions from adjoining lumber regions in Arkansas, Texas, and Louisiana. The local rates of the State of Indiana are in a snarl in which the Ohio intrastate rates are a factor. Not only may the change of an intrastate rate affect interstate traffic, but the physical separation of the two 312 Railroad Freight Rates kinds of traffic is practically impossible. The same trains running over the same rails may carry interstate and intrastate traffic in proportions that vary in different trains ; the services of station men, despatchers, and yard men, and train men may be given to both kinds of traffic in proportions that vary from time to time, and, likewise, with the services of the administrative officers. The average cost of moving one ton one mile is but an ap- proximation when the entire freight traffic of a railroad is taken cognizance of in the calculations. The attempt to ascertain the cost of moving one ton of intrastate traffic one mile as distinguished from the cost of moving one ton of interstate traffic one mile cannot be arrived at except by an approximation that, at the best, is enti- tled to but moderate respect. Yet, at this time, the traffic manager of every railroad traversing several States is kept in a condition of chronic perplexity in endeavoring to adjust its practice, not only to the regulations prescribed by the Interstate Com- merce Commission, but to those ordained by the various States. This division of governmental authority over the conduct of the traffic of this country is a factor of greater hindrance to its just and equitable movement than are all the conflicting customs of the different rail- roads and discordant classifications of the different re- gions combined. That no one can serve two masters is a maxim which might be amplified by the statement that two masters cannot rule one servant without contention. That strife has grown out of the mixed Federal and State regulation of freight rates is a matter of recent history. A local agent in Northfield, Minnesota, was arrested, tried and sentenced by a local judge to one hour in jail because he would not accept rates enacted by the State legisla- ture, although the enactment had been legally enjoined by a Federal judge. In North Carolina the legislature passed an Act lowering passenger rates, and also re- ducing freight rates, from 15 to 25 per cent. The United States Court issued an injunction against the enforcement Influence Toward Uniformity 313 of the order, but the State authorities disregarded the injunction and found numerous indictments against the railroad company, which had been active in obtaining it, and its agents, and for a time it did not seem un- hkely that the president and other officers of the com- pany would be imprisoned. The amazing spectacle was presented of the State deliberately driving the road out of the United States Court to which it had applied for refuge. In this case the controversy over the passenger rates was the cause of the more intense friction. Ala- bama not only legislated as to rates, but decreed that if a railroad company, chartered in another State, but doing business in Alabama, should question in a Federal court a procedure of the State legislature or of the State Railroad Commission, such corporation shall for- feit its license for doing an intrastate business in Ala- bama. In accordance with this decree the license of a principal railroad company traversing Alabama was ac- tually revoked by the Secretary of State, and not re- stored until imminent danger had arisen of a clash between the State and Federal authorities. That the States may properly exercise police author- ity over the maintenance and operation of the railroads within their respective limits cannot be disputed at this time. It may, however, not be an entirely absurd prop- osition that, inasmuch as intrastate rates and interstate rates are so closely correlated as fo form a practically indivisible rate structure, such authority as may be con- ferred upon the Interstate Commerce Commission to regulate interstate rates should, as a corollary, include the regulation of so-called intrastate rates. Indeed, it is not too much to predict that before this question is settled, the Federal Government will find itself compelled to exercise the same exclusive control over rail trans- portation that it exercises over marine transportation. CHAPTER XXI TRAFFIC EXPERTS IN THE EMPLOY OF SHIPPERS In the absence of recorded law the growth of definite and continued relations between men develops custom governing those relations which subsequently often re- ceives legislative sanction and is made the basis of legal enactment. This development is exemplified by the growth of the freight rate structures of the different traffic regions, and it was in process with the railroads when they formed traffic associations, and especially when they resorted to pooling contracts, for which it was endeavored, throughout a considerable period, to secure legal recognition. Another development that has been conspicuous during the past few years is the coming forward of interme- diaries between the shippers and the railroads, through whose instrumentality inequalities and maladjustments in the rate structures are being brought into equipoise with a decreasing resort to either courts or commissions. In these days of multiplying and intertwining railroads it is exceedingly difficult for their traffic officers to trace the effect of a change, even in one rate, throughout its various ramifications. The situation is not altogether unlike that when, in a delicately balanced iron bridge or steel tower, the changing of the strain upon one strand of cable or one beam will shift the incidence of weight throughout the entire structure. This compari- son is particularly appropriate to the effect produced by the building of a transverse railroad crossing two or more parallel lines, or, indeed, the building of any new line that, by crossing other lines, changes the pat- tern of the network, as by the introduction of a new thread. In such a case the distances by rail between towns 314 Traffic Experts 3 1 5 and cities are changed, the relation of competing markets and competing distributing centers are modified, with a resultant upheaval of the rate structure, whose pertur- bations may extend far and wide. For example, as has been pointed out in a previous chapter, the building of a railroad from Kansas City directly to the Gulf caused another line, that had been bringing grain from points in Kansas to KanSas City for eastbound shipment, to arrange a route to the Gulf, over which it sent grain in competition with the new line, the reversal of the grain currents radically changing the grain rate structure of a considerable section. When such changes occur a shipper not infrequently finds new combinations by which a rate can be made from a station on one to a more or less remote station on another line at less than the published rate. Indeed, an appreciable number of the cases in which the Inter- state Commerce Commission has awarded reparation to shippers, have arisen out of just such kinks, which are being gradually straightened out. Then, again, it is difficult for a traffic officer, dealing with the adjustment of rates on merchandise of all kinds, to trace the effect of a change in the rate on one commodity throughout the rates on all other commodities to which it bears a direct or indirect relation. It is this difficulty which gives rise to many of the problems that continually beset the classification committees. This extension and intertwining of the railroads, the ramifying of the different factors that affect the ad- justment of rates, have made the scrutiny of these rates and the estimate of their effect upon his business too complicated and specialized a task to be handled by a member of a firm or an officer of a corporation in con- nection with other duties. Many a corporation and many a firm that is an extensive receiver and an extensive shipper of freight, therefore, employs a " traffic man," whose principal duty once was to bargain with the rail- roads for rates, obtaining rebates when he could, but whose time and energy nowadays are largely absorbed in 3i6 Railroad Freight Rates keeping continually familiar with the tariff sheets of the different railroads, in watching the ramifications of any change in rates in order that he may take advantage of an adjustment that may favor the interests of his em- ployers, and endeavor to obtain a revision of an ad- justment that may militate against those interests. Such a traffic representative, by specializing upon the study of the rates affecting the materials and products received and shipped by his company, not infrequently obtains a more thorough and far-reaching knowledge of those rates than many, even of the traffic officers of the railroads, each of whom is concerned with the movement of all sorts of traffic under the divers tariffs affecting that traffic. Such a traffic representative of an industrial or commercial company can often trace combinations of rates and weaknesses in the rate structure applicable to his particular commodity, which the railroads are glad to have called to their attention. It is from such men that the information in previous chapters concerning the relation of the transportation charge to prices on the principal products of manufacture has been obtained. They have almost, if not quite, without an exception, said that the railroad companies are ready, as a rule, to give full and prompt consideration to the matters which they bring to their notice; that they are ready to adjust dis- crepancies, or, in cases of difference of opinion, to make a statement of the points involved as they appear to the railroads. Every shipper, however, cannot afford to employ an especial traffic representative. In every considerable city there are many establishments, each having a business which, although large, may not justify any one of them in maintaining a representative exclusively to look after traffic matters in its interest. Such shippers are coming very generally to employ, through a Chamber of Com- merce, Board of Trade, Business Men's League, Freight Traffic Bureau, or other association, a traffic representa- tive, whose duty it is to scrutinize the tariffs and watch the rates of the railroads as they affect the commerce Traffic Experts 317 of his city. A few cities had such representatives a dozen or more years ago, but their number has greatly increased in the last five years. The generally ex- pressed reason for this is that in the old days each ship- per wanted to negotiate with the railroads himself to the end that he might secure as large rebates as possible, of which no one but himself would know; but that since the enactment of the Elkins law in 1903, the en- forcement of which makes rebates on interstate traffic impossible, the shippers of each city find it desirable to work together. The duties of a traffic representative of a city and of the traffic representative of a particular firm or corporation are similar, but there is the vast difference that while the latter serves but one master, the former has several. In behalf of his clients he studies the tariffs, watching changes in rates. The members of the association through which he is em- ployed advise with him in regard to the rates of freight as affecting their respective business, put before him what they consider to be grievances, and consult with him as to the possibility of obtaining changes in rates and classifications. The traffic representative proceeds, as an attorney, analyzing grievances, and examining ap- plications for changes in adjustments before approaching the railroads. The history of the Freight Traffic Bureau has not been the same in every city. At many places the rail- roads have welcomed the offices of a traffic representa- tive as those of an expert intermediary tending to con- serve the relations existing between the shippers and the carriers. In other cities, however, the railroads at first declined to recognize these functionaries, saying that as their business is directly with the shippers their negotia- tions must also be directly with the shippers. This atti- tude, of course, is, in its essence, without justification, as the shippers have the same right to employ a traffic representative as they have to employ a legal represent- ative. The conduct of the traffic representative, how- ever, has often been such as to bring about this attitude. 3i8 Railroad Freight Rates Here and there he has filled the newspapers with ac- counts of how the railroads discriminate against the city, and has approached their traffic officers with the overbearing manner of one who will obtain what he is after whether or no. This type of the traffic representa- tive is prone to keep the air filled with complaints against the railroads in order that his constituents may think he is guarding their interests and earning his salary. Many of the causes which, all unwittingly on the part of the railroads, may lead to inequalities in the rates affecting a city have been pointed out, and these they are ordinarily prompt to remedy when attention is directed to them. The pressure of the different influ- ences which have made the rate structures what they are has, however, necessarily borne unevenly. It has forced the lowest rates along the lines of greatest traffic movement, and where there has been water or other forceful competition. This varying incidence of economic demand in connection with the discordant decrees of State legislatures and State Commissions has caused, at certain places in divers sections, an unevenness in the rate adjustment that may be compared to the roughness at the bottom of a river whose rocky bed contains cor- rugations over which the current flows, but that resist its erosive power. In such cases there are often features of the rate adjustment that cause complaint in an im- mediate locality, but which the railroads do not desire to change because of the ramifying effect that would derange the flow of traffic in more important currents. It would be as though an attempt were made to even the bed of the river by blasting out the rocks, but the effect of which would be to break down the banks of the river with a resulting greater disturbance in the flow of the current. A striking example of the situation referred to thus generally exists at Indianapolis, and will be described in a following chapter. It should also be borne in mind that in the absence of other adjustments the rates on commodities are deter- mined by the regular tariffs and the regular classifica- Traffic Experts 319 tions. The pressure of a large volume of traffic or of competition of whatever kind forces reductions. A rate thus reduced and applying on a particular commodity in a considerable traffic channel may be much lower than the regular classification rate for a similar distance where the movement of that commodity may be infre- quent and inconsiderable. That is, to use extreme ex- amples, the rate on raw cotton from Memphis to Savan- nah is much less than the rate on raw cotton from Los Angeles to San Francisco; the rate per ton on iron ore from Ashtabula to Pittsburg much less than the rate on iron ore from Des Moines to Little Rock. The rates upon which little or no traffic moves are known among the railroad men as " paper rates." It is an easy matter for a man to collect a bundle of tariffs and, by picking out a lot of paper rates, make a superficial demonstration that his city is the victim of discrimination. There are traffic representatives who employ a portion of their time in this very procedure. Still another situation is presented in a large city of an interior State. The President of the Chamber of Commerce, a man of sane conservatism, capable of see- ing both sides of a question, frankly says that while the railroad rates are not in every case exactly as he would like them, he thinks the railroads are doing the best they can to smooth out inequalities and that they should not be the object of persecution. This man is the head of a large business and an extensive shipper. It hap- pens, however, that the Chairman of the Transportation Committee of that Chamber of Commerce, a broker of but slight practical contact with traffic matters, is what the railroad men designate as a " fire-eater," unsparing in his attacks upon railroad rates and railroad methods in general. The traffic representative of that Chamber of Commerce at the time of his appointment was rather inclined to work along the lines of his immediate superior, the Chairman of the Transportation Committee. The railroads would have none of it. In time he moderated his demeanor and it is now his own testimony that the 320 Railroad Freight Rates railroads, as a rule, are willing and ready to give cour- teous consideration to any proposition he makes to them, and that the freight rates affecting the commerce of his city on the whole are satisfactory. It is noteworthy that the traffic representatives of the large firms and the great corporations, as well as the traffic representatives of the shippers' associations of the various cities, are, in nearly all instances, men who have been trained in the railroad service, and are fa- miliar with traffic conditions and the construction of rates and rate sheets. In very many cases these men have been taken directly from positions in the railroad service by the offer of higher salaries and find no jiiffi- culty in conducting intercourse with the railroad com- panies on the dignified basis that elicits mutual respect. In other instances these representatives are men who, for one reason or another that oftentimes has not re- flected in the least upon either their character or ability, have not been in the transportation service at the time of their selection, but are entirely efficient in the sphere to which they have been chosen. In exceptional cases, however, an officer or an employee of a railroad com- pany, discharged for cause, has enlisted in behalf of a shippers' association, and actively taken up the cudgels against his former employer. With all its incidental evils, however, it is happily evident that the conduct of negotiations on behalf of the shippers of the country with the railroads by traffic rep- resentatives, made expert by their training in the railroad service, and study of the situation on behalf of their clients, is leading, and will lead in increasing degree, to the attainment, not only of amicable relations between the shippers and the carriers, but of a status mutually satisfactory to both. A traffic representative having the confidence of the shippers of his city can analyze complaints before they are presented to the railroads, and, by explaining to his cHents the nature of those that are without foundation, can save their being brought to the attention of the rail- Traffic Experts 321 road officers at all. That their efforts are often used in this direction is testified to by the railroad officials themselves. When direct resort to the railroad com- panies does not bring redress of what is considered to be a well-founded grievance, and resort to the Interstate Commerce Commission or other tribunal finally be neces- sary, it can be made upon a clearly defined issue. It happens in that city which produces a greater ton- nage than any other in the United States that the re- lations between the shippers and railroads are amicable to an extraordinary degree. This good feeling has been brought about in a large measure by the Traffic Club, formed for the purpose of promoting acquaintance be- tween the traffic representatives of the large manufac- turing establishments and the traffic representatives of the railroads, it being thought that through acquaintance and calm discussion would be attained by the shippers and by the railroads a knowledge of the view point of each, and that this would lead to harmony. The shippers who are represented in the Traffic Club, however, are the concerns of great production, each having a representa- tive who gives his entire attention to its transportation interests. The similar needs of the smaller manufactur- ing and mercantile establishments are met by the Mer- chants' and Manufacturers' Association, whose achieve- ments, through methods inaugurated by its traffic man- ager, who used both energy and urbanity in solving the problems that confronted him, have been so remarkable that they are chronicled here in some detail. A fundamental discussion of the freight rates indicated that many members of the Association were lacking in comprehensive knowledge of the adjustments. It was found that ostensible inequalities did not work to the prejudice of the city — indeed, that in at least one case an apparent disadvantage on the whole inured to its benefit — and that the rates on the raw material consumed in and the products manufactured by the city were en- tirely equitable in almost every instance. Real grievances were promptly adjusted by the railroad companies, who 322 Railroad Freight Rates also made certain modifications that were requested in classifications. It was ascertained that the wholesale dealers of the city, although enjoying freight rates as favorable as those of competing commercial centers, were not selling mer- chandise in as large volume in some parts of the com- petitive area ; that in many cases shipments did not reach their destination in this area until 24 or even 48 hours after shipments from rival commercial centers at no greater distance. This led to the Association arrang- ing that each of its members enclose a postal card with the invoice of each shipment to a customer. The cus- tomer would note upon the card the number of days the shipment had been in transit and whether it was received in satisfactory condition, and return the card to the traffic manager of the Association. In the course of a year nearly 20,000 of these postal cards were re- ceived by the Association and classified according to the towns from which they were received. When it was exceptional that a shipment took an undue time in transit complaint was not made to the railroad, but when such long time in transit was the rule, inves- tigation was made to ascertain the cause. It was found that, for instance, freight for a given destination was loaded in the same car with shipments destined to other points and transferred at an intermediate junction, this unloading, waiting for a car and loading again, con- suming time. In many of such cases a railroad company was induced to run a car — RQ, as it is termed, regard- less of quantity of load — through to the place of destina- tion, thereby avoiding the delay of transfer from one car to another. The Association would notify its mem- bers of the inauguration of such through car service and ask them to endeavor to provide traffic sufficient to justify its continuance. The merchants, thereupon, would, for a period, concentrate the efforts of a number of their traveling men in the region served by the through car, their solicitation on the strength of the improved service not infrequently resulting in additional cars being placed in service. In the case of outlying cities Traffic Experts 323 and towns, each of which could be reached by two or more routes, it was sometimes found that tonnage suf- ficient to justify the maintenance of an especial through car could be secured if the merchants would send all of their shipments via one route. In cases where shipments did not continue at a rate sufficient to justify the service of an especial car every day, the railroads would agree to provide such a car every second day or twice a week, in rare instances even only once a week, the shippers agreeing to forward their consignments on the days of the special service. The consignees preferred such an arrangement notwithstanding that their receipts were in- termittent, it being to their advantage to have regular days for receipt and that their shipments be not subject to the handling necessitated by transfer. It sometimes happened, in the case of a railroad receiving freight at two or more stations, that an aggregate shipment, suf- ficient to justify a special car to a destination of even minor importance, could be obtained if the merchants would concentrate their deliveries at one station. It was sometimes found that consignees would fre- quently report freight as being 24 or 48 hours late, although the records of the railroads showed that it had promptly reached its destination, it developing that the fault was with a consignee's drayman, who had allowed the freight to remain unnecessarily long at the station. Other cases of delay were due to the inadequate indica- tion of the address ; packages often being badly or im- properly marked, or even not marked at all. Such dere- lictions were brought to the attention of the members of the Association, who explicitly instructed shipping clerks to avoid repetition. Both the merchants of the city and the railroads were agreeably surprised at the results obtained from the im- proved service, which owed its inauguration to the As- sociation, their traffic with any one of several cities and towns being increased from 50 to 600 per cent. These results clearly indicated that whatever had been the short- comings on the part of the railroads they pertained not to rates, biit to service, which the railroads were only too 324 Railroad Freight Rates glad to improve when the directions in which improve- ments could be made were indicated to them. The work of the Association was directed, not only toward the facilitating of outbound shipments, but to im- provement in the handling of inbound shipments. It co-operated with the railroads, who found that the freight received at the local freight houses was often allowed to remain an undue time on the platforms, the merchants preferring to incur storage charges to taking it promptly away. The attention of the merchants was called to the fact that this resulted in freight being piled up to a height of fifteen or sixteen feet, and that it often had to be handled over and over again to obtain par- ticular shipments in the bottom or middle of stacks, the liability to damage thereby being increased and delay caused to drays and wagons in waiting. The shippers agreed to assist the railroads by taking their freight from the stations promptly and also to aid them in the move- ment of carload freight by giving prompt attention to the loading and unloading of cars placed on team tracks and industrial sidetracks. One of the many advantages secured by the co-opera- tion of the shippers in this Merchants' and Manufac- turers' Association was the promotion of acquaintance- ship among its members, many being brought into cor- dial and helpful relationship who had been in business for many years, often in the same neighborhood, with but the barest acquaintance. In earlier chapters has been indicated the relation that the freight rates bear to the movement of the prin- cipal raw materials, and have been outlined the regional rate structures under which distribution is made through the commercial centers of manufactured products and merchandise in general. The attitude of each city to- ward the freight rate adjustment, as it affects the in- dustries and commerce of that city, is disclosed by the results of a survey made during the period extending from February, 1907, throughout October, 1^6$. CHAPTER XXII THE COMMERCE OF THE CITIES The commerce of a city, as well as of any other traffic district, naturally divides into three classes: first, that in the commodities which it produces for market elsewhere ; second, that in the commodities which it must bring from elsewhere for consumption within its limits ; and third, that in the commodities for which it is a distributing center, those which both come from elsewhere and are marketed elsewhere. A fair con- sideration of the eflfect of the freight rates upon the commerce of a city must, therefore, take into account, not simply the extent to which they facilitate or hinder the movement of a fractional part of the traffic, but the total effect of the rate adjustment upon the total com- merce. Of the three classes of traffic the first is the most im- portant, for if a community cannot find adequate mar- ket for that which it produces it will not be able to purchase that which it needs. The first class is also the most important, not only as affecting the prosperity of a city, but as affecting the material welfare of the nation, for a prime factor in that material welfare is the facility with which the people of all communities may obtain the products which they require. The sec^ ond class of commerce is also of importance to the nation, as a whole, for another prime factor in its ma- terial welfare is the facility with which the products of different communities find markets. In other words, that articles of material need shall be produced is the first consideration, and that they shall be conveyed to those who need them is a consideration that is almost, if not quite, as important as the first. The test of a system of freight rates from the point of view of the entire 32s 326 Railroad Freight Rates nation is, therefore, the extent to which it affords facility or hindrance to the production and consumption of commodities on the part of the whole population, the extent to which distribution is facilitated among the people of the whole nation. Viewed in this broad aspect, it makes little difference to the nation as a whole whether the people of a given community make their purchases from one or another retail merchant, or whether the retail merchants of a certain area obtain their stocks from one or another equally convenient and serviceable wholesale center. It makes a vast difference, however, to a retail merchant whether the residents of the com- munity purchase their suppHes from him or from a rival, and it makes a vast difference to the wholesale dealers of a commercial center whether the retail merchants of a considerable area obtain their stocks from them or from the competing wholesale dealers of a rival dis- tributing center. That is, while the requirements of an extended population can be met as well, within limits, through one as through another series of distribu- ting centers, the merchants of each distributing center are at all times desirous to increase their business and, therefore, to extend the radius of their markets. When the freight rate adjustment gives, or apparently gives, the wholesale dealers of one city an advantage, or an apparent advantage, over the competing wholesale deal- ers of a rival city, pressure is brought to bear upon the railroads for a readjustment of the rates. It has, there- fore, often come about that the rate adjustment af- fecting a city as a distributing center, — that is, in the marketing of goods obtained from other places and sold at other places which, from a broad economic standpoint, is of less importance than either of the other two classes of its commerce, — has subjected the freight rates to the greatest stress because of the immediate importance of that adjustment to its wholesale merchants. As the railroads followed the westerly extending pop- ulation, the great cities of the North Atlantic seaboard Commerce of the Cities 327 sought to retain the distributive function. As the rail- roads were built beyond the western termini of the Trunk Lines, those termini endeavored to prevent the through shipment of merchandise that their dealers might continue to profit by having it pass through their warehouses. A most conspicuous example was at Erie, where the citizens en masse endeavored to prevent phys- ical connection between the tracks of the railroad con- necting that city with the East and the railroad being constructed from that city toward the West; the ensu- ing riot, known as the Erie War, not being quelled until there was the interposition of Federal power. Rivalry between commercial centers and towns aspiring to be- come commerical centers, as bitter in spirit although not so forcible in manifestation, has followed the develop- ment of the country step by step as it has progressed beyond the Missouri River. This rivalry, through the influences which it has brought to bear upon the rail- roads, has been, as shown in the chapter devoted to the regional rate structures, a prime factor in the moulding of those structures. The manner in which the rate structure of the region affects the commerce of each of the principal industrial and commercial centers of that region will now be considered. Where the relation of the freight rates to the products brought into a city for its consumption and to the products manufactured by a city for market elsewhere have been indicated in pre- vious chapters, reference to these classes of its com- merce will be omitted here, and consideration given alone to the rate adjustment as affecting its status as a dis- tributing center. THE NORTH ATLANTIC SEABOARD The commerce of the City of Boston is fairly typical of that of any one of the score or more of important towns of southern New England. Under the rate struc- ture which brings raw material to every one of these 328 Railroad Freight Rates towns at the same rate, and takes out manufactured prod- ucts at the same rate to the consuming population west of the Alleghany Mountains, placing the entire district upon practically the same basis as to the charge to and from these markets that applies to and from the com- peting region of which New York and Philadelphia are the focal centers, it would be singular if there were not general satisfaction on the part of the manufacturers and merchants with the rates of freight. That there is such general satisfaction was disclosed by interviews with leading men in every line of industry extending over a period of three weeks. The only suggestion that even savored of complaint was from a manufacturer of rubber goods, who thought he should have a carload rate to Chicago. This satisfaction does not apply to the export grain rate, which is the same as to 'New York; , the Boston grain dealers being much opposed to the dif- 'ferential rate enjoyed by Philadelphia and Baltimore, which was fixed at its present status by arbitration of the Interstate Commerce Commission. To the extent that the freight rates of the railroads affect their commerce in general, New York, Philadel- phia and Baltimore, the other principal cities of the North Atlantic seaboard, together with the thriving cities and towns that are thick in the intervening territory, have as little cause for complaint as Boston. These cities, the Eastern termini from which extended the first through lines toward the West, were the beneficiaries of the competition that raged between the Trunk Lines and resulted in giving them the lowest through rates on raw material inbound and on manufactured products out- bound that exist in the United States. The fact that no one of these cities appears as a complainant against the railroads during the period of the analysis of the docket of the Interstate Commerce Commission set forth in a previous chapter, indicates that their shippers are aware of their favored status, and this was almost inva- riably the testimony of the considerable number whose expressions were sought. Commerce of the Cities 329 BUFFALO The Great Lakes are navigable from the western shores of Lake Superior to where the eastern flow is over the Niagara precipice. Its location to the west of this obstruction made Buffalo the most prominent lake port in the State of New York, the city which the rail- road lines from the metropolis sought to enter. Its early prominence was as a place of reception and dis- tribution for lumber brought down the lakes. Of later years it has been the leading port through which grain brought down the lakes has been transferred for further shipment by the railroads or the Erie Canal; a port to which ore is brought from the North by boats that take anthracite and bituminous coal as return cargoes, as well as vast quantities of the merchandise manufactured in the industrial cities of the North Atlantic seaboard. The fact that it has the advantage of water transportation, and of rail rates adjusted thereto, on the staple food- stuffs from the grain and grazing grounds of the West, together with its proximity to the eastern manufactur- ing centers, accounts for the fact that Buffalo enjoys rates of freight on her articles of general consumption averaging as low as those of any city in the United States. The water carriage of grain has led to this city becom- ing a flour milling center, and to consequent rivalry with Minneapolis. The millers at the head of the lakes nat- urally desire the difference between the rates on wheat and the rates on flour kept at a narrow margin to facili- tate the distribution of flour from their mills; while the millers of Buffalo likewise naturally are in favor of the lowest rates on grain that they may obtain their raw ma- terial at a cost that will enable them to sell flour at prices that will secure its wide distribution in competition with Minneapolis. The fact that the Trunk Lines endeavored to increase the rate on flour from Buffalo to places of eastern consumption by one or two cents per 100 pounds, while the western lines made no increase from 330 Railroad Freight Rates the northwestern mills to the same points, aroused com- plaint of the Buffalo millers, in response to which the Interstate Commerce Commission restored the rates pre- viously in effect. Beginning at about the time of the Pan-American Ex- position, the commerce of Buffalo received a new stim- ulus. The diffusion of knowledge as to the many advantages of the city led to an increase in the popula- tion; the utilization of the power of Niagara brought industries. The eyes of iron masters opened to the fact that the cheapness with which ore is brought by lake to Buffalo, together with the low transportation charges on limestone, give the city an advantage in the production of iron and steel, notwithstanding that it is not so near the coal fields as Pittsburg. Hence the erection of the great plants at Buffalo, the population of the city from this source alone having increased 50,000 or more in half a dozen years. Its industrial limits have extended far beyond the belt lines that once encircled the city, upon which so many establishments have located that a large portion of the traffic is the movement from one to another mill or factory upon the same belt line. This, as the rail- roads point out, is not switching service, but a complete transportation service that saves the industries long, tedious and repeated hauling by team. In order that their charges for this service should in some degree be commensurate with its value, and especially as the cars at present in use are of far greater capacity than those of the time when the switching charges of these belt lines were established, the railroads advanced these charges, but so sharply as to create a good deal of feel- ing on the part of the shippers, who took the matter to the Public Service Commission of the State of New Yodc. This complaint as to the switching charges and the complaint of the millers as to the rates on flour seem to be the only ripples that have occurred in the Buffalo rate adjustment for many years, and they have been Commerce of the Cities 331 straightened out. There is no question that the lack of adequate yard and terminal facilities, which were evi- dent throughout the country during the high traffic pres- sure of the early years of the decade, was especially marked at Buffalo, these facilities here being under un- usual stress because the city is an important railroad terminus, a place where large quantities of freight are transferred to and fro between the vessels of the lakes and the railroad cars, and also because of the acceler- ated industrial development. The railroads are taking steps to remedy the situation, but long-standing friction between them and the city as to rights of way and loca- tion of stations apparently impede the most satis- factory solution. It would seem to be time for both the citizens and the railroads to forget the past in that co- operation which will effect the end desired by both. PITTSBURG Pittsburg owes its site to the juncture of the three rivers that once were potent in the conveyance of her commerce. When old Fort Duquesne was built on the point of land where the Allegheny and Monongahela meet and whence the Ohio takes its course, there was no por- tent of the city that would spread over the hills, or of the difficulties that would beset the development of the channels of transportation that were destined soon to outweigh by far the waterways in importance. When the first railroad was constructed along the narrow val- ley from the East, the only thought was to reach the river's edge, where connection would be made with the packets. When railroads were built toward the West, one along the terrace on one side of the Ohio River and the other along the terrace on the opposite side, there was no thought but that these railroads, and those which later were built along the rivers' shores, would suffice for such traffic as would be offered for movement to and from, as well as through the city. But before many years the limited area that lies be- 332 Railroad Freight Rates tween the hills and the rivers was covered vi^ith build- ings. The tonnage that originated in Pittsburg in- creased, the tonnage that passed through Pittsburg in- creased. The opening between the hills and the rivers was as the narrow part of an hour-glass through which con- verge trains from the East that radiate throughout the West, and trains from the West that radiate throughout the East. The mills absorbed enlarging quantities of coal, coke, ore, limestone, sand, and gave forth increas- ing quantities of bars, billets, blooms, rails, and glass. These materials and products, coal from the adjacent mines and oil from near-by refineries, pressed upon the tracks through this narrow part of the hour-glass. The circumscribed area of the city was more and more given over to business, forcing residence beyond the hills, the increasing- suburban traffic heightening the physical dif- ficulties of the railroads. Indeed, the difficulties that arose were without parallel, and the difficulties that re- main are without parallel in any other leading city of the world. The circumscribed area of lower New York forces a large suburban traffic, but there is no such heavy movement of freight. In Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, and St. Louis there is a greater or less vokime of suburban passenger traffic, but no comparable move- ment of heavy freight, and no such limitation of the available area,, the level land permitting a network of rails. In Pittsburg the heaviest freight tonnage, the heaviest through passenger traffic, and the densest sub- urban traffic press for movement upon the tracks be- tween the hills of solid rock. The place of greatest traffic pressure in the entire United States and of the greatest natural resistance to traffic movement coincide. A solution of the problem has been measurably attained through the building of tracks around the city, over which through traffic can pass from one railroad to another without going through the city proper. Such connecting tracks have been built from one railroad to another, covering longer and longer reaches in an ex- tending radius. The magnitude of the problem is dis- Commerce of the Cities 333 closed by the fact that the tonnage handled in Pittsburg exceeds in quantity the combined tonnage of New York, London, Liverpool, Hamburg and Antwerp. Pittsburg does not produce food, but in the one year of 1907 were brought for the consumption of the Pitts- burg district 240,000,000 dozen eggs, aggregating at 20 cents per dozen a value of $48,000,000; 150,000 tons of butter, aggregating a value of $45,000,000; 12,700 cars of dressed meat, aggregating in value $16,192,000; and 1,762,770 head of livestock, aggregating in value $^2,- 387,000, as well as 30,000 cars of grain and grain prod- ucts and 29,000 cars of vegetables and fruit. It is note- worthy that the consumption of eggs is double that of Greater New York, and of butter one and one-half times greater. This consumption is that of the Pitts- burg district, the region within a radius of 40 miles from the Court House, which constitutes a definite traffic area, the rates to and fro between any place within that radius and any place beyond that radius being the same. The great consumption of foodstuffs is doubtless ac- counted for by the high wages earned by the workers in the mills and mines, the need for abundant nutrition caused by the exhausting nature of their work, and in no small degree by the fact that their pleasures are largely of the table. Although vastly the greater proportion of the traffic of Pittsburg, from seventy-five to ninety per cent., is of the coarser raw materials and the heavier products of manufacture, she is also a distributing center of general merchandise, second neither to Buffalo, Cleveland nor Cincinnati, her principal competitors in this respect for the trade of western Pennsylvania, West Virginia, Ohio and Indiana. During the dozen or so years beginning in the early seventies when the Trunk Lines were fighting bitterly for the traffic between the North Atlantic seaboard and Chicago and St. Louis, the competitive through rates were often out of proportion to and sometimes actually less than those applying to and from Pittsburg, and her 334 Railroad Freight Rates citizens were in a state of chronic indignation because of the discrimination. That this status long ago ceased is proved by the noteworthy fact that with all its vast commerce not a case has been brought before the Inter- state Commerce Commission growing out of a com- plaint as to the freight rates aifecting the commerce of this city. The only case before the Commission con- cerning the city was that in which a railroad, whose sta- tion was remote from that of a brewery, endeavored to equalize its disadvantages in competition with a railroad having a station nearer the brewery, by allowance for the cartage of shipments, a practice condemned by the Com- mission. CLEVELAND AND COLUMBUS The officers of the Chamber of Commerce of Cleve- land, as well as the foremost merchants, say that that city is practically without grievance against the railroads because of the rates of freight, and has less reason for lack of satisfaction with their facilities than many other commercial centers. This does not mean that either terminals or yards are all that they ought to be, but each of the principal railroads has a large modern and thoroughly equipped yard through which the movement of traffic — exasperatingly slow as at times it may have seemed — has been fairly expeditious even during periods of great congestion in other cities. On hardware, gro- ceries, dry goods and clothing, the great staples of which Cleveland is a distributing center of importance, the freight rates permit her to compete to the fullest extent with her natural rivals, Buffalo, Pittsburg, Columbus, Cincinnati, Indianapolis, Detroit and Chicago. The dia- gram of the markets in the Chamber of Commerce shows that her wares go almost to the very portals of each of these cities. The rates on grain are so nicely adjusted that the grain merchants unhesitatingly affirm that Cleve- land receives, distributes and mills the full share which logically should come to her. The provision industry does not think that its rates on live animals from the Commerce of the Cities 335 west of Chicago, together with the rates on the animal 1 products to the East, are low enough to put that indus- ! try on an exact parity in competition with Chicago for the eastern and export trade. The railroads point out, how- ever, that the Cleveland packers have an advantage over Chicago in the case of livestock from Illinois, Indiana and Ohio; and that Chicago, Omaha and Kansas City are, for economic reasons, logically the packing centers for the livestock of the West. The rates on iron ore from the upper lake ports, and on the coal that moves in the opposite direction, are so adjusted that the traffic that comes through each of the Lake Erie ports, Erie, Ashtabula, Fairport, Cleveland, Lorain, Sandusky and Toledo, is determined by its facilities or the interests of the shippers. The adjustment of freight rates that is so favorable to the commerce of Cleveland is quite paralleled by that affecting the commerce of Columbus. There is scarcely a market in the United States with which this city does not have direct communication by rail, and it may be stated on the authority of her citizens who are most fa- miliar with traffic matters that in so far as railroad rates are concerned the commerce of Columbus is without impediment. Such commodities as are distributed throughout the city, such commodities as are manufac- tured in the city for market elsewhere, and such com- modities as are brought from without for consumption within the city, move at rates of freight of which her merchants and manufacturers make no complaint. THE SOUTHEASTERN RATES COMPLAINT The cities of Chicago, St. Louis, Louisville and Cin- cinnati have one common grievance as to freight rates which is the subject of perennial complaint. It was this complaint that was the basis of the Freight Bureau Cases in 1896, and it recently has been presented anew to the Interstate Commerce Commission. It is that the railroads leading from the Ohio River into the South- 336 Railroad Freight Rates east do not accord as low rates of freight per ton mile to certain of the southern cities as "are made to these cities by the railroads extending thereto from New York, Philadelphia, Baltimore and Richmond. The offi- cers of these railroads say that the charges on the lines from the eastern cities into the South are kept down by the rates of the coast line steamers ; that if the rates of these seaboard lines were advanced the traffic in in- creasing proportion would go from the eastern seaports by water ; that if the rates from the Ohio River into the Southeast were reduced, revenue would be diminished that even now is all too inadequate to enable the railroad companies to properly maintain and to build up their properties. Bearing upon the actual efifect upon the commerce of these cities of the present adjustment of the southern and southeastern rates, it is obvious that much of the traffic into this region from the East is without competition from these cities and the West, and that much of the traffic into this region from these cities and the West is without competition from the East. The finer fabrics, the more delicate textiles, the smaller and more intricate appliances and pieces of mechanism are shipped almost exclusively from the New York and New England districts. Grain and grain products, meat and meat products, are shipped into the South almost exclusively from the region to the north and west of the Ohio River. The expensive and luxurious vehicles find their way into the South largely from the East; wagons and agricultural implement^ from the North and West. The division of these traffic currents is caused by geographical and physical conditions, and it is also furthered by the long-standing endeavor of the southern lines to prevent that circuitous competition which one time ensued from the carrying of the eastern products into the South by way of the Ohio River and western products by way of the Atlantic seaboard. (See page 256.) Woodworking machinery and woodenware of various kinds, manufactured in the cities on the Ohio River and Commerce of the Cities 337 to its north and west, are sold throughout the South, and, for that matter, all over the world, without let or hin- drance from railroad rates. There is some competition between the region to the north of the Ohio River and the East on hand tools, but the freight rates enter so slightly into their value that their sale throughout the South from the northern and western places of manu- facture is not hampered. On manufactured clothing of all kinds, garments for both men and women, and on shoes, Chicago, St. Louis, Cincinnati and Louisville are in active competition with Baltimore, New York, and the East generally, but here again the transportation charge enters so slightly into the cost as not to circumscribe the market from any place of production. In these and in many other lines of merchandise the quality of the goods, the excellence of workmanship, the organization for securing business, the inteUigence and activity of salesmen, are the controlling factors in the markets, and not the freight rates. Indeed, the manufacturers and the shippers of the East are lamenting the fact that so much of their trade is passing to these interior cities. That their fear is not without foundation finds illustra- tion in the fact that a principal market for a leading shirt manufacturing firm of Chicago is the State of Virginia. To maintain and extend their business in the Southeast the manufacturers and merchants of these cities in many cases have to equalize the freight rates with their com- petitors in the East. It is quite true that this equaliza- tion, while of little consequence on any single consign- ment, may mean a good many dollars in the course of a year to each shipper, and a good many thousands of dollars in the aggregate in the course of a year to the railroads. The question is who needs the money the more, the shippers or the railroads ? Would a reduction in rates decrease the revenue of the railroads to the ex- tent of hampering their service to the greater injury of the shippers than the amount which the shippers have to allow for the equalization of freight? 338 Railroad Freight Rates CINCINNATI By common consent and general admission the freight rates of the railroads extending east, west and north from Cincinnati are satisfactory to her shippers. Pig- iron from the southern furnaces, lumber from the southern forests, whiskey from the southern stills, ma- chinery of her manufacture and the wares of her whole- sale merchants flow through Cincinnati to the markets in these regions without hindrance from freight charge. The northern lines likewise bring commodities to Cin- cinnati from the New York and New England district on the east; from Pennsylvania, Ohio, Indiana, Michi- gan, Illinois and the vast regions beyond Chicago and St. Louis, at rates of freight of which her merchants make no complaint. The report of the Chamber of Commerce for 1906 states that the rates of freight from Cincinnati to the markets of the United States, and, what is of more immediate importance, to the markets within 600 miles, average less than the rates of freight from Chicago, St. Louis or Minneapolis. Of the staple commodities of general and daily need a vast propor- tion are manufactured in the city. This is largely due to the fact that coal of most excellent quality is brought by river from Pittsburg, Ohio and Virginia fields at the ' cheapest transportation rates known in the country, and by rail from mines not so remote at rates correspond- ingly low. The access of the various factories to the different railroads would be facilitated, and current disagreement as to switching charges eliminated, were there a belt line over which a factory located on one could easily reach the tracks of another railroad. The construction of such a line would be difficult because of the local topography. LOUISVILLE Located where the currents of traffic from the South meet the currents of traffic from the North, Louisville Commerce of the Cities 339 is naturally a distributing center for each region of the products of the other. In the cheapness and variety of lumber supply she is not second to any city of the coun- try ; her furnaces are fed by the best of coal brought from the Pittsburg and Ohio fields by the river tows and from the Kentucky fields at low rates by rail. To the total value of the shipments from Louisville whiskey contributes over 20 per cent. Without let or hindrance because of railroad rates, this whiskey goes - throughout the entire United States. The dealers think that perhaps the difference between the rates on whis- key bottled or in cases, and on whiskey in barrels, is un- duly great, but the railroads state that there is far greater risk of damage to shipments in bottles, and that, as a matter of fact, they have to pay heavy claims for dam- ages to such shipments. Another foremost commodity in the shipments from Louisville is tobacco. This, like- wise, without let or hindrance from railroad rates, goes not only all over the United States, but all over the world, even to the interior of Africa, for the use of the far- away cousins of the colored folk who assort it and pack it in the hogsheads here. Louisville is conspicuous in the manufacture of wagons and agricultural implements. They have the sweep of the entire South, which buys thousands of carloads every year, and in competition with the great factories of Illinois they are sold through- out the West, even on the Pacific Coast, the freight ! charge in no case restricting their market. In competition with St. Louis and Memphis, Louis- ville distributes grain throughout the South and South- east, and she mills wheat into flour which is likewise dis- tributed throughout the South and Southeast on rates that place her on a parity with these cities ; her packing houses gather hogs from the near-by regions and supply pork not only to the South, but export it to Europe, at rates which, if anything, give her an advantage over the great packing houses of Chicago, St. Louis and the West. In common with the nation-wide trend in the distribution of groceries and dry goods, her market for 340 Railroad Freight Rates , the great staples in these lines is within a narrower area ; but her manufactured clothing goes over the country at rates so low that the manufacturers do not take them into consideration. Both specialties and staples of hard- ware and plumber's supplies are marketed throughout the South from the Carolinas and Southern Florida to Texas. In brief, the adjustment of railroad rates on the com- modities that Louisville produces is such that they can be sold anywhere in the United States, and they are sold in the East, North and West, as well as throughout the South. On the goods that she distributes to the Vir-' ginias her rates are slightly higher than the rates from Cincinnati. Her rates to the region from the Carolinas to Alabama are the same. The rates to the Southeast give Louisville an advantage over St. Louis, but to Ala- bama the advantage is with St. Louis. On the great bulk of merchandise, however, the difference in rates to any part of the Southeast, South or Southwest is not suf- ficient to keep Louisville out of the markets. The local rates of the southern railroads are, owing to their scant traffic, admittedly high, but they do not place either of the Ohio River cities in any market at more than a trifling disadvantage in relation to another. The won- der is that with her geographical and physical advan- tages and her extending communication by water and rail, Louisville is not a greater city, especially a greater manufacturing city. Whatever the retarding factors may be, railroad rates are certainly not among them. This affirmation rests upon the statements of a dozen or more of the foremost shippers and foremost citizens. CHICAGO As a midway station in the channel of through east- ern and western traffic Chicago is on a parity, in so far as freight rates are concerned, with St. Louis, Kansas City and Omaha, not only as a center of eastern distri- bution for the grain and grain products, livestock and Commerce of the Cities 341 livestock products of the West, but in great reaches of competitive territory as a center of interior and west- ern distribution for the manufactured goods of the East. The manufacturing activity of the city rests upon sure foundations. Iron ore, the basic material of the impe- rial industry, is brought by boats the length of Lake Michigan from the finest ore beds in America to the fur- naces at Chicago. This advantage and low freight rates on coke and limestone have led to the erection of the great plant of the United States Steel Corporation at Gary. While there were yet abundant forests in the adjacent States were laid the beginnings of the wood- working industries which increase yearly. Chicago is a focal market for the coal of the Danville, 111., field ; of the Sullivan County, Ind., field; of the Springfield, Gi- rard and Northern Illinois fields, and it annually con- sumes hundreds of thousands of tons of both coal and coke from the Ohio, West Virginia and Pittsburg fields. It is no wonder, then, that the special census of manu- factures for 1905 found within the city of Chicago more than 8,000 factories with a capital of nearly $650,000,- 000, with over 280,000 names on their payrolls. These returns do not include the industries of the surrounding district, which industrially and commercially is part of Chicago. The conspicuous products of these plants are the heavy articles of commerce, the products of lumber, machinery and agricultural implements. There is little or no attempt at the manufacture of woolen goods, cot- ton goods, or the smaller delicate and complicated ap- pliances. The difference between the carload and the less than carload rate, that in some cases seems unduly wide, per- mits the interior cities of Illinois, Wisconsin, Iowa, Minnesota, and those located on and to the west of the Missouri River, to do a jobbing business in groceries, hardware and other staple commodities in the region that a generation or so ago was supplied almost entirely by the wholesale dealers of Chicago. In the higher grades of merchandise, however, the freight rates do 342 Railroad Freight Rates not interfere with Chicago buying anywhere or seUing anywhere in the United States. At her great furniture sale exhibits are made by factories of all parts of the country, and it is attended by buyers from every sec- tion. Her fancy groceries are marketed in Arizona, Montana, and even in New York; the principal dry- goods house has seven solicitors in San Francisco. For her manufactured specialties her market is the world. The old-time rivalry between Chicago and St. Louis for the trade of the western markets resulted in the fixed differences estabhshed in the rates from the two cities to certain competitive areas. Chicago has never ceased to chafe because of the advantage accruing to St. Louis on account of her rates into the Southwest, and it also feels that the difference of but five per cent, against the rate from St. Louis to St. Paul is not quite equitable. The St. Louis-St. Paul rate, however, is the result of a long established adjustment, and St. Louis will probably never relinquish her advantage in the Southwest unless overpowered by an armed force. Therefore is equilibrium. ST. LOUIS A study of the commerce of St. Louis leads to a repe- tition of the statement that applied to Chicago. As a gateway for the distribution to the Eastern States and the Atlantic seaboard of the grain and grain products, livestock and livestock products of the West, St. Louis is, so far as through rail rates are concerned, on a par- ity with Kansas City, Omaha and Chicago. As a gate- way for the distribution throughout the West of mer- chandise from the manufacturing districts of New York and New England, St. Louis has a very favorable basis of rates that gives it a far-reaching advantage. There is a vast area of the Southwest wherein the jobbers ob- tain from the wholesale dealers of St. Louis the stocks which these jobbers sell to the retailers. For the higher grades of merchandise, drygoods, clothing, the lighter Commerce of the Cities 343 weight manufactures of all kinds, St. Louis can draw from any part and sell in any part of the country, or, indeed, of the world. This city is a large manufacturer of shoes, furniture, enameled ware, stoves, all of which are sold throughout the United States ; and as a distrib- uting center for hardware, woodenware, and tobacco, her fame is world-wide. Aside from the complaint as to the rates into the Southeast, which St. Louis shares with Chicago, Louis- ville and Cincinnati, there is very little in the freight rates to cause her merchants to demur. The adjustment of competitive rates on grain with Kansas City and Lit- tle Rock hangs in the balance, but here it is a contest be- tween communities which the railroads would be glad to have them settle for themselves. St. Louis and Kan- sas City each desire to command Little Rock's market, while that city would gladly be independent of either and become a grain center herself. The carload rates on potatoes, onions and cabbage, from the farms of Iowa and Minnesota through to Texas by direct routes, are less than reconsignment rates via St. Louis. These com- modities, therefore, are shipped direct instead of paying toll to the St. Louis warehouse men as in former years. This naturally elicits their regret, but the St. Louis commission merchants, through agents in the field, are still in large measure the intermediary between the northern grower .and the southern consumer, and like- wise between the southern grower and the northern consumer. St. Louis long suffered from the error of a previous generation through which the terminals of the eastern lines were laid on the Illinois instead of the Missouri side of the river. The arbitrary charge for transferring across the Mississippi bridge, in addition to the through rate, has been an incubus that has been almost abol- ished, the Trunk Line Percentage rate from New York being made 117 per cent, of the Chicago rate, including the bridge toll ; this is far more favorable than the pre- vious 116 per cent, to which the bridge arbitrary was 344 Railroad Freight Rates added. Within a radius of lOO miles of the city, the bridge arbitrary still applies. From and to this area, however, there passes but three-tenths of the traffic using the bridge. Here remain struggles between the producers and shippers of coal and other heavy commodities as to the relative rates from place of production to place of market within the radius. These matters, arising out of friction between local competitors for the local mar- kets, do not affect the broader area or the total volume of the commerce of the city. KANSAS CITY The traveler from the East finds Kansas City on the manufacturing frontier. The traveler from the West finds Kansas City on the eastern boundary of the great grain and grazing region, the larger portion of the sur- plus grain and nearly all of the merchantable cattle being produced to her west. Kansas City, therefore, is one of the first of the receiving and distributing points for the livestock and livestock products, grain and grain prod- ucts, and in respect to the rates thereon there seems to be general satisfaction as they apply from places of pro- duction and to eastern and southern markets. Coal from adjacent fields is brought to her confines at a freight rate that does not exceed from 50 to 60 cents a ton, even for distances so great as 150 miles; the lum- ber rates are also entirely favorable, the tariff being 23 cents per 100 pounds from the yellow pine forests of Louisiana; cement and brick are produced at kilns al- most within the city, the freight rates forming an incon- siderable fraction of the selling price. In regard to the principal food supply, Kansas City is equally fortunate; no city in the United States obtains grain and meat, the basic foods, more cheaply; from the surrounding coun- try come eggs and chickens, butter and cheese at rates that give the railroads but a small fraction of a cent a pound. Agricultural implements, the tools without which the farmer's hand would be impotent, come to Commerce of the Cities 345 and through Kansas City in a flow that is entirely un- impeded by freight rates. The rate on a one-horse walking plow, that retails at $14 from the Illinois man- ufacturing district to Kansas City is but 22 cents; and on a sulky plow, that retails at $45, about 80 cents. As to the rates from the East on the manufactured merchandise, the lighter articles that are found on the shelves and counters of the stores, there has been long- standing friction between the wholesale dealers of Kan- sas City and the railroads. When the writer entered the office of a conspicuous wholesale drygoods establish- ment and stated his errand to the senior member, that gentleman, with the alert and vigorous action that char- acterizes the progressive and successful western man of business, called in the junior member of the firm and the clerks in charge of traffic. He lined them up, intro- duced the writer to them seriatim, and announced the reason for the visit. He then waved his hand to a jun- ior partner, saying with great emphasis, " You can tell him all about the freight rates of Kansas City; you can tell him what we have to contend against." The junior partner with fervor asseverated that Kansas City was the place most discriminated against in the way of freight rates in the United States ; that the railroads apparently had taken particular umbrage against the city, and the shippers had endeavored to obtain relief without avail. He asserted that if the railroads would not listen to a final appeal, the citizens of Kansas City would rise en masse and secure their rights. This was forcible, but not definite, and an attempt was made to ascertain just in what respect and upon what commodities the freight rates bore oppressively. The gentleman soon admitted that he was talking about the drygoods business alone; that he was not informed as to the effects of the rates upon other merchandise. He also admitted that he was speaking only in regard to the wholesale drygoods busi- ness. Further questioning elicited the nub of the griev- ance to be that the rate on freight of the first class — which includes drygoods — from New York to Kansas 346 Railroad Freight Rates City was $1.47, while from New York to St. Paul, a similar distance, the rate was but $1.15. It was ad- mitted that the wholesale merchants of St. Paul and Minneapolis do not compete with the wholesale mer- chants of Kansas City, except, perhaps, in a very limited area. When it was asked what effect a reduction in the rate to Kansas City would have upon the price of mer- chandise of the first class, it was admitted that on cer- tain staple cotton piece goods, for example, the reduc- tion of 32 cents per 100 pounds in the freight would make a difference of something like one-tenth of one per cent, of their value. When it was asked if the drygoods firm would give to the retail dealers the benefit of this reduction of one-tenth of one per cent., it was frankly admitted that it would not. The reduction would, how- ever, make a difference of a great many dollars a year — several thousands doubtless — in the freight bills of the Kansas City wholesalers. The rate of $1.47 to Kansas City is made by adding to 87 cents, the first class rate from New York to St. Louis, the first class rate from St. Louis to Kansas City, which is 60 cents. The railroads claim that the low rates from New York to Chicago and St. Louis are the result of years of strife between the railroads extend- ing from the East to those cities, and that they apply on traffic that moves from the East to these cities in greater volume than from either of them toward any mar- ket to the west thereof; and point out that if the through rate to Kansas City be reduced the wholesale merchants of that city would obtain, what is evidently their desire, an advantage over the wholesale dealers of Chicago and St. Louis in much of the territory in which those three cities are competitive. As was pointed out in the de- scription of the rate structure of the trans-Mississippi and trans-Missouri region, the rate between St. Louis and Kansas City determines the through rate, by way of all Mississippi River crossings, from St. Louis on the south to Dubuque on the north, to all points on the Mis- souri River from Kansas City on the south to Omaha Commerce of the Cities 347 and Sioux City on the north. A reduction in the through rate from the East by way of St. Louis to Kansas City would, therefore, reduce all of the rates from the East via these various routes across the Mississippi River to the various points specified on the Missouri River, and, therefore, would reduce the through rates from the East to the area between the Missouri River and the Rocky Mountains. The merchants of Kansas City, St. Joseph and Omaha finally joined in a formal complaint to the Interstate Commerce Commission. Sioux City intervened, asking that whatever might be done for Omaha should also be done for Sioux City. The business organizations of St. Paul, Chicago, and St. Louis intervened, defending the existent rate structure and opposing any modification that would give the Missouri River cities an advantage at their expense. The Commission decided that the Mis- souri River cities are not entitled to the same rate from the East as St. Paul and MinneapoHs, and made no change in the established rates between the Mississippi and Missouri Rivers as applying on local traffic, but it did reduce those rates as applying on through traffic, making such proportional rate 51 cents instead of 60 cents. Because of the far-reaching efifect of this reduc- tion the railroads at once contested the decision through the courts. It will be perceived that the entire conflict is between the competing wholesale dealers of rival cities ; that it does not appreciably, if at all, affect the prices at which retail merchants can obtain their stocks from one city or another; nor does it affect the goods which the con- sumer will purchase from the retail dealer in quality, and to but a negligible extent, if at all, in price. It is quite evident that the Kansas City wholesale merchants are seeking an advantage over their competitors in Chi- cago and St. Louis, which those competitors are resist- ing as vigorously as Kansas City in turn is resisting the growing ambition of Wichita and other cities to her west to conduct and extend a wholesale business. The 34B Railroad Freight Rates reduction ordered by the Commission was apparently on the ground that as the railroads between the Missis- sippi and Missouri Rivers carry traffic to and fro be- tween the East and the Pacific Coast for lower compen- sation, they can afford the reduction on the traffic mov- ing from the East to the Missouri River, although the conditions attending that traffic are radically different from those which force the extraordinarily low rates on the transcontinental movement. ST. PAUL AND MINNEAPOLIS St. Paul owes its development primarily to the fact that it is at the head of navigation on the Mississippi River. This, in addition to the proximity of Lake Su- perior, by reason of which it obtains low through rates from the East, and that it is the starting point of rail- roads leading throughout the Dakotas to the far North- west, have given it command of a distributive trade in that region. It has, moreover, always been the policy of the lines leading from St. Paul to the far Northwest to so adjust rates that neither Chicago, nor any other city to the East, can have any advantage over the St; Paul jobbers in the northwestern territory on traffic that passes through St. Paul, the rate from St. Paul even to Utah, for example, being as low as the rate from Chicago to Utah. The Mississippi River is an active factor in the commerce between St. Paul and St. Louis, and therefore forces the rail rate between these cities to a lower level than that applying in this region generally. If there are any grievances as to the rail- road rates affecting the commerce of St. Paul, they are but of minor importance, affecting individual shippers, the kind of inequalities which the railroads are willing to remove if possible. Minneapolis, a newer city especially devoted to the milling interests, is as yet but an indifferent rival of St. Paul as a wholesale center, and is therefore rather in- clined to be radical in seeking readjustments of rates Commerce of the Cities 349 in order that her jobbers may extend the area of their markets. For instance, to places in southern Minnesota and the Dakotas directly penetrated by through lines from Chicago that extend to the south of the Twin Cities, the rates give the wholesalers of Chicago some- thing of an advantage over those of the Twin Cities. This advantage St. Paul does not contest, thinking it logical that Chicago should have it. Minneapolis, how- ever, is striving for a readjustment. It is even sug- gested in Minneapolis that the rail rate to that city from the East should be as low as to St. Louis, because the lake and rail distance from New York to Minneapolis is less than the lake and rail distance from New York to St. Louis. The rates in which Minneapolis has the most interest are those on flour. On flour that goes from Minneapolis via Duluth and lake to Buffalo the vessels obtain seven cents per loo pounds, while they carry grain for one cent and upwards per bushel, the seasonal average being about three cents. Although grain can be loaded in bulk and the expense of loading and unloading is much less than that of flour, the milling companies think that this difference, which materially favors the competing mill- ers of Bufifalo, is so wide as to be unjustifiable. The all- rail rate on flour from Minneapolis to New York is 25 cents per 100 pounds, and up to 1898 the rate by lake and rail averaged 20 cents. The difiference of 5 cents per 100 pounds, amounting to 10 cents a barrel, gave an advantage to the Minneapolis mills over those of other northwestern cities that can not so readily avail of the lake route. In 1898, through the lake and rail rate being increased by two cents, the difference was re- duced to three cents, and in 1900, through the lake and rail rate being increased another one cent per 100 pounds, the difference was reduced to two cents. These published rates did not for a time particularly concern the millers, as they made special contracts with the railroads for low rates. The possibility of such arrangements having come to an end, the Minneapolis millers are seeking 350 Railroad Freight Rates concessions that will tend to restore their former ad- vantage. DENVER It is easy to forget that Denver but a generation or so ago was no more than a health resort on the Colo- rado plateau. The purity of the air, excellence of the climate, fertility of the contiguous soil, and the wealth of the ore deposits in the near-by mountains, attracted a population which, in line with that progress charac- teristic of a developing city, established retail stores, then certain lines of manufacture, and then sought to extend the area of distribution, and incidentally, through the tireless efforts of one of her energetic business men, acquired a reputation throughout the country as being peculiarly the victim of an iniquitous conspiracy entered into by the railroads to burden her citizens and hamper her development. It was really, therefore, a matter of exceeding surprise for a dispassionate investigation to disclose that Denver, by the admission of the officers of her business organizations and her principal shippers, has very little grievance against the railroads as to freight rates. The peculiar location of the city midway between the Mississippi Valley and the Pacific slope, in proximity to vast areas that are being reclaimed by irri- gation, gives to the commerce of Denver and of Colo- rado Springs, Pueblo and Trinidad, the other of the Colorado common points, peculiar characteristics that justify more extended reference than has been given to other of the cities. The channels of traffic to and from Denver are those of the great West, and the develop- ment of her freight rates has necessarily been in adapta- tion to those channels. In so far as her food supply is concerned, Denver cer- tainly is not hampered by rates of freight. The trans- portation charge on fresh meat and other products ob- tained from the packing houses within her limits is neg- ligible, and even when she draws on the packing houses of Omaha the rate is but three-fifths of a cent per Commerce of the Cities 351 pound for fresh meat and one-half cent per pound for packing house products, the retail price being the same whether the meat has been prepared in Omaha, Kansas ^ City or Denver. The rates of freight from Denver allow her to supply South Dakota with fresh meat in compe- tition with Omaha; she also supplies not only western and southern Colorado, but New Mexico and much of Texas. Wheat comes from the Cache Valley for consump- tion in Denver at 35 cents per 100 pounds. It may be turned into flour in Denver, and sent through on the milling in transit privilege at an aggregate rate from the Cache Valley of 50 cents to the Missouri River, to be sold in large quantities in the Southeastern States in competition with Kansas City, Omaha, and Minneap- olis. It furnishes a large portion of the supply of Texas, even along the Mexican frontier, 1,200 miles away. Butter comes from Kansas and Nebraska in refrig- erator cars at a trifle less than one cent a pound, and chickens, likewise in refrigerator cars, at a trifle more than one cent, the transportation charge not affecting the retail price. Eggs come from Kansas at an average freight rate of a trifle over one cent a dozen, cheese from the Colorado dairies at about one-third of a cent a pound. A ten-pound package of coffee from New York will have paid the railroads 7.9 cents ; ten pounds of sugar from northern Colorado one cent, or loaf sugar from New York 8.1 cents, or from California 6 cents. The railroads have made rates on the beet sugar of Colorado that encourage its shipment to the widest markets, the rate to the Missouri River being 25 cents, to the Mississippi River 30 cents, and to Chicago 35 cents, per 100 pounds. Tea is brought from China to Denver and the entire region to its east at i^ cents per pound; rice from Japan to Denver at 65 cents per 100 pounds. Potatoes come from northern Colorado at a freight rate of 12 cents per 100 pounds. This cannot be called 352 Railroad Freight Rates low, but some consideration must be given to the fact that to enable this region to supply Kansas and Ne- braska with potatoes it.is accorded a rate of 35 cents to the Missouri River. The supply of potatoes for Okla- homa and Texas moves from the Colorado field at rates that vary from 51 to 54 cents. New potatoes in the early spring are brought from California to Denver at 75 cents per 100 pounds; the other fresh vegetables come from near-by truck farms at freight rates that make no difference one way or the other to the consumer, and do not burden the producer. Celery is shipped to both Chicago and New Orleans. Peaches, pears, and apples are shipped from the Colorado orchards to Chicago, St. Paul and the interior generally at $1 per 100 pounds. Dried fruits, raisins, prunes, and figs move on this rate of $1 from Grand Junction to the same regions. The canned goods of Colorado also penetrate to the eastern markets, Colorado peas being a delicacy on bills of fare as far as Boston. These canned peas and canned small fruits, such as red raspberries, cherries and gooseberries, pay a rate of 35 cents per 100 pounds to the Missouri River, 50 cents to the Mississippi River, and 55 cents to St. Paul — rates that permit them to be sold in competi- tion with the canned goods of any other locality. Five years ago the canned tomatoes consumed in Colorado were imported from Wisconsin, Indiana and Baltimore. Now the State not only cans almost all of the tomatoes consumed within her limits, but supplies Montana, Utah, New Mexico, and Texas. New household furniture will likely come from Chi- cago, whence it pays a freight rate of $1.10 per 100 pounds. That is, a bed weighing 200 pounds will have paid the railroads $2.20; a dining-room suite of table, four chairs and a sideboard, weighing 700 pounds, $7.70, and a parlor suite of sofa, table, and four chairs, weigh- ing 500 pounds, $5.50. Furniture of the incoming set- tler, however, whether new or old, is brought from Chi- cago as immigrant movables at 47^ cents per 100 pounds. Commerce of the Cities 353 The coal used in the city of Denver for domestic pur- poses comes largely from coal fields within 18 or 20 miles of the city at freight rates of 80 cents per ton on lump coal, and 60 cents a ton on slack coal. These are undeniably high rates, but no more is charged from the fields 50 or 60 miles away, and the rate on coal for steam and manufacturing purposes from fields 200 miles away is $1.60 per ton. The brick used in Denver is made in the city. Portland cement made at Portland, Colorado, comes at 6 cents per 100 pounds or from lola, Kansas, a distance of 530 miles, at 15 cents per 100 pounds. Yellow pine lumber comes from Louisiana at from 34 to 40 cents per loo pounds ; cedar, fir, and beech from Oregon, Washington, and Idaho, at from 50 to 60 cents; hickory and oak from Mississippi, Missouri, and Tennessee, at rates ranging from 32^ to 40 cents. Build- ing stone is right at hand on every side, and is shipped throughout Kansas and Nebraska, the rates to the Mis- souri River being but 20 cents. Clothing, generally speaking, is sold at prices that do not range a great deal higher than those of the cities to the east. The freight rate is $2.30 per 100 pounds from New York, a suit of clothes weighing 8 pounds, therefore, having paid the railroads 18 cents, which is but 6 cents more than it would have paid at Kansas City. A pair of shoes will, perhaps, have paid 3 or 4 cents. The rate on cotton piece goods is $1.53 per 100 pounds from New York, the transportation charge on 10 pounds — which approximates 60 yards of cotton sheeting — therefore, being a trifle over 3 cents. It is fairly well authenticated that a customer once said to a Denver haberdasher that a necktie for which he was asking $1 could be purchased in Chicago for 50 cents, to which the dealer replied, " But look at the freight rate ! " It happened that this customer was the traffic manager of one of the western railroads who knew that the freight rate on that necktie from New York was not more than one-third of a cent. Colorado is nearly self-sufficient in the production of 354 Railroad Freight Rates machinery. She makes her own rails, rolls, castings, cores, wire nails, and bar iron. She not only makes the mine cars and hoisting machinery used in her mines, but ships mining machinery- to Mexico, South Africa, Japan, Russia^ and Australia. The cost of production of this machinery is somewhat greater than in the east- ern factories because of the higher transportation charge on the raw material, which is brought from greater dis- tances, but this does not seem to restrict the markets. That the mineral products of Colorado move to the widest markets without impediment from transportation charge is beyond question. In short, Denver enjoys a freight rate adjustment that permits the sale in wide markets of the products of Colorado, whether of the soil or manufacture, and that brings to her citizens the commodities of daily need at a transportation charge so low that their prices in the majority of cases, for any effect of the freight rates, need be advanced but little, if at all, above the prices at the places of production. The relation of the freight rate adjustment to the wholesaling of products of eastern manufacture, or to the bringing from the East of raw material to be manu- factured in Denver in competition with eastern factories is another matter. As her merchants wanted their rates adjusted to enable them to reach a wider area, the rail- roads, knowing that the people of the adjoining States and territories would be supplied with merchandise from the eastern factories, whether jobbed from Chicago or St. Louis or the Missouri River, and knowing that any concession accorded to Denver that would militate against shippers of Chicago, St. Louis, Kansas City or Omaha would be bitterly contested by the merchants and manufacturers of those cities, did not hasten to give the merchants of Denver what they wanted just because they wanted it. One of the concessions which the Denver Chamber of Commerce asks of the rail- roads is that Denver be made a "basing point," that Colorado common points be placed on a " basing line." Commerce of the Cities 355 To ask that Denver be made a basing point in general without bringing to bear upon the railroads any con- siderations in the way of increased traffic or increased revenue is, of course, a different proposition from pre- senting to the railroads such irresistible arguments of particular rates on particular commodities which Den- ver can wholesale with advantage to the railroads as well as to herself. This latter procedure has gained and is gaining many readjustments of benefit to her dealers, the traffic expert in their employ having in but a year and a half obtained reductions in rates throughout Ari- zona and Texas ; into the Black Hills ; to stations in Wyoming, Idaho, and Montana ; to stations in western Nebraska, Nevada, and Mexico. These reductions in many instances give the Denver shippers an advan- tage over those of the Missouri River cities, and in other instances place them upon a parity with those shippers. This development, which tends more and more to bring the freight rates affecting the commerce of Denver into the closest adaptation to the needs of that commerce, is fairly typical of the development in the freight rate ad- justments that affect Cheyenne, Albuquerque, El Paso, and other growing centers of the Rocky Mountain re- gion. It is significant that the wholesale merchants of Denver think that the freight rates favor Salt Lake City, while the latter thinks that the rates favor Denver. The fact is that rates have been made the same from both cities throughout a considerable area of Idaho and Wyoming. To the smaller settlements in the interior of the as yet sparsely populated Rock Mountain district, espe- cially over branch railroads built and maintained through mountainous regions at great expense, the local rates are higher than in other portions of the country, enter- ing to a greater extent into the price paid for merchan- dise by the consumers. 356 Railroad Freight Rates HELENA AND BUTTE Butte is another city whose merchants desire to enter the wholesale field. Heretofore, as is always the case in mining towns, where money is easily made and easily spent, little consideration has been given to the rates of freight. The merchants have purchased what their cus- tomers wanted and paid the freight. Their customers have purchased to meet their requirements at prices willingly paid, and which have yielded high profits to the dealers. But the city is now outgrowing the swad- dling clothes of a western mining camp under the stim- ulus of a movement to give it rank as a municipality of organized enterprise. One feature of this is the scru- tiny of the freight rates to ascertain their relation to potential wider markets. Helena, however, will not easily relinquish her pres- tige as a distributing center, the retail dealers of Mon- tana, who do not purchase their supplies at St. Paul, usually patronizing the jobbers of this city, which is contiguous not only to a developed mining region, but to ranches on which cattle and sheep are still grown by the thousands. Wheat is also raised in the Gallatin Valley, which, however, does not produce sufficient for the adjacent mills. This has led the farmers to form " Societies of Equity," through which it is attempted to obtain from these mills a price equal to that which the millers have to pay for wheat of other sections, plus the freight rate therefrom to the mills. THE SOUTH AND SOUTHEAST The traditions of the South are those of a country devoted to agriculture. Although the industrial agents of the railroads during recent years have attracted many manufacturing establishments to the territory penetrated by their lines, there are not as yet many kinds of prod- ucts that are sold in widespread markets. The cotton mills of the Carolinas produce fabrics that compete with Commerce of the Cities 357 those of New England throughout the country gener- ally, and in foreign markets with those from the mills of any country; the furnaces and iron mills in Ala- bama sell their surplus products north of the Ohio and west of the Mississippi Rivers; and the furniture fac- tories of various localities are sending the grades which they make to both northern and western markets. Aside from the carrying of these products to markets the transportation lines of the South, with few excep- tions, are especially concerned with the conveyance of the products of the soil to the markets where the fruits and vegetables are consumed, and the raw material con- verted into forms of use; and with the distribution throughout the South of the foodstuffs of the West and the manufactured merchandise of the East, and of the cities on and to the north of the Ohio River. When, however, it is stated that the South has not attained to manufacturing in varied degree, an excep- tion must be made of Richmond, Va., which has been transformed in but little more than a dozen years into a conspicuous manufacturing as well as a prominent distributing center. This city has the benefit of the same low Trunk Line rates from the West as Balti- more, and, therefore, can obtain raw material of various kinds as cheaply as the industrial cities of the North Atlantic seaboard. It has the advantage of water trans- portation, and correspondingly low rail rates to and from these cities, therefore being able to obtain their products at freight rates that are held to the lowest level. It has the benefit of water communication and correspondingly low rail rates with the southern At- lantic ports, and the interior tributary thereto, through which it is therefore enabled to distribute the products of its own manufacture, as well as those secured from other sections, at rates that are at a low level. The mer- chants and manufacturers of Richmond are well aware of their blessings in this respect. This city, supplied with water power by her rivers, is the seat of extensive tobacco manufacture; makes a large proportion of the 358 Railroad Freight Rates nails and horseshoes used in the South; by far the greater proportion of the blotting paper used in the United States, and is making progress in other lines of manufacture that may lead to her becoming no mean rival of the older industrial centers to her north. As a commercial center she contests the supremacy of Balti- more throughout Virginia, a large portion of the Caro- linas, and competes with Cincinnati and Louisville in eastern Kentucky and Tennessee. The freight rates permit Wilmington, N. C, to draw cotton from the interior in competition even with Savan- nah. Her merchants buy this cotton on the plantation, put it through their own compresses and export it in vessels which they have chartered, their enterprise mak- ing Wilmington a port of consequence in the export of cotton, as it is in the shipment of naval stores, the resin and turpentine from the Carolinian forests. After the Civil War, Charleston was slow to resume the export of cotton largely because of the estabhshment of cotton mills in the interior, which largely absorb the cotton from the plantations formerly and logically tribu- tary to Charleston. This city is the largest market for sea- island cotton, the center of the fertilizer industry and of a developing region of truck farms. Of recent years the railroads have made adjustments in the rates in the interior country in which Charleston merchants may nat- urally expect to conduct a wholesale trade, and have accorded as low rates on the western foodstufifs, for export traffic, from Chicago, as from Chicago to Nor- folk, the distance being about the same. Savannah is in a condition of happy content with the freight rates. They permit her to draw from vast areas cotton and lumber, which are carried by great lines of steamboats to foreign ports. Merchandise from the East is brought to her stores and warehouses almost entirely by the coastwise steamers and distributed throughout a wholesale area extending into Florida and Alabama as well as throughout Georgia. The merchants and manufacturers of Atlanta, the Commerce of the Cities 359 great interior distributing center of the South, have no complaint of consequence in regard to freight rates. They are so adjusted that she can obtain the materials and the products of the West, the North and the East, and can distribute them throughout a wide area. The city does not have the milling in transit privilege on wheat enjoyed by the competing city of Nashville. This was accorded Nashville long ago, and the railroads say they cannot abolish it now because the mills of that city have been established and are largely sustained by the privilege which, however, the railroads do not care to extend. Memphis, the largest inland cotton center of the United States, is the natural point of concentration for the cotton of southern Missouri and Arkansas, part of Louisiana and Texas, and of northern Mississippi and western Tennessee. It is shipped to the Atlantic sea- ports, to the mills of New England, and for export to the Gulf at rates that have been established through years of adjustment, and are not the subject of com- plaint. Memphis is also the greatest hardwood lumber market in the world, being the natural point of concen- tration for logs and lumber from vast areas of the tim- ber lands to its west and southwest. The rates on this commodity do not impede its shipment to any logical markets. Memphis is also a principal gateway for the distribution of the foodstuffs of the West throughout the Southeast, and a center for the distribution of gen- eral merchandise throughout an extended area of Mis- souri, Arkansas, Kentucky, Tennessee, Mississippi, and Louisiana, being a strong competitor of St. Louis for the trade of a great part of this region. The merchants of Montgomery, Ala., complained to the Interstate Commerce Commission because the rates on certain merchandise from the North are lower to Mobile and Pensacola than to that city. This is a case of charging less for the long than for the short haul, which the railroads say is justifiable because of the water transportation down the Mississippi to New Orleans, 360 Railroad Freight Rates and thence to Mobile and Pensacola. The Commission upheld this contention, but ordered a reduction in cer- tain rates that were higher to Montgomery than the rate to the Gulf, plus the rate from the Gulf back to Montgomery. Mobile and New Orleans obtain high class merchan- dise from the North Atlantic seaboard by water. Their grain and grain products^ meat and meat products and many manufactured articles from Chicago, St. Louis and Memphis are brought down at low rates because of the water transportation made possible by the Missis- sippi and the Gulf. The rates are the same from these cities to Mobile and to New Orleans, the competing railroads extending down the Mississippi Valley to the respective ports insisting that the freight rates be no greater to one than to the other. Each of these cities thinks the other has certain ad- vantages in the way of rates that restrict the markets of its wholesale merchants in competition with the wholesale merchants of the other. There is no com- plaint, however, as to the rates on the commodities that flow to and through these cities in great volume; that is, none that are serious. Certain of the dealers in New Orleans rather think that instead of meat and meat prod- ucts being exported over her wharves at through rates made from the packing houses in the North and West, the rates should be so adjusted that these products can be handled by, and pay toll to, the dealers in New Or- leans. The growers of rice now and then contend that as their products in a measure come into competition with flour, the rates ought to be as low as those on flour. As they are, however, the distributive rates on rice are but slightly higher than the rates on flour, a com- modity which forms a far greater proportion of the total volume of traffic, and are generally satisfactory. New Orleans and New York are the chief receiving ports and distributing centers for the sugar of the West Indies and the coffee of South America, which move upon Commerce of the Cities 361 rates that are the source of complaint only in excep- tional and negligible instances. OKLAHOMA When Oklahoma was opened to settlement the rail- roads scrambled to cover it with their tracks in very much the same way that the settlers scrambled to take possession of the homesteads, with the result that the tracks at first laid had little or no ballast, and the roads generally were not in good condition. This was doubt- less a factor in the marked antagonism to the railroads which led to extraordinary powers being given that State's Public Corporation Commission. The chairman- ship of this body was conferred upon a cattle man of admitted physical prowess, the hero of many character- istically western adventures. He once manifested the playfulness of his disposition by marching a barber, who had not pleased him, up and down the streets of the town with a revolver at the point of his nose. The senti- ment of the State was so very radical that its business men formed an organization for the purpose of bringing about a more conservative tone, and fair play for the railroads, whom they generally admit had not been flagrantly aggressive. This movement has had good ef- fect even upon the redoubtable chairman of the Public Corporation Commission, who is reported to have said to a party of railroad officers, " We are all men together ; we are willing to spread out a blanket and sit down on it with you and talk things over any time." In the eighteen years of its existence Oklahoma City has attained a population of 60,000, and its physical characteristics are those of an entirely modern munici- pality. The wholesale merchants sell groceries within a radius of 50 or 60 miles; hardware, agricultural im- plements and drugs throughout the State, as well as into the Pan Handle of Texas. The rate on merchan- dise of the first class from New York by vessel to the 362 Railroad Freight Rates Gulf ports and thence by rail to Oklahoma City is $1.25 per 100 pounds, which permits a certain wholesale dis- tribution of the high grade merchandise. Agricultural implements come principally from St. Louis, a two-horse walking plow, weighing 300 pounds and retailing for $24, having paid a rate of $1.80 from that city. Oklahoma City mills grain which it draws largely from Oklahoma and Kansas, distributing the product throughout the State, in Texas, Arkansas and Louisiana, and to a limited extent east of the Mississippi River and in Mexico. Rates throughout the State on grain and grain products are adjusted on a mileage scale which is about as low as that applicable in Illinois. To places outside of the State these shipments are handled under the milling in transit privilege. In Oklahoma the rail- roads have taken the side of the millers in that conflict which is quite general between the rates on wheat and rates on flour. Notwithstanding that grain can be more readily carried and a car be loaded to its capacity of wheat, while it will not carry more than 24,000 to 30,000 pounds of flour, the rate on flour has been made the same as on wheat. An exception is made on shipments to Texas, which insists upon the interstate railroads mak- ing their rates into that State 5 cents lower on wheat than on flour: this is because there are numerous mills in Texas, but the State does not produce enough grain to keep them actively employed. The Texas Railroad Commission thus protects the Texas millers who are at the consuming end of the rate, at the expense of the millers in other States who are at the producing end of the rate, this difference of 5 cents just about placing the distant on a parity with the nearer mill. It is ad- mitted that no other item of commerce of Oklahoma is so well taken care of as the grain and grain products. There is even now a small packing house in Okla- homa, and the industry will doubtless grow because that portion of the State which constituted Indian Terri- tority raises corn and hogs, while the region that con- stituted Oklahoma Territory is largely devoted to the Commerce of the Cities 363 growing of wheat. At this time hogs from Oklahoma are a considerable factor in the supply of the packing houses at Fort Worth and Kansas City. As the State becomes more thickly settled and the farmers more in- tensively cultivate their homesteads, they will naturally raise more of both hogs and beeves. This will accelerate the development of the packing industry of Oklahoma City, bringing still more favorable adjustments of the freight rates which are now fairly equitable. Oklahoma produces oil, as do Kansas, Colorado, and Texas. The producers of each State desire to market both crude and refined oil in the cities of the other States, while from their respective intrastate markets they desire to keep away the oil of the other States. The oil consumers, however, of each State desire to have the benefit of the competition of the oil from each of the other States. The railroads have, therefore, been be- sieged to reduce their rates from Colorado, and then the rates into that State from the wells of Kansas and Oklahoma, because those rates are too high compared with rates from Colorado; then Oklahoma applied for lower rates into Texas, and both Kansas and Texas for lower rates into Oklahoma. A pipe line carries crude oil from Oklahoma to the Texas refineries, and the Pub- lic Corporation Commission has made low rates on the refined oil marketed throughout the State. Manufacture has begun in Oklahoma with the mak- ing of Cottonwood into egg crates, butter boxes and fruit boxes, which are sold throughout the South and South- east. The city also manufactures wire chicken coops, which are distributed throughout the western poultry region. TEXAS Under the Texas Common Point System of freight rates, which has been described at some length in a pre- vious chapter, the freight rate adjustment affecting the commerce of one is so nearly like that affecting the commerce of another city that there is little occasion 364 Railroad Freight Rates for reference to the traffic of individual commercial centers. A modification of the Texas Common Point System has been made to allow the merchants of Dallas to compete with those of Texarkana. That place was given rates from New Orleans and other cities but slightly higher than those which were applied to the neighboring city of Shreveport because of the steamboats that formerly reached that city via the Red River. The rates made by the State Commission of Arkansas also enabled Tex- arkana to obtain merchandise at low rates from Mem- phis. These adjustments so affected the trade of Dallas that it was granted rates less than those applying throughout Texas in general that its merchants might compete with those of Texarkana in the northwestern corner of Texas and its vicinity. The rates of Paris, also a rival commercial center, were likewise adjusted to enable it to compete with both Texarkana and Dallas. These and other adjustments have extended to their general satisfaction the area reached by the Dallas wholesale dealers: a dozen years ago its radius was but forty or fifty miles, while it is now one hundred or more. The millers of Ft. Worth were at some disadvantage while the elevation privilege was accorded to Kansas City, but its cancellation makes their grain rates en- tirely satisfactory. This city now sells agricultural im- plements in New Mexico and Arizona under rates that have been reduced to enable the dealers of Texas to com- pete in this region with those of Kansas City. The city of Galveston, for several years, bitterly con- tested the specific differences in freight rates applying between that city and Houston, urging that Galveston be made an initial point of application of the scale of intrastate rates that is general throughout Texas. It finally brought suit for the abolition of the difference as applied to the line leading from Galveston to the Southwest without passing through Houston, and ob- tained a favorable verdict in the District Court, which was sustained by the Court of Appeals. Appeal was Commerce of the Cities 365 thence taken to the Supreme Court of the State, which has enjoined the collection of this difference on traffic from Galveston that goes over this line. As Galveston and New Orleans are both ports on the Gulf of Mexico, through either of which traffic may be consigned from a considerable area of the interior, there has been an equalization of the rates on some commodities to these ports. For example, the maximum rate on rice from the Texas rice fields to Galveston, as fixed by the Texas Railroad Commission, is 19 cents, and the same rate applies to New Orleans. (See page 131.) THE PACIFIC COAST The commerce of the cities of the Pacific slope has been fairly indicated in the description of the freight rate structures applying to the transcontinental traffic. As there stated, the rates under which the products of California are distributed throughout the East are, as a rule, satisfactory to her producers. This is also the case in the far Northwest, with the exception of the lumber rates. As the various Pacific ports from San Diego to Seattle receive merchandise from the East at rates that are the same to each port, the wholesale merchants of the vari- ous terminal cities are on an exact equality in so far as the inbound rates are concerned. Their competition, therefore, is in the distribution to the markets of the in- terior. Broadly speaking, the seaports of importance are separated by such long distances that the wholesale merchants of each city make distribution throughout a fairly well defined area that is recognized as tribu- tary to it. The disaster which overwhelmed San Francisco gave an exceptional stimulus during the period of its recuper- ation to the trade of Los Angeles, and this city is now endeavoring to have the freight rates to places in the San Joaquin Valley so adjusted that it can compete with the older city for the trade of that section. The railroad 366 Railroad Freight Rates companies state that the lower rates apply from San Francisco because of the haul along level tracks, while the higher rates from Los Angeles are necessitated by the expensive movement over the mountains. They like- wise decline to antagonize the long established whole- sale interests of San Francisco as well as to suffer a re- duction in their revenue by reducing the rates from Los Angeles. This latter city is also endeavoring to obtain the trade of the Nevada gold regions, which has been with the older city. The fact that San Francisco retains its prestige as the commercial metropolis of the central and southern reaches of the Pacific slope is strikingly manifested in that it is still the headquarters of the salmon shippers, although Seattle has been striving to wrest the suprem- acy. The vessel owners obtain their outfits in San Fran- cisco in April and May, and embark then for the Colum- bia River with the Chinese laborers, the material for boxes, the fishing implements and provisions sufficient for the entire season. After spending the summer in the fishing waters and at the canneries, they return in the latter part of August, or in September, with the canned fish, which is shipped from San Francisco to England, and by rail throughout the Eastern States. The practice of the transcontinental railroads in mak- ing rates from the East to interior cities and towns on the Pacific slope the sum of the rate to the Pacific termi- nal plus the rate from the Pacific terminal to the interior town, provided that the rate so made be less than the rate made on the normal basis from the East to such interior towns, in the past years has been the source of much complaint on the part of these interior towns. This complaint, however, was largely stilled by the rul- ing of the Supreme Court of the United States that the basis is justifiable. The fact is that it gives these interior towns the full benefit of water competition. Their rates are less than they would be if the existence of the ocean did not lower the level of the Pacific termi- nal rates. Their rates are just what they would be if, Commerce of the Cities 367 instead of their being served by the railroads extending across the continent, they were obliged to rely upon the service of a railroad extending into the interior from the Pacific terminal. This situation has become fairly well understood by the residents of the Californian interior, and is no longer the subject of general complaint. The city of Spokane, however, has never been sat- isfied with its status in this respect, largely because of other factors which have complicated the conditions affecting that city. It was a complainant before the Interstate Commerce Commission during the earlier period of that body's existence, and the renewal of its complaint was the first case to appear upon the docket of the Commission after the Hepburn law became effect- ive. Spokane, however, although on the western slope, is not simply a town of the Pacific interior, as that des- ignation ordinarily indicates. The surrounding country throughout a vast area is of such fertility that it is known as the Inland Empire. That it may fulfill its logical function as a distributing center for this region, rates lower than those applying to the Pacific terminals have been made to Spokane on merchandise from the Missouri and Mississippi Valleys and other sections of the interior that are not immediately served by vessel lines to the Pacific Coast, as is the Atlantic seaboard. It is interest- ing to find that while the wholesale merchants of Spokane insist that they should be accorded lower than Pacific terminal rates on all merchandise from the East, in order that they can compete with Seattle toward the West, the wholesale merchants of Seattle insist upon the justice of the application from the East to Spokane of the rates that are constituted by adding to the rate to the Pacific terminal the rate therefrom to Spokkne. This adjustment, of course, gives the Seattle wholesale dealer an advantage over his competitor at Spokane in the intermediate territory. It has been modified by the decision of the Commission that although water com- petition modifies the rates from the Atlantic seaboard to Seattle it does not affect the rates from Chicago and 368 Railroad Freight Rates' St. Paul to Spokane. The reductions ordered in both classes and commodity rates from these cities will en- hance the importance of Spokane as a distributing center. THE SITUATION AT INDIANAPOLIS As has been shown by the complaints made to the In- terstate Commerce Commission, and by the survey of the commerce of the cities, the results of which have been embodied in the preceding pages, the communities that, as a rule, are dissatisfied with the freight rate ad- justments are not those whose natural advantage of location and whose economic strength have led to their becoming established commercial centers. When com- plaints have come from such centers they have not, at least in recent years, been in regard to the rate structure affecting the commerce of the city in general, but of certain particular rates. The list of community com- plaints on page 296 contains the name of no town or city of New England, none in the Trunk Line territory, and but one in the Central Traffic territory. The com- plaints, both from the South and from the West, are mostly from inconspicuous towns that are without any considerable degree of economic strength. That mould- ing of the freight rate structures which are, on the whole, admirably adapted to facilitate the flow of traffic, has been under economic influences which have acted upon the railroads with far greater power than the railroads have reacted upon them. As we have learned, however, there are certain lines of cleavage between the sections in which the regional rate structures respec- tively apply — and there is undeniable inconvenience in the adjustment of rates on inter-regional traffic that necessitates the use of different and divergent classi- fications. It is evident that were every conceivable dis- turbing element a factor in the rate adjustment applying to the commerce of any one city, the merchants and manufacturers of that city would doubtless consider themselves aggrieved. That these factors do focus with Gommerce of the Cities 369 perturbing effect upon a particular city is quite true, and it would seem to be the irony of fate that it is one of the fairest in the land. That city, however, does not owe its location to any industrial or commercial advantages. When it was sought to establish a capital for the newly admitted State of Indiana, a site was selected almost exactly in the center of the State. The " Governor's Mansion " was erected in a circular plot in the center of the settle- ment, and a plan of streets staked out, the thoroughfares six squares from the circle in each direction being des- ignated as East Street, West Street, North Street and South Street, to indicate the extreme limits to which un- der the fondest hopes then entertained the city might reach. Because of its central location the railroads be- tween Chicago and Cincinnati and Louisville, and be- tween St. Louis and the East, naturally intersected at Indianapolis, which therefore became a railroad center, and, hence, a distributing point for the towns and vil- lages of the surrounding counties. There' was no material in Indiana for manufactures, unless coal from the fields in the southwestern counties be so designated. But from time to time the industry and the ambition of one and now another of her resi- dents led to the development of an artisan's shop into a factory. The products naturally and necessarily were not such as grow out of the assemblage of vast quan- tities of raw material, but those dependent upon ingenu- ity and skill of workmanship. Thus developed the man- ufacture of vehicles, saws and other tools, and of cer- tain high grade machinery; and the growth of livestock in the adjacent regions led to the establishment of a packing house. The products of these establishments, and other articles, found markets in Indiana and else- where, the freight rates not being given particular con- sideration, as they did not measurably restrict their sale. Fifteen or more years ago, however, after the dis- covery of natural gas in central Indiana, glass and tin plate factories were erected in the natural gas belt; the 370 Railroad Freight Rates State progressed in manufacture and in ambition. The manufacturing establishments of IndianapoHs did not radically increase in number, but the existing concerns vastly increased in extent and output. They sought to widen the area of their markets even in competition with Chicago and St. Louis, and the wholesale merchants were no longer content with the patronage of customers of the surrounding towns. This led to a scrutiny of the freight rates, develop- ing many cases in which the rates per ton per mile from Indianapolis to distant markets are higher than for sim- ilar distances from other long-established manufactur- ing and distributing centers that originate great volumes of traffic. This can be partly and broadly accounted for by the fact that Indianapolis is not served by any navigable waterway, as are its overshadowing neighbors, Chicago, Cincinnati, Louisville and St. Louis. It can be accounted for partly by the fact that Chicago, Cin- cinnati, Louisville and St. Louis are each an initial point of lines leading to the West and leading to the South upon which the manufacturers and merchants of these cities bring pressure to bear for rates that will inure to the benefit of their trade. The commercially and industrially weaker city of Indianapolis, pocketed between these communities that were of established might while she was yet but the capital town of an in- terior State, can exert no such economic demand. Its shippers are subjected to annoyance growing out of the fact that although the city is in the territory in which the Official Classification applies, it is so near the dividing lines that its shipments to the West have to be made under the Western Classification, and to the South under the Southern Classification. The railroads do not attempt to contest the obvious facts, but broadly claim that the freight rates to Indian- apolis permit her shipments to go to all logical markets, saying that if she desires to sell vehicles in the South in competition with Louisville and Cincinnati, or products of whatever kind in the West in competition with Chi- Commerce of the Cities 371 cago and St. Louis, and to do so is obliged to absorb the difference in the freight rates, which at the most are but a small item in the marketing of such products as she makes — she only does what other cities have to do to overcome their handicaps, what they naturally ought to do in order to enter markets already served by competi- tors of greater economic strength. They call attention to the fact that Indianapolis benefits by the Trunk Line Per- centage System on East and West bound traffic, and that to change its percentage of the New York-Chicago rate would disturb other rates. The railroads point out that the commodities which Indianapolis needs to bring from other places, for the use and consumption of her citizens, are carried to her portals at rates relatively as low as to any of the cities of the traffic region in which she is located; that in so far as the transportation charge is concerned, the retail merchants of Indianapolis do not need to ask higher prices on wearing apparel, foodstuffs, furniture, or on the appliances of general use than the retail merchants of even Chicago or St. Louis or Cincinnati. In this connection, however, the wholesale grocers of Indianapolis state that while the railroads charge 17 cents per 100 pounds for carrying sugar 710 miles from New Orleans to St. Louis, 17 cents for the 700 miles to Evansville, 17 cents for the 811 miles to Louisville, and 25 cents for the 922 miles to Chicago, they charge 25 cents for the 838 miles to Indianapolis. They state that sugar is the foremost item of a wholesale grocer's stock, that it is sold at little or no profit at the best, but that it is the main staple which attracts trade, retail grocers purchasing other merchandise where they obtain sugar. These wholesale grocers of Indianapolis are especially incensed because rates were increased on sugar to their city, while no increases were made to the other river cities named, whose wholesale dealers are thereby given an increased advantage over their rivals at In- dianapolis for the trade of the competitive area. The railroads point out that the sugar rates cannot be made 372 Railroad Freight Rates higher to the cities on the Mississippi and Ohio Rivers, as they are now at the limit above which the boats would take the traffic, and that in the absence of this water competition they are not compelled to continue this low level to Indianapolis to which the present rate is not unreasonable, being one cent less for the 838 miles from New Orleans than for the 825 miles from New lYork. The situation at Indianapolis is aggravated by local complications. One railroad system, extending through- out Ohio into Indiana, has made effective over its lines to the east and south of Indianapolis the scale of local rates decreed for Ohio by the legislature of that State. Other of the Indiana lines adhere to the older scales under which rates are somewhat higher, except that on that portion of their lines east of Indianapolis they have met the rates of the line that applied the Ohio scale as far as that city. As even the railroad system carrying the Ohio rates as far as Indianapolis has not applied those rates to such of its lines as extend from Indian- apolis to St. Louis, there are at least two scales of local rates effective in Indiana. A wholesale dealer of Indian- apolis, therefore, finds his freight charge, for example, for thirty-five miles in one direction higher than for forty miles in another direction. While it is quite true that the same rates apply over the different lines to a point east of the city, and that the rates are the same by the different lines to a point west of the city, it is difficult for a shipper to see why there should be the different scales. The railroads of Indiana, aware that if some uniform and satisfactory adjustment is not made of these intrastate rates the legislature will likely, as the State Railroad Commission has already attempted, de- cree still lower rates than any now in effect, have en- deavored to come to an agreement. Certain of the rail- roads of the State, whose lines are not in the great traffic channels, are, however, not inclined to reduce their local rates to the level of those of the great systems Commerce of the Cities 373 carrying a large volume of through in addition to their local traffic. Another phase of the situation is also vexatious to the wholesale merchants and the manufacturers of this city. Because of the- river communication between both Cincinnati and Louisville and St. Louis, the direct rail lines between those cities have been obliged to make rates that will enable them to secure traffic in competi- tion with the boats. If the lines between either Cin- cinnati or Louisville and St. Louis by way of Indian- apolis desire to carry any of this traffic, they must do so at the water- forced rates in effect by the direct line, and these in some cases are lower than the rates from In- dianapolis to St. Louis. This naturally gives an advan- tage over Indianapolis to the shippers of Cincinnati and Louisville who send merchandise to St. Louis. The railroads, however, say that the rates from Indianapolis to St. Louis are not unreasonable; that the fact that lower rates are in effect from Cincinnati and Louisville is because of the geologic forces that determined the course of the rivers ; that inasmuch as such of this traffic as they can obtain at competitive rates more than pays the immediate outlay because of such traffic, it is good business for them to take it. The continuance of the Indianapolis lines in this traffic does not hurt that city: their retirement from that traffic would not help that city. CHAPTER XXIII A COMPARISON OF THE RAILROADS WITH THE AGRICULTURAL AND MANU- FACTURING INDUSTRIES The foregoing chapters have treated principally of the freight rates of the railroads from the exterior view- point of their effect upon the commerce of the country: that is, in their service to the industrial and commercial agencies. It remains to consider the freight rates as a factor in the revenue derived by the railroads from the performance of transportation and the relation borne by this revenue to the maintenance and extension of the railroads; that is, from the interior view point of the effect of the service of the industrial and commercial agencies to the railroads. The three material functions that are vital and essen- tial to the social organization are those of agriculture, manufacture, and transportation. They are as vital and essential to the social organism as are the heart, the stomach and the lungs to the processes of the body. It is imperative that the nourishment absorbed by the body, as a whole, be distributed to the heart, the lungs and the stomach to renew their tissue and to maintain the energy with which each contributes to the welfare of the body, as a whole. So also is the national welfare pro- moted by each industry under justly economical adminis- tration obtaining adequate return over expenditures to provide for its effective maintenance and operation, and to attract capital sufficient for its continuance. One test of the efficiency of the railroads as a factor in the social organism is that gained by a comparison of the relative parts performed in the material activity of this country by agriculture, manufacture and the railroads. At first glance, there would seem to be difficulty in the 374 Comparison of the Railroads 375 way of obtaining a comparison adequate for effective deduction. As, however, the foot is the unit of measure of length and the pound the unit of measure of weight, so also in this country the dollar is the unit of measure of value. In every industry — in agriculture, manufac- ture and transportation — there must be capital and capi- tal is measured by dollars. There must be expenditure, and expenditure is measured by dollars. There must be gross earnings and net returns, and the gross earnings and the net returns are measured by dollars. There must be workers in each industry, and their salaries and wages are measured by dollars. With the dollar is meas- ured the value of such dissimilar things as a ton of iron, and a physician's visit. That is, if the price of one is twenty dollars, and the fee for the other two dollars, their relative value is ten to one. Likewise with the dollar can be measured the diverse elements that enter into the industries of manufacture, agriculture and trans- portation, which may not be so radically diverse as they may seem at first. Although the dollar may not be as inflexible a unit throughout time as the foot or the pound, it is a definite and exact unit of measure of value at any specified time. The following tables express the measurement by dol- lars of the value of the intake and the outgo of these three branches of industry. The amounts for the rail- roads have been ascertained from the reports of the In- terstate Commerce Commission for the years 1905, 1900 and 1890; for manufactures, from the census of 1900, the census of 1890, and the special census of manufac- tures for 1905 ; for agriculture, from the census of 1900, the census of 1890, and the reports in the year book of the Department of Agriculture for 1905. These latter reports have been analyzed and criticised by statisticians of the Division of Agriculture of the United States Census and subjected to certain modifications in accord- ance with estimates made by them. In the comparisons based on these tables, the returns for 1890 are not used, as the census figures for that year are admittedly in- 376 Railroad Freight Rates complete and the statistics of the Interstate Commerce Commission are not so highly developed as for later years. MANUFACTURES 1905 1900 1S90 Capital $13,872,035,371 $9,817,434,799 $6,525,136,486 Number of salary and wage-earners 6,718,618 5.705.165 4,712,622 Gross value of products.. 16,866,706,985 13,004,400,143 9,372,437.283 Cost of materials used 9,497,619,851 7.345.4i3.65i 5.162,044,076 Total salaries and wages.. 3,623,589,623 2,726,045,110 2,283,216,529 Miscellaneous expenses.... 1,651,603,535 1.027,755,778 631,225,035 Net returns from products. 2,093,893,976 1,905,185,604 1,295.951.643 RAILROADS Capitalization $13,805,258,121 $11,491,034,960 $9,437,343,420 Number of salary and wage-earners 1,382,196 1,017,653 749. 301 Gross earnings 2,082,482,406 1,487,044,814 1,051,877,632 Cost of materials used... 550,657,472 384,163,670 Total salaries and wages.. 839,944,680 577,264,841 692,093,971 Miscellaneous expenses.... 75.538,597 53,765,267 Net earnings 616,341,657 471,851,036 359.783.661 AGRICULTURE Capital $30,043,000,000 $22,939,901,164 $18,082,267,689 Number of farmers and farm laborers 10,900,000 10,381,765 8,565,926 Value of product 5,738,850,000 4,311,372,177 2,933,985,914 Wages paid labor 393,690,000 357,391,930 257,450,387 Fertilizer 61,366,300 53,430,910 38,469,598 Taxes 225,322,500 172,049,257 135,617,007 Interest on capital at 7 per cent 2,103,010,000 1,605,793,081 1,265,758,738 Net return to farm owners 2,945,461,20a 2,122,706,999 1,236,690,184 Because of the lack of absolute returns in the case of manufactures and agriculture, deductions cannot be made from the foregoing premises that will be of the clear cut and exact nature required by an accountant in making up a balance sheet. The figures in the fol- lowing comparisons, therefore, in the case of manu- factures and agriculture are not to be considered as defi- nite calculations, but rather as indications so veiled with mist that the clear-cut outlines are obscured, but yet allowing sufficient perception of form and mass to guide the pilot. From the standpoint of the investor, the standpoint of the man whose money is in a business, the prime consideration is always what is the rate of return on the capital in that business? From the standpoint of the consumer, of the purchaser of commodities and services, Comparison of the Railroads 377 a prime consideration is the greatest satisfaction that can be obtained for the lowest price. The interest of the nation, as a whole, is that its citizens should obtain a fair return for their efforts, and should obtain at fair prices the commodities and services which they need. To revert to the simile used in a previous paragraph, if the equilibrium of the functions of the body be dis- turbed, if ovemutrition of one organ lead to the im- poverishment of another, if the unduly accelerated func- tions of one lead to an impairment in the performance of another, there will, if such a condition continue, ulti- mately result the prostration of the body as a whole. So also it is with the social organism, the body politic. From the foregoing table we ascertain the following to be the NET RETURNS PER EACH $1,000 OF CAPITAL I90S 1900 Manufactures $151 $194 Railroads 44 41 Agriculture 98 92 The most extreme modification of the tables conse- quent upon the completest information would not in all probability alter the conspicuous deduction from this comparison ; that is, the investor looking for the greatest immediate profit in either 1900 or 1905 would have turned first to manufacture, then to agriculture, and lastly to the railroads. The tremendous development of manufactures and the enormous prosperity of the farm- ing regions of the West confirm this deduction. If it be claimed that the low net returns to the railroads is because of their inflated capitalization the reply is made that the actual capitalization of the American railroads, including all cases of inflation, is only about $52,000 a mile, which is far less than that of the railroads of any other country. Recent reports of the actual expenditure for construction show that it costs in this country to build one mile of railroad from $25,000 over level coun- try, where there are no obstacles, to over $100,000 in 378 Railroad Freight Rates places of dense population and where construction is difficult. This does not include buildings or equipment. If it be claimed that the capitalization of the railroads is inflated, cognizance should be taken of various lines of the manufacturing industry whose capitalization was multiplied again and again at the time of the industrial amalgamations succeeding the depression that termi- nated in 1898, and of the fact that the values at which farming and timber lands are held in many parts of the country have doubled and quadrupled since that time. The net returns are what remain of the gross returns after the payment of all expenses. The ratio of these gross returns and expenditures to capital is shown in the following table: GROSS RETURNS PER $1,000 OF CAPITAL 1905 1900 Manufactures $1,216 $1,324 Railroads 150 128 Agriculture 191 187 The excessive amount in the case of manufacture is largely due to the fact that in selling a manufactured product the manufacturer has to be reimbursed for the cost of all the elements that enter into that product, and these elements in large degree consist of commodities which, although raw material to the final manufac- turer, may be the finished products of intermediate manufacture. For example, boots and shoes are a prod- uct of which manufactured leather is the raw material, manufactured leather is a product of which tanned hides are the raw material, and raw hides are the raw material of the tanner. TOTAL EXPENDITURES PER EACH $1,000 OF CAPITAL 1905 1900 Manufactures' $1,065 $1,130 Railroads 106 87 Agriculture 75 77 In the case of manufactures these expenditures are 88 per cent, of the gross returns, the high ratio being Comparison of the Railroads 379 caused by the high value of the products of intermediate manufacture that are included as raw material. The deduction of the value of such partly manufactured products from the gross value of the manufactured products eliminates duplication. That is, the value of manufactured leather, which appears in the gross value of products as an output of the leather factory, disap- pears from the net returns of the boot and shoe factory when the value of the raw material used by the boot and shoe factory is deducted from the value of its products. In the case of agriculture, the expenditures are but 39 per cent, of the gross returns. This is due in part to the fact that the farmer's payments for raw material are low ; and in part to the fact that the sun and the rain, for which he does not pay, are the farmer's most efifect- ive instruments. The expenditure of the railroads is 71 per cent, of the gross returns, 32 points higher than the expendi- ture of agriculture and but 17 points below the expend- iture of manufactures, even although the expenditure account of the railroads for material contains no items similar to the partly manufactured products of manu- factures. Although the labor cost is not the total cost of any industry, it is a most important factor in that total cost, and in the analysis of any business is subject to rigid scrutiny. On nearly every farm the farmer himself is an active worker, but the census returns do not show separately the farmers and the farm laborers. There- fore, the labor cost in the case of agriculture is omitted from the following tables : TOTAL SALARY-WAGE FOR EACH $1,000 OF CAPITAL 1905 1900 Manufactures $261 $277 Railroads 61 50 In the case of manufactures, labor received 'jz P^r cent, greater return than capital ; in the case of the rail- 3S0 Railroad Freight Rates roads, labor received 38 per cent, greater return than capital. The ratio of labor cost to capital for the rail- roads was but 23 per cent, of that for manufacture, while the labor charge of the railroads per dollar of net returns was but 78 per cent, of that for manufacture. The labor of the railroads, however, is applied through machinery to a far greater degree than the labor of either manufactures or agriculture, the horse-power of the machinery of the railroads exceeding the horse- power of the machinery of manufactures and agricul- ture combined. It is, moreover, disclosed by the first of these comparative statements that the capital of manu- factures received a net return of 107 points higher, or 243 per cent, greater, than that of the railroads. That is, it required to produce one dollar of net returns, $6.62 of capital in the case of manufactures, $9.44 in the case of agriculture, while it requires $22,40 of capital in the case of the railroads. AVERAGE SALARY-WAGE PER WORKER I90S 1900 Manufactures $539 $477 Railroads 607 567 TOTAL SALARY-WAGE PER EACH $1,000 OP EXPENDITURE I9OS 1900 Manufactures $245 $245 Railroads 572 568 TOTAL SALARY-WAGE PER $1,000 NET RETURNS I9OS 1900 Manufactures $i,730 $i,430 Railroads 1,362 1,223 The average salary-wage paid by the railroads was 12.6 greater than the average paid by the manufacturers. Notwithstanding this, manufactures paid 27 per cent, more salary-wage to produce $1,000 net returns than the railroads. The salary-wage required to produce $1,000 in net returns increased in five years 21 per cent. Comparison of the Railroads 381 for manufactures and 11 per cent, for the railroads. That the high average salary-wage for the railroads is not caused by the heavy salaries of the administrative officers is shown by the fact that of the $839,944,680 paid in 1905 by the railroads in salaries and wages, but $15,155,278, or 1.8 per cent, went to the general offi- cers. In the aggregate, the high salaries of the presi- dents are insignificant. In comparison with the salaries paid the executive officers of the great industrial corporations of this day, the salaries of the railroad presidents are no longer ex- traordinary. It is conspicuous and significant that of the total expenditure of manufactures but 24 per centi was for salary-wage, while of the total expenditure of the railroads 57 per cent, was for salary-wage. The tables that are given next cast further light upon the relation of labor to each of the three branches of industry. NUMBER OF WORKERS PER $100,000 OF CAPITAL I9OS 1900 Manufactures 48 58 Railroads 10 9 Agriculture 36 4S That is, for each $100,000 of capital, manufactures give employment to 380 per cent, more workers than the railroads, agriculture to 260 per cent. more. NUMBER OF WORKERS PER $100,000 NET RETURNS I9OS 1900 Manufactures 320 291 Railroads 224 215 Agriculture 37° 489 That is, to produce $100,000 of net returns, manufac- tures require 43 per cent, more workers than the rail- roads, and agriculture 65 per cent. more. Not only is the ratio "of labor charge to capital less in the case of the railroads, but the number of workers per given amount of capital is vastly less. Although their work- 382 Railroad Freight Rates ers receive a higher average wage, a given amount of net returns is produced by the railroads with 70 per cent, of the number of workers required in manufac- tures, and 60 per cent, of the number required in agri- culture. The comparisons brought out by the preceding tables and the deductions therefrom show that while the ad- ministration of the railroads is far more economical than that of either manufactures or agriculture, the re- turns to capital are far less. This would indicate that the prices for the product of the railroads — that is the rates for transportation — are relatively lower than the prices for the products of manufacture and for the products of agriculture. This deduction is borne out by figures which also are obtained from publications of the United States Government. Bulletin No. 65 of the Bureau of Labor, issued July, 1906, contains the results of an investigation into the wages and hours of labor in the manufacturing indus- tries from 1890 to 1905, and of an investigation of the retail prices of food from 1890 to 1905. It states : " The average wages per hour in igos were i8.g per cent, higher than the average for the ten-year period from 1890 to 1899, inclusive. The average earnings per week were 14 per cent, higher, and the average hours of labor per week were 4.I per cent, lower." The same report says: " The average prices of wheat, bread, butter, cheese, chickens, cornmeal, eggs, fresh fish, salt fish, milk, mutton and veal were higher in 1905 than in any other year of the sixteen-year period. The advance in bacon since 1896 has been 43.5 per cent. ; the advance in Irish potatoes, 43.1 per cent. ; the advance in eggs, 41.8 per cent. ; the advance in dry or pickled pork, 31.9 per cent. ; the advance in fresh pork, 30 per cent. ; the advance in flour, 29.3 per cent. ; the advance in cornmeal, 28.6 per cent. The advance in food, . . . according to its consumption in the family of the workingman, has been . . . 12.4 per cent., when compared with the average for the ten-year period 1890 to 1899." Bulletin No. 69 of the Bureau of Labor, issued March, 1907, contains a record of wholesale prices of all com- Comparison of the Railroads 383 modities from 1890. Taking the average wholesale price from 1890 to 1899 as 100 per cent., this record shows that wholesale prices increased as follows for 1905 : farm products, 24.2 per cent. ; food, etc., 8.7 per cent ; cloths and clothing, 12 per cent. ; fuel and light- ing, 28.8 per cent. ; metals and implements, 22.5 per cent. ; lumber and building materials, 27.7 per cent. ; drugs and chemicals, 9.1 per cent.; miscellaneous, 12.8 per cent; all commodities, 15.9 per cent. Turning to the reports of the Interstate Commerce Commission we find that the average rate per ton per mile for 1890 was .941 cents — that is, nine hundred and forty-one one-thousandths of a cent; for 1900, .729 cents, and for 1905, .766 cents. Although the average rate per ton per mile for 1905 increased one-half of one per cent, over the average rate for 1900, the average rate for 1905 was but 91.2 per cent, of the average for the period from 1890 to 1899. That is, the average for 1905 was 8.8 per cent, lower than the average for the ten-year period. CHAPTER XXIV THE PROGRESSIVE ACHIEVEMENT OF THE RAILROADS Another viewpoint from which to j"udge the height- ening efficiency of the railroads of this country is af- forded by a comparison for different periods of the various phases of their status and of their performance. The principal factors through which the record of a railroad is brought to test, are: (i) The operating revenues, which depend on the rates and the volume of traffic. Traffic is measured by ton miles, the unit being one ton of freight carried one mile; and by passenger miles, the unit being one pas- senger carried one mile. The sum of ton miles and passenger miles may, for the purposes of this presenta- tion, be considered as the number of traffic units, al- though the two units differ in many respects. (2) The operating expenses, which depend upon the facilities for operation, modified, however, by the volume of traffic and the peculiar requirements of particular traffic. Facilities are measured by miles of line, miles of track, number and tractive power of locomotives, num- ber and capacity of freight cars, and number of em- ployees of the various grades. Efficiency of operation is measured, other things being equal, by the ratio be- tween the units of operation and the units of traffic ; and, also, other things being equal, by the ratio between the gross earnings and the expense of operation. Units of operation are freight-train miles and passenger-train miles. The greater the ratio of tons to freight-train miles and the greater the ratio of passengers to passen- ger-train miles, the greater, other things equal, is the efficiency of operation. The lower the ratio of operating expense to gross earnings, other things equal, the greater is the efficiency of operation. 384 Achievement of the Railroads 385 (3) The operating income, what is left of the operating revenues after the operating expenses and taxes have been paid. This remainder, plus the income from sources other than operating, constitutes the fund from which interest on funded debt and the dividends are payable, and from which contribution is made to the surplus. (4) The capitalization, the amount upon which the bondholders and stockholders expect returns. The relation borne by these various factors one to another, in the progressive performance of the railroads of this country, is shown by the following tables of per- centages. As publication of collected statistics of the railroads of this country did not begin until a number of years after the close of the Civil War, and as the comprehensive presentations of the present day were attained only by gradual development, no one of these tables is based on information for any part of the period prior to 1871, and for many of the headings informa- tion is obtainable only for more recent years. Data for the years prior to 1889 has been compiled from Poor's Manual; for 1889 and subsequent years, from the sta- tistics of the Interstate Commerce Commission. During the decade from 1875 to 1885, the comparative increases in the different phases of railroad activity were as follows: FACILITIES Increase (per cent.) Miles of line 72.38 Locomotives 67.09 Freight cars II3-8S Passenger cars 23.32 FINANCE Capitalization 77-6i Gross earnings 5357 Net earnings 45-27 Operating expenses 58.42 Interest and dividends 57-93 This decade of rapid extension of the railroads im- mediately followed the uniting of small roads, serving a local traffic, into through lines. These through lines 386 Railroad Freight Rates were extended in advance of traffic, and new railroads were built into undeveloped regions. With the exten- sion of the through lines was inaugurated the competi- tion for long-distance traffic. Rate wars and rebates were at their height during the early years of the dec- ade; then, owing to the steadying efifect of the traffic associations, dividends increased until the volume of traffic fell with the minor depression of 1884. Of the increase in capitalization, about two-thirds is accounted for by the cash value of new line and new equipment, leaving about one-third, or about $1,200,000,000, to be accounted for by buildings and other structures, fran- chises, and other assets^ and the natural increase in the value of the properties in general with whatever there may have been of " water." The ratios of increase from 1885 to 1895 are as fol- lows : FACILITIES Increase (per cent.) Miles of line 41-45 Miles of track 47-Si Locomotives 38.46 Freight cars 47-34 Passenger cars 9I-5I TRAFFIC Ton miles 73-39 Passenger miles 33-44 Traffic units 66.00 FINANCES Capitalization 21.34 Gross earnings 39-19 Net earnings 29.74 Operating expenses 44-25 Interest and dividends 27.42 That during this decade there was more of intensive than of extensive growth is shown by the fact that the percentage of new line was little more than half as great as during the previous decade, and was six per \ cent, less than the ratio of increase of miles of track. \ \ Achievement of the Railroads 387 Miles of line, miles of track, supply of locomotives, and freight cars, all increased in practically double the ratio of the increase in capitalization. It was toward the close of this decade that new and powerful locomotives and the new and enlarged freight cars came into serv- ice, the increase in power per locomotive and in ca- pacity per freight car making the actual increase in equipment far greater than that indicated by the increase in number. There was a marked increase in the number of passenger cars. The cost of additional track and equip- ment acquired during this decade exceeded the increase in capitalization, a fact which indicates that the cost was met in great measure from the earnings. The low ratio of increase indicates a hardening-down of capitalization caused by this placing of earnings back into the proper- ties, and also by the scaling down through receiverships and reorganizations following the panic of 1893. The earnings for the decade as a whole did not gain in pro- portion to the increase in facilities. The last year of the decade, however, was one of severe industrial depres- sion, gross and net earnings each falling about twelve per cent, below the amounts of 1893. The ratios of increase from 1895 to 1905 are as fol- lows: FACILITIES Increase (per cent.) Miles of line 20.72 Miles of track 29.29 Locomotives 35-46 Freight cars 44-76 Passenger cars 22.96 TRAFFIC Ton miles "8.78 Passenger miles 95-26 Traffic units iiS-84 FINANCES Capitalization 17-34 Gross earnings 93-65 Net earnings 98-45 Operating expenses 91.62 Interest and dividends 62.4a 388 Railroad Freight Rates This decade also exhibits a greater proportion of in- tensive than of extensive growth, miles of track, supply of locomotives and freight cars, all increasing in far greater ratio than miles of line. The extraordinary in- crease in the number of passenger cars during the pre- ceding decade explains the low ratio of increase in this decade. The cost of the additions to facilities again exceeds the increase in capitalization. Indeed, the pro- portion of the earnings of the American railroads that was being turned back into the properties excited such apprehension in foreign countries that the English in- vestors sent over an expert to examine into this dispo- .sition of the earnings to ascertain if there were justifi- cation for it. He reported that the maintenance of the railroads and their development to meet the extraordi- nary increase of traffic that began with 1898 made imperative the expenditure of vast sums upon improve- ments and extensions. These expenditures for improve- ments out of earnings tended still further to solidify the capitalization. This naturally elicited complaints from the stockholders whose dividends were not aug- mented to an extent at all commensurate with the increases in traffic or in earnings. The pressure for lower rates, the steady increase in taxes of all kinds, the rapidly increasing wages and the mounting prices of all material used by the railroads, forced great economies in methods of operation. These were made possible largely by the powerful locomotives and the capacious freight cars. The traffic units carried per dollar of capitalization, which had increased 38 per cent, from 1885 to 1895, increased 91 per cent, from 1895 to 1905. The number of traffic units carried per mile of track increased 13 per cent, from 1885 to 1895, and 66 per cent, from 1895 to 1905. The number of traffic units carried per locomotive increased 21 per cent, from 1885 to 1895, and 59 per cent, from 1895 to 1905. The number of traffic units carried per employee increased 22.59 per cent, from 1895 to 1905. This greater per- formance per unit of plant is also reflected in the ratio Achievement of the Railroads 389 of the capitalization to the earnings. In 1885 it took $10.15 of capitalization to produce one dollar of gross earnings; in 1895, $8.84; in 1905, but $5.36. The capi- talization per unit of traffic was 13.4 cents in 1885, 9.7 cents in 1895, and but 5.3 in 1905. This result was at- tained notwithstanding that the average rate per ton per mile in 20 years had decreased 27.5 per cent. The progressive efficiency of the American railroads, the progressive increase, both relative and absolute, in their contribution to the activity of the nation, are shown by the fact that the rate of increase in traffic carried was persistently greater than the rate of increase in cap- italization or in earnings, notwithstanding the decreas- ing charge for transportation. These results are sum- marized in the following tabulation: 187s 1885 1895 to 1885 to 189s to 1905 I Keturn to capital: increase (.per cent.; Rate per ton per mile : decrease (per cent.) 20.00 8.70 to I885 to 189s to 1905 Traffic units: increase (per cent.) 66.00 115.84 Capitalization: increase (per cent.).. 77.61 21.34 17-34 Gross earnings : increase (per cent.) 53-57 39.19 93-65 Net earnings: increase (per cent.).. 45.27 29.74 98-45 Return to capital: increase (per cent.) 27.42 62.40 Ratp Tipr tnn npr mile r Herrease ^ner In the vociferous discussions of recent years so much has been said about the " fictitious " capitalization, the " over " capitalization, the " wind and water " in the capitalization of the railroads of the United States that the statement that the capitalization per mile has been gradually diminishing will doubtless be received with incredulity. Yet, that is the exact truth as shown by the statistics published by the Interstate Commerce Commission. In connection with the tables of capital- ization published in its volume of statistics for 1905, the Commission states that in so far as the given amount of capitalization includes bonds or stocks of railroads which are owned by other railroads, the total represents a duplication. For example, the Northwestern Ohio Railway Company and the Pittsburg, Fort Wayne and Chicago Railway Company have each issued stock, which. 390 Railroad Freight Rates however, is owned principally by the Pennsylvania Com- pany. The Pennsylvania Company has issued stock which is in large measure supported by these under- lying issues of the Northwestern Ohio Railway Com- pany and the Pittsburg, Fort Wayne and Chicago Rail- way Company. All the stock of the Pennsylvania Com- pany is in turn owned by the Pennsylvania Railroad Company. It is, therefore, manifestly a duplication to include the stock issues of the subsidiary companies, as well as the total stock issue of the Pennsylvania Rail- road Company. For another example, a majority of the stock of the Mobile and Ohio Railroad Company is owned by the Southern Railway Company, and is, there- fore, covered by the stock of the latter company. It is, therefore, a duplication to list the entire stock of the Mobile and Ohio, as well as the entire stock of the Southern in a table giving the capitalization of the American railroads. This, however, notwithstanding the statement just referred to, is what the Commission does, making the average capitalization $65,926 per mile for 1905. If from the total capitalization, as given in the tables of the Commission, we deduct the amounts of duplicated capitalization, as given in the statistics of the Commission, the average capitalization per mile for 1905 is found to be $51,201* instead of over $65,000. The average capitalization per mile for 1895 was $52,676 ; for 1885, $61,400; for 1875, $59,593- In 1875 there was very little ownership of the issues of one railroad company by another, and in 1885 the proportion was still small. This period of promotion and rapid extension doubtless knew more or less of * The Special Report, No. I, of the Interstate Commerce Commission on Intercorporate Relationships of Railways, as of June 30, 1906, shows the net capitalization per mile to be $36,173 of bonded debt, and $21,877 of stock, a total of $58,050. The compiler of this report states that : " It is probable that this net amount will be further reduced by a later and still more exhaustive investigation." Therefore, the calculations in this chapter, which was written prior to the publication of this report, and based upon the Interstate Commerce Commission's Statistics for 1905, have not been revised. Achievement of the Railroads 391 watered capitalization; that is, if the capitalization be considered at par. It was the custom, however, to issue large amounts of stock as a bonus to induce investors to place their money in bonds, and these issues of stock, dependent upon future development for whatever value they might have, sold far below par. The receiverships and reorganizations following 1893 reduced the average capitalization to $52,676 in 1895. In the following dec- ade the development of the " community of interests " led to very large purchases by this company and that company of the stocks and bonds of other companies, and one effect was that the average capitalization per mile, in 1905, was but $51,201 at par. This low aver- age is also in part accounted for by the extensions made out of earnings. In 1890, for every $295 of gross earn- ings, one dollar was spent for permanent improvements. In 1895, the ratio was one dollar for improvements to every $320 of gross earnings; in 1900 one dollar for every $66; in 1905, one dollar for every $63, and in 1906, one dollar for every $49. The relative decrease in capitalization, together with the tremendous increase in facilities and in improve- ments in operation, accounts for the fact that the ratio of the value of plant to a given amount of traffic de- creased 28 per cent, from 1885 to 1895, and 25 per cent, from 1895 to 1905. In view of these facts, it seems impossible that there can at this time be any sub- stantial amount of water in the capitalization of the rail- roads of the United States. Such over-capitalization as still exists is sporadic, and where water is still to be found, it is being forced out by the receiverships and the reorganizations that occur from time to time, just as the healthy body forces deleterious elements in the blood to the surface, and then ejects them from the system. For the decade ending in 1905, the railroads carried 115.84 per cent, more traffic for 93.65 per cent, more money, the volume of traffic, therefore, increasing 22.19 per cent, more rapidly than the compensation for carry- 392 Railroad Freight Rates ing it. The employees, dealers in supplies, and others concerned in the operation, received 91.62 per cent, more compensation, while capital received but 62.4 per cent, greater returns. The disposition by the railroads of the United States of their income, dollar by dollar, for the year 1907 is indicated by the following exhibit of one of the trunk lines; for salaries and wages, 38.2 cents ; to dealers for supplies, etc., 30.8 cents ; for taxes, 3.1 cents; for interest and rentals, 17.8 cents; for div- idends, 9.7 cents; for surplus .4 cents. The facts brought to light by this scrutiny — ^that the railroads have moved a greatly increased traffic at lower rates, that they have vastly increased their facilities with a relatively decreasing capitalization, and yet that their expenses for operation have increased about 50 per cent, faster than the returns on their capital — demon- strate a progressive economy of administration from which their employees and the public have derived a far greater proportion of benefit than the bondholders and stockholders. Another question of foremost importance is what has been the effect of this economy upon the railroads? Although the record of their performance, as disclosed by these statistics, is that of constantly increasing achievement, everyone knows that during the period from 1898 to 1907 the railroads of this country had to face increasing criticism and execration, and a seem- ingly universal hostility. Shippers were not supplied with as many cars as they desired, nor as promptly as they desired them. Shipments were subjected to long delays in transit, and there was one disastrous wreck after another. The popular antagonism found vent in laws enacted by Congress, and by many of the State legislatures — many of these laws increasingly impeding the operation of the already overburdened railroads. There were few to believe that the officers of the rail- roads, the men who in reality were accomplishing the magnificent results here placed in evidence, were doing the best that they could do. There were few to believe Achievement of the Railroads 393 even their simple statement that if any one would show them how to produce better results under the limita- tions that bound them, they would be only too willing to avail themselves of suggestions. The truth is that the- railroad employees, from gen- eral managers down to section men, were struggling with an ever-rising tide of traffic that threatened to overwhelm them. The figures tell the story. In ten years the traffic increased 115 per cent. This was double, or more than double, the increase in facilities and about seven times the increase in capitalization. Had it not been for the panic of 1893 the ton miles for the decade ending 1895 would have increased at least 100 per cent. They did increase 73.39 per cent., and for the decade ending 1905 they increased 118.78 per cent. Speaking broadly, the freight traffic of this country increases about 100 per cent, every ten years, and there is every likelihood that it will increase 100 per cent, or more in the next ten years, a period of de- pression being more than made up by a return of pros- perity. Twenty years ago the traffic units were eighty billions a year, and preparation for a one hundred per cent, in- crease meant provision for an additional eighty billions. Now the traffic units are over two hundred and fifty billions a year, and preparation for a one hundred per cent, increase means preparation for an additional two hundred and fifty billions. It is not likely that it will be possible during the next ten years to reduce the ratio of the value of plant to unit of traffic in any such pro- portion as during the last ten years. Freight cars cannot be built any higher without a change in the standard of overhead clearances throughout the country. They cannot be made any wider, for they will not pass on a double track. They cannot be made any longer, for they are now standardized in length to fit the loading and unloading facilities at elevators, warehouses and ore docks; and are as long as the curvatures on the leading railroads of the country will permit. Likewise the 394 Railroad Freight Rates power of the locomotives cannot be increased except through intensive improvements. Therefore, provision for a one hundred per cent, increase in traffic will more nearly approximate a one hundred per cent, increase in facilities than heretofore. There must be extensive pur- chases of real estate for enlargement of yards and ter- minals. If provision for a one hundred per cent, increase of traffic were to mean an increase of one hundred per cent, in facilities, the existing railroad plant of the United States would have to be doubled within ten years. Let us assume, however, that the traffic increased by one hundred per cent, can be handled with facilities in- creased by eighty per cent. Taking the cost of main line track at $30,000 per mile, other track at $15,000 per mile, locomotives at $15,000 each, freight cars at $1,000 each, and passenger cars at $5,000 each, it will be found that an eighty per cent, increase in the track and equipment of 1905 would cost over eight and one- half billion dollars. The requisite real estate would probably cost another half billion dollars, bringing the total expenditure necessary to provide for the traffic of the decade ending with 1915 to an average annual in- vestment of nine hundred millions of dollars. If this expenditure is made on capital account, the capitalization of the railroads of the United States will have to be increased to over twenty billion dollars. In 1885 the total return to the capitalization of the rail- roads was but 3.38 per cent., in 1895 but 3.55 per cent. In 1905, on the capitalization as given by the Inter- state Commerce Commission, the return was 4.4 per cent. ; on the net capitalization, as given in this chapter, it was 4.9 per cent. For that year, moreover, 62.84 per cent, of the total railway stock paid no dividends at all, and the average rate of dividends that were paid was less than six per cent. Of the total funded debt 78 per cent, reaped a return which averaged less than six per cent. The entire surplus of all of the railroads of the United States was less than one-tenth of the an- Achievement of the Railroads 395 nual expenditure that will be needed to keep them abreast of the traffic. As shown in the previous chapter, the net return to the capital invested in manufactures averaged 15.1 per cent, for the year 1905, the net return to the capital invested in agriculture 9.8 per cent, for that year. Into these two branches of our national industry, particularly into the manufacturing and the allied mining industry, capital was unhesitatingly poured. When, however, the overburdened condition of the railroads, as a whole, had become apparent to everyone, and they entered the market with propositions for hundreds of millions of dollars of new capital, the nation stood aghast at their temerity. When even the clogged and the con- gested Pennsylvania Railroad sought to parallel its facilities between Pittsburg and New York, voices were not lacking to criticise what was called its rashness. The truth is that the railroads did not begin to ask for new capital soon enough nor in amounts large enough. Had their requisitions begun with the resumption of business activity in 1898 and 1899, fewer mills and sky- scrapers might, perhaps, have been built in the next half dozen years, but the facilities of the railroads might have been kept well ahead of the demand. When they did ask, what did they receive? Bond issues even of stable companies could be sold only at a discount, and in many cases only at a heavy discount. It is a condition and not a theory that confronts the railroads. They must make ends meet, and they must provide for the future. Not only must they make returns on the capital in the existing plant, but they must dem- onstrate the possibility of making returns that will enlist capital in the doubling of that plant. This must be done, not merely that the investment of capital may be profitable, but that the transportation needs of the coun- try may be met. To whatever extent the waterways may be developed, they cannot supplant the railroads upon which the greater portion of the burden of transportation now 39^ Railroad Freight Rates falls, and of necessity will continue to fall. In sub- stantiation of this statement it is necessary only to re- flect that, particularly in the busier Northern States, canals and rivers are frozen over throughout a consid- erable portion of the year. It is necessary only to look at the network of railroad lines on the map of any of the States of developed commerce, and to consider what would have to be done before waterways could even fractionally take their place. Holland would no longer be the typical land of dykes and ditches. How could canals supplant the service now rendered to mills and warehouses into which the tracks of the railroads pene- trate? CHAPTER XXV CONCLUSION In all of the web of condition and circumstance, out of which has developed the freight rate structure of the railroads of the United States, was not woven one thread of effective precedent. There was entire absence of that experience of the past which serves as a guide for the future. The concerted use of steam and rails revo- lutionized transportation, not only its physical mechan- ism, but its economic relations. The charges of the canal boat and the wagoner were no adequate criterion by which to fix the charges of the railroads. The man- ner in which they were used indicates that they were little more than a starting point from which to make a guess, it being necessary, of course, that the charges of the railroads be lower than those of the antecedent agencies, or that their service be better. Both of these desiderata were attained within a generation, and that attainment firmly established the railroads as the domi- nant instrument in this country for the conveyance of passengers and freight. Another salient feature is that the introduction of the railroads in the United States was not into a developed and settled nation. Their services and their rates had to be progressively adapted to the needs of a population that was irregularly extending over the vast areas of the national domain, forming communities at points of natural advantage whose location was not in the least determined by intervals of distance. The beginnings of the railroads, moreover, were when the processes of industry were being revolutionized by the use of steam in no less degree than the methods of transportation. Coincident with the growth of popula- tion was the increasing use of a greater variety of the 397 398 Railroad Freight Rates materials of nature and a continual multiplying of the kinds of products wrought from these materials. There has been a continual multiplying of the sources whence raw material is obtained, of the places where it is manu- factured, and as the population has extended far and wide a ramifying of the channels of distribution. It must also be borne in mind that with but few excep- tions the railroads of the United States have not been State owned institutions. There were, especially in the earlier years, subscriptions by States, cities and towns, and there were grants by the national government of large tracts of land ; but in the main the capital by which the railroads have been built has been subscribed by individuals, as has been private capital in other enter- prises. In the earlier years the first aim was often to have a railroad, and capital was expended in its con- struction with little or no regard to the likelihood of profit from its operation. In later periods the return on capital has been the foremost consideration, and as a rule money has not been invested unless there has been prospect of return. That is, as an avenue for invest- ment the railroads have had to compete with other ave- nues for investment; their success in the eyes of the investor has meant pecuniary success. At all times the railroads of the United States have been dependent upon their earnings for their operation and their maintenance. Judgment passed upon the freight rate structures of the railroads of the United States must be posited on these premises. It must be considered how completely they have been adjusted to meet the requirements of an irregularly extending and rapidly growing popula- tion, of the rapidly extending and developing processes of industry and commerce, to what extent they have met the requirements of investors for return on their capital. That period prior to the Civil War, when each rail- road served only the local needs of the territory which it traversed, has left no record that the rates of the rail- roads were not satisfactory to their patrons. The in- auguration of through service in the period immediately Conclusion 399 succeeding the War, the rapid extension of the railroads, the growing competition for both short distance and long distance traffic, the increasing effect of the rates of the waterways upon the fates of the railroads, the building of the railroads in advance of traffic, led to that buffeting of the waves through which it was nec- essary for both railroads and shippers to gain the ex- perience that has enabled the steering of an evener course, and to problems whose solution has been slowly working out. Widespread and radical differences of opinion between the railroads and their patrons, and mutual misunderstandings equally widespread, culmi- nated in the report made by the Cullom Committee to the United States Senate in 1886. That report listed eighteen causes of complaint against the railroad sys- tem. Inasmuch as these complaints then expressed have been the basis of nearly if not quite all of the accusa- tions bearing directly or indirectly . against the trans- portation charge that have been made since that time, probably no more clear understanding can be gained of the present status than by contrasting the conditions exhibited by that list of complaints formulated twenty- three years ago with the conditions that exist to-day. This list of complaints, although embodied in a previ- ous chapter, is repeated here for this purpose. THE COMPLAINTS OF THE CONDITION AT 1886 PRESENT I. That local rates are un- i- Local rates are still of reasonably high, compared varying levels, and are usually with through rates. higher per ton per mile than through rates, but complamts upon these specific bases are nowadays seldom made. It has been recognized by both the Interstate Commerce Com- mission and the Courts that the lower through rate per ton per mile is not a criterion by which to meas- ure the reasonableness of the higher local rate. 400 Railroad Freight Rates Complaints of 1886 (Continued) 2. That both local and through rates are unreason- ably high at non-competing points, either from the ab- sence of competition or in con- sequence of pooling agree- ments that restrict its opera- tion. 3. That rates are established without apparent regard to the actual cost of the service per- formed, and are based largely on "What the traffic will bear." 4. That unjustifiable dis- criminations are constantly made between individuals in the rates charged for like ser- vice under similar circum- stances 5. That improper discrimi- nations are made between ar- ticles of freight and branches of business of a like charac- ter, and between different quantities of the same class of freight. 6. That unreasonable dis- criminations are made between localities similarly situated. Condition at Present (Continued) 2. Complaints as to unrea- sonably high rates at non-com- peting points are now infre- quent. Effective mechanism exists for the correction of any such rates that may be found. 3. That " What the traffic will bear," or as it is more ac- curately expressed, " Not what the traffic will not bear," is the only equitable basis for the ad- justment of rates is the opin- ion of the highest authorities whether in the field of eco- nomic theory or in that of railroad practice. 4. These discriminations were prohibited under, but in prac- tice not abolished by, the orig- inal Interstate Commerce Law. Since the enactment of the Elkins law and the Hepburn law, and the enforcement of their provisions, they have ad- mittedly ceased to exist. 5. While, with constantly changing commercial condi- tions, instances now and then occur of rates not being prop- erly adjusted on similar arti- cles, and for similar branches of business, no general com- plaint of this nature exists at this time. It is generally con- ceded that rates on small ship- ments should in general be higher than rates on carload lots. 6. The adjustment of rates between competing localities in a manner that will satisfy all of the contending interests re- mains one of the most per- plexing problems with which the railroads and the Commis- sion have to deal. Many Conclusion 401 Complaints of 1886 (Continued) ^. That the effect of the pre vailing policy of railroad management is by an elaborate system of special rates, re- bates, drawbacks, and conces- sions to foster monopoly, to enrich favored shippers, and to prevent free competition in manjr lines of trade in which the item of transportation is an important factor. 8. That such favoritism and secrecy introduce an element of uncertainty into legitimate business that greatly retards the development of our in- dustries and commerce. Condition at Present (Continued) cases of discrimination that seem unjust to a surface view have been found not to be un- reasonable by the Interstate Commerce Commission ; other cases seemingly unreasonable and condemned by it have been upheld as reasonable by the Supreme Court of the United States after broad considera- tion of the effect upon the en- tire population. 7- The statement set against complaint Number 4 applies to this complaint, Number 7. Until recently it would have held good in regard to the di- visions of through rates al- lowed " industrial roads " and " tap lines," and by the pay- ment of " elevation and trans- fer charges." But these prac- tices have been condemned, and are now in one or another stage of elimination. Their abolition will leave, perhaps, the only fields for secret con- cessions to be in the abuse of the " reconsignment " and " milling in transit " privileges, and the possibilities afforded by so-called "reciprocal de- murrage." ' 8. That _ these practices hampered individual shippers in competition with their shrewder and more aggres- sive rivals is unquestionable, but it is not demonstrated that they retarded the industry and commerce of the country, which expanded with great rapidity during the entire period of rebates and discrimi- nations. The shrewder and the more aggressive still trans- act the greater volume of business, although now with- out concessions from the rail- roads. 402 Railroad Freight Rates Complaints of 1886 (Continued) 9. That secret cutting of rates and the sudden fluctua- tions that constantly take place are demoralizing to all busi- ness except that of a purely speculative character, and fre- quently occasion great injustice and heavy losses. 10. That in the absence of national and uniform legisla- tion, the railroads are able by various devices to avoid their responsibility as carriers, es- pecially on shipments over more than one road, or from one State to another, and that shippers find great difficulty in recovering damages for the loss of property or for injury thereto. II. That railroads refuse to be bound by their own con- tracts, and arbitrarily collect large sums in the shape of overcharges in addition to the rates agreed upon at the time of shipment. Condition at Present (Continued) 9. Legislation against the secret cutting of rates and their rapid fluctuation is as drastic as against rebates and secret discriminations. 10. There is not now any lack of national legislation, but the enactments of the various States are sadly lacking an uniformity. Competition, espe- cially since the abolition of secret _ concessions, has forced the railroads to give more care to the settlement of claims for loss and damage in order that they may retain the business of the claimant. Indeed, ficti- tious claims — which are ob- viously equivalent to rebates — have been paid for this pur- pose. II and 12. During the two years' survey that has resulted in the preparation of this book no such complaints have come to the writer's attention. 12. That railroads often re- fuse to recognize or be re- sponsible for the acts of dis- honest agents acting under their authority. 13. That the common law fails to afford a remedy for such grievances, and that in cases of dispute the shipper is compelled to submit to the de- cision of the railroad man- ager or pool commissioner, or run the risk of incurring fur- ther losses by greater dis- criminations. 13. _ Certainly no such ac- cusation is made at this time of abundant Federal legislation and superabundant State legis- lation. Conclusion 403 Complaints of 1886 (Continued) 14. That the difference in the classifications in use in various parts of the country, and sometimes for shipments over the same roads in differ- ent directions are a fruitful source of misunderstanding, and are often made a means of extortion. 15. That a privileged class is created by the granting of passes, and that the cost of the passenger service is largely increased by the extent of this abuse. 16. That the capitalization and bonded indebtedness of the roads largely exceed the ac- tual cost of their construction or their present value, and that unreasonable rates are charged in the effort to pay dividends on watered stock and interest on bonds improp- erly issued. 17. That railroad corpora- tions have improperly engaged in lines of business entirely distinct from that of trans- portation, and that undue ad- vantages have been afforded to business enterprises in which railroad officials were inter- ested. Condition at Present (Continued) 14. Instead of the hundreds of different classifications in effect at the time this com- plaint was drafted, there are now but three promulgated by the railroads, which are earn- estly endeavoring to merge these into one that will apply throughout the country. The various classifications and modified classifications issued by separate States are a large factor in the confusion that still exists. 15. The granting of passes has been prohibited by the Congress, and by various States, except for certain specified charitable purposes, and to the employees of rail- road companies. 16. That the first clause of this complaint holds good as to the entire railroad system of the United States is vigor- ously contested, not only by officers of the railroads, but by eminent economists. In any event, rates are not and can- not be determined by or based upon capitalization. Over- capitalization and financial manipulation, where they exist, may have the effect of impair- ing the physical condition and the service of a railroad. They injure the investor, but do not affect the rates of the shipper. 17. That clause of the Hep- burn law forbidding railroad companies to carry on a com- mercial business in commod- ities owned and transported by them has been declared uncon- stitutional by the Circuit Court of the United States for the Eastern District of Penn- sylvania, as being an invasion of property rights. The ques- 404 Railroad Freight Rates Complaints of 1886 (Continued) Condition at Present (Continued) tion is now before the Su- preme Court of the United States for final decision. The Interstate Commerce Commission has full power to prevent any abuses in the transportation charge that might arise from the continu- ance of the railroads in dealing in such commodities. 18. That the managernent of the railroad business is ex- travagant and wasteful, and that a needless tax is imposed upon the shipping and travel- ing public by the unnecessary expenditure of large sums in the maintenance of a costly force of agents engaged in a reckless strife for competitive business. 18. Statistics based upon re- turns published by the Inter- state Commerce Commission, the Census Bureau, and the Department of Agriculture, show that while the average wage paid by the railroads is greater than that paid in the agricultural industry or the manufacturing industry, the railroads produce a far greater return measured per employee and have far fewer employees in proportion to capital; but that notwithstanding this their net return averages less than one-half of that in agriculture, and is far less than one-third of that obtained in the man- ufacturing industry. In the eyes of the investor they are, therefore, at a disadvantage in comparison with either of these principal fields of activity. A serious abuse not specified in the list of complaints formulated by the Cullom Committee is that economic waste, to which attention has been called of late years, caused by the carrying of traffic by long and circuitous routes in competition with direct routes. This is being reduced to a minimum by the abolition of rebates, and other secret concessions, it standing to reason that a shipper having any regard for the time his wares spend in transit, or for their liability ta injury from repeated Conclusion 405 handlingf, will not send a consignment over a long and roundabout route when he can send it over a shorter and more direct route at the same rate. It is apparent from the foregoing comparison that since the report made by the Cullom Committee, in 1886, the conduct of transportation by the railroads of this country has undergone a radical and comprehensive ref- ormation, brought about in part by the working of economic law, and in part by legislation. It is essential that following this revolution there should be a period of calm during which the railroads and the shippers may have the opportunity to adjust themselves to the new conditions and solve the new problems. Because of the irregular extension of the population of the United States, the varying geographical and eco- nomic conditions that have led to the unsymmetrical de- velopment of industry and commerce, and, therefore, to necessarily irregular and unsymmetrical channels of trafi&c, it follows that the development of the freight rate structure necessarily has been likewise irregular and unsymmetrical. That this development has been in accord with the needs of industry and commerce would seem beyond question, and that the moulding to which it is continually subjected is adapting it the more closely to those needs has abundant demonstration. Any radi- cal or abrupt modification of the existing rate structure, or any attempt to substitute for it another scheme of rates of apparent mathematical symmetry, could not but react injuriously, not only upon the railroads, but upon industry and commerce, and, therefore, militate against the national welfare. INDEX Abuses, in privileges, 401 ; Pri- vate Car Line, 187; Traffic Associations and Railroad, 171. Accounting, Association of Railway Accounting Officers, 302, 303 ; Diversities in, 301 ; Interstate Commerce Com- mission and forms of, 278, 302; Systems, 301-304; Uni- formity in, 302. Act to Regulate Commerce, 1887, 248. Adams, Charles Francis, and Railroad regulation in Mas- sachusetts, 242. Adjustments in rates. Con- serving equilibrium in mar- kets, 138-143. 325-327, 354; Conserving equilibrium in places of production, 138; Conserving manufactures, 69, 289; in Cotton, 31; Texas Commission and, 102; in Southeastern district, 89 ; Traffic Associations and, 171 ; Varying influences of, 148; Intertwining of railroads and, 315, 316. Administration and equipment, cost of, 218. Advisory Railroad Commis- sions, 242. Agriculture, Capital employed in, 1890, 1900, 1905, 376; in- terest on, zi(>'> Colonial, 4; Expenditures in, 378; for fertilizers, 376; for Taxes, 407 376; Machinery in, 16; rail- road revenue on implements of, 230; Production, 1890, 1900, 1905, 376; increased cost to consumer, 382; Schools and Experiments stations, 15, 36; Railroads and, 14, 374-383; Labor, numbers, 376, wages, 376; Rotation of crops in, 22; Department of, work of, 26, 34, 36. Alabama, Coal fields, 12; cot- ton mills, 10; iron and steel industry, 11; Truck farm- ing, 22. Alfalfa, Cattle food, 17; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Sheep food, 19. Altoona, Consignment to stor- age at, 193, 194. Amalgamation, Railroad, 251, 269. Amarillo, Texas, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. American Economic Associa- tion, Transportation Com- mittee on the Railroads, 247. American Railway Associa- tion, 215. Animal Foods, Complaints to Interstate Commerce Com- mission on rates, 290, 291, 298. Animal Products, Railway rev- enue per ton-mile from, 229. Annual Reports, Interstate Commerce Commission to Congress, 277; Carriers, 278. 4o8 Index Anthracite coal, Railway rev- enue per ton-mile from, 229. Anti-Trust Law, 1890, 263. \ Appeals, Supreme Court, 278, 280. Apple, American, at Paris Ex- position, 1900, 24; European origin, 22; export, 23, 24; Industry, 29; Supremacy of, 23, 24. Arizona, Coal fields, 12. Arkansas, Apple crop, 23; Peach crop, 24; egg ship- ments from, 9. Asphaltum, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Association of General Freight Agents, 206. Atlanta, Commerce of as af- fected by rates, 359; Prices and rates, flour, 54, sugar, 55 ; Rate, 91. 92- Atlantic Seaboard, Apple crop, 23; Cotton mills, 10; Early European traffic, 4; Early inland traffic, in agricultural products, 4; Importation of Sicilian lemon, 26; Looms, 10; Importation of Salmon, 20; Truck Farms, 9. Axes, rates and prices, St. Louis, Kansas City, Denver, SI. B Back Traffic, California prod- ucts, 109-111; Wheat, 120. Bacon, American, in English markets, 18. Bahia, Brazil, Navel Orange importation, 25. Baldwin, Loanii, and apple culture, 23. Baltimore, Competition with New York and Philadelphia, 70; Differential, 74, 76, 77, 118, 119; Fish- and oyster- trains, 9; Group rate, 77; Railroad connection with Ohio, s; Trade of food products for European man- ufactures, colonial, 4. Baltimore and Ohio Railroad, Charter, 70; Chesapeake and Ohio Canal and, 235; En- trance to New York, 73. Bananas, price of, and trans- portation charge, 56. Bankruptcy, railroad, 232; pe- culiar character of, 169. Bar and sheet metal. Railway revenue from, per ton-mile, 230. Barley, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Barrels and kegs, empty, rail- way revenue per ton-mile, 230. Bartlett pear, 24. Basing points. Southeastern district, effect on commerce in, 89, erected by distribut- ing centers, 88 ; in the Trunk Line Percentage system, 74; Water points and, 87; the Junction and the evolution of, 160. Beans, Dried, Railway fevenue per ton-mile from, 229. Bedsteads, rates and prices, 31. Beef, Corn crop and, 16; Feed- ing cattle for, 17; Rates and prices. New York, 49; West- ward movement of source of supply, 27. Beer, Complaints on rates. In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion, 286; railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Beet, refuse as sheep food, 19; sugar, markets, 42, sources of supply, 13, 42, 103 ; Sugar beets, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. "Belt" lines, Pittsburg, 332; Index 409 switching charge, 176, 177, Buffalo, 330. Betterments, earnings and, 388; English Capital and ex- penditures for, 388; Capital- ization and, 387, 388, 394. Bill of lading, through, 188- 190, 237; evolution cf, 161, 166; responsibility of initial carrier on, 278, 279; Trunk Line Association and uni- formity in, 189. Biscuits, rates and prices, 58. Bituminous coal. Railway rev- enue per ton-mile from, 229. Blanchard, Geo. R., and Fed- eral legislation, 248. Blue Line Through Freight, 164. Boards of Trade and rates af- fecting cities, 316, 317. Bookkeeping and statistics, 303, 304- Boots and shoes. Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 288; New Eng- land and manufacture of, 68. Borax, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Boston, Commerce, colonial, 4, 6; as affected by rates, 328; Copper smelting, de- cline in, 67; Differentials and, 118, 119; Iron manufac- tures, decline in, 67; Rail- road connections, western, 68; Ship-building interests, decline in, 67; Water-forced rates to Portland, 70; Wheat export, decline in, 119; Wooden manufactures, de- cline in, dT. Box Shooks, Timber and Lum- ber, railway revenue per ton- mile, 230. Brandy and Wine, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Breakfast foods, machinery in preparation of, 16. Brick, areas of supply, 12; Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230, 287; Rates, complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 287, 288; Prices and rates, 52. Bridge Arbitrary, St. Louis, 344. Bridge and structural iron, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Brokers, in distribution of cot- ton, iron ore, coal, and petro- leum, 40; in manufactured products, 43, 44. Broom corn, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Broom cotton, complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on rates, 286. Brown, vs. Walker, and com- pelling of testimony, 265. Buffalo, Early base of sup- plies, 4; Commerce of, as af- fected by rates, 329-331; Foodstuffs complaint, In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion, 285; Iron and steel in- dustry, 330; Milling indus- try, 329; Niagara water power and, 330; Lumber trade, 133; Packing house industry, 127; Prices and rates, flour, 127. Building materials, local areas of supply, 12. Bulk, transportation of wheat in, 16; developed into Clas- sification, 150. Bullion, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Bureau of explosives, 215. Burlington group rates, 83. Business Men's Leagues and rates affecting cities, 316,. 317- 4IO Index Butte, commerce of, as affected by rates, 356. Butter, Rates and prices, Den- ver, 351 ; Channels of move- ment, 9; Effect of rates on New York prices, 48; Ex- tent of area of supply, 9, 21 ; Pittsburg consumption, 333; Refrigerator cars and trans- portation of, 32. Cabbage, A general crop, 22. Cakes, Rates and prices, 58. Calico, Effect of rates on prices of, 54- California, First railroad, Sac- ramento to Folsom, 104. California, Apple crop, 23; Beet sugar supply, 13, 42, 103 ; Canning industry, 27 ; Cantaloup, 25 ; Deciduous fruits of, 13, 102; Fruit growers' exchange, 30 ; Grapes, 25 ; Lemons, 26, 27 ; Lumber supply of, 11, 103; Navel orange, 26; Peach crop, 24 ; Petroleum oil, 103 ; Seed farms, 22; Tanneries of, 10; Truck farm products of, 9, 102; Wheat, 102; Wines, 103; Wool, supply of, 10. Calves and cattle. Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Canada, Grain rates, 124; Pa- per pulp supply from, 42. Canals, vs. Railroads, 1830- 1860, S, 23s ; Erie Canal and building of the Penn. R. R., 70; Erie and Baltimore & Ohio R. R., 70. Cane sugar, effect of rates on prices of refined product, 55 ; sources of supply, 13; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Canned Goods, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 286 ; Industry, variety of goods and location of factories, 27; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, meats and fish, fruits, vege- tables, 229; Colorado rates, 352 ; Transcontinental rates on. III. Cantaloup, crop, 25; rates and prices, New York, 50. Cape Cod Ship Canal Project, probable revenue and feasi- bility, 231, 232. Cape Horn Route, 8, 104, 105. Capital, Employed in Agricul- ture, Manufacture, 376, com- pared with that in Railroads, Z17, 378; Railroad, 246, 378. 385, increase in, 385, 386, 387, 388, 389-391, and mile- age. 390. 403, and rates, 231- 234. 403. Car distribution, complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 293, coal, 293, citrus fruits, 293, difficul- ties of, ZT. Car shortage, 1899, 271, 392; and storage pending con- signment, 194, 195. Carload lots, and carload rates. Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 294; eggs, 9; in distribution of manufactures, 44; less than, 173; ratings, increase in number of, 203 ; rates, de- velopment of, 151, 153 ; less than, 200-205, 400; livestock and lumber, and develop- ment of the hundredweight basis, 201. Carding mills, 10. Carnegie Steel Company, and rebates, 270. Carolinas, Cantaloup, 25 ; Cot- Index 411 ton mills of, 10, 131 ; Fur- niture factories of, 10; To- bacco supply, 13, 41; Truck farming, 22. " Carrier " means " common carrier," 276. Carriers and transportation subject to Interstate Com- merce Law, 276. Carriers' Liability on original bill of lading, 189. Cars, Demonstration, 2^, 209; Empty, on own wheels, Rail- way revenue from, per ton- mile, 230; Freight, number, 13, 384, 386, 387, 388, En- largement of, 65, 154, 201, Improper use of, 182, 191- 192, 272; Passenger, number of, 38s, 386, 387; Private ownership of, 183-187. Cartage allowance case, Pitts- burg, and Interstate Com- merce Commission, 334. Cassatt, A. J., and rebates, 269. Castings and machinery, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Cattle, fattening, 16-17; Prices at stockyards, 49; Rates, eastern and western on, 308, and " transportation on the hoof," 127, and prices, 129, 130; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Cement, areas of supply, 12; rate structure, 141 ; railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Central Traffic Association, 7Z, 78; Rate-cutting in ter- ritory, 7Z. Chain stores, 205. Chambers of Commerce and rates affecting cities, 316. Change of station location, complamts before Interstate Commerce Commission, 292, 293- Channels of traffic, early, 6; Erosion of, by exchange of food for manufactured prod- ucts, 7-8; Interstate, 4-14, 309-310; Secondary, 45, 309; Train-load character of movements over, 45; Com- modities of, and percentage system rates, yy. Charges, complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion, reconsignment and switching services, 292, 293. Charleston, Commerce of as affected by rates, 358; early European trade, 4; fertilizer industry, 358; Prices and rates, bananas, 56. Chesapeake and Ohio Canal and Baltimore and Ohio Railway, 235. Chicago, Commerce of as af- fected by rates, 340-342; cold storage facilities, 33; Car- load " spread " and, 203 ; as determining line of traffic territory division, 114; " Belt " line switching, 176 ; early interior supply base, 4; Furniture manufacture, 11; Grain trade, Milwaukee and, 120; Importance to Trunk lines, 71 ; industries of, 341 ; Packing houses, 127; Rail- road connection, i860, west- ern construction and, Bos- ton capital and, 68; Rate basis. New York, Dressed meats and livestock rate, 130, wheat rate, 119, and Trunk Line percentage sys- tem, 74; western rates, 79, 80; Rates, fixed differences with St. Louis, 342. Chickens, Export of, 20; Feed- ing, 20; Importation of, 19. 412 Index Cincinnati, Commerce of as affected by rates, 338; early interior base of supplies, 4; as Western gateway, impor- tance to Trunk lines, 71 ; Packing house industry, 127; Primary market for tobacco, 41 ; Railroad connections, i860, S- Cincinnati rates. Differential on Chicago to Virginia Cities, 88. Cities, Commerce of, 325-373; Traffic representatives, 316, 317. Citrus Fruits, California Fruit Growers' Exchange, 30; Car distribution, com- plaints of, 293; Crop, 26, 27; European origin, 26; Move- ment of from California, 13; Railway revenue per ton- mile, transcontinental from, 229. Civil war and railroad con- struction, 5-6, i6s; Inter- ruption to commerce, 6. Claims, freight, 213, 214, 246, 402. Classification, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on, 298; Basis of, 150, 152, 222, 223; Dif- ferences in, evils of, 307, Indianapolis and, 370; diffi- culties due to staples and re- ' gions, 306; Dairy Products, 306, 307; Rates, early devel- opment of, 152, number of, 152, on high and low grade freight, 222; South Carolina Railroad, 150; Traffic Asso- ciations and questions of, 171; Uniformity in, 304-309, 403- Clay, Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Cleveland, Commerce of as af- fected by rates, 334-335; early base of supplies, 4; Packing house products, 127, 335 ; Rate, ^(s■, staple prod- ucts of, 334. Clipper Ships and Transcon- tinental rates, 104, 105. Cloth, Effect of rates on prices of, 53- Clothespins, Effect of rates on prices of at St. Louis, 51. Clothing, Prices, as affected by rates, 52; Denver, 353. Coal, Abundance of and pros- perity, 12; Anthracite, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Area of supply, 12; Boats, source of lumber for, 133; Bituminous, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Channels of movement of, 12; Car distri- bution, complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 293; F.O.B. vessel delivery, 178; Elimination of broker in distribution of, 40; Railroad consumption of, 218 ; Rates, 60, through, com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on, 290, 291, special, to conserve Indiana industries, 289, rate structure and equilibrium in common markets, 139, Prices and, Denver, 353 ; Routes, complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on, 290, 291 ; Recon- signment, 195 ; Gondolas, 185. Coffee, Channels of movement of, 13. Coke, through routes and rates on, Complaints before Inter- state Commerce Commission on Hepburn bill, 290, 291 ; Railway Revenue per ton- mile from, 229. Index 413 Cold Storage, 31; Chicago fa- cilities for, 33 ; Effect of, on quality of food, 33. Colorado, Apple crop, 23; Beet sugar supply, 13, 42, rates, 351; Cattle feeding, 17; Can- taloup, Rocky Ford, 25; Coal fields of, 12; Common Points Rates, Common through rates to Chicago and St. Louis, 84; Iron and steel mills, 11 ; Manufacture of machinery, 354; Sheep grazing, 19. Columbus, Commerce of, 334- 33S. Combination rates, Chicago- Omaha, 81 ; On Interregional traflSc, 115-116; On Missouri river, 83; On Texas Com- mon points, 94; On Virginia Cities' rate, 88. Commerce, of the cities, 325- 373, Rivalries in, 327, Traf- fic Bureaus and, 316, 317; Conditions and rates, 76, 89; Dependence of railroads on, 14; Early, with Europe, 4; Influence of transportation charge on, 47-66; Interrup- tion to, by Civil War, 6; Transportation and develop- ment of, 2, 172. Commission and Rebates, 260. Commission Man, Dishonest methods with growers, 29; Distribution of tobacco, 41 ; In distribution of foodstuffs, 29. Commodities, competition of and rates, 143; rate struc- tures, 1 17-147, on cotton, 130-133, Grain and grain products, 1 17-126, Livestock and dressed meats, 126- 130, Lumber, 133-138, on import and export trafljc, I43-I47, Types of, 138-143; Rates, South Carolina Railroad, 1855, 150, determined by character of commodity, 153 ; Shifting sources of and ef- fect on rates, 143; Trans- portation of, and Railroad ownership of, 277, 403, 404. " Common carriers," compa- nies included as, in Hepburn Bill, 276. Common points, and decentral- ization of distribution, 99- 100; Baltimore group, 77; Colorado, 84; In transcon- tinental traffic, 107, 108; Mississippi River, 81; Mon- tana, 84; New England, 6g, 70; Philadelphia group, 77; Texas, 94, 95, 97, 98, 99. Community complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 295, 296, 297. " Community of Interests," and Anthracite and Bitumi- nous coal rates, 139, 140; and Capitalization, 391 ; and obliteration of rebates, 269; effect on legislation, 276. Competition, Commercial, of cities, 347, 348, 360; of mar- kets, as developed by junc- tion points, 156, as affected by rates, 65, 66, 400, as af- fecting transcontinental rate, 104, as affecting wheat rates and prices, 125, 126; Rate structures and, 66, 117; rate fixing and, Atlantic Sea- board-Texas traffic, 96; Un- restrained, evils of, 208, 209, 227, 262. Complaints, against Railroads, 1886, 245-247, 1886 and 1909, 399-402 ; before Interstate Commerce Commission, num- ber of and treatment, 275, 281, 290, 295-300, on animal foods, 281, 290, from Com- 414 Index munities, 196, 295, 297, food- stuffs, 286, Incidental serv- ice, 292, 293, 294, Lumber, coal, and oil, 288, 289, 291, miscellaneous manufactures, 286, 295, miscellaneous law materials, 286, 295, through routes and rates, 290. Compress fee, paid by Texas railroads, 132. Compressing in transit, cotton, 132. Congestion of traific, 1899, 271, 392, 293- Connecticut, Canning industry, 27, manufacturing, 68. Connecting tracks, complaints of service before Interstate Commerce Commission, 292. Consignment, storage pending, 194- Construction, railroad, 217; evils of too rapid, 236, 238. Consumer and the transporta- tion charge, 47-66. " Contract plan," and evolu- tion of transcontinental rate, 106. Conveyance and secondary services, 174-187. Cooley, T. M., and the differ- entials, 119; on large and small shipment rates, 258 Copper, Rates on ore as af- fecting price of, 58; Smelt- ing and refining companies, and direct supply of ores of, 42; Sources of supply, 11. Copper wire. Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Texas special rate on, loi, 102. Cord Wood, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Corn, Broom, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Can- ning of, 27; Effect of rates on prices of. New York, 49; Production of, 16; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Selection and cultiva- tion of, 16; Small export of, 15 ; transformed into beef and pork, 15. Corporations liable to convic- tion, under Elkins Act, 266; under Hepburn Bill, 277. Cost of construction, 217, 377. Cost of operation, 384; and rates, 172; increase, 1875- 1885, 38s; Railroad, and cost of road hauling, 38; earnings, as indicated in Sen- ate Document, 257, 274. Cost of Transportation, 219, 220, 221, 228. Cotton, Area of production, 10, Memphis, 359, careless han- dling, 133 ; Channels of move- ment, 10; Commodity rate structure, 130-133 ; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 286, 287; Bro- kers, 40; Compression, com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 292; Mining, Carolina, 131, North Atlantic seaboard, 10; Grow- er's Associations, 40; Piece Goods, complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 288, rate and prices of, 54, New England manu- facture, 68; Plantation meth- ods of handling, 40; Cotton seed, complaints, rates and practices, 286, railway reve- nue per ton-mile from prod- ucts, 229, effect of excessive use in cattle feed, 17; Rail- way revenue from, per ton- mile, 229; Rates and prices, 59 ; Transportation charge and effect on prices of cot- ton goods, S4; Texas rates, 131; Warehousing, 182. Index 415 Courts and the Commission, provisions of Interstate Com- merce law, 251. Crackers, rates and prices, 58. Creameries, 21 ; and long dis- tance rates, 285. Criminal provisions, Hepburn Bill, 277. Cross-fertilization, wheat, oats, and barley, 15. CuUom, S. M., on Interstate Commerce law and rate- making power, 252; Cullom Report, 1886, 244, 247, 248, 399- Customs duties and import rates, 147. D Dairy products, Area of sup- ply, 9; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 28s, 286; Move- ments of, 9; Railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 229; Rates of different classifica- tions, 306, 307; State Schools, 36. Dakotas, Cattle feeding, 17; Egg shipments from, 9; Grain routes from, 8. Dallas, Texas, Commerce of, as affected by rates, 364; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Damages, money, award of by Commission, 278. Danville Case, and discrimina- tions between localities, 254. Decentralization of distribu- tion, 203, 204; Texas, effect on limitation of stocks, 99, 100. Deciduous Fruits, Channels of movement of, 13; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, transcontinental, 229; Trans- continental rates, no, in. Decline in rates, 389. Delaware, Canning industry, 27; Manufacturing industry, 69; Peach crop, 24, uncer- tainty of, 38. Demonstration cars, 36, 209. Demurrage, incidental service, 191-192. Denver, Colo., Commerce of, as affected by rates, 350-355; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296; Effect of rates on prices, food supplies, 350-352, fur- niture, 352, coal, 352, cloth- ing, 353, axes, galvanized iron tubs, padlocks, stoves, washboards, 51 ; Rates, af- fected by water rates, 84; Packing house industry, 127; as a "basing" point, 355. Department of Agriculture, Freezing food products for shipment, 34; Importation of navel orange from Bahia, 26; Improvement in produc- tion and preparation for shipment of food supply, 36. DesMoines, Iowa, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Detroit, an early interior base of supplies, 4. Development, Complaints and, 243; of Commerce and In- dustry by division of labor, I, 5 ; of business, Railroads and, 159, 235; of United States, Railroads and, 235. Differentials, Baltimore, Phil- adelphia, and New York, 73, 76; Chicago, St. Louis, and Missouri river, 80; Evolu- tion of, 73, 170; Gulf Ports, wheat, 198; New England, on foodstuffs, 70, on manu- factured products, 69, on raw material, 69; Interstate Com- 4i6 Index merce Commission and, 119; in Grain Export, 118-119; Cincinnati and Louisville on Chicago, to Virginia Cities, 88; Savannah to Galveston, 84; Wheat, 198. "Differing rates," and differ- entials, 170. Discriminations, Abolition of, 400 ; Betwfeen large and small shippers, 259; Between lo- calities, 254; Between Local and Through rates, 245; Negligible in early railroad history, 237; White pine against Yellow pine, 135; Unjust, Hepburn bill penal- ties, 277. "Distance" Tariff, Effect on industry and Communities, 227, 228; first railroads and, 149; Basing points and, 160, 161 ; in Percentage system, 75 ; Modified by growth of junction points, 156-161. Distribution, Centers of, car- load rates to, 204, rates as affecting, 326, for manufac- tured products, 45, Rates from, and percentage sys- tem, TJ, Trans-Missouri " Jobbers' rates," 85, 204, In Southeastern territory, 88 ; Decentralization of, carload ratings and, 203, 204, Texas, 94, effect of a " tapering tariff " on, 228 ; Foodstuffs, defective systems of, 60, 61 ; Involution of, 28; Produc- tion and, Railroads and, 159, 325-327, good roads and, 38; Intimate relations between, 15 ; Raw material and Mer- chandise, 40-46; Rates and equilibrium in, 139-143. Diversion en route, incidental service, 193; California Fruit Growers' Exchange, 2, 30. Dividends, 388; Earnings and, 38s, 386, 387, 388. Division of labor, i ; furthered by railroad construction, 5- Divisions of joint rate, power of Commission over, 278. Dock companies, service charge, 178. Dollar as measurement of val- ues, 375. Drain tile and sewer pipe. Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Dried Fruits, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 286 ; Transcontinental, Railway Revenue per ton- mile from, 229. Drovers, Elimination of, in purchase of livestock by packing houses, 35. Duck, 19. Duluth, Grain Trade, 120, 121, 198; Ore and coal trade, 121 ; Wheat elevators, 16. Durum wheat, and manufac- ture of macaroni, 15. Earnings, Cost of operation and, 384, 387; dividends and, 386, 387, 389; interest and, 385, 386, 387; Net, increase in, 38s, 386, 387, 389. 1890, 1900, 1905, 376; Stock and, 388 ; Taxes and, 388. Eggs, Arkansas shipments, 9; Channels of movement, 9; Development of production of, 20, 21 ; Effect of rates on prices of, at New York, 48, at Denver, 351 ; English mar- ket methods for, 21 ; Extent of area of supply, 9, 21 ; Freezing for shipment, 21 ; Packing, 21 ; Pittsburg con- Index 417 sumption, 333 ; Railroad rev- enue per ton-mile from, 229; Refrigerator cars and trans- portation of, 32. El Paso, Texas, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Electric and steam roads, through routes and rates, complaints, before Inter- state Commerce Commission, 298. Elevation, 34, 182-183; Chi- cago, 121 ; Charges for, and Interstate Commerce Commission, 182 ; Kansas City, 121 ; Omaha, 121 ; St. Louis, 121, 294; Service, complaints of, before Inter- state Commerce Commission, 291. Elkins Law, 1903, 210; Re- bates and, 265, 279; Penalties of, 26s, 266. Emergency Rates, Indiana coal rate, 289, Texas rates, loi, 102. Emigrants' Goods, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230; Rates to Denver, on, 352- Employees, Railway, 218, 381 ; and Free Passes, 276. Equipment, Cost of, 218; idle, 1897, 267; lack of adequate, 1899, 271; Increase in, 385, 386, 387. Erie Canal, And construction of Penn. R. R. and B. & O., 70. Erie Railroad charter and in- terstate traffic, 162. Esch-Townsend Bill, 276. Exchange, mechanism of, i. Expenses, Manufacturers, 379; 1890, 1900, 1905, 376; Mis- cellaneous, and uniformity of accounting, 303; Rail- roads, 1890, igoo, 190S, 376, 378, 379- Experimental Rates, 223. Export rates, America, 147; Germany, 147; Wheat, 119. Export Trade, Wheat and the differential, 119. Express Companies, " Common Carriers" in Hepburn Bill, 276; Complaints against, be- fore the Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 282. Express trains. Flour, 118; For sea-food traffic, 9. Facilities, equal, and Interstate Commerce law, 250 ; Increase of, 38s, 386, 387, for live- stock traffic, 129. Farm lands, Railroads and conversion of timber land into, 135. Farm Owners, net return to, i8go, 1900, 1905, 376. Farmer and careless egg col- lection, 21, And the commis- sion man, 29, And farm la- borers, 1890, 1900, 190S, 376, And good roads, 38, Prices on food products, 48, 49, 50, And railroad demonstration car, 27, And trolley line, 39. Fast Freight Lines, 163, 164, 207; Flour, 118. Federal supervision, beginnings of, 1868, 244. Federal versus State Rate Reg- ulation, 243, 309-313- Feeding, Cattle, 16, 17. Ferries, Railroad, 178. " Ferry-car " switching, 177. Fertilizer, Charleston, S. C, industry, 358 ; Agriculture, 1890, 1900, 190S, 376; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile 4i8 Index from, 229; Low rates to en- courage use, 57. Filing schedules, 277; Inter- state Commerce law relating to, 250, 261 ; Rates filed, the legal rates, 261 ; Three days' notice of change, 261. Finance, Railway, 384-389. Fines, Elkins Act, 265. Fink, Albert, and Federal reg- ulation of Railways, 248, 249. Fire Brick, rate structure, 140, 141. Fish, Channels of movement of, 9-10; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; through routes and rates on. Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 290. "Fixed differences," In Lum- ber-milling districts, 134, 137 ; Trans-Mississippi and Trans- Missouri territory, 80 ; Chicago and St. Louis, 342. Flax Seed and Products, Ex- cept Oil, Railway Revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Flemish Beauty Pear, 24. Florida, Truck farming, 22; Cantaloup, 25 ; Orange, 26. Flour, Effect of rates on prices of, 52, 54; Extent of produc- tion, 16; Machinery in mill- ing, 16; Milling, Butte, 356; Movement of, 118; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Rates, commodity, 118, Minneapolis and, 349, relation to wheat rates, 124; Milling in transit, 195-200, Atlanta and Nashville, 359. Food products. Channels of movement of, 8; Distribu- tion of, 28-39; Employment of machinery in preparation of, 16-17; Exchange of, for manufactured products, and erosion of traffic channels, 6- 7; New England differential on, 70; Pittsburg consump- tion of, 333; Preparation of, 15-27; Prices and rates, 48- 50, 60, Denver, 350-352, in- creased prices compared with decrease in rates, 382, 383; Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 65; Trolley lines and distribution of, 39; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission con- cerning, 298 ; New England differential on, 70. Forest products, railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 230. Forfeitures, for disobedience of Commission's Orders, 278. Fort Worth, Commerce of as affected by rates, 364; Pack- ing house industry, 127; Rates and prices, 52. Forwarding companies, in through traffic, 163. Freezing for shipment, eggs, 21 ; strawberries, 34. Freight Bureau Cases, 255, 256, 335- Freight Cars, Enlargement of, as affecting rates, 65, 154, 201, Improper use of, as af- fecting car shortage, 272, grain, 182, demurrage, 191- 192, Number in use, 13, in- crease in, 384, 386, 387, 388; Claims, 213, 214, 246 402; Services, switching, 174-178, private tracks, 179-181, tap- lines, 181, elevation and ware- housing, 182-183, special cars, 183-187; Solicitors, 207, 208, 210, and increased cost of transportation, 247 ; Traffic Bureaus, 317, Departments, 206-215, Managers, 209, Heterogeneity of, 173, 219, Index 419 220; Trains, local and through, 173; High grade, rates, 222. Fruit, Canned, industry, 27, railway revenue from, per ton mile, 229 ; Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 286 ; Growers' Associations, California, Georgia, Norfolk Truck re- gion, 30; Diversion en route, 193; Prices and rates, Den- ver, 352; Rate structure, to conserve common markets, 139 ; Reconsignment, 193 ; Transcontinental, Railway revenue from, 229. Fuel, Oil and Waste, cost of, 218. Furniture, car, 185 ; Centers of production, 11 ; Rates and prices, 52, Denver, 352 ; Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on, 288 ; Railway revenue per ton mile on, 230. Gallatin Valley, wheat produc- tion, 356. Galveston, Cotton rate, 131; Commerce of, as affected by rates, 364 ; early base of sup- plies, 4; Water rate to, af- fecting rates to Sante Fe and Albuquerque, 85. Game, Fish, and Poultry, Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Gauge, railway track, and in- terstate commerce, 162. General Electric Company, and the switching charge, 181. General Freight Agent, 206. Georgia, Cantaloup, 25; Cotton mills, 10; Growers' Associa-. tion, 30; Peach crop, 24; Rate contentions, 237 ; Rocky Ford Melon, annual importa- tion of seed from Colorado, 26; State Regulation, 149. Germany, State ownership in, and export rates, 147. Glass and tin-plate industry, Indiana, 369. Glucose, Syrup, and Molasses, Railway revenue per ton mile from, 230. Glutting a market, 30. Goats and sheep, railway reve- nue per ton mile from, 229. Good Roads, Industrial Com- mission on, 38. Grain and Grain Products, Ag- ricultural schools and grain varieties, 15, Distribution of, Louisville, 339, Elevator service in marketing, 34, 35, 182, Machinery employed, 16, Movement of, to the East, 8, 71, 120, Rates and prices. New York, 49, Reconsign- ment 193, 194; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 285, 286; Com- modity rate structure, 117- 126; Broker, elimination of, through milling industry, 35; Gulf Export, 285; Rates, 122; Rate Wars, 120, 121 ; Sup- ply, 15-16, channels of move- ment, 8. Granger Laws, 241, 243. Grape, indigenous origin and crop, 25. Gross income, Agriculture, Manufactures, Railroad, 378. Group rates, Baltimore, Phila- delphia, "JT, Burlington, St. Louis, Kansas City, 83; New York to Chicago plateau, in transcontinental traffic, 107 ; Omaha, 83 ; Pittsburg, Cleve- land, Johnstown, 76 ; " Shoe- 420 Index string district," 76; Virginia Cities, 87, 88. Gulf Ports, Adjustments in wheat rate by Interstate Commerce Commission, 285; Differential, wheat, 122, 123; Movement of Cotton through, 10; movement of manufac- ture through, 8; Rates and Texas Rates, 93. H Halibut, shipments to Atlantic coast, 10. Hattiesburg, Miss,, Complaints before the Interstate Com- merce Commission, 296. Hay, classification. Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 282, 284; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Rates and prices. New York, 49; Reconsign- ment, 193, 194. Heading and staves, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Heating apparatus, railway revenue per ton-mile, 230. Helena, Ga., Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Helena, Mont., Commerce of, as affected by rates, 356. Hemlock, sovtrce of supply of, 133- Hepburn Bill, Private car line abuses, 187; Provisions of, 276-279; Complaints on, be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 275-300. Hides, Area of siupply, 10; Channels of movement, 10; Complaints on, before Inter- state Commerce Commission, 286; Direct purchase of, by tanners, 42; Railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 229; Transportation charge on, as affecting prices of leather goods, 57. High Grade Freight, rates on, 222. Hogs, Extent of production, 18, improvement in feeding, 18, railway revenue per ton mile from, 229; Products, and corn crop, 16, 17, Rates and Prices, 52, San Luis Val- ley, 18. Hogsheads, Tobacco, 41. Horses, as motive power, 216, railroad horsepower, 380 ; Railway revenue per ton mile from, 229; Rates and prices, 129, 130; Special cars for Race horses, 185. Household Goods, Railway revenue per ton mile from, 230. Houston, Differential, 95 ; Rates, 92, 95, cotton, 131. Hundredweight, Rate basis of, 201, 202. Ice, Complaints before Inter- state Commerce Commission, 286; Extension of market for, by traffic men, 212 ; Rail- way revenue per ton mile from, 230; Rates, 143. Icing charges, 184, complaints of, 32; transcontinental, no. Idaho, Beet sugar supply, 13; Cantaloup, 25; Wool supply from, ID. Illinois, Canning industry, 27; Coal fields of, 12; Hogs, 18; Manufacture of woodenware, II. Import and Export traffic, 144- 147- Import Rates Case, 254-255. Index 421 Imprisonment, penalty of, 277, 279. Income, Railway, 385, 386, 387, 389; disposition of, 392, 404. Indiana, Canning industry, 27; Coal fields, 12, rates, special, 289; Glass and tin-plate in- dustry, 289, 369; Wooden- ware manufacture, 11. Indianapolis, commercial situ- ation at, 368-373 ; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 296, 368; Pack- ing house industry, 127. Industrial agents, 209. Industrial tracks, 179-181. Industrial Commission, on cost of hauling over country roads, 38; on grain rate structure, 125-126; on rates and prices of horses and cat- tle, 1901, 129, 130. Industries, building up of, rates and, 227; Preservation of, rates and, 275, coal rates and, Indiana, 289. Informal Complaints to Com- mission, 27s, 281, 282. Initial carrier and responsibil- ity for losses, 278. Intercorporate relationships, 390, 391- Inter-Regional Rates, 114-116; Traffic, 113-116. Interest, Earnings and, 385, 386, 387 ; on agricultural cap- ital, 376. Intermediaries, freight, 314-324- " Intermediate " stations, and basing point rates, 156-159. i6S. Interstate Commerce, Enabhng act, 162, 166, 206, 237, 309; Demand for Federal super- vision of, 243; Development of, 162-164; Relations to In- trastate, 312. Interstate Commerce Act, 1887, 248; provisions of, 250-251; and discriminations, 251, fil- ing tariffs, 251, interpreta- tion of, 250-260, and pooling, 251, publication of rates, 145, rate-making power, 251 ; and long and short haul, 75, 251, and Trunk Line Percentage System, 75, 252, penalties, 251, 265; 1906, and icing charges, 32. Interstate Commerce Commis- sion, and Accounts of car- riers, 278, annual reports of carriers, 278, and Bill of lad- ing, uniform, 189, and Com- plaints, 275, 295-300, and Conciliation, 299-300, and Differentials, 119, and Dis- criminations between locali- ties, 253, and Elevation charges, 182, Enlargement of, 279, on Flour and wheat rates, 125, Kansas City rates, 347, and Liability of carriers for losses, 278, and livestock rates, 129, and local and through rates, 399, and Lum- ber rates, 112, 137, and Long and short haul, 252, 258, 359, Membership of, 252, number of members, 279, Orders of, as to reasonable rates and practices, 277, 278, Orders to continue in force two years, 278, and Pooling, 251, and publication of rates, 145, and the rate-making power, 251, 256, 257, 279, and Rebates, 260, 266, 279, Reports of, publication, 277, and Senate Document, No. 257, 257, 273, 274, Spokane and the Pacific Terminal rate, 368, Switch- ing charges, 181, Tap Line allowances, 181, Territorial groups and complaints, 285- 300, Through routes and 422 Index joint rates, 278, Pittsburg Brewery, Cartage allowance, 334, Wichita grain rate, 124. Intrastate traffic, demurrage and, 192. Iowa, hogs, 18. Iron and Steel, Articles, com- plaints on, before Interstate Commerce Commission, 288; Industry, 10, 11, elimination of broker in, 40; Ore, chan- nels of movement, 10, elimi- nation of broker in distribu- tion, 40, Lake Superior supply, ID, Rates on, 59-60, Railway revenue per ton mile from, 229; Iron Pipe, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230; Iron Rails and Trimmings, railway rev- enue per ton-mile from, 230. J Japan, Cotton export to, 133. "Jobbing," Centers, Texas, 95; Carload rates and, 204; " Jobbers' Rates," Trans- Missouri territory, 85. Joint Traffic Associations, and the anti-trust law, 264, pro- cedure of, 264. Joint Weighing and Inspec- tion, 214, 215. Judson, F. N., on public policy and wholesale and retail rates, 259. Junction points, and distance tariffs, 156-161, 165; in Dis- tribution of commodities, 45 ; and Erosion of secondary channels of traffic, 45 ; Multi- plicity of, 166; Texas, 95. K Kansas, Cattle feeding, 17, Coal fields of, 12, Corn canning. 27, Grain routes from, 8, Hogs, 18, Sheep grazing, 19. Kansas City, Beet sugar mar- ket, 42; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on Hepburn Bill, 347; Commerce of, as af- fected by rates, 344-348; Dry goods rates, 345 ; Effect of rates on prices at, on axes, galvanized iron tubs, pad- locks, stoves, washboards, 51 ; Group rate, 83 ; Industry of, 344, Packing house indus- try, 127; Rates, St. Paul, St. Louis, 82, 347; Sugar at, ef- fect of rates on prices, 55 ; Wheat elevators, 16, 121. Kegs and barrels, empty, Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Kentucky, Coal fields of, 12, Hogs, 18, " Prizing" tobacco, 41, Tobacco supply, 13. Kerosene Oil, Use as illumi- nant, 12. Labor, Cost of, in Agriculture, Manufactures and Rail- roads, 380, 381 ; Division of, I, 5- Lake Erie Ports, movements of iron ore through, 10, of man- ufactures and grain, 7, 8; Railroad ferries, 178. Lake Michigan, Railroad fer- ries, 178. Lake Superior, iron mines, 10. Lamb, 19. Lead, S. Dakota, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Lead, Rates on ore as affect- ing prices of, 58; Smelt- ing and refining companies, Index 423 and direct supply of ore of, 42; Sources of supply, 11. Leather, raw material of. Area of supply, 10 ; Effect of rates on prices of, 57 ; Goods, New England and manufacture of, 68. Legislation, hasty, 210, 392. Lehigh district. Cement rock supply, 141. Lemon, California and im- ported Sicilian variety, 26, 27 ; transcontinental rates on, 109. Length of haul, 221. Lexington, Primary market for tobacco, 41. Lighters, 178. Lime, Local area of supply, 12 ; Rate structure, 143 ; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Lincoln, Neb., Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Liquors, Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 286; railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Liverpool, Rail and ocean routes to. And differentials, 119. Livestock, Association, and packing house products rates, 129; Cars, 128, 183, 184; Carload rates and the hundredweight basis, 201, Pacific Coast, 202; and Dressed meats commodity rates, 126-130; disparity in, 128, 129, 130; Through rates and routes complaints to Commission, 290; Com- plaints as to Kansas City as distributing point for, 285, 286; Rates, Chicago- New York, 130, South Caro- lina Railroad, 1855, 151. Local interests and interstate rates, Texas, 98. Local freight, cost of service on, 173. Local rates, 1855, 1909, 399, Texas intrastate, 98. Locomotives, increase in num- ber of, 38s, 386, 387, 388. Logs, Railway revenue per ton mile from, 230. Long and short haul, 167, 239; Interstate Commerce Law and, 75, 76, 253 ; Interstate Commerce Commission and, 252, 258, 359; Virginia Cities group and, 87, 88. Long Island, Truck farming, 22. Los Angeles, and San Fran- cisco rates, 366; Early in- terior base of supplies, 4; California Fruit Grower's Exchange, 30; Long and short haul clause and, 253. Louisiana, Rice supply, 13; Sugar cane crop, 41 ; Truck farming, 22. Louisville, Commerce of, as af- fected by rates, 338-340; Early base of supplies, 4; Differential on Chicago to Virginia Cities, 88; Grain distribution, 339 ; Tobacco primary market, 41, ship- ments of, 339; Whiskey ship- ments, 339. Louisville and Nashville Rail- road, original Tariff of, 152. Low-grade freight, rates on, 222; importance of, to com- munities, 222. Lumber, Associations, 41 ; Commodity rate structure, 133-138, Oklahoma intrastate rate, effect of, on, 311; Com- plaints before Interstate 424 Index Commerce Commission, 288, 289, on through routes and rates, 291 ; Diffused market, 41 ; Memphis industry, 359 ; Railway revenue per ton mile from, 230; Rates, adjust- ments and complications, 134, fixed differences in, 134, 136, Carload, and development of hundredweight basis, 201, Shifting, due to shifting sources of supply, 59, and Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 137, Transconti- nental, 112, Unremunera- tive, to preserve industries, 135. 136 ; Tap lines, 181 ; Re- consignment, 194 ; Sorting at mill, 134; Rates and prices, 52. Lynchburg and Danville case, 254- M Macaroni, manufacture of, from Durum wheat, 15. Machinery, in harvesting, 16, in preparation of grain, as foodstuffs, 16, of packing house products, 17, 19, in creamery products, 21 ; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. McRae, Ga., Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 296. Maine, Corn canning, 27. Maintenance, Cost of, 148, as related to revenue from rates, 374 ; Use of petroleum in, 13; Roadway and, 217. Manhattan Island, " lighter- ing" to, 178. Manufactures, Capital em- ployed in, 379, 380, 381 ; Cost of materials used, 376, Trans- portation charge in cost, 2; Dependence of railroads on, 14; Domestic, stimulated by Revolution, 4, 6, Expendi- tures in, 376, 378; Products, Channels of movement, 7-8, Exchange of, and erosion of traffic channels, 7-8, Gross value of, 376, Multiplicity of, and separation of tariffs and classification, 153, as affect- ing rate structures, 398, Necessity of middleman in distribution of, 44, New England differential on, 69, Net returns from, 376, 377, 378; Rates and equilibrium in, 138, adjustments in, 6g, 70; Salaries and wages, and labor conditions, 376, 379, 381, 382; Miscellaneous, rail- way revenue per ton mile from, 230, complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 288; Compared with Agriculture and Railroads, 374-383; Segregation in, 7. Markets, competition of, and grain rates, 125; Extension of, by traffic men, ice and strawberries, 212, 213; Rates as affecting selection of, 65, bricks and cement, 140, 141, coal, 139, Fruits and vege- tables, 138, Glass, 141, salt, 143, sand, 143; Rates as af- fecting widening of, 47, 48. Maryland, canning industry, 27; Eastern Shore, Truck farming, 22; peach crop, 24. Massachusetts, Canning in- dustry, 27; Industrial losses of, 68; Regulation of Rail- roads, 242. Materials used, cost of. Man- ufactures, and Railroads, 1890, igoo, 190S, 376. Maximum rate, to be prescribed to replace " unjust or pre- Index 425 judicial" rates, 277; Texas, a specific rate, 93. Meats, canned and dressed, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Melon Crop, 25, 26. Memphis, Commerce of, 359; Cotton industry, 359; An early interior base of sup- plies, 4; Lumber industry, 359- Merchants' Despatch, 163. Merchants and manufacturers' Association and traffic ad- justments, 321. Mexico, Prospective use for grazing grounds, 17; Na- tional railroad and export rates, 147. Michigan, Coal fields of, 12; Corn canning, 27; Depletion of lumber supply of, 11; Furniture manufactures of, 11; Peach crop, 24; Sheep, English breeds, 19; Truck farm products of, 9. Middleman, In distribution, 28 ; In purchase of raw material, elimination of, 40; in manu- factured products. Necessity of, 43, 44. "Midnight" tariff, 261. Mileage, Capitalization and, 2,^T, cost of construction, 377, 394; increase in 385, 386, 387, 389; Rates, in England, 70, Wagon tolls and, 148. Milk trains, 9. Mill products, railway revenue per ton mile from, 229. Milling, Cotton and adjustment of rates, 131; Flour, relation of wheat rate to American industry, 125 ; grains, 16, and elimination of broker, 35; Private tracks, 179-181 ; Wool, 10. Milling in transit, Atlanta and Nashville, 359 ; Complaints as to locations befoie Inter- state Commerce Commission, 291 ; Incidental service, 195- 200; Minneapolis, and Du- luth's grain trade, 121, 198- 200. Milwaukee, Early interior sup- ply base, 4; Chicago and, in grain trade, 120. Mine props, posts, and poles, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Mineral products, railway reve- nue per ton mile from, 230. Minerals, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on Hepburn Bill, 286. Minneapolis, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on discrimina- tions in localities, 254, flour rates, 349; Flour, Effect of rates on prices of, from, 52, 54; Milling and the wheat trade, 121, 197, 198; Rates, see St. Paul rates. Minnesota, Eastern flow of grain of, 8; Egg shipments from, 9; Intrastate rates, ef- fect on rate structure, 312; Milling in transit in, 196- 198, 200. Mississippi, Truck farming, 22. Mississippi River, as Basing line. Common points to the east, St. Louis to Dubuque, 81 ; Water-forced rates, go. Mississippi Valley, Eastward flow of grain of, 8. Missouri, Apple crop, 23; Coal fields of, 12; Grain routes from, 8; Hogs, 18; Peach crop, 24. Missouri Valley, Beet sugar 426 Index consumption, 13, Grain pro- duction of, 8. Mobile, Commerce of, 360; An early interior base of sup- plies, 4; Price of bananas at, affected by rates, 56; Rates, indirect effect of New Orleans water-forced rates, 90. Molasses, glucose, and syrup. Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Montana, Common Points, common through rate from St. Louis and Chicago, 84. Montgomery, Ala., Commerce of, 359; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on long and short haul, 359. Morrill, Justin Smith (Sena- tor, Vt.), And advanced methods in handling food supply, 36. Moultrie, Ga., Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Mules and horses, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. N Nails, Effect of rates on prices, St. Louis, 51. Nails and wire, railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 230. National Hay Association and classification of hay, 284. National Petroleum Associa- tion, and oil rates, 291. National Railroad of Mexico and export rates, 147. Nebraska, Cattle feeding, 17; Grain routes from, 8; Hogs, 18; Sheep grazing, 19. Nevada, Lead, copper, and sil- ver production, 11, Wool supply from, 10. New England, Cotton market, 10, Depletion of lumber sup- ply of, II, Effect of rates on prices at mills of, 53, Ex- port of products, 69, Flour mills, decline of, 200, Im- port of food products, 70, Import of raw material, 69, Industries of, 68, Manufac- tures of, movements west, 7- 8, Mileage rates in rate struc- ture region, 70; Rate struc- ture, 67-70. New Hampshire, Manufactur- ing industry of, 68. New Jersey, Canning industry, 27, Flow of manufactures from, 7, Manufacturing in- dustry, 69, peach crop, 24. New Mexico, Coal fields of, 12, Cattle feeding, 17, Lead, cop- per, and silver production, 11, Spanish Merino sheep, 19. New Orleans, Commerce of, 360, Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 296, An early interior base of supplies, 4, Importation of coffee and cane sugar through, 13, Price of flour at, affected by rates, 54, Price of bananas at, affected by rates, 56, Railroad con- nection with Chicago, i860, 5, Water-forced rates, effect on Mobile rates, 90. New York, Differentials and, 118, 119; Early trade of food products for European man- ufactures, 4 ; Food prices, not affected by rates, 48-50; Im- port of coffee and cane sugar through, 13; Milk supply, 9; Prices, as affected Index 427 by rates, bananas, 56, flour, 54, hides, 56, sugar, 55; Railroad connection with Buffalo, 5. New York-Chicago Basic rate, 165; And Trunk line per- centage system, 74, "j^. New York (State) Canning industry, 27; Flow of manu- factures from, 7; Iron and steel industries of, 10; Peach crop, 24; Public Service Commission, 242 ; Truck farming, 22. New York Central System and the Merchants' Despatch, 163. Newspapers, Consumption of paper, 42. Newtown Pippin, 23, 24. Norfolk, Truck farming, 22, Truck farm association, 30; Water-forced rates to, 86. Norfolk differential. And Nor- folk group rates, 87, 88, Com- mon rate with Baltimore, 87. North Atlantic Seaboard, Cot- ton milling, 10 ; Water-forced rates to Norfolk, 87. Northfield, State and Federal regulation at, 312. Nuts, Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 229. o Oakland, " lightering " service to San Francisco, 178. Oats, Effect of rates on prices of. New York, 49; railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Ocean rates, Fluctuations in, 145, Wheat export, 119. Official classification, 305, 307; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, on, 298. Ohio, Coal fields of, 12, Hogs, 18, Iron and steel industries of, 10, Oil wells of, 13, Rates, 78, Sheep, English breeds, 18, Woodenware, manufac- ture of, II. Oil, Complaints before Inter- state Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 288, 291 ; crude and refined, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230 ; Distribution, elimina- tion of broker, 41 ; Lines subject to Interstate Com- merce act, 276; Refining, 13; Sources of supply, 13. Oklahoma, Coal fields of, 12, Cotton export to Pacific coast and Orient, 10, Effect of rates on prices, 52, Oil rates, 363, Oil wells of, 13, 363, Public Corporation Com- mission, 361. Oklahoma City, Commerce of, as affected by rates, 361-363, Packing house industry, 127, 362, Milling in Transit, 362. Omaha, Beet sugar market, 42, Effect of rates on prices, stoves, 51, Group rate, 83, Lumber trade, 134, Packing house industry, 127, Rate, 81, Sources of lumber supply, 134, Wheat elevators, 15, 121. Operation, cost of, 218, 384, 38s, 386, 387. Orange, California, transconti- nental rate, 109, no, Florida and California crops, 26, Mediterranean origin, 26. Orchard products. Distribution of, 13, Transcontinental rates on, 109, no. Orders of the Commission, Carriers must comply with, 276, 278, Commission may modify or suspend, 278, Di- visions of joint rate, 278, 428 Index How obeyed, 275, Not sus- tained by the courts, 275, Punishment for noncompli- ance, 278, Reasonable rates and practices, 278, Time of going into effect, 278. Ore — Iron and Zinc, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Rates, As affecting prices of manufactured prod- ucts, 57, 58. Oregon, Apple crop, 23, Lead, copper, and silver produc- tion, II, Wool supply of, 10. Organs and Pianos, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Orient, exports to. Conditions of traffic with, 145, 146, Cot- ton, ID, Pacific coast prod- ucts, 102, 103. Oshkosh, Wis., Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296, Lumber rates and preservation of industries of, 135- Over-capitalization, 389-391, 403- Overcharges, 246, abolition of, 402. Oyster Trains, Movement of, 9- Pacific Coast, commerce of, as affected by rates, 365-367, Cotton market, 10, First rail- road to, 1869, 6, General products, 102, 103, Plum crop, 25, Prunes, export of, 25, Requirements in mer- chandise and manufacture, 103, 104, Water and rail routes to, 7, 8, Transconti- nental traffic and, 102-113, 365- Packing houses, elimination of the drover, 35; Machinery in, 19; Private cars, 184; Products, Prices and Rates, Denver, 351, Railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 229; Sources ot supplies, 16-17. Padlocks, Rates and prices, Denver, Kansas City, St. Louis, SI. " Palace livestock cars,'' 184. Panama route, 8, 106. Panics, and the railroads, 268; 1873, 262; 1893, 266, 393. Paper, Manufacture of. New England, 68, ownership of pulp supply, 42; Prices, as affected by pulp rates, 57; Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. " Paper " rates, improper ex- ploitation of, 319. Paris Exposition, 1900, exhibit of American apples and sub- sequent European demand, 24. Passenger Cars, increase in number of, 385, 386, 387; Fares, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on, 282; Traffic, proportion of railway ex- penses, 219. Passes, free, 210, 246, 403 ; ex- cepted classes, 276, 277 ; Pen- alty for issue, 277; Traffic associations and, 171. Peach, area of crop, 24, Chi- nese origin, 24, uncertainty of crop, and car distribu- tion, 38, Georgia, complaint of rates, 287. Pears, Crop, 24, European ori- gin, 24. Peas, dried, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Pecos, Texas, Complaints be- Index 429 fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Penalties, Elkins act, 265, 266; Hepburn Bill, for im- proper issuance of passes, 277; Interstate Commerce Law, 250, 251, 265. Pennsylvania, Manufactures, 7, 69, steel and iron, 10; Oil wells, 13 ; Tobacco, 13 ; Line of Public Works and State Ownership, 236. Pennsylvania Lines, and abo- lition of rebates, 269-271 ; built to compete with New York and Erie Canal, 70; Entrance to New York, 73; Increased mileage, 395 ; Ownership of stock of other lines, 390; and the Union Line, through freight, 163. Percentage System, in Trans- Mississippi Territory, 83 ; Trunk Line, 74, 75, 76, 78, 117. Petroleum, Area of produc- tion, 12-13, Consumption in illumination, 12, Consump- tion in railway operation, 13, Elimination of broker in dis- tribution of, 41, Rates and prices, 57. Philadelphia, Competition with New York, 70, Differential, 74. 76, 77, 118, 119, Early trade of food products for European manufactures, 4, Effect of rates on prices at, SO, 54, S6, Fish trains from, 9, Group rate, 77, Price of bananas at, effect of rates on, 56, Price of flour at, ef- fect of rates on, 54, Railroad connection with Pittsburg, 5- Pianos and Organs, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Pickles, Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 286. Pig-iron, Area of production, 10, Complaints before Inter- state Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 286, Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Pipe Lines, " common car- riers," 276; and Oil Trans- portation, 13, Oklahoma- Texas, 363. Pittsburg, Commerce of, 331- 334; Consumption of food products, 333, An early in- terior base of supplies, 4, Effect of rates on prices at, SO, Price of flour at, effect of rate on, 54, Railroad con- nection with Philadelphia, i860, s, Rate, 76, Suburban traffic of, 332. Plaster, lime and cement, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Plums, Crop, 25, Relation to peach, 24. Poles, posts, and mine props, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Pooling, money and tonnage, Cullom report on, 248; In- terstate Commerce law and, 250; Proscription of, 209; Railroad amalgamation and, 251 ; Remedy for abuses, 262, for rebates, 169, 170; Traffic, 208, 209, Wheat, 120. Population, Concentration of, and enlargement of area of supply of fruit and vegeta- bles, 9, Increased demand for grain, effect on grazing grounds to West, 17. Pork, and the corn crop, 16. Portland, An early interior 430 Index base of supplies, 4, Water- forced rates to Boston, 70. Posts, poles, and mine props, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Potatoes, extension of market of. Freight agents, 212, A general crop, 22; Effect of rates on prices of, New York, 49, so, Denver, 351, 352, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229 Poultry, Effect of rates on prices of. New York, 49, Ex- tensive supply area, 9, Food, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 290, Improve- ments in, 20, Railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 229, Refrigerator cars and trans- portation of, 32. Practices, power of Interstate Commerce Commission over, 277, 278, abuses in, 40. Preparation of foodstuffs, 15- 27. Preserves, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission, 286. Prices, Bureau of Labor Bul- letin on, 382, 383 ; and Rates, 47-66; Adjustment to mar- ket conditions, 47; At In- dianapolis, 371, New York, 48, 49, so, Philadelphia, 50, Pittsburg, so; As affecting food, 48, so, 60, 350-352, Cost of raw material, S3-56, Colorado, 3S4, bananas, 56, copper and lead, s8, leather, 57, paper, 57 ; As affected by transcontinental rate, 107, 108; Cakes and crackers, s8, Cotton, S9. Denver, si, 52, 350-355, Fort Worth, S2, Horses and cattle, igoi, 129, 130, Iron ore, 59, 60, Kansas City, 51, 52, Lumber, S9, Oklahoma, 52, San Antonio, 52, St. Louis, SO, SI, Sugar, Indianapolis, 371. Primary markets, sugar, 42, tobacco, 41. Private cars, 183-187; England, 183 ; influence on routing and transportation charge, 32 ; Livestock, 184; Coal, 185; Refrigerator, 32, 183. Private Industrial Tracks, 179- 181. Privileges, reconsignment. Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 291. " Prizing" tobacco, 41. Producers, Competition of, 142. Production, equilibrium in. Rate adjustments, and, 138; and distribution. Defective system of distribution and returns to producer, 60, 61, Fluctuations in, 46, Intimate relations between, 15, Sec- ondary channels of, 45, Traffic channels of, 4-14, 45. Products, Agricultural, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229, value of, 376; Manufactures, gross value of, 376; packing house, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 229; competition of, and rates, 104. Proportional rates. On export and import traffic, 146, On interregional traffic, 116, To Mississippi river crossings, 81. Proprietary interest and trans- portation in Hepburn Bill, 277, 280, 403. Prosperity of United States, Coal supply and, 12; Rates and, as facilitating produc- Index 431 tion, distribution and con- sumption, 325-327; Railroads and, 172, unpreparedness for, 1899, 268, 393. Prunes, Home and export markets, 25. Pulp, newspapers and, 42; rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230 ; Transportation charge as affecting price of paper, 57. Railroads, Achievements of, 384-396 ; Capitalization, 376, 377> 378; Conferences be- tween, 166, and the Traffic Associations, 171 ; Associa- tion of General Freight Agents, 206 ; Construction of, early character of, 23s, 236, stimulated by Revolu- tion, 6, and Civil War, 166, 167, from seaports to inte- rior, 5, 165, demands of the future for, 395 ; Dependence on agriculture, industry and commerce, 14, 374-383 ; Earn- ings, 276, 277; Expenses, 376, cost of materials, 376, salaries and wages, 376, 379, 380, 381 ; Development of markets by, 159, 212, 213; Farmers and demonstration cars, 37; Courts and, pro- cedure in Hepburn Bill, 278 ; Public and, 235-274; Pro- prietary interest in traffic, 247, 280; Canals and, 5, 70, 235, 395. 396; Development by, 4, 14, 325-7. Railway income, 385, 386, 387, 389, disposition of, 392, 404; Rates and Wages, 381, 382; Revenue per ton-mile from products of agriculture, ani- mals, forests, mines, 229- 230; Service, Elevation and warehousing, 182-183, Local and through traffic, 173, Pri- vate industrial tracks, 179- 181, Special cars, 183, Switching, 174-178, Tap lines, 181. Rate adjustments, In Missis- sippi basing line, 81, In trunk line percentage system, 1892, 75, New England, 69, 70, To conserve equilibrium in dis- tribution and production, 138-143, To conserve manu- facturing interests, 69, 70, Traffic associations and, 171 ; Basis, 149, 258; Changes, far-reaching effects of, 314, 405, Time of notice of, 146, 278; Cutting, Abolition of, 402, and excess of railroad facilities, 167, and packing house products, 128, Trans- Mississippi territory, 79, Trunk lines, 72, 73, General business and, 238, 402, over- loading an equivalent to, 201 ; Equilibrium, differen- tials and, 170; Making, dif- ficulties due to lack of pre- cedent, 397, a Legislative act, 257, Power, Interstate Commerce Commission and, 256, 257, 279, 280, Texas Commission and, 97, 242; Reductions, far-reaching ef- fects of, 256, 257; Struc- tures, and competing inter- ests, 66, 75, commodity, 117- 147, development of, 67, 405, regional, 67-116, State lines and, 310; Wars, 165-173, 386; Trans-Mississippi Ter- ritory, 79, Trunk Lines, 72, Minneapolis-Chicago, 1882, 120, Wheat, 120, 122. Rates, American and Euro- 432 Index pean, 48; Basis of, 216-234; Character of freight and, 43, 151, 153; Capitalization and, 231-234; Carload, number of, 307, 308; Classification and, 152 ; Competition of products and, 104; Commodity, 117- 147 ; Competing commodi- ties, 143; Correlation of, 310-311, 31S, 405, in Trunk line territory, 75, 76, Wheat, 122; Dressed Meats, 126- 130 ; Experimental, 223 ; Ex- port and import, 14S; Fluc- tuations in, so; Georgia, 149; Increase in, 273; Intra- state and rate structures, 311; Livestock, 126-130, dis- parity in, with packing house products, 128, Chicago-New York, 130; Prices and, see Prices and Rates; Supplies and, 65; Senate investiga- tion, 275; Switching service and, 180; Mileage, in New England, 70; Railway reve- nues and, 273, 374-383; Sea- son, 153; Value of competi- tive traffic and, 225, 226; Local and through, 245 ; Long and short haul, 239, 240, Interstate Commerce law, 1887, and, 75, 76, 250, Virginia Cities group, and, 87, 88; Lumber, see Lumber, rates; Mileage, in South Carolina and Georgia char- ters, 148, 149; Non-competi- tive, 400; Proportional, 81, 116, 146; Publication of, im- port and export, 145; Rea- sonable and just, 250; Re- consignment and, 193; Spe- cial, 142; Specific, ^()\ Through, see Through rate; Transcontinental, see Trans- continental rate; Wages and, 64. Ratings, classification, number of, 307- Raw materials, of manufacture, Areas of supply, and move- ment of, 10-13; Effect of rates on cost of, 52, 53 ; New England differentials on, 69; Rates to aid manufactures, 224; Segregation of produc- tion and manufacture, influ- ence on problem of trans- portation, 43; Rates on, and cost of manufactures, Colo- rado, 354 ; Miscellaneous, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 286. ■"eagan, John H. (Judge), Theory of distribution for Texas, 94. Reasonable rates. Interstate Commerce Commission to determine and to prescribe, 277; Present prevalence of, 399. Rebates, Abolition of, 401 ; Corporations liable for grant- ing, 277; Elkins law and, 210; Favorite shippers and, 24s, 246; Freight agents and, 208; General business and, 238, 246; Interstate Com- merce Commission and, 260; Large shippers and, 259; Offering or granting, a crime, 277; Over-rapid Rail- road construction and, 236, 238; Penalty for, 277; Pool- ing as a remedy for, 169, 170; Soliciting, a crime, 277; Switching charges and, 180; Tap line allowances and, 181; Trunk lines and, 72; A. J. Cassatt and, 269. Receiverships, railway, 233, 266, 387, 391; rebating and, 169. " Reciprocal Demurrage," 191, 192. Index 433 Reconsignment, incidental serv- ice, 192-195; Privileges and charges, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Com- mission on Hepburn Bill, 292. Refineries; Beet Sugar, Califor- nia, 103, Ore, direct sources of supply of, 42, Sugar, Lou- isiana, 41. Refrigeration, And transpor- tation of perishable food products, 31, And western movement of packing house industry, 127, Transconti- nental, no; Car, 183-184, Early employment of, 31, Private ownership of, 32, 184. Refunds, Interstate Commerce Commission and, 285 ; and Rebates, 281. Regional gateways, and pro- portional rates, 114. Regional rate structures. New England, 67-70, Pacific coast and transcontinental traffic, 102-116, South of Ohio and East of Mississippi, 85-92, Texas, 92-102, Trans-Mis- sissippi and Trans-Missouri territory, 78-85, Trunk Line and Central Traffic Terri- tory, 70-78. Reno, Nevada, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission, 296. Restraint of trade. Traffic agreements and, 263. Revenue, as determining in- vestment, 231. Revolution, American, Its stimulus to manufacture, 4,6. Rhode Island, Manufacturmg industries of, 68. Rice, Area of production, 13, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 286; Sources of supply, 13, Railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 229. Richmond, Commerce of, 357, Early trade of food products for European manufactures, 4, water-forced rates, 357. Rocky Ford melon, Colorado, 25, 26. Rocky Mountain region, Ap- ples, superior quality of, 23, Lead, copper, and silver ores, II, 12. Roswell, N. Mexico, Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Rotation of crops, 22. Routing, Private car compa- nies and influence over, 32. Rubber goods. New England manufacture of, 68; shoes. Effect of rates on prices, 54. Russell, Wm. E. (Governor, Mass.) And industrial losses of Massachusetts, 67. Rye, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 229. Sacramento, First California railroad from, 104, Water point, 104. St. Louis, And Missouri river traffic, 80, An early inte- rior base of supplies, 4, As Western gateway, impor- tance to Trunk Lines, 71, Beet sugar market, 42, Bridge Arbitrary; 344; Car- load " spread " and, 203 ; Classification difficulties, 305 ; Commerce of, as affected by rates, 34^-344 '. Differential between, and Chicago, 80, 434 Index Effect of rates on prices of manufacturers' material at, SI, Elevator service. Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission, 294; Furniture manufacture, 11, Group rate, 83, Primary market for tobacco, 41, Railroad connections, i860, S, Rates and Chicago Rates, fixed differences, 342; Rate on sugar beets, and price of sugar at, 56, Rates to Texas common points, 95, Southern Rates Complaint and, 343; Wheat elevators, 16, 121. St. Paul, Commerce of, 348- 350; An early interior base of supplies, 4, Rate, 82; Sugar at, effect of rates on prices, 55. Salary and wage earners, num- ber of, and Salaries and wages, Manufactures, 1890, 1900, 1905, Railroads, 1890, 1900, 190S, 376, 379, 380. Salmon, San Francisco and Shipments to Atlantic sea- board, 10, 366. Salt, Complaints before Inter- state Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 286; Rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230; Rate structure, 143- San Antonio, Effect of rates on prices at, 52. San Bernardo Board of Trade, and the long and short haul, 253- San Buena Ventura, Cal., Complaints before the Inter- state Commerce Commission on the Hepburn Bill, 296. San Francisco, Carload " spread," 203 ; Commerce of, 365-367 ; " Contract Plan," 106; An early interior base of supplies, 4; Impor- tation of coffee, and cane sugar through, 13 ; " Light- ering ' service from Oak- land, 178. San Luis Valley, Cal., Hog products of, 18. Sand, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230; Rate struc- ture, 141 ; rates, special, 142. Santa Barbara, Cal., Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Sash, doors and blinds, facto- ries, New Mexico, 137; Osh- kosh, rates and preservation of, 13s. Savannah, Commerce of, as affected by rates, 359; Early trade of food products for European manufactures, 4 ; Water differential to Galves- ton, 84. Schedules, filing of. Interstate Commerce Law, and, 277. Scrap and Pig-Iron, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Sea food, Channels of move- ment of, 9. Seaports, influence of, on dis- tance tariffs, 156-161, 165. Seckel pear, 24. Seed farms, California, 22, Colorado (melon), 25. Segregation, in manufacture, 7, 43 ; in production, 43. Seligman, E. R. A., on eco- nomic justification of long and short haul rates, 240; prophecy of railroad amal- gamation, as result of pro- scription of pooling, 25. Senate, investigation, and Doc- ument No. ^57, 273. Service, Quality of, ixnprove- ment in, 211, Traffic clubs Index 435 and, 321-324 ; Incidental, 188-205, Bill of Lading, 188- 190, Demurrage, 191-192, Diversion en route, 193, Milling in transit, 195- 200, reconsignment, 192-195, Complaints of, before Inter- state Commerce Commission, 292 ; Local and through, 173 ; Secondary, 174-187; Value of, as rate basis, 231, 287! Sewer pipe and drain tile, rail- way revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Sheep, American, English breeds, Spanish Merinos, 19; railway revenue per ton- mile from, 229. Sheet and bar metal, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Sheldon pear, 24. Shipbuilding, Boston's pre- eminence in, 67, Weymouth and, 68. Shippers and Traffic Men, 316; Rebating, 168; large and small and rate discrimina- tions, 258-259. Shoes, Effect of rates on prices of, SI, S3, Rates, eastern and western compared, 308, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 288. " Shoestring district," and north and south bound lines, 72, 76. Shooks, Box, Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Side Tracks, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 292; Service from, 175. " Sides," cattle, 19. Silver, Sources of supply, 11. Sioux City, Iowa, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Sioux Falls, Iowa, Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Skilled labor, Industrial pros- perity, New England, and, 69. Sleeping Car Companies, Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, re, 282, In- cluded in Hepburn Bill as " common carriers," 276. Smelters, Direct sources of ore supply of, 42. Smithfield hams, 18. " Societies of Equity," and wheat rates, 356. Solvay Process Co., and switching charge, 181. South Africa, importation of peaches from, New York, 24. South and Southeast, Com- merce of, as affected by rates, 356-361. South Carolina, Government regulation in, 148, 149. South Carolina Railroad, Tariff of 1855, 150-152. Southeastern Rate structure, 85-92; Influence of water rates in, 85, 252 ; Staple man- ufactures in, 336, 337. Southern classification, 305, 307; Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 298; Early Tariffs, 152. Southern Railway and Steam- ship Association, Adjust- ment of cotton rates, 130, 131. Southeastern Rates Complaint, 335-337; Louisville and, 340; St. Louis and, 343. Special equipment cars, 183- 436 Index 187; Coal cars, 185, Dem- onstration cars, 31, Livestock cars, 184, Refrigerator car, 31, 183, Tank cars, 184, Ven- tilator car, 31. Specific rates, Hepburn Bill and, 280; Interstate Com- merce Commission and the Freight Bureau Cases, 256, 257; In Trunk Line terri- tory, 76. Spencer, Samuel, and the rate- making power of the Com- mission, 280. Spitzenburg apple, 23, 24. Spokane, Washington, Com- merce of, 367; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, on Pacific Terminal rates, 367. " Spotting " cars, on industrial tracks, 179, 180. "Spread" in Carload Rate, 202, 203, 205. Spurs, and Carload rates, 154; Service from, 175; jurisdic- tion of Interstate Commerce Commission over, 276. Stability of rates, pooling and, 170; ocean rates and, 145. Standards, Roadway and Fa- cilities, 393. State Classifications, 309. State Colleges of Agriculture, Benefits of, to grain produc- tion, 14, Work of, 36. State ownership of utilities, Pennsylvania 236. State Railroad Charters and through Traffic, 162. State Railroad Commissions, and rate stability, 311; Texas, 94 ; Massachusetts, 242; Regulation, 209; and Federal, 309-313. Station Location, Change of. Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 292. Statistical difficulty in uniform accounts, 303. Staves and Heading, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Steam, Source of power, 12, 235- Steam road and electric road. Through routes and rates, Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 291. Steamship rates, instability of, 145. Steel productions. Areas of production, 10, 11, Channels of movement, 11. Stock in trade, effect of Trans- portation facilities on, 99, 100, 159. Stone, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230; crushed, special rate, 142. Storage, and Reconsignment, 193 ; Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 292. Stoves, Effect of rates on prices at Denver, Kansas City, Omaha, 51 ; Prices at St. Louis, 51 ; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230. Straw, Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Com- mission on Hepburn Bill, 290; Railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Strawberries, Southern, exten- sion of market for, by freight agents, 213. Structural and bridge iron, railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Suburban Traffic, Pittsburg, 332. Sugar, Complaints before In- Index 437 terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 286; Effect of rates on prices of, SS, Indianapolis, 371, 372; railroad revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Suits against Commission, Ap- peal to Supreme Court, 278. Summerville Hay case, and the long and short haul clause, 253. Supreme Court, and intrastate rates, 313; And import and export rates, 147, 255; Ap- peals to, 278; On live stock rates, 129; On rate-making power of Commission, 257; Rulings of Commission, Dan- ville rates, 254, Elevation charge, 182, Import rates, 25s, Summerville Hay case, 253. Switches, spurs, and sidetracks, 174-177 ; Jurisdiction of Com- mission over, 276; To be provided, when justified, 277. Switching charges, 176; Buf- falo, 330; Complaints before Interstate Commission on Hepburn Bill, 292. Switching, 174-178; "Belt" Lines, 176, 177; "Trap-car," 177, lightering, 178, Charges of industrial lines for, 180, 181. Syrup, Molasses, and Glucose,' railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Tank cars, 185. Tanning, 10, 42. Tap Lines, 181; lumber com- panies and, 181. " Tapering Tariff " and decen- tralization of distribution, 228. Tariffs and Classifications, early, 148-155. Tariffs, South Carolina R. R., 150-152, Louisville & Nash- ville R. R., 252, Carload and less-than-carload rates. Fil- ing of. Interstate Commerce law and, 250. Taussig, F. W., on economic justification of long and short haul rates, 240. Texas, Agriculture, 1890, 1900, 1905, 376. " Team " Tracks, 154, 175. Tennessee, Coal fields of, 12, Egg shipment from, 9, " Prizing " tobacco, 41, To- bacco supply of, 13. Terminal Facilities, Buffalo, 331 ; Jurisdiction of Commis- sion over, 276; Rates, On transcontinental traffic, 107, 108, Spokane and, 367. Terminals, Trunk Line, 71, 113, 114. Territorial groups. Commis- sion, 283; complaints in, 285-300. Texarkana, rate adjustment, 364. Texas, Cantaloup, 25, Cattle, 16, Commerce of, 363-365, Common point territory, 94, 95, 97, 98, 99, 363, 364, Cot- ton export to Orient, 10, Egg shipments from, 9, Hogs, 18, Oil wells of, 13, Packing houses in, 17, Peach crop, 24, Rate structure, 92-103, Rice supply, 13, Turkeys, 20, Turkeys, prices of, in New York, 49, Truck farming, 22. Texas Railroad Commission, And decentralization of dis- tribution, 100, 102, And emer- gency rate on wire and nails, loi, 102, As a court, 102, 438 Index Cotton compressing, 132, Cotton rates, 131, Flour and wheat rates, 362, Inaugura- tion 1890, 94; Intrastate Maximum rate, 93, 96, 97, 36s ; effect of rate structures, 311; Power over rates, 97, Car service. Traffic Bureaus and, 322, 323. Through freight lines, 163, 164. Through rate, Interstate Com- merce Commission, and, power of apportionment, 278, Through Rates, 1885, 1909, 399; Chicago and St. Louis common to Montana Com- mon points, 84; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 290; Western primary- markets, wheat, to Liverpool, 119; division of, Traffic As- sociation and, 171. Through routes, Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 255, 290; Import and export traffic, 144-147; Com- mission may prescribe, 278. Through traffic. Civil War and, 161, Enabling Act 162. Thurman, Allen G., and dif- ferentials, 119. Ties, Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 230. Timber and products, railway revenue per ton-mile, 230; expected from " commodity " clause, 277. Tobacco, Commission mer- chants, 41, Effect of rates on prices of, 55, Primary mar- kets for, 41, Sources of sup- ply, 13, Warehousing, 183, Louisville shipment and rates, 339. Tolls, primitive, 216, 217. Tomatoes, Canning, 27, Effect of rates on prices of, New York, so. Ton-mile, Railway revenue from, 383 ; Products of, Ag- riculture, Animals, Forests, Manufactures and miscella- neous. Mines, 229-230; Road hauling, cost per, 38. Ton-mile basis of cost of trans- portation, 220, 274; rates, de- cline in, 389. Ton-mileage, increase in, 384, 386, 387, 388, 389. Tonnage, pooling of, 170, 262. Track, Gauge, and through traffic, 161 ; Storage charge, incidental service, 192; Ju- risdiction of Commission over, 296. Traffic, Agents, and extension of markets, 212, 213; Agree- ments, 261, 262, rate wars and, 165-173; Associations, and abuses, 171, and Anti- Trust law, 263; Bureaus, 316-317; Channels, erosion of, 6-8, Character of train- loads over, 45, Commodities of, and percentage system rates, "^7, Secondary, 45 ; Clubs, 321-324; Competition for, and rate-cutting, 167, 239; Competitive, value of, in relation to rates, 225 ; Con- gestion, 1899, 271, 392, 393; Earnings, 389; Experts, 314- 324; Traffic Men and Ship- pers, 316; Increase in, 386, 387, 388; Units and efficiency of operation, 384; Unremu- nerative, as conserving re- munerative, 266. Transcontinental Commodity Tariffs, 305. Transcontinental rate, 366, Clipper ships and, 104, 105, Competition of markets and, 104, "Contract Plan," and, Index 439 lo6, Rate plateau. New York to Chicago, 107, And long and short haul clause, 252; rates per ton-mile, Railway revenue from, Fruits and vegetables, 229; Traffic, 102- 113, Filing of export and im- port rates, 145, First trans- continental Railroad, 1869, 105- Trans-Mississippi and Trans- Missouri territory, 78-85. Trans-Missouri Freight Asso- ciation, and Anti-Trust law, 263. Transportation, early, 2 ; effects of seaports on, 4, 5, 156-161 ; Charge, basis for, 216-234, as affected by extent, 65, com- plaints of, in early traffic, 327, private car companies and, 47, as related to reve- nue and maintenance, 3; Cost of, 219, 220, 221 ; Coun- try road, cost per ton-mile, 38, Meaning of term in Hep- bum Bill, 276; Function in Commerce, 2, 159; "on the hoof" and Cattle rate, 126, 127; Wages and purchasable amount of, 64; Segregation in manufacture and produc- tion, as related to, 43, 159. "Trap-car" switching, 177. Trimmings and Iron Rails, railway revenue from, 230. Trolley lines, and distribution of farm products, 39. * Truck farm products, Califor- nia seed supply for, 22, Channels of movement, g. Extent of area of supply, 9, 22. Trunk line and central traffic territory. Local rates in, JT, long and short haul rates, 252, obliteration of rebates in, A. J. Cassatt and, 270, Regional rate structure, 70- 78. Trunk Line Association, 171, Differentials, 118, 119, Form- ation of, 73, Uniform bill of lading, 188. Trunk Line rate, On South- eastern grain traffic rate, 91. Trunk Line Percentage Sys- tem, 170; Erection of, 1876, 74, Revision of, under I. C. Law, 1887, 1892 and 1896, 75. 76, 78, Steadying water and rail competition, 117. Trunk Lines, 71, Baltimore to Parkersburg, New York to Buffalo, New York to Sala- manca, Philadelphia to Pitts- burg, Their relation to Chi- cago, St. Louis and Cincin- nati, 71. Trust law, anti, 263. Tubs, galvanized iron. Effect of rates on prices of Denver, Kansas City, St. Louis, 51. Turkeys, 19, Effect of rates on prices' of, New York, 48, 49, Texas supply, 20. U Undue preference or advantage forbidden, 277. Uniform classification, 304-309, 403- Unjust discrimination defined and forbidden, 277. " Unjust and unreasonable " rates and a maximum rate, 277. Union Line, origin of, 163. Union Springs, Ala., Com- plaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 296. Unremunerative rates to pre- serve industries, 136, to con- serve other traffic, 226, 227. 440 Index Unrestrained competition, evils of, 262. Use, as determining rate, 151. Utah, Beet sugar supply, 13, 42, Cantaloup, 25, Coal fields of, 12, Lead, copper, and sil- ver production, 11, Truck farm products of, 9, Wool supply from 10. Value of service, rate basis, 231. Values, as entering into fix- ing of rates, 150, 221 ; Dol- lar as measurement of, 375. Vegetables, Canning of, 27, Diversion en route, 193, Rate structure, to conserve equi- librium in common markets, 139, Rates, carload, on, 1 10, revenue per ton-mile from, 229. Vehicles, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 230; lumber rates and preservation of Factories, 135. Ventilator cars, 31. Virginia, Grass-fattened cattle of Southwest, 18, Oil wells of, 13, Smithfield hams of, 18, Tobacco supply, 13, 41. Virginia Cities' rate, 87, 88. W Wages and salaries, Manufac- tures, 376, 380, Railroads, 218, 376, 380; Agriculture, 376. Wagon Toll, 148, 216, 397. War of 1812, Stimulus of, to manufacture and exchange, 4- Warehousing and elevation, 182-183; Cotton, 182, To- bacco, 183. Washboards, Effect of rates on prices of, Denver, St. Louis, 51. Washburn, Elihu B., And the differentials, 119, On dressed meats and livestock rates, 130. Washington, Apple crop, 23, Coal fields of, 12, Lumber production of, 112. Water, delivery, 178. Water-forced rates, 165, bear- ing on Southwestern rates complaint, 336, California and Pacific Coast, 108, 109, Denver, 84, New England coast, 70, On grain transpor- tation, 117, Southeastern rate structure, 86, 87, on jMississippi river points, 90, Transcontinental rates, 104, 105, 106, 366, and Value of competitive traffic, 225. Water points. Basing points in Southeastern rate structure, 87. "Water" Stock, 232; exces- sive rates due to, 246. Water transportation. Fluctua- tion in rates of, 117, 118. Waters, Complaints before In- terstate Commerce Commis- sion on Hepburn Bill, 286, railway revenue per ton mile from, 230. Watermelon, African origin of, 25, Crop, 25, Rate instance, 61-64. Wages and rates, 64. Weights, minimum carload and estimated. Complaints be- fore Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 292. Weight, Relation to rates, 43, in early tariffs, 150-155. West, Flow of grain from, 8, Flow of manufactures to, 7, Index 441 Food products of, as erod- ing channels of traffic, 7, Growth of railroads towards, 5-6, Raw material of leather from, 10. West Virginia, peach crop, 24, Iron and steel industries of, ID. Western Classification, 305, 307; Carload ratings in, 203; Complaints before Interstate Commerce Commission on Hepburn Bill, 298. Weymouth, Mass., arid ship- building industry, 68. "What the traffic will bear," 227, 231, 24s, 400. Wheat, Back traffic, 120; Com- modity rate, 1 17-126, Cross- fertilization in, IS, Differ- entials, ii8-iig, 198; Gulf export of, 122, 123, Durum wheat, 15, Gulf rates, 123, Effect of rate on prices of, New York, 49, Improve- ment of the crop, 15, Ma- chinery in handling, 16, Railway revenue per ton- mile from, 229; Rates and "Societies of Equity," 356, and prices, 126, 351, wheat growing, care in, 15. Wholesale and retail mer- chants. As affecting cost of distribution, 44. Wichita, grain rate, 124, Com- plaint before Interstate Com- merce Commission on Cotton piece goods rates, 289. Wilmington, Commerce of, as affected by rates, 358, Early trade of food products for European manufactures, 4. Wine and brandy, railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 230. Wire, copper, railway revenue per ton-mile from, 229; Effect of rates on prices, 51. Wire and nails, railway reve- nue per ton-mile from, 230; Texas Railroad commission and emergency rate on, 100, loi. Wisconsin, Corn canning, 27, Egg shipments from 9, Grain routes from, 8, Hogs, 18, Railroad building, 241, To- bacco supply, 13, Vegetables from, 9. Witnesses, Interstate Com- merce Commission and, 265. Woodenware, Manufactures of, area of, 11. Wool, area of production, 10; effect of rates on prices of, 53 ; railway revenue per ton- mile from, 229. Woolen and worsted goods. New England and manufac- ture of, 68. Wyoming, Cattle feeding 17, Coal fields of, 12, Wool sup- ply from, 10. Yellow pine, And white pine, 13s, 136, Area of production, II, Rates, New Orleans to Chicago, 59. McPherson's The Working of the Railroads By Logan G. McPhekson, Lecturer on Trans- portation at Johns Hopkins University. 12mo. $1.50 net, by mail $1.63. " Simply and lucidly tells what a railroad company is, what it does, and how it does it. Cannot fail to be of use to the voter. Of exceeding value to the young and ambitious in rail- road service." — The Traveler's Official Railway Ouide. " The most important contribution to its branch of the subject that has yet been made." — The Dial. " The author's connection with practical service gives this a value which no other book quite equals. Up-to-date, inform- ing, ... an excellent piece of work." — Wall Street Journal. Carter's When Railroads Were New By Charles Feedeeick Carter With an Introductory Note by Logan G. McPherson. 16 full-page illustrations, 8vo, 312 pp. $2.00 net, by mail $2.16. A history of the every-day difficulties, discourage- ments and triumphs of the pioneers who built and ran the early railroads. With many anecdotes that add to the abundant human interest. " Full of interest. Besides the general chapter on the beginnings, it gives the early history of the Erie, the Pennsyl- vania, and the Baltimore and Ohio, of the Vanderbilt lines, the first Pacific railroad, and of the Canadian Pacific. Very readable." — N. Y. Sun. " As readable as a first-class novel. Not only a study of railroads but also a study of human nature." — N. Y. Globe. " Invaluable. It gathers the floating fragments of railroad history, weaving a human interest into a coherent record of every day trials and triumphs. A human and personal docu- ment, not a dry historical treatise or a batch of anecdotes." ■ — Baltimore Sun. " No book of adventure contains more exciting episodes or more varied interest. Every page is of live interest. So re- plete with curious information, thoroughly entertaining and instructive." — Brooklyn Eagle. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY PUBLISHERS NEW YORK amerlcan public problems EDITED BV RALPH CURTIS RINGWALT IMMIGRATION : And Its Effects Upon the United States By PRESCOTT F. HALL, A.B., LL.B., Secretary of the Immigration Restriction League. 393 pp. $1.50 net. By mail, $1.65. " Should prove interesting to everyone. Very readable, forceful and convincing. Mr. Hall considers every possible phase of this ^eat question and does it in a masterly way that shows not only that he thoroughly understands it, but that he is deeply interested in it and has studied everything bearing upon it." — Boston Transcript. "A readable work containing a vast amount of valuable informa- tion. Especially to be commended is the discussion of the racial effects. As a trustworthy general guide it should prove a god- send." — N. 7. Evening Post. "Earnest and unprejudiced. . . . Cannot fail to be of great assistance in clarifying and setting on a solid foundation the ideas of people who are now becoming convinced that the problems of immigration in the nation and the municipality will soon reach a more acute stage than ever before." — Philadelphia Press. "An auspicious omen of the worth of Messrs. Henry Holt and Company's recently announced series on American Public Prob- lems. . . . Mr. Hall has been in close touch with the immigration movement and he writes with a grasp and a fullness of information which must commend his work to every reader. ... A handbook ... to which one may turn conveniently for information for which he would otherwise be obliged to search through many a dusty document." — TJie World To-day. THE ELECTION OF SENATORS By Professor GEORGE H. HAYNES, Author of " Rep- resentation in State Legislatures." 300 pp. 11.50 net. By mail $1.65. Shows the historical reasons for the present method, and its effect on the senate and senators, and on state and local government, with a detailed review of the arguments for and against direct election. "A timely book. . . . Prof. Haynes is qualified for a historical and analytical treatise on the subject of the Senate." —N. Y. Evening Sun. " Well worth reading, and unique because it is devoted wholly to the election of senators and to the deliberations of the Senate." — Boston Transcript. "Able and dispassionate, and ought to be widely read." — New York Commercial. " Of considerable popular as well as historical interest."— Dia?. Henry Holt and Company 29 West 23d Stkeet New Yobk TWO BOOKS ON VITAL QUESTIONS FOR THOUGHTFUL AMERICANS THE NEGRO AND THE NATION By GEORGE S. MERRIAM Probably the first complete history of the negro in his relation to our poHtics. 2d printing 436 pp. $1.75 net. By mail $1.92. The Rev. Edward Everett Hale in " Lend a Hand " ; *' Sensi- ble people who wish to know, who wish to form good sound opinions, and especially those who wish to take their honest part in the great duties of the hour, will read the book, will study it, and will find noth- ing else better worth reading and study." •'Admirable, exactly the sort of book needed. , .. Enlightened and persuasive discussion of the negro problem in its present phases and aspects. Not a dry history. Human, dramatic, interesting, absorb- ing, there is philosophy of national and political life back of it— a philosophy wnich not only furnished interpretation of past events, but offers guidance for the future. . . . Impartial and informing, . . . There is much that tempts quotation. . . . Mr. Merriam has given us an excellent, high-minded, illuminating book on the problem of the American negro." — Chicago Record- Her aid. "A deeply interesting story. . . . An exceedingly readable vol- ume, especially valuable in its analyses of conditions, causes, situa- tions and results; and against his main conclusions no sane person can contend." — Boston Transcript. STUDIES IN AMERICAN TRADE-UNIONISM J. H. HOLLANDER and G. E. BARNETT (Editors) Twelve papers by graduate students and officers of Johns Hopkins University, the results of original investiga- tions of representative Trade Unions. There are also chapters on Employers' Associations, the Knights of Labor, and the American Federation of Labor. (380 pp., 8vo, S2.7S net. By mail, $2.98.) "A study of trade-unions in the concrete. Impartial and thor- ough . . . expertly written." — New York Times Review. "Though confined io particular features of particular trade unions, the data dealt with are comprehensive and typical ; so that the result is a substantial contribution to our knowledge of trade- union structure and functions. . . . Excellent studies." — New York Evening Post. *' It is doubtful if anything approaching it in breadth and co-ordi- nation has yet found its way into print. ... A very useful book." — San Francisco Chronicle. Henry Holt and Company 34 W. 33D Street (v, '06) New York STANDARD BOOKS IN ECONOMICS BUCHER'S INDUSTRIAL EVOLUTION Translated by Dr. S. M. Wickett, Lecturer in Toronto Univer- sity. 393 pp. 8vo. $2.50. The Outlook :— A work of prime importance to economic students. While German in the thoroughness of its scholarship, it is almost Oallic in its style, and is, for the most part, decidedly iuteresting reading. CLARK: THE LABOR MOVEMENT IN AUSTRALASIA By Victor S. Clakk. 837 pp. 12mo. $1.60 net. Quarterly Journal of Economics :— A valuable work based upon investi- gation in the field. Treats judicially the various aspects of the Australian labor movement and estimates critically its significance. HOLLANDER AND BARNETT: STUDIES IN AMERICAN TRADE UNIONISM Edited by J. H. Hollander and G. E. Baknett, Professors in Johns Hopkins University. 380 pp. 8vo. $2.75 net. Twelve papers by graduate students and officers of Johns Hopkins University, the results of original investigations. McPHERSON : THE WORKING OF THE RAILROADS By Logan G. McPhbrson. 373 pp. 12mo. $1.50 net. Simply and lucidly tells what a railroad company is, what it does, and how it does it. MORE'S WAGE-EARNERS' BUDGETS A Study of Standards and Cost of Living in New York City. By Louise B. More. With a preface by Professor F. H. Gid- DiNGS. 380 pp. 8vo. $2,50 net. A report of the first investigation carried on under the direc- tion of the Committee on Social Investigations at Greenwich House, a social settlement on the lower West Side of New York City, among workingmen's families of difEerent races and occu- pations. ZARTMAN: THE INVESTMENTS OF UFE INSURANCE COMPANIES By Lester W. Zartman, Instructor in Yale University. 359 pp. 12mo. $1.35 net. It analyzes investments and the earning power of the various assets of life insurance companies. The interest rate is calculated by a new and exact method. The author also discusses the rela- tions of the investments to social welfare, and the proper control of the immense assets of the companies. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 34 West 33d Street New Yotk SEAGER'S JNTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS By Henry Rooers Seagbr, Professor in Columbia Univer- sity. Tliird Edition, Revised and Enlarged, xxii + 604 pp. 8vo. $3,25. This book presents in simple language the pi'inciples of Eco- nomics in vital relation to tlie facts and problems of contemporary business life. In the revised edition a chapter on Public Expendi- tures and Public Revenues and another on Taxation and Tax Reform in the United States have been added, and the chapter on Production and Distribution has been rewritten. F. H, Dizon, Professor in Bartmoath College :— Professor Seager has writ- ten what is probably the beet text-hook on the elements of economics that has yet appeared. . . . The feature of the book is the exhaastive treatment of the subject of distribution, to which eight chapters are devoted. The mental bal- ance of the writer is here most evident, for in spite of his Austrian training, he finds himself unable to follow the Austrian writers in their extreme positions. His acceptance of much of the thinking of the classical school in combination with the more conservative portions of modern theory, results in a presenta- tion which, far from being wavering and indefinite, as one might fear, is con- sistent, sane, and satisfying. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science ; — Professor Seager not only has given UB an unusual text-book, but he has made as well an important, if not original, contribution to the literature of Economics. Indeed, it is not too much to say that he has brought the work of contemporary American theorists into its proper relation to the work of Pro- fessor Marshall, much as Professor Marshall himself bad already adjusted the theories of the Austrian economists to those of the English classical school. . . , The chapters on practical problems are models of exposition andargu- mentation, the treatment of the trust and labor problems being particularly clear and comprehensive. . . . The book is, altogether, the best introduc- tion to the itudy of Economics that has yet been written. L, L. Price, in " The British Economic Journal":— The exposition of the principles of Economics presented in the earlier chapters of the book is, it appears to us, equally suited to students on this and to those on the other side of the Atlantic. . . . His treatise, indeed, seems to us to possess, as a whole, great advantages both for master and for pupil, and to deserve the Tel- come which we believe it will receive on both sides of the Atlantic. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 34 Wet 33d Street New York TEXT-BOOKS IN ECONOMICS ADAMS'S SCIENCE OF FINANCE By Henry C. Adams, Professor in the University of Michigan. 573 pp. 8vo. {American Science Series.) $3.00. Edwin K. A. Seligman, Columbia Univerflity, in "Political Science Quar- terly " :— Will at once command attention ae a lasting contribution to eco- nomic literature. ... It is perhaps no exaggeration to say that Professor Adams is at the head of those American scholars who have grasped the easen- Ual spirit of modem industrial life ; and it is likewise no exaggeration to claim for this volume the distinction of being one of the most original, the most sug- gestive, and most brilliant productions that have made their appearance in recent decades. DANIELS'S ELEMENTS OF PUBUC FINANCE By WiNTHBOP Moke Daniels, Professor of Political Econ- omy in Princeton University. 878 pp. 12mo. $1.50. F. Spencer Baldwin, Professor in Boston University ;— It is a piece of work well done both from a scientific and a literary point of view— a text-book with a style. . . . The lacid explanation of the financial system of the United States makes the book particularly valuable for the American student. SCOTT'S MONEY AND BANKING By W. A. Scott, Professor in the University of Wisconsin. 881 pp. 8vo. $3.00. H, E. Hills, Professor in Vassar College :— It is clear, comprehensive, and conservative. All in all, it seems to me the best single book to use in connec- tion with a course on Money and Banking. SEAGER'S INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS By Henry R. Sbagbb, Professor in Columbia University. Third Edition, Revised and Enlarged. 604 pp. 8vo. $3.35. Journal of Political Economy :— Thoroughly modem in doctrine ; wide in sympathy, clear, sprightly, and stimulating in style and manner of presentation. SEAGER'S ECONOMICS, BRIEFER COURSE By Henry R. Sbager, Professor in Columbia University. 467 pp. Large 13mo. Intended primarily for those who wish to give only that amount of attention to economic theory that is essential to the intelli- gent discussion of practical economic problems. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 34 West 33d Street New York BY THE LATE FRANCIS A. WALKER DISCUSSIONS IN ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS Edited by Professor Davis R. Dewey. With portrait. 2 vols. 8vo. 454 + 481 pp. $6.00 net. Important papers by a great authority on Finance, Taxation, Money, Bimetallism, Economic Theory, Statistics, National Growth, Social Economics, etc. The Dial :— ■ . ■ Bconomics in the bands of this master was no dismal science, becaase of his hroad sympathies, his healthy, conservative optimism, his belief in the efficacy of effort ; and, in a more snperflcial sense, because of his saving sense of hamor and his happy way of putting things .... he was the fortunate possessor of a very pleasing literary style .... clear and interesting to the general reader, as well as instractive to the careful student. There could have been no more fitting monument to his memory than these two volumes, together with the other volume of " Discussions in Education." MONEY 550 pp. 12mo. $3.00. Kew York Tribune :— The essential facts of monetary experience in every country are presented with sufficient fullness and with judicious mingling of authority on disputed points. The work will win a very honorable place for its author among the few who are advancing toward the mastery of a most dif- ficult science. MONEY IN ITS RELATIONS TO TRADE AND INDUSTRY 339 pp. ISmo. $1.35. Boston Courier :— The present volume is of a more popular nature than his previous one on Money, but certainly is not on that account less important. Viewed in its immediate relation to the money questions of the day which are entering more and more into politics and becoming therefore active levers for the advancement of society .... adapted to easy comprehension by a mixed audience, it is a publication of greater moment than its more elaborate and critical predecessor. INTERNATIONAL BIMETALLISM 297 pp. 13mo. $1.25. The Outlook ;— The best hook yet published in the English language for the exposition of the distinctively economic questions at issue between bimetallists and monometallists. WAGES A Treatise on Wages and the Wages Class. 438 pp. 13mo. $2.00. Kation:— The most complete and exhaustive treatise on the wages question with which we are acquainted. . . . The general correctness of its line of argument is in striking contrast to much that has been written on the subject. POLITICAL ECONOMY Advanced Couksb. 537 pp. 8vo. $2.00 net. Bribper Course. 415 pp. 13mo. $1.30 net. Elementary Course. 333 pp. 13mo. $1.00 net. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 34 West 33d Street New York BIOLOGY AND ITS MAKERS By W. A. Locy. By the Professor of Biology in Northwestern University. 123 illustrations. 8vo. $2.75 net, by mail $2.88. " Entertainingly written, and, better than any other existing single work in any language, gives the layman a clear idea of the scope and development of the broad science of biology."— 7"^« Dtal. CANADIAN TYPES OF THE OLD REGIME By C. W. Colby. By the Professor of History in McGill University. 18 illus- trations. 8vo. $2.75 net, by mail $2.90. " A light and graceful style. Not only interesting reading, but gives as clear a notion of what the old rfegime was at its best as may be found anywhere in a single volume."— /.j/^rary Digest. THE BUILDERS OF UNITED ITALY By R. S. Holland. With 8 portraits. Large i2mo. $2.00 net, by mail $2.13. Historical biographies of Alfieri, Manzoni, Gioberti, Manin, Mazzini, Cavour, Garibaldi, and Victor Emmanuel. " Popular but not flimsy ."— The Nation. THE ITAUANS OF TO-DAY By Ren6 Bazin. By the author of "The Nun," etc. Translated by Wm. Marchant. $1.25 net, by mail $1.35. "A most readable book. He touches upon everything."— 5oj/<»» Transcript, DARWINISM TO-DAY By V. L. Kellogg. By the author of " American Insects," etc. 8vo. $2.00 net, ty mail $2.12. " Can write in English as brightly and as clearly as the oldtime French- men. ... In his text he explams the controversy so that the plain man may understand it, while in the notes he adduces the evidence that the specialist requires. ... A brilliant book that deserves general attention."— A^ra; York Sun. «% If the reader will send his name and address, the publishers will send, from time to time, information regarding their new books. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY M WEST 33d STREET NEW YORK