"" '- 1 BOUGHT WITH THE INCOME FROM THE SAGE ENDOWMENT FUND THE GIFT OF Hettrg W, Sage 1891 Cornell University Library arV11619 Outlines of camparative politics. 3 1924 031 323 409 olin.anx Cornell University Library The original of tliis bool< is in tine Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924031323409 OUTLINES OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS OUTLINES OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS BY B. E. HAMMOND UNIVERSITY LECTURER IN HISTORY FELLOW AND FORMERLY LECTURER OF TRINITY COLLEGE, CAMBRIDGE. AUTHOR OF 'political INSTITUTIONS OF THE ANCIENT GREEKS' RIVINGTONS 34 KING STREET, CO VENT GARDEN LONDON 1903 PEEFACE Until about twenty years ago it was impos- sible for any one to say witb certainty whether knowledge of the laws governing political phenomena could be derived from the evidence of history. The writer of the present volume was led in the years 1885 and 1886 to believe that it could. In those years he heard Pro- fessor Seeley lecture on the classification of communities, and Professor Henry Sidgwick on the evolution of the forms of governments. The tasks that they set themselves corre- sponded, one to the work of Cuvier, and the other to the work of Darwin, in the science of Zoology. About two years later the present writer attempted to give instruction in a department of that part of political study which is founded on history ; and for fifteen years his chief employment consisted in re- writing and re-delivering his lectures. He chose for his department Comparative Politics (or the classification of States and their Govern- ments), because he believed that it required vi PREFACE less preliminary knowledge than any other. Experience showed him that beginners in the subject needed a text-book as well as oral teaching. A lecturer's proper business in such a subject is to expound guiding principles; but the student needs examples as well as principles, and the examples in any historical study are better learned by reading than by hearing, because they cannot be understood without attention to a voluminous mass of details. The present volume is intended to serve as a text-book for beginners in Com- parative Politics. It contains a general survey of States and their Governments : the plan of the work is explained in the first chapter, and the results are summed up in the last. The book is founded on two courses of lectures by Sir John Seeley (for more than twenty years a kind friend to his disciple, its writer), which were published in 1896 under the title of an Introduction to Political Science. Although it avoids distracting the reader's attention by frequent reference to them, large parts of it are little more than a collection of facts to test their conclusions. It sketches the beginnings and early growth of the more important States, and contains, at the end of the last chapter and elsewhere, PEEFAGE vii Tables intended both to exhibit the classes into which political societies are divided by differences of form, structure, or origin, and to show that som0 of them (but not all) have definite types of government appropriate or peculiar to themselves. It does not attempt to deal with the evolution of any given form of government from its predecessor, and does not borrow anything directly from Professor Sidgwick's early lectures delivered in 1886; but those lectures gave the writer valu- able aid by suggesting good examples for him to study. And lastly, the present volume has, unhappily, missed all the improvement it might have gained if Professor Sidgwick's Development of European Polity had been published earlier. When that long-desired work appeared, the printing of these Outlines of Comparative Politics was so nearly finished that alterations could not be introduced; and, though their writer looks forward confidently to receiving great pleasure and enlightenment from reading the work of his old friend, he is, to his regret, debarred from communicating to his readers the advantages which he will him- self enjoy. Cambridge, December 1903. h CONTENTS INTRODUCTION, .... 1 I. PREHISTORIC TRIBES, ... 7 II. EUROPEAN TRIBES, . . . .16 III. UNIONS OF TRIBES, .... 38 IV. CITY STATES, .... 55 V. SIMPLE CITY STATES IN ANCIENT HISTORY, . 62 VI. UNION OF GREEK CITIES : ATTICA, . . 80 VII. UNION OP ITALIAN CITIES : ROME, . . 101 VIII. COMPLEX CITY STATES, . . .146 IX. ATHENS, ..... 151 X. HETEROGENEOUS EMPIRE : ROME, . . 176 XI. MIXED POPULATIONS, . . 211 XII. SMALL COMMUNITIES IN THE MIDDLE AGES TO 1150 A.D., . 236 XIII. UNIONS OF LIKE COMMUNITIES EFFECTED BY CONQUEST, 800-1300 A.D., . 255 XIV. NATIONS IN THEIE YOUTH : MEDIEVAL CON- STITUTIONS, . . . .288 CONTENTS CHAPTBE PAGE XV. CITY STATES IN THE MIDDLE AGES, 309 XVI. CITIES WITH DEPENDENCIES, . . 342 XVII. NATIONS IN THEIE FINAL ADVANCE FKOM UNION TO UNITY : DESPOTIC GOVERNMENTS, 358 XVIII. UNITARY NATIONS : THE DECLINE OF DE- SPOTIC GOVERNMENTS, . . . 381 XIX. UNITARY NATIONS : MODERN CONSTITUTIONS, 394 XX. VOLUNTARY UNION OP EQUALS : THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, . . . 417 XXI. VOLUNTARY UNION OF EQUALS : MODERN SWITZERLAND, .... 442 XXII. MODERN UNIONS OP STATES, . 451 XXIII. SUMMARY, ..... 468 TABLE OF STATES AND THEIR GOVERNMENTS, 474 APPENDIX HYPOTHESES OF A UNIFORM ORIGIN OF POLITICAL BODIES AND GOVERNMENTS, 477 INDEX, ..... 483 OUTLINES OF COMPAEATIVE POLITICS ^^ INTKODUCTION It is generally admitted that some light may be thrown upon the characteristics and growth of political communities by comparing those of them which are alike. It is my intention in the following chapters to compare political communities; and in order to carry it out, it has been necessary to settle which communities I regard as like one another, or, in other words, to make a classification of bodies politic. There are many possible ways of classifying communities. It will be convenient here to state what classification I have adopted, because in so doing I shall show what communities I regard as comparable, and shall inform the reader what is to be expected in the following pages. The earliest communities were tribes or small societies of men bound together by kinship, by religion, and by interest. Originally every tribe was a single undivided so- ciety. In course of time tribes were united by conquest, but when this took place they usually coalesced completely, so that a union of tribes made A 2 SIMPLE AND [int. by conquest became a single tribe, scarcely showing a trace of local cleavage. Tribes then in general will be regarded as simple undivided societies. Next after the tribes came cities. A tribe grew into a city by concentrating itself within walls. A large proportion of the cities were never ^'''^^' united by conquest, but remained separate states. These single cities when they came to ma- turity were the most compact and indivisible states known to history. We shall then count the tribes and the single cities as being simple and undivided, or at any rate as being more undivided than most m^?tfes crn- other States. It will be shown hereafter form to a few f,]iat these simple and undivided com- ^ ' munities all conform to a few definite types, and each type has its organ of government constituted in a certain way peculiar to itself. The regularity which prevails among the simple and un- divided states seems to prove that their development is controlled by natural laws rather than by man's contrivance, and that in some way or other each simple state has its form of government allotted to it by nature. The simple communities can be joined together either by conquest or by their voluntary consent so as to form new states : and the new states are Composite . states more Composite. The composite states include variable. ^j^ unions of cities such as that which formed the Roman Republic, (2) unions of small and similar rural communities such as those which made INT.] COMPOSITE STATES 3 the mediaeval kingdoms, (3) unions of unlike peoples such as constituted the Roman Empire and the Empire of Charlemagne, and lastly (4) those unions made by voluntary consent which are known as federal states. The composite states do not conform to a few defined types, but seem to be capable of indefinite variation. Their variability will be re- garded as arising from their artificial origin: for it will be shown that a union of two states must always be brought about, at least partly, by deliberate design, and not entirely by instinctive action, and therefore composite states are distinguished from simple states by having a more artificial character. Although composite states seem to be capable of indefinite variation, some composite states are alike. Groups of similar composite states are r . Some com- lound among the heterogeneous empires posite states and the federal states. Heterogeneous ^re similar, empires and federal states are made more de- liberately and consciously than any other states, and their character is very largely determined by the plan of construction which their founders- adopted. The founders of empires and of federations have tried many plans in constructing them, and therefore there are many varieties of each of these kinds of composite states ; but one plan of making an empire and two plans of making a federation have been found especially useful, and accordingly there is a group of similar empires and there are two groups of similar federations constructed after the most advantageous designs. The successful empires then 4 TRANSITION TO SIMPLICITY [int. form a group of similar states, and every successful empire may be compared with every other ; and the same is true of the two groups of federations con- structed according to the designs that have generally yielded the best results. Among the states formed by union of cities and in the media3val kingdoms I have failed to find any groups of precisely similar communities. It would seem that their growth was too natural to be controlled by the designs of their founders, and their origin too artificial to allow them to grow naturally. As these states in ancient and mediaeval history refuse to be classified, my discussion of them must be limited to pointing out certain well- known analogies and differences in the development of their constitutions. It will be seen then that I shall regard the distinction between simple states and composite states as fundamental, since simple states may States Seem to grow of themselves, become ^^(j composite States are more or less simple. . deliberately designed and constructed. But the distinction is not indelible. A composite state, under certain conditions, may take to grow- ing of itself, and may be converted into a single community and into a simple state. In order that it may do this it is necessary that it should be composed of like materials, and that it should not renew its composite character by uniting more communities with itself. Unions of cities do not often grow into simple states, because they usually go on annexing new communities continually. The INT.] CLASSIFICATION 5 mediaeval kingdoms, on the contrary, had bounds set to their ambition either by geographical limits or by the strength of their neighbours, and many of them have been converted into single and undivided communities, which are generally denoted as unitary nations to distinguish them from federal states. The unitary nations all conform to one type, and all have a kind of government not found except in unitary nations. They are then a class of naturally formed states easily distinguishable from other classes, and the individual specimens can be profitably compared with one another. It will indeed be necessary to admit that only one of the unitary nations developed its organs of government for itself : the other nations copied their governments from the nation which set the example, but they have now had some experi- ence of the governments which they adopted, and have found them hitherto suited to their require- ments. The general lines then of our classification will run as follows. We shall divide states into simple states and composite states. All simple states can be arranged in a few classes, each classification class conforming to a definite type and ^^°P^^^- having a kind of government peculiar to itself. A great number of the composite states cannot be arranged in classes ; sometimes, however, many com- posite states have been designed by the founders according to a common plan, and then these states form a class by themselves ; but it is a class of objects rather of artificial construction than of 6 CLASSIFICATION [int. natural growth. The types of states cannot be enumerated here, since it will be the work of our discussion in the ensuing chapters to discover and define them : a list of them will be found in the last chapter in the volume. CHAPTER I PKEHISTORIC TRIBES In starting on our survey of states and governments, we are met at the outset by the inevitable question, What was the origin of pohtical com- munities and their governments? At- states"and tempts have been made to answer it from governments observation of ancient customs embedded in the institutions of peoples who afterwards attained to various degrees of civilisation, as the ancient Romans and Greeks.^ It appears to me that all attempts to discover the origins of political organisa- tions by this method must, for the present at least, be doomed to failure. We have had accessible to our scrutiny in modern times the uncivilised peoples of Asia, America, Africa, and Australasia, who are cer- tainly much nearer to the most primitive forms of organisation than any of the historical peoples of ancient Europe, and yet we do not know how political societies and governments first came into existence in any one of them. There is indeed reason to suspect that their origins may have varied very greatly in different parts of the dark continents. But till we have discovered far more than we know at present about the first beginnings of political life in modern ^ See Appendix at the end of the volume. 8 PREHISTOEIC TRIBES [ch. i. uncivilised peoples, who have varied comparatively little from their most primitive forms, and who have been subjected to careful observation, it seems hope- less to attempt to ascertain the first origins of societies and governments among the European peoples of ancient times, who offer in many ways a less favour- able field for investigation of the subject. Passing over then the problem of origins as being for the present insoluble, we direct our attention to- the very different question, What con- What con- _ ■' ^ ' ditions are ditions must exist in a group of human the"eStence ^^ings in Order that they may have a of govern- government and constitute a political society ? This question can be answered from the conclusions derived from observation of those races of mankind which have never attained to a civilised condition. Uncivilised peoples are divided into four well- marked classes or grades, according to the degree of material well-being which falls to their uncivilised lot. The lowest class are the hunting peoples. peoples, who have no regular resources for their sustenance, but depend from day to day upon their success in killing wild animals and gathering the fruits or roots of wild plants. The class next above them are the nomads, or peoples who have flocks and herds to yield them flesh and milk, but have no fixed habitations, because they are compelled to wander about in search of pasture. Next above these come the settled pastoral peoples, who have both flocks and herds and fixed abodes. Highest of OH. I.] FOUE GEADES 9 all among uncivilised mankind are the agricultural peoples, who know the arts of tilling the soil and of growing corn, and of making bread or pulse. It seems to be an established fact that the only instances of peoples without any government at all are found among the hunting peoples.^ Some of the nomads, such as the Bedouin Arabs, may have very little of government, and yet in the rule of their sheikhs they have something ta which the name of government cannot be completely denied. On the other hand all the settled peoples with fixed habitations, whether they are pastoral or agricultural, are found to be formed into political communities and to have governments more or less regularly constituted. The conditions then which are necessary to the existence of government seem to be pretty clearly established. The hunting peoples may in some cases be totally devoid of government: all peoples who have means of subsistence other than those derived from hunting have something of government, and those who are settled in fixed habitations have governments of some solidity and durability. And the reasons why these conditions prevail may per- haps in some measure be discovered and understood. If we consider firstly the hunting peoples, it is quite easy to see the reasons that may debar them ' I am led to this conclusion by a passage in Mr. Herbert Spencer's Political Institutions (§ 442). All the instances that he there cites of peoples without governments come from the class of savages or hunting peoples ; and, after consulting his Descriptive Sociology, I do not think any instances adverse to my conclusion can be found. 10 PREHISTORIC TRIBES [ch. i. from having any government. The life of a primi- tive hunter is always spent for the most part in isola- tion. There are some of them whose only weapons for the chase are wretched bows and arrows: with such miserable appliances it is impossible to obtain food enough to support life unless each family wanders in complete isolation, because any gathering of men would frighten away the game ; and as they do not live together nor act together, the idea of having a government does not occur to them, and if any rules of government existed there would be no means of enforcing them. And something of the same sort occurs even among those hunting peoples who are raised to prosperity by the proximity of wealthy neighbours, from whom they can obtain commodities and comforts in return for the furs of wild animals. They may have effective weapons ; they may be able to make such elaborate appliances as stockades to catch buffalo; and yet they too find it advantageous to hunt singly or in twos or threes during the greater part of the year, although for a few days at a time they unite for a great hunting party. Whenever they are gathered together, a government is formed for the time being ; but, as a matter of course, as soon as the hunters disperse the government goes into abeyance.^ * The remarks here made about the life of savages are founded on actual instances — namely, the Bushmen of South Africa in the early part of the nineteenth century, and the Red Indians of North America about fifty years ago. The authorities for them are Burchell, Travels (1822), and H. Y. Hind, The Canadian Red Kii-er Exploring Expedition (1860). CH. I.] PRIMITIVE ORGANISATION 11 On the other hand, when we turn to the settled peoples, we easily see how governments are possible and useful to them. As they have a sure resource in their herds or their grain, and are not dependent on hunting alone, there is nothing to prevent them from living permanently grouped together in small bodies without danger of starvation ; they dis- cover the advantages of living together and acting together for defence or for aggression; accordingly they do live together and act together, and under these circumstances some kind of leadership or government is necessary, and it readily comes into existence. How it arises no one can say; it may be that the birth of a primitive government never occurs twice over in the same way. All that we know is, that when men live together and act to- gether government is needed, and government is there. Now that we have considered what are the con- ditions necessary to the existence of government, we may turn to inquire. What kinds of _. , •> _^ The form of political communities and governments primitive are most prevalent among primitive °''8^^"'^^ '°"- peoples ? This question, like the one recently under discussion, can only be answered if we observe what happens among the most primitive peoples known to us — namely, the non-European uncivilised peoples of modern times. Among these rude peoples of our own days, the prevalent political bodies are tribes or small communities under governments of their own, living in the open country, without any walled city. 12 PEEHISTOEIC TRIBES [CH. i. The circumstances in which the tribes are placed determine the form which their governments assume. As tribes are constantly employed in fighting with one another, their governments are such as to pro- mote military efficiency and success in war. The chief conditions necessary for military success in a rude people are two : there must be some leadership or command, and at the same time all the tribesmen must be ready to fight zealously. Accordingly we find in almost all uncivilised tribes that in order to provide leadership there is, firstly, a commander-in- chief or king, and secondly, under him, lesser captains or chieftains ; and in order to ensure that all the tribesmen shall fight zealously and none shall be discontented, the whole mass of the fighting men have a share in settling the policy of the tribe. Thus the tribal governments as we see them in the uncivilised races of the present day are mixed governments containing the three elements, king, chieftains or nobles, and common folk ; the govern- ment is conducted in assemblies or folkmoots, in which all the three elements are present, and each has such a share of political power as is fairly proportioned to the services which it renders to the tribe upon the battlefield. ^ The conclusions derived from observation of modern ^ See Mr. Herbert Spencer's Descriptive Sociology, the tables relating to African and Indian tribes ; also his Political Institutions, § 464. A tribal assembly held by the Ma-tchappi, a Bechuana tribe, in South Africa about 1822, was witnessed by Thompson and Moflfatt, and its proceedings are vividly described by Thompson, TraveU (1827), vol. i. pp. 156-191. CH. I.] ARYAN TRIBES 13 uncivilised peoples can be applied to the elucidation of the prehistoric condition of the Aryans, from whom the peoples most important in history prehistoric are descended. Our chief conclusion Aryan tribes, hitherto has been that all settled peoples, whether pastoral or agricultural, have governments, and their governments are usually conducted in assemblies attended by king, nobles, and people. From the evidence of language we know that in the remote prehistoric age, when the Aryans lived together as neighbours, some of them were settled pastoral peoples. The evidence to this effect occurs in abundance in the languages of the Greeks, the Romans, the Germans, the Persians, and the ancient Hindus. It proves that the forefathers of these peoples while they lived together had domesticated some of the animals most useful for the sustenance or service of man ; they certainly kept cows, sheep, and dogs, and probably also pigs and horses. They knew how to make use of the strength of their cattle for draught ; they had carts on wheels, and yokes for the necks of the oxen. They were not entirely ignorant of the use of corn for food, though it must be admitted that they knew and cared very little about the tillage of the soil. And lastly — what is a very important indication of the progress they had made — they were not wanderers, but had fixed abodes and settlements ; their dwellings were not mere movable tents, but houses with doors. They were, in short, settled pastoral peoples; and hence, as has been shown above, we may infer with certainty that they 14 PEEHISTOEIC TRIBES [ch. i. had some kind of political organisation, and with much probability that they were governed by assem- blies in which king, nobles, and people took part. In regard to the forefathers of the Greeks, the Germans, and Hindus, the probability of the second inference becomes a certainty when we take into account the well-known fact that their descendants in later ages have lived under tribal governments of the ordinary type.i So then in that distant age, when the Aryans all lived together, the forefathers of the Greeks, the Germans, and Hindus were already settled pastoral peoples, organised in political communities and governed by their folkmoots. How distant that age may have been no one can tell ; it is separated from times of which we possess records by a gulf of ages which we cannot bridge over and cannot measure. In the interval between the Aryan age and the beginning of history, the changes that occurred were immense: the Aryans divided by means of some great migration into two branches, of which the one inhabited Europe and the other Central Asia ; in the Asiatic branch there arose the great Persian Empire, and the voluminous sacred literature of the Hindus ; in the European branch the Greeks and Italians advanced from mere barbarism to that degree of cultiire which we find them possessing when first the light of history dawns upon them. ^ The linguistic evidence about the material condition of the ancient Aryans has been carefully examined by Schrader in his Sprachvergleichimg und Urgeschichie, translated into English by Mr. Jevons under the title Prehistoric Antiquities of the Aryan Peoples. CH. I.] THEIR ANTIQUITY 15 Before I leave the consideration of the Aryans in prehistoric times, it is desirable to point out that I make no assertion whatever about the condition, in those ages, of the Celtic and Slavic branches of the race. There may be evidence in the languages of the modern Celts and Slavs sufficient to show the condition of their forefathers in the Aryan age ; but if there is I do not know it. With this word to guard against misconception, I pass on to examine the tribes of Germans and the Greeks as they are known to us from literature. CHAPTER II EUROPEAN TRIBES The earliest and least artificial of all the European communities known to us from literature were those which grew up among the ancient Germans and Greeks. When first we can discern them, each was a single community having a territory and govern- ment of its own, living mainly in the open country, and devoting itself to pastoral, agricultural, or military pursuits. So long as they retained these characteristics unaltered, we must call them by the vague name of tribes, because no more expressive name has been invented. The communities which cannot be denoted otherwise than as tribes form a class by themselves. They include most obviously the Spartans in the early part of their career, the German peoples described by Tacitus, and the Anglo- Saxon peoples of the so-called Heptarchic period. I must also place in the same class the Achaean communities known to us from the Homeric poems, because though they possessed fortified towns and were on their way to become city states, the mass of their populations had not as yet diverged perceptibly from those pursuits which are especially characteristic of tribesmen. CH. II.] POOE TRIBES 17 Before I describe the early tribes known to us from literature, it may be remarked that any one of them may have been formed from a union of many smaller tribes. We know of the existence in some parts of Europe of tribes no larger thaa villages ; and it is not improbable that such minute tribes may have existed elsewhere. It is obvious that they might easily be merged in larger tribes. In speaking of the European tribes which form the subject of the present chapter, it will obviously be convenient to begin with those among 1-1111 /■ 1 Poor tribes. them which had departed least irom the conditions that had prevailed among the prehistoric Aryans who are known to us only from the evidence of language. The old Aryans had lived as rude, poor herdsmen, knowing nothing of wealth and luxury ; and it will be natural for us, in treating of tribes known to us through the medium of literature, to speak first of some among them who lived even in the age of literature in a like condition of primitive simplicity. The tribes among the Germans and the Greeks who still lived on into the age known from literature unaltered from their original tribal state, and in a condition of primseval poverty, were the Germans whom Tacitus described, and the Spartans _in the earliest part of their history. Of the habits and governments of these primitive peoples I shall now proceed to sketch in outline the most salient characteristics. Our knowledge of the ancient German tribes is derived from the descriptions of them left to us by B 18 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. Julius Csesar and by Tacitus. Csesar in the year 55 B.C. made a flying incursion of eighteen days' dura- tion into Germany, and in the remainder In Germany. j • n i 01 his proconsular command m (jraul, which lasted till 49 B.C., he diligently collected information about the Germans from travellers. Tacitus published his description of the Germans in 98 A.D., and could make use of the knowledge which the Romans had acquired during their mili- tary occupation of Germany from b.c. 9 to a.d. 16, and in their subsequent dealings, peaceful or war- like, with the German peoples. Among all the characteristics of the German tribes none made more impression, both on Csesar and Tacitus, than the hardy simplicity of their mode of living and their ignorance of all kinds of luxury. From the descriptions given by these authors we learn that, though the Germans were not entirely unacquainted with agriculture, they were still rather herdsmen than tillers of the soil. Their only riches were their flocks and herds ; they had no commerce, no accumulations of wealth, no towns, nor even villages in the ordinary acceptation of the word; for their houses were never grouped closely together, but each was a separate homestead standing apart in its own plot of ground. Property, such as they had, was evenly distributed; none were rich, few were destitute. In warfare all used the same simple weapons — a shield and a short spear, fit alike for thrusting and for casting: they had not any large supply of good horses, and the strongest of the CH. II. J GERMANS 19 warriors fought on foot; for the cayalry and the infantry formed a mixed force, and the footmen were expected to run fast enough to keep up with their mounted comrades.^ The governments of the German tribes, carefully described by Tacitus, were a product of the con- ditions in which they lived. The elements of the population were still three, as in more primitive tribes; at the head was the king, below him the chieftains, and lastly the ordinary warriors. The supreme government, as in other primitive tribes, was conducted in general assemblies or folkmoots, in which all three elements were present ; and as all men were nearly alike in possessions and in military efficiency, the final decision in all great matters, such as questions of war or peace, rested with the whole host, and not with the chieftains and king. The king and chieftains formed a council which settled matters of less importance, and undertook a pre- liminary consideration of proposals to be submitted to the general assembly ; but this was the limit of their powers. The king was not exalted high above the chieftains unless he gained a lofty position by lofty personal qualities. In the general assembly the proposals were usually made by the king or some chieftain ; but each man got a favourable hearing only in proportion to his own merits and the merits of what he said ; and the assembled people could, if they thought fit, summarily reject the proposals that were made by uttering a general murmur of ' Caesar, Bdl. Qall. vi. 22 ; iv. 1, 2. Tacitus, Oermaniay e. 6, u. 6. 20 EUKOPEAN TRIBES [ch. n. dissent. The folkmoot then was a sovereign folk- moot in which each man counted for what he was worth ; and it settled all the business which the tribe regarded as important. It had the power and duty of electing a king among candidates of princely lineage ; it named generals to command in war, and elected chieftains to administer justice in time of peace.^ Although we possess descriptions of many other political institutions of the ancient German tribes, besides those that have been mentioned above, it seems to me convenient to put off the consideration of these other institutions to a later part of the present chapter. We have already observed what was the supreme organ of government in the German tribes, and we can now direct our attention to the supreme organ of government in a Greek tribe which was as hardy and simple in its mode of life as were our own forefathers in their German homes. It happens (unfortunately for students of political institutions) that, though all the Greek tribes must once have lived in a condition of primitive poverty, there is only one of them which remained in that condition to so late a period that traditions about it have been handed down to us in books. That one tribe is the Dorian tribe of the Spartans. The whole- Greek race was made up through junction of many lesser races : historians are able to count up about eighteen of these lesser races, ' Csesar, Bull. Qall, v'\. 23 ; Tacitus, Qermania, c. 11, u. 12. CH. II.] SPARTANS 21 each of -which comprised in itself a number of tribes. Among the lesser races which made up the Hellenic name, the most conspic- uous are the Achseans, the Dorians, and the lonians. In the time of Homer many tribes belonging to the Achaean race had attained to great material prosperity; and in consequence of their material prosperity and the accumu- lations of wealth which they had made, they are not suitable for comparison with our rude Ger- man forefathers. In the same age of Homer the Dorians were so obscure a race that they are only mentioned once or twice in the Homeric poems, and even' then they are barely mentioned. They were living, as we learn from Herodotus,^ in a small district situate on the southern side of Mount CEta, which, in the neighbourhood of Thermopylae, forms the northern bulwark of Greece. Their home was a narrow rocky valley, walled in on the north by the range which has just been mentioned, and on the west and south by continuous ridges which join that range with Mount Parnassus. On the east the waters of their valley flowed out, first into Phokis and then into Boeotia ; and as Phokis and Boeotia were already occupied by tribes who were not Dorians, the Dorians were debarred from access to the sea. It was the sea in those days which brought wealth into Greece, and, as the Dorians had no communication with the sea, they knew nothing of those material advantages which the Achaean tribes enjoyed. They were of ' Herodotus, viii. 31. 22 EUEOPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. necessity hardy mountaineers inured to poverty and habits of endurance. At some time between the age of Homer and the beginning of Greek history, properly so called, the sturdy Dorian tribes issued out of their Spartans. mountain gorge, invaded the Pelopon- nesus, expelled the Achaean tribes out of their abodes, and themselves occupied the conquered territory. In many cases the conquered lands con- tained excellent sites for cities, on which the Achseans had already built small towns, as Corinth, Mycenae, Argos ; in those cases the Dorian communities settled in the towns, adopted urban habits of Hfe, lost their old tribal condition, and grew into Dorian city states, so that they do not belong to the subject of the present chapter. In two cases the conquered terri- tory was suited to the rural pursuits by which tribes are distinguished; and in these two cases the con- querors remained in their tribal condition under the names of Messenians and Spartans. Of the Messenians we have no trustworthy records, and the Spartans are the only Greek tribe in a condition of primitive poverty that is accessible to our investigation. Of the habits of the Spartans immediately after their settlement in the country which they had conquered from the Achseans we have no contemp- orary records ; that settlement was long antecedent to the age of written history. But we know from a treatise which is attributed to Xenophon, and was certainly written in the time when he lived, that in the central period of Greek history (about 400 b.c.), CH. ii.J SPARTANS 23 they lived such a life of poverty and hardship that Spartan endurance has ever since been proverbial; and, as they lived in poverty in an age when wealth was widely diffiised among the other Greeks, there is no doubt that they were poor from the beginning and always remained poor. To state details of their poverty is unnecessary ; it will suffice to say that all were poor, and there was no class superior to the rest in possessions or in military efficiency. In the Spartan community, as in the German tribes, the supreme organ of government was a folkmoot in which the three elements of „ . . , Onginal the population were all present and each Spartan had a share of influence and authority. S"'^™™^" • Kingship, however, was not the same thing among the Spartans as it was in German tribes ; a German tribe, as we have seen, had one king, a man chosen by the folkmoot from among candidates of princely lineage; the Spartans had duplicated the kingly office, and they recognised two kings and two royal families ; there was no such thing as election in the process of filling the kingly office, but the heads of the two royal families ruled conjointly, and when a king died his heir male mounted the throne by right of descent. The remaining two elements in the Spartan folkmoot, as it was defined in the constitution which bore the name of the legendary lawgiver, Lycurgus, were just like those in a German folkmoot : there was a council of elders, exactly twenty-eight in number, so as to make thirty with the two kings ; and it was ordained that the whole 24 EUROPEAN TRIBES [cH. ii. folkmoot, king, elders, and people, should meet at fixed times and within fixed limits of place, close to the group of unwalled villages which collectively bore the name of Sparta. The relations, too, of each component part of the folkmoot to the whole was the same as in Germany : resolutions were proposed by the council of thirty, but the whole people had the power of accepting or rejecting the. resolutions according as they thought fit. The con- stitution then of the early Spartans was one in which every element of the population had its share of power, and an even balance was kept up by the action and reaction of the forces exercised by king, elders, and people. This constitution was observed, and this even balance of powers was maintained, until the reigns of two kings, Polydorus and Theo- pompus, somewhere about 700 e.g. In their reign for the first time the Spartan tribe was altered out of its original tribal form by contact with another people ; and in that same reign an attempt was made to alter the balance of the constitution. The attempt was made by the commoners in the folkmoot ; they took to a practice of moving amendments to the resolutions submitted to them by the council of thirty, and thereby encroached on the established privilege of the council, who had till then possessed the sole right of proposing resolutions and initiat- ing measures. The usurpation of power by the commoners was a failure, and they suffered defeat through the resistance of the kings and elders. The measure, however, by which they were defeated is CH. ii.J EICH TRIBES 25 only a part of a series of measures which were adopted by the Spartans when the whole form of the Spartan community was altered by contact with another people. These measures form a part of the revolution which, about 700 B.C., changed the Spartan community from being an excellent example of the original form of tribes into a shape so distorted that, till fifty years ago, there was no parallel to it in all history. The revolution which altered the Spartan state will be described in my third chapter; the defeat of the usurpation of the commoners will there be explained, and therefore no further account of it need here be attempted.^ We have now observed that both the Spartans and the many tribes of the Germans known to Tacitus are examples of poor tribes, in which ^ , . „ 1 1 Rich tribes. there were no accumulations oi wealth, nor any class superior to the rest in possessions or in military efficiency; and we have further noticed that both at Sparta in early times and in the German tribes the supreme organ of government was a folkmoot, in which every class of the popula- tion had a share of power and influence. We may now turn our attention to two groups of tribes in which wealth had been accumulated, and had been amassed in private hands so as to form a class of men superior to the rest in social position. The two groups to which I refer are the Achaean tribes among whom Homer lived, and those German tribes who ^ The chief authority for the earliest Spartan constitution is Plutarch, Lycurgus, u. 6, c. 7. 26 EUROPEAN TRIBES [on. ii. migrated to Britain and were there known as Angles and Saxons. Both the Achseans and the Anglo- Saxon tribes properly belong to the subject of the present chapter; for, though they had attained to material prosperity, they had not been altered out of their original tribal form nor deserted the pursuits characteristic of tribesmen. The Achaean tribes of the heroic age, as every reader of Homer knows, lived in a condition far Achaean removed from the poverty of the peoples tribes. of whom I have thus far been speaking. They had become skilful and diligent in agriculture, ploughing the soil, growing corn, cultivating the vine and the olive tree ; they were rich too in flocks and herds. At their sacrificial banquets there was always abundance of bread, wine, and oil, and plenty of victims for slaughter. Of the useful metals they had what they needed ; they employed bronze for weapons of war, and iron for the ploughshare and the mattock. The precious metals were not want- ing : the princes drank the red wine sometimes out of goblets of gold; and it might chance, when a guest on coming to a house washed his hands, that the water was poured on them from a golden ewer over a silver basin. They had good weapons and armour. Each chief carried a long sword and short dagger, as well as two spears suited either for hurling or for thrusting. Every warrior had helmet and shield, greaves and cuirass ; but the chiefs had them of finer quality and make than the ordinary fighting men could obtain. And lastly, there was one form of CH. II.] ■ ACH^AN TRIBES 27 wealth more important than all the rest: the rich men and chieftains had chariots for war, and swift horses to draw them. If we were to take the descriptions of battles in the Iliad as corresponding precisely with battles that actually occurred, we should conclude that one warrior in a chariot was more than a match for a score of men on foot; it is, however, only reasonable to remember that the heroes whose deeds the bard recited were usually fighting in chariots, and that the bard, in his desire to emphasise the prowess of the heroes, was com- pelled to make the man in the chariot invincible by any number of the ordinary herd. But still, after making all possible allowance for distortion of facts arising from the exigencies of the poet's art, it remains indubitable that the possession of a chariot and a pair of swift horses gave a man a great advantage in a battle, and that the rich men who fought in chariots were far more efficient in warfare than an equal number of poor men who fought on foot. The governments of the prosperous Achaean tribes were in one respect like those of the poor tribes of the Germans and the Spartans: assem- AchKangov- blies were held for carrying on political emments. business, and in those assemblies king, elders, and people were present. But in the Achaean tribes power belonged exclusively to the rich class of the king and elders ; for this class consisted of the men whose prowess and equipment decided the fate of battles. The king and elders often met as a council 28 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. apart from the people ; in their council they settled what was to be done, and the meeting of the assembly of the whole people scarcely served any purpose, save to give them a convenient opportunity of making known their decisions. There are two pictures of political assemblies in the Iliad and Odyssey ; ^ and from both it is clear that the rulers were the king and elders, and the part of the people was to hearken and obey. The political communities of Anglo-Saxon England were tribes when first they settled in the island ; and ^^ Jo. tribes they continued to be until they Saxon tribes, ^ere united into one large community under ^ing Egbert in the early part of the ninth century. There were, to begin with, about seventeen independent tribes whose names have come down to us, and possibly others of whom no traces have been left. In course of time some of the weaker tribes lost their independence and were incorporated with stronger neighbours, so that by the middle of the seventh century there were only six tribes with governments of their own; and this small number was still further reduced towards the end of the tribal period in England when the South Saxons and the men of Kent were reduced to dependence on the West Saxons. It would be rash to attempt precision in speaking about the economic condition of the English during the tribal period; but we possess some documents which were composed in that period, and from them ' Iliad, ii. and Odyssey, ii. CH. II.] ANGLO-SAXONS 29 we can form some actions on the subject. Our autho- rities are the collections of the early laws of Kent and Wessex, Bede's Ecclesiastical History (finished in the year 731), and the English translation of Bede made by order of King Alfred in the ninth century. From a comparison of these writings we can see that there was a well-marked gradation of classes both in Kent and in Wessex during the tribal period. The middle class were the ceorls or yeomen, freeholders of the estates which they cultivated. The word hide originally meant the amount of land held by a ceorl; in the time of the Norman Conquest it had come to be a measure of land, denoting an area that varied in different parts of England, but was nowhere less than a hundred acres ; and we may fairly believe that in the tribal period a ceorl usually held land in fee simple to an amount of one or two hundred acres. The rich class can be recognised both in Kent and in Wessex ; in the Kentish laws we find two classes of rich men known as eorls and gesith- cundmen, and can see that they were rich because in- juries done to them or by them entailed twice as much payment of damages as in the case of a ceorl ; ^ in the laws of Wessex we find enactments about men who own estates of twenty hides apiece under a condition that they shall get at least twelve hides out of the twenty into order for occupation.^ The very poor classes both in Kent and in Wessex were servile or semi- ^ Aethelberht, 13 ; Wihtraed, 5. The laws of the Anglo-Saxon tribes are printed in Thorpe, Ancient Laws and Institutes of England, and in Sohmid, Oesetze der Angel-Sachsen. 2 Ine, 64. 30 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. servile dependents on the rich men ; thus in both com- munities there were theows and esnes (two words for slaves) ; and in Kent we find the ceorl's hlaf aeta, a ceorl's servant who lived in his house and ate his bread. These facts show that there were gradations in the size of landed estates, but do not prove much about the material well-being of the Anglo-Saxon tribes. There are, however, two facts which throw more light on the economic condition of the people. Ploughing was an ordinary occupation, and therefore the people were agricultural as well as pastoral ; i and the laws in prescribing the amount of compensation for in- juries — the injuries are discriminated from one another with wonderful minuteness and elaboration —always ordain that the compensation shall be paid, not in sheep or oxen, but in a definite and some- times very large amount of coined money. This one fact proves of itself that coined money was in general circulation as the measure of value, and shows that the Germans in England were in a condition of prosperity very far removed from the hardy poverty of their ancestors in the old fatherland of the race. The governments of the Anglo-Saxon tribes may now be recalled to the recollection of the reader. The three elements of the free population Saxon gov- were still present — the king, the rich class ernments. ^£ ^j.^^^ landowners, and the ordinary yeomen or ceorls. But the control of the common policy and the care of the common interests of the tribe belonged exclusively to the king and the rich 1 Ine, 67. CH. II.] LAEGE TRIBES AND SMALL 31 men ; the supreme organ of the government was the king and his council of the Witan, or wise men, a very small gathering of men selected from the rich ; and there were no folkmoots or assemblies of the whole people.! yf}xj it was that in the Anglo-Saxon tribes power belonged exclusively to the king and the rich men, I know not ; probably the rich men, or their fathers before them, had become rich because they were distinguished in warfare as soldiers or as chieftains, and thus the rich class being the most effective in war were also the influential class in counsel. The fact at any rate, that among the Anglo- Saxons the rich men were the rulers, is useful, because it helps to establish a coincidence between the fortunes of two peoples so remote from one another as the Achseans in the age of Homer and our own ancestors soon after their first settlement in Britain. Both peoples were arranged in tribes, both had attained to material well-being far different from the poverty of more primitive tribes, and in both the supreme organ of government in each tribe was a council consisting of the king and a small body of rich men. The division of tribes into poor tribes and rich tribes is the only division that has been noticed thus far ; it is at any rate a convenient division, Large tribes because it leads straight to the handy and small, rule that all the poor tribes in European history have been governed by folkmoots, and all the rich ' The supreme power of the king and his Witan is clearly shown in the preludes to the laws of Wihtraed and of Ine. 32 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. tribes by small councils of rich men. But there is a way of subdividing both the class of poor tribes and the class of rich tribes : in each of these classes some tribes were large and others small ; and we shall have to observe that everywhere the large tribes possessed local governments and the small tribes had none. Let us look first at the poor and primitive tribes. The Spartans were a very small tribe; even when they were at the height of their power, in 480 B.C., just before their King Leonidas and his three hundred had made their heroic defence at Thermopylae, their fighting men numbered only eight thousand.^ In ancient Germany the tribes were incomparably larger; the two tribes of the Usipetes and the Tencteri, when joined together, mustered a force of 180,000 men to invade Gaul ; ^ and the Cherusci, led by Arminius, destroyed a regular Koman army of about 28,000 men at the massacre of the Teuto- burgerwald. The Spartans then, owing to the small size of their territory, had no need of local govern- ments; in a German tribe, on the contrary, local governments were a necessity. Each German tribe was cut up into a number of districts known to the Romans as pagi ; in each pagus was a popular law- court for deciding suits between individuals ; the president of the court was a chieftain elected by the folkmoot of the tribe, but the judges or jurymen were a hundred of the inhabitants of the district.^ ' Herodotus, vii. 234. = Csesar, Bell. Gall. iv. 1-15. ^ Tacitus, Germ., c. 12. CH. II.] LOCAL GOVERNMENTS 33 It may be remarked in passing that the district was under an obligation not only to find a hundred jurymen, but also to send a hundred warriors to the host ; and from these facts it is certain that the pagi of Tacitus are identical with the hundreds which were important for many centuries as local divisions in England. We may now observe the tribes which had made progress in material prosperity. We shall notice that among these rich tribes, no less than among the poor tribes, some were large and some were small ; and that the large tribes had local govern- ments but the small tribes had none. The tribes of the Achseans were certainly not larger than the Spartan community — from any map of Greece it may be gathered that none of them had a territory that in any direction measured tjyenty miles across — and accordingly there was no such thing as a local government in an Achaean tribe : the central govern- ment of the king and elders was at hand for every- body. In Anglo-Saxon England the Mercian tribe in the eighth century inhabited all the land that lies between the mouth of the Humber, the Thames, and the Bristol Avon. In the Anglo-Saxon tribes there were local governments everywhere; and in some of those tribes they were more highly organised than they had been in Germany. In all tribes there were popular law-courts extremely like the courts of the fagi; — so I am compelled to believe, because, though no such courts are mentioned in the tribal period of English history, hundreds and hundred 34 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. moots for the administration of local justice are mentioned in a decree of King Edgar in the ninth century as a familiar and well-known institution. The large tribe of the West Saxons was cut up so early as the reign of Ine (688-728), not only into the very small districts known as hundreds, but also into shires, which have continued to be the most impor- tant of all local divisions of England until the present day. We do not know much about the government of the shires in the tribal period ; but we know that in each there was a scirman or sheriff as judge, and an ealdorman as commander of the armed forces.^ In Mercia also there were large local divisions, as for example the Middel Engel of Leicestershire and the Hecanians of Herefordshire. In the country north of the Humber, however, there are no traces of shires during the tribal period, and it is probable that in Northumbria the shires did not exist as administra- tive units till about the time of King Edgar in the ninth century, when all England was for the second time united under a single ruler. Enough has now been said to show that large tribes and small tribes are unlike in their governments, no less than rich tribes and poor tribes. And here I might leave the subject of tribes in thejr unaltered forms ; but I prefer before passing on to notice some other institutions of the Germans and the Greeks which are not, so far as I know,- associated with any of their economic conditions or the area of their territory, and may have arisen in each people from ' Ine, 3f), 8 ; Anglo-Saxon Chronicle, a.d. 837, 845, 851, CH. II.] GEEEK KINGS : GEKMAN KINGS 35 earlier social customs, or been adopted for reasons at wliich I cannot guess. In most tribes there are some duties which cannot be performed by an assembly or council, but must be allotted to some one man. These duties are — (1) presidency in the assembly or council, (2) command in war, (3) performance of religious rites, (4) presi- dency in the law-courts. The Germans allotted these duties to different functionaries : among the Greeks the only public officer was the king. Among the Germans the king was only president in the assembly and council, and the other public duties were given to separate officials : the generals were elected in the folkmoot, there was a separate order of priests, the presidents in the law-courts were chieftains specially elected for the purpose. Among the Greeks there was no division of labour in the performa;nce of public duties : the king was president in the assembly and the council, commander-in-chief of the army, sole high priest of the tribe, and, if there was any presi- dent in a law-court, he was none other than the king.^ In Anglo-Saxon England, as well as in ancient Germany, public duties were allotted to many separate officers: the king, it is true, united the command in war with the presidency in the Witan, but there was still a separate order of priests, pagan at first and Christian at a later date ; and the ' In our only description of a Greek tribal law-court {Iliad, xviii. 497-508) no president is mentioned. The accumulation of many functions in the person of a Greek heroic king is well discussed by Mr. Warde Fowler, The City State, pp. 68-74 . 36 EUROPEAN TRIBES [ch. ii. presidency in the law-courts belonged in the shires to the sheriffs, and in the hundreds to some humbler officers. Yet one more German institution must be men- tioned. It was a privilege enjoyed in the old German tribes by the king and by all the lesser chieftains to surround themselves with a body of sworn comrades, who fought under their command in war. The institution of the sworn comradeship, or coTnitatus, was most important in its subsequent results. When the Germans in the fifth and sixth centuries con- quered western Europe, the king's comrades in every tribe had large allotments of land granted to them in the conquered territories; and in every country of the west they were the founders or forerunners of the feudal families of nobles in the middle ages. I may now conclude this chapter by appending to it a table embodying all the results which seem likely to help towards a classification of political communities. CH. II.] EUEOPEAN TRIBES 37 TABLE. TRIBES AND THEIR GOVERNMENTS. KINDS OF TRIBES. 1. Poor tribes. (a) Small and poor. Ex. Sparta before 700 B.C. (b) Large and poor. Ex. Grermans. 2. Rich tribes. (a) Small and rich. Ex. Achseans in Ho- mer's time. (b) Large and rich. Ex. Anglo-Saxons. GOVERNMENTS. A folknioot (with subordinate council of great men) for central government. A folkmoot (with subordinate council of great men) only. A folkmoot (with subordinate council of great men) for central government: popular law-courts for local govern- ment. King and a small council , of nobles for central government. King and a small- council of nobles only. King and a small council of nobles for central government : popular law - courts for local government. CHAPTER III UNIONS OF TRIBES Tribes were the protoplasm for the making of all bodies politic, but the only political societies deriYed from them quite directly and visibly were (1) unions of tribes, and (2) city states. If several tribes joined together they formed a union of tribes which was often rapidly converted into a single tribe : if they remained separate but adopted urban pursuits they turned into city states. Of unions of tribes they were the component parts : of city states they were the germs. The processes by which tribes joined together are often unknown : their results are visible. (1) Some- times tribes coalesced completely, and then the resulting community was simply an enlarged tribe. (2) Sometimes (but very rarely) a tribe, having another tribe at its mercy, retained the tribesmen in personal slavery; in that case the political com- munity consisted only of the masters, and they were a tribe of slave-owners. (3) Lastly, in many cases, tribes have voluntarily joined together and set up a common government for defence of their common interests, each keeping, however, a separate govern- ment for managing its internal affairs : in that case the resulting community was a tribal federation. CH. III.] COALESCENCE OF TRIBES 39 The coalescence of tribes, more or less com- plete, is of extremely frequent occurrence : in fact kindred tribes living near together are always likely to coalesce, unless they are Coalescence separated by strong physical barriers. In °^*^'''^=- the ancient world the Macedonians led by King Philip were only a union of tribes, made originally by conquest, but afterwards amalgamated. In Ger- many, during three centuries after the time of Tacitus, coalescence of tribes completely changed the distribution of the population. Ptolemy, writing half a century after Tacitus, enumerated more than fifty German tribes ; two centuries and a half later still, about the year 400, nearly all had gathered themselves into about seven great hordes, among which the Salian Franks, the Burgundians, and the Visigoths were then the most conspicuous. Each of these great hordes was only a magnified copy of a tribe, living under a single government. The same thing happened repeatedly in Anglo-Saxon England, as for example when the tribes of the East Saxons and the Middle Saxons were joined into the enlarged kingdom of Essex with the Mid- Saxon town of London as its capital,^ and when Wessex, Sussex, and Kent were united to form the enlarged kingdom of Wessex. When large tribes had been formed by amalgama- tion, their governments were determined by their economic condition and the pursuits of the tribes- men. The large tribes in England prospered by ^ Baeda, ii. e. 3. 40 UNIONS OF TRIBES [pn. in. agriculture : the Macedonians and the German hordes were predatory, militant, and aggressive : they could not be otherwise in presence of the tribes ruled temptations offered by decadent Greek by a. king cities or the declining Eoman Empire. only. The English tribes continued to be ruled by a king and a small council of wise men: the Macedonians and the German hordes needed a man to lead them to victory, and each had only a single ruler who combined the. dignity of king with the power of commander-in-chief Philip, Alexander, Alaric, Clovis, Theodoric, and Alboin are reckoned among their rulers. AH these, and their like in other aggressive hordes, were habitually absolute sovereigns: but they had to remember that their warriors might rise in mutiny or assemble in a folkmoot. Alexander did not dare to put his general Philotas to death till he had been condemned by the assembled officers and soldiers, and Clovis could not punish the destroyer of the vase at Soissons except by a singularly treacherous and cowardly murder.^ The most conspicuous example of a slave-owning tribe is furnished by the Spartans after the reign of Theopompus. Before his time they were. Slave-owning- as we have noticed already, a poor tribe, tribes. The Q^uch ii]je any other poor tribe. They op3rL3,ns> ^ had indeed conquered some neighbouring peoples, whom they called Perioeki, and prevented * Grote, History of Greece, ch. xoiv. Gregory of Tours, ii. c. 18 ( = 0. 27 in a different numbering). CH. III.] SLAVE-OWNING TRIBES 41 from amalgamating witli themselves by refusing them political privileges ; but there is no reason to suppose that in acting thus they took an unusual course. In the reign of Theopompus, on conquering their neighbours the Messenians, they reduced them to personal slavery, and by becoming their task- masters changed the whole character of the Spartan commonwealth. The Spartans, the Periceki, and the Helots, and their relations to one another, are fully described in so many books on Greek history and antiquities that I hope to be pardoned if I omit many details from my account of them. The Spartans were the ruling caste, living in and about the five villages which collectively bore the name of Sparta, devoting them- selves solely to perfecting their military skill and prowess, and disdaining the practice of all the use- ful arts so completely that they were cut off even from the pursuit of agriculture, which other warlike peoples have deemed respectable. It was enjoined on them by the customs and ideals of their race that they must not only be brave and hardy, but also abstemious and poor : they fed at a common mess- table on the coarsest diet, their coinage consisted of cumbrous blocks of iron, and the possession of gold or silver was a criminal offence.^ The hard rule of custom cut them off from the enjoyment of many things which men most naturally and instinctively desire : at all times of their history there were occasions when human nature was too strong for ' Xenophon, De Rep, Lac. , o. 7. 42 UNIONS OF TEIBES [ch. hi. rule, and a Spartan accepted a bribe from some wealthy foreigner ; but the rule which prohibited the acquisition of private wealth was on the whole well obeyed till near the end of the Peloponnesian War, about 405 B.C., and till that time the Spartan tribes- men were poor though the treasury of the Spartan state might be rich. The Pericfiki were a population subject to the Spartans, personally free but absolutely excluded from all political rights or priYileges. They were, as their name denotes. Dwellers Around the Spartans: they lived in small towns or villages mainly in the outlying parts of Laconia, and in each of their little communities they were allowed to manage their local affairs for themselves.^ They formed the class of tradesmen, artificers, and farmers, following the pursuits which the Spartans despised. The Helots were the slaves, and their enslavement was the most potent of all factors in determining the later course of Spartan history; for, as Thucydides remarks, 'most of thQ Spartan institutions were framed by way of precaution against the Helots.' ^ The past history of the Helots might well breed apprehension in the minds of their masters. When the Dorians conquered the Pelopon- nesus, the two Dorian peoples who retained in their new abodes that tribal condition in which they had ' If they had not had the management of their local affairs Herodotus would not have called their communities by the Greek word which means cities. Herodotus, vii. 2.34. ^ Thucydides, iv. 80. CH. III.] SPARTANS 43 lived before they left their mountain valley of Doris, were, as we noticed in the last chapter, the powerful communities of the Spartans and the Messenians. These two peoples lived on in their new Peloponnesian homes for many generations as neighbours, rivals, and equals. In the' reign of Theopompus, which marks the great turning-point in Spartan history, the Spartans, about 700 B.C., entered on a new policy towards the Messenians. They waged one great war against them in the time of Theopompus, and another about fifty years later; in the end they completely conquered the country and reduced the whole of its brave and independent inhabitants to the condition of slaves, whom they compelled to till for the benefit of the Spartan state those broad and fertile plains which had once been their own property and their pride. From this time forth the little garrison of slave-owners, which held Laconia by the terror of the spear, the sword, and the dagger, was in per- petual peril of a great servile revolt: once they actually learned what a rebellion of slaves was like. In 464 B.C. the Helots made an organised rebellion, fortified themselves on Mount Ithome, and held their stronghold for nine years in spite of all the efforts of the Spartans to drive them out. The rebellion of the Helots was in some respects analogous to the secession of the Roman plebeians to the Mons Sacer ; but it could not have a similar ending. Between the patricians in Rome and the plebeians on the Mons Sacer compromise was possible; between the Spartan slave-owners and their revolted Messenian 44 UNIONS OF TRIBES [cH. in. slaves nothing of the kind could be dreamed of. In the end those of the Helots .who were actually in occupation of Mount Ithomg, being hard pressed in nine years of war, consented to depart from Pelopon- nesus as free men : they went away with their wives and children, and were provided by the Athenians with a place of settlement at Naupactus, on the north side of the straits at the mouth of the Cor- inthian gulf, where they established themselves as an independent community bitterly hostile to their old masters. These Helots, however, who thus departed from Peloponnesus, were only a small part of the whole enslaved Messenian people ; the rest remained in their old condition of servitude and nursed their old feelings of indignation and hatred, so that the Spartans were never free from the apprehension that they might rise in renewed rebellion. The Spartans in their dealings with the Messenians adopted a policy for which I cannot iind any precise Spartan parallel in European history: they deliber- character. ately and undisguisedly compelled a people who were their own kinsmen and their equals to toil in their fields as bondmen. The character of the Spartans, though not, like their policy towards the Messenians, unique, had yet such unusual features that its peculiarities may usefully be set down in a connected form. We have already chanced to notice three of their distinctive habits of mind. They despised wealth, commerce, and all the useful arts. They were devoted to slave-owning. They spent their best energies in acquiring military CH. III.] SPARTAN GOVERNMENT 45 excellence. To these three we have to add one more to complete the picture. They regulated all their actions by rigid adherence to old traditional rules. The political institutions of the Spartans in the later part of their history are easy to understand: they were fashioned by the introduction spartan of two simple but far-reaching changes in government, the machinery of the old tribal constitution which was attributed to Lycurgus. These two changes were both rnade in the reign of Theopompus, they were both undoubtedly connected with the new policy then adopted towards the Messenians, and taken together with that policy they gave as time went on a new aspect to the Spartan state. The changes were these : firstly, the attempt of the Spartan commoners to legislate on their own initiative in the folkmoot 1 was defeated by a new constitutional enactment which ordained that ' if the people chose crookedly, the kings and elders should have the final decision'; and secondly, to compensate the commoners for their defeat, it was arranged that in every year they should elect five Ephors or Overseers as a board of magistrates to supervise the doings of the kings and the elders. We do not know how these changes affected the practical working of the Spartan constitution in the first two hundred years after their intro- duction, because nothing of Spartan his- tory during that time has been preserved except some detached stories. These stories, however, relate 1 See p. 24. 4^ UNIONS OF TRIBES [CH. iii. to the doings of Spartan kings, and they seem to indicate that from 700 B.C. to 500 B.c. the kingly- power was strong in Sparta. In the reign, however, of Cleomenes i. (519-491 B.C.), who committed many follies and at last slew himself in a fit of madness, the kingly power visibly declined. In a few years after his death the board of Ephors had risen to be the supreme authority in the Spartan state. In the central period then of Greek history, from 480 B.C. onward, the chief governing organ in the Spartan community was the board of Ephors, endowed with all the powers that we generally call executive. They were aided by the deliberative council of thirty, and some small share in controlling the affairs of the state was assigned to the Spartan folkmoot and to the two kings. The part taken by the folkmoot and the kings was so small that it counted for nothing unless a question of war or peace arose : when war was suggested the folkmoot settled whether war should be declared, and when war was being waged the post of commander was assigned to one of the kings. The folkmoot might, if it had chosen, have gained influence, because it elected the Ephors; but the method of electing them was childish, and it seems that the elections roused little interest in the minds of the Spartan commoners.^ A parallel, but not a perfect parallel, to the slave- owning tribe of the Spartans was recently seen in the South African Republic. The Boers, at the time of the ' Aristotle, Politics, ii. 9, 19-24. CH. III.] SOUTH AFRICAN REPUBLIC 47 Great Trek in 1835, were a tribe : after their settlement in the Transvaal they had black slaves corresponding more or less to the Helots, and in the Uit- _ The South landers they afterwards acquired a subject- African population in the same position as the ^^P"'"'^'^- Periceki. The black slaves were not precisely analo- gous to the Helots, because they came of a race which had never been on terms of equality with their masters, and were not likely to attempt a rebellion: but in other respects the Boer Kepublic and Spartan Commonwealth were alike in all the dominant facts of their position. In character also the Boers closely resembled the Spartans. They so despised wealth and most forms of productive industry, that when gold character was discovered in their territory they did °^ ^^^ Boers, not dig for it themselves but left the work of mining to foreigners. They were so devoted to slave-owning that they expatriated themselves from their old homes in Cape Colony as soon as slavery was forbidden by Act of Parliament in the British possessions. They cultivated military excellence to a pitch which has cost us dear. And lastly, they regulated their actions . in conformity with ancient rules, taking as their authority the precepts laid down for the guidance of the Hebrews in the books of the Old Testament. As the Boers resembled the Spartans in circum- stances and character, it is not surprising that they also resembled them in government. The chief authority in the South African Republic was an 48 UNIONS OF TEIBES [ch. hi. executive board of seven members, elected by all the fully qualified burghers, and corresponding to the Government Ephors. The Other organ of government of the Boers, ^^^g ^ deliberative chamber known as the First Volksraad. I cannot say that it was pre- cisely like the Spartan council of thirty, because its members were chosen under a representative system copied no doubt by the Boers from Cape Colony : but its members were only twenty-four in number, they generally did as they were bidden by the executive board of seven, and thus this First Volksraad resembled the Spartan council of thirty in being a small deliberative council subordinate in importance to the executive government. The executive board of seven and the First Volksraad were the only effective organs in the government of the republic: there was a Second Volksraad, but it was entirely devoid of influence. The Uitlanders were allowed to take part in electing its members, and it was therefore necessary for the ruling caste of the Boers to see that it was reduced to impotence. This was very easily ensured, because no proposition of the Second Volksraad was of any validity unless it was confirmed by the First Volksraad which was wholly elected by the Boers.^ Tribes have formed Federations both in many well-known instances and in others less conspicuous. The best example of all is furnished by the Iroquois, whose six nations once inhabited what is now the State of New York. They were joined into a 1 Statesman's Year Book, 1897, p. 939. CH. III.] TRIBAL FEDEEATIONS 49 Federation in the fifteenth century through the efforts of Hiawatha and another hero who is forgotten save by few because he lacked the sacred bard ,,> to immortalise his name. For a descrip- Tribal tion of their federal state I must refer my readers to the works of Mr. Lewis Morgan, who has given full details in his book on the Iroquois, and a very clear and instructive summary in his Ancient Society. In ancient Europe tribal federations were formed by many peoples in northern Greece — by the Phokians, the Akarnanians, and the .^tolians, besides others too obscure to be noticed here. The individual tribes that made up the jEtolian people were no more than unwalled villages in the time of Thucydides, and we have evidence to show that the Akarnanian tribes were equally minute.^ These miniature commonwealths could not defend them- selves against such aggressive powers as Athens and Sparta if they remained separate, and this was no doubt the reason why they joined in federations and set up federal governments. We know very little about their arrangements : but it is well established that in each federation the federal government con- sisted of a council, which must have been composed of men chosen by the villages and other tribes which had united for defence.- In Peloponnesus, too, an ancient tribal federation was established. When the Dorians left their home near Thermopylae and over- ' Warde Fowler, 7%e City State, p. 35, from Thucydides, iii. 94, 97, and Diodorus, xix. 67. 2 Freeman, History of Federal Oovernment in Greece and Italy, oh. iv., ch. vi. D 50 UNIONS OF TRIBES [ch. hi. ran the peninsula they overpowered the Achsean tribes who are well known to us from the Homeric poems and drove them from their old settlements around Mycenae, Argos, Sparta, and their other towns, to the rocky valleys near the Corinthian Gulf. The refugees in their new abode formed a federation.^ We have now noticed all the conspicuous forms of tribes and tribal communities, and have easily referred to their proper forms all the munities of Specimens about which we have anything doubtful li^e full information. There are, however, species. . . some groups of men m a tribal condition about whom we know very little, and accordingly their place among tribal communities is disputable. One such tribal group is found in ancient Boeotia and another in Germany. When Hesiod and his brother Perses lived at Ascra on Mount Helicon, the judicial authority for settling their disputes was a council or bench of kings. Hesiod tells us the kings were hungry for bribes, but nothing more. Was the community that they judged a single tribe or a federation ? If il was a single tribe, the word kings (/3ao-iX?5e?) is used by Hesiod to denote the men who are elsewhere called elders (yepovTe<;) : if it was a federation, the kings were really kings in the component tribes. Again, in ancient Germany we know for certain that our own forefathers the Saxons were not a single tribe : but there is a time in their history when we do not know whether they were a federation under ' Polybius, ii. 41, CH. III.] SAXON FEDERATION 51 a common government, or a league merely united in permanent alliance. It is certain that in the fourth century of our era, and afterwards, they were not merely a single tribe. In the year 358 a.d. they sent one of their component tribes (fioipav a-(f>a)v) to attack the Romans in Gaul, where Julian, as Csesar not yet Augustus, was commanding. The tribe that was sent had a name of its own (which is given in Zosimus, our authority, but is perhaps written wrongly in the manuscripts), and a king, whose son during the expedition was taken prisoner by a Frank named Charietto in the service of Julian.^ But were the Saxon tribes already joined in a federation, or was it then merely a permanent alliance ? I do not think it is possible to know for certain. About the year 700 A.D., when they were visited by two missionaries from England named Hewald the White and Hewald the Black, they had a federal government to manage their external affairs. The kings of the component tribes had disappeared, and their place had been taken by other rulers whom Bseda denotes as satrapoi. These rulers, who might perhaps in their own language be called ealdormen, may possibly have been in time of peace mere local administrators : when war was at hand they were a central government, and chose by lot one from their number to be commander-in- chief.^ The most conspicuous characteristic of tribes and tribal communities is, that they are to a less extent products of conscious contrivance than the elabo- 1 Zosimus, iii. 6, 7. ^ B^cla, v. 10. 52 TRIBES [CH. III. rate states of civilised men, and to a greater extent products of the instinctive, unconscious part of Tribes human nature : and, in proportion as they General are more instinctively made, they are more conclusions, j^^^^^j.^^ ^^^ Ig^s artificial. It must be admitted at once that even the tribes are not purely natural products. The only constructed things which can be called purely natural are those made by animals not endowed with human reason — as the cells of the bees, the nests of the birds, and the colonies of the beavers. All these things are made by instinct solely, and so the cell of a given species of bee and the nest of a given kind of bird have forms from which they do not vary perceptibly. But in all constructions made by man, even in the simplest, there is some element of design, and the constructions are not purely natural products. But those things which are made most instinctively and with least conscious design are most like natural products, and are most capable of being distinguished into different kinds or forms which are subject to little variation. So it is with tribes. They are made more instinctively than any other communities, and are more like natural products : and we can divide them under a few well-marked forms, each having a kind of government suitable and peculiar to itself^ (1) Tribes in their original form were poor, and approximate equality prevailed among the tribesmen. ' The co-operation of unconscious instinct and conscious con- trivance in the making of states is pointed out by Sir John Seeley, Introduction to Political Science, p. 20. ■CH. III.] GENERAL CONCLUSIONS 53 While they kept this original form, their governments were conducted in assemblies attended by king, elders, and people, wherein every class Tribal had a share of influence. Governments governments, then of this kind are the original source of all tribal governments. (2) When distinctions of wealth came in, they brought with them distinctions in efficiency for warfare and counsel; the popular element was extruded from political influence, and governments were conducted solely by a council of king and elders. (3) When tribes became large, militant, and aggressive, a single commander-in-chief was needed ; the elders in their turn lost their share in the government, and the sole ruler was a king. (4) When several tribes joined in a federation, they set up a council to manage their common affairs, keeping separate governments for the affairs of the component tribes. The federal, council must at first have contained the kings of the component tribes, as well as some of their elders ; but in course of time kings were not needed in the component tribes, and the federal council consisted simply of important tribesmen nominated by the component tribes. The only forms of tribal communities which recur fre- quently are those contained in this enumeration: slave-owning tribes might be added, but only two such tribes are known, and it would be rash to make any general statement in regard to them. The results of the enumeration so far as they affect the common forms of tribes and tribal communities can be briefly expressed in a table. 54 TEIBES [CH. HI. TEIBES AND TRIBAL COMMUNITIES. THE COMMONEST FORMS AND THEIR GOVERNMENTS. FORMS. GOVERNMENTS. Form 1. Poor Tribes. King, elders, and people in assembly. Form 2. Rich Tribes. King and elders only. Form 3. Aggressive Tribes. King only. Form 4. Tribal Federations. Federal council. CHAPTER IV CITY STATES The class of communities which has next to be considered consists of the city states, because com- munities of this kind followed next after the tribal age in the lands around the Mediterranean Sea, and so it came about that city states are the earliest civilised powers known to European history. There were, however, in addition to the ancient city states, other communities of the same kind in the Middle Ages. One group of such communities arose in Italy and another in Germany. In order to settle what meaning we attach to the term city state, we must let the mind's eye rest for a moment on individual communities in .... Definition, various portions or history to which that term is applied. We have to pass in hasty review the cities of the ancient world: Greek cities as Corinth, Athens, Syracuse; Italian cities as Capua and Rome; the Phoenician cities of Tyre and Carthage; and in the Middle Ages Italian cities as Florence, Bologna, Milan, Genoa, together with German cities as Liibeck, Niirnberg, and Strassburg. After very little consideration of individual city states we find that the characteristics common to 56 CITY STATES [CH. iv. all of them are these : each city state was an inde- pendent community, having a territory and govern- ment of its own, in which a single walled city was of supreme importance and controlled the whole. Moreover, these characteristics are not only common to all city states, but also are not found in any community which is not a city state. We shall therefore sufficiently define a city state if we say that it is an independent community, having a territory and government of its own, in which a single walled city is of supreme importance and controls the whole. We may now go on to examine what are the conditions and causes necessary to the rise and establishment of city states. From the Conditions. -, „ . . . . detimtion oi a city state we see that two conditions are necessary to its existence : firstly, there must be a walled city or town; secondly, the com- munity must be independent, and a single city must control the whole. If we now observe what causes lead to the realisation of these two conditions, we shall discover what are the causes which generate city states. The first condition necessary to the establishment of a city state is the existence of a walled city or town. The causes which lead to the erection of walled towns are everywhere the same, whether the towns are built in local districts within great nations or in small independent communities. The causes are the accumulation of wealth and the need to secure it against violent robbery. If these two causes CH. IV.] ORIGIN OF CITIES 57 are present, as they were in ancient Greece, and in England, France, Germany, Spain, Italy about the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, walled towns are certain to be erected. If, on the other hand, either cause is absent, town walls are not wanted. The Germans whom Tacitus described, and the Dorians at Sparta, had no wealth and they had no walls: we at the present time have wealth in the utmost abundance, but we do not need walls to pro- tect it, because it has the far better protection which is afforded by an organised force of police and system of law-courts. The second requisite for the establishment of a city state is, that the city shall be independent and supreme in a territory of its own. This second con- dition is generally realised in conjunction with the first if a walled town is erected in a small community, but not if it is built in a large one. The walled towns of ancient Greece, and of mediaeval Italy and Ger- many, were built in small communities, and those communities grew into city states ; the walled towns of England, France, and Spain arose in large com- munities, they were therefore ruled by the govern- ments of those communities, and they never rose to be independent city states but always continued to be dependent municipalities. The reasons why the communities of Greece, Italy, and Germany were small, and those of England, France, and Spain were large, will be seen hereafter as each case comes before us, and therefore they need not at the present moment be considered. 58 CITY STATES [ch. iv. The city states were the most compact of all communities: they had excellent defences, and the Simple city inhabitants of each city state were de- states, termined not to be ruled by foreigners. In consequence of these characteristics of city states they were harder to conquer than any other communities of the same size that have ever existed, and the conquest of a city state by a city state was an event of rare occurrence. There must have been several hundreds of city states in all ; and I think it is true of at least five-sixths of the number that they never conquered a city state, and never were conquered by a city state. These city states which went on living side by side with one another, and retaining their old territory without sensible enlargement or diminution, may be called the small and simple city states, because they were of small size, and because each of them had only a single city as the sole centre of population, society, wealth and government. But though the conquest of a city by a city was difficult, it was not always impossible. It is true Complex city that a city state in its mature condi- states. ^Jqj^ jg gQ compact that it cannot be conquered, and can more easily be destroyed than subjugated; but a city in its infancy, and before it has attained maturity, is not so tightly knit together. The vast majority of cities escaped subjugation in their infancy either because their natural defences made them unassailable or because their neighbours were weak. Three groups of cities during their CH. IV.] SIMPLE AND COMPLEX 59 infancy enjoyed neither of these advantages; they were situated in Attica, in the plain of Latium, and in the corner of northern Africa now known as Tunisia. In each of these regions the immature cities had no ranges of mountains to surround their territories, and in their neighbourhood were the strong and aggressive cities of Athens, Rome, and Carthage. Athens and Rome succeeded in conquering many cities in their own vicinity, and in converting them into obedient and contented dependent towns. Carthage also overpowered neighbouring cities and incorporated them in its own body politic, though it was perhaps unable to obtain their cheerful acquies- cence in its supremacy. Each of the three cities, Athens, Rome, and Carthage, when its conquests of neighbouring cities were completed, appeared as the head of a community in which there was one domi- nant city and many dependent towns. Genoa, too, in the Middle Ages, was ruler of many dependent neighbouring towns, and it acquired its authority over them nearly in the same way as the conquering cities of ancient history. In all the four instances the result was the same : Athens, Rome, Carthage, Genoa succeeded in founding city states very different in character from the small and simple city states. The communities established by the conquering city states bore the same relation to the simple city states that a star with a nebula round it bears to a single star. In each of them there was a central dominant nucleus, and around it there were many lesser nuclei 60 CITY STATES [CH. iv. bound to it by the compelling force of its attraction. These communities founded by the successful con- quering cities may be called complex city states, because each of them contained not only a central ruling city but also many towns which obeyed its commands and were bound to it by ties of allegiance. The perfectly simple and the markedly complex varieties of city states form two contrasted species. Other Intermediate between these two extreme varieties, forms there are other sorts of city states, which I shall not here attempt to enu- merate exhaustively, because they are somewhat miscellaneous. The most remarkable among them were city states such as were founded by Syracuse and by Milan. These two cities succeeded in over- powering other cities in their neighbourhood, but did not attempt to convert them into dependent towns, because they feared that they could never win from them a cheerful and serviceable submission. They knew that the inhabitants of the towns they had vanquished were, like the inhabitants of all other city states, strongly attached to the indepen- dence of their communities and inspired with an ardent local patriotism. They feared therefore that if the communities were allowed to continue their existence, and live on in their old homes, they would rebel, and might some day regain their old indepen- dence. To guard against the danger of rebellion they destroyed the communities by dispersing the in- habitants; and they sometimes took the further precaution of razing their habitations to the ground. CH. IV.] VARIOUS FORMS 61 Another variety intermediate between the simple and the complex city states arose in mediseval Italy. Many of the cities in northern Italy had as their neighbours many independent villages, and many independent landowners who ruled their estates as petty princes. The villages and the landowners often felt that their condition of independence was un- profitable or insecure, and requested the neighbouring city to admit them among its subjects ; upon their admission they swore allegiance and promised obedience to the city, and in return they obtained protection and secured the opportunities for trading advantageously which belong to the citizens of an urban community. The cities which admitted them did not become complex city states, but they ob- tained an accession of territory and an increase in the numbers of their rural population. There were also other varieties of city states which were not perfectly simple nor markedly complex ; but it is not necessary at the present moment to make further reference to them. The following chapters, from the fifth to the ninth, will be occupied in an examination of the city states which occur in ancient history : the mediseval cities must be deferred to their proper place in chronological sequence. CHAPTER V SIMPLE CITY STATES IN ANCIENT HISTORY Greece, Italy, and Phoenicia, in the age which shortly preceded the beginning of European history properly so called, fulfilled, in perfection all the conditions necessary to the establishment of city states. Their physical structure ensured that the communities inhabiting them were small; their in- habitants had made accumulations of wealth; and the prevalence of disorder and violence made life and property insecure unless both were sheltered behind the bulwarks of fortified towns. All the three countries, which have been just mentioned as natural homes of city states, were lands Physical of rocks and mountains. Their lower surroundings, rocky eminences formed admirably de- fensible and convenient sites for habitation by small communities; and their continuous mountain chains opposed insuperable obstacles in a barbaric age to the formation of large communities. In such an age it is only in lands where communication is very easy — such as Germany, France, or England — that large societies of men can be established. In Greece, Italy, and Phoenicia communication by land 62 CH. v.] FOUNDING OF CITIES 63 was very difficult, and those countries both in the prehistoric ages and for centuries after the time (about 650 B.C.) at which chronological history begins, were inhabited by small communities only. The material prosperity of the peoples around the Mediterranean shores in early times is well known from the testimony of Homer ; what were T • 11 Wealth. the conditions which enabled them to become rich is not so well ascertained. They had a climate and a soil which could be relied upon to reward the labours of the herdsman and the tiller of the ground ; and nothing perhaps is more conducive in the long run to the material well-being of an undeveloped people than such a soil and such a climate. The commerce which in the later ages of Greek and Jloman history enriched the Mediterranean peoples, did not begin during their infancy. The commodities which were exchanged in the later period were bulky goods, such as corn, wine, and oil ; the merchants of Homer's age had only a petty trade in portable commodities. The Phoenicians were the traders and the carriers of trade ; they sailed far and wide over the Mediterranean, collecting copper and tin probably from Spain, gold from Thasos, ivory probably from Africa, fine products of the loom from their own home under Mount Lebanon, or from the interior of Asia. These portable products they dispersed abroad among the Greeks, sailing perhaps sometimes to the mainland of Hellas, often to the islands of the ^gean Sea. Whether a trade such as theirs, limited to merely portable goods, had much 64 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. effect in promoting accumulations of wealth among the Greeks, it is hard to say. The economic con- ditions under which the Italians acquired wealth in very early, times are entirely unknown ; but it is proved by the census of Servius TuUius that pro- sperity was widely diffused among the Romans at the very moment when they come for the first time within the view of history; and what was true of the Romans, was undoubtedly true also of their neighbours and kinsmen of the Latin race. The insecurity of life and property was one of the troubles to which the growing peoples of Greece and Italy were universally exposed. Piracy, Insecurity. . '' . . ^ i j ' kidnapping, brigandage, were honourable pursuits in the time of Homer, and they were generally practised till the time of Thucydides, except in regions where they had been forcibly repressed.^ Amid the dangers of an age of violence, there was no safety for life or property unless they were protected by town walls; towns were built, and so the city states of Greece and Italy were begun. The Achaean communities in the age of Homer Avere the first European builders of towns: they Cities in established their little strongholds at Greece. Mycense, Tiryns, Pylos, and elsewhere, but had not time to found city states before they Avere expelled by the Dorians. The first city states were the Dorian communities at Mycenae, Argos, Corinth, Epidaurus, Sicyon, Megara, and the Ionian communities in Attica. These Ionian ' Odyuey, iii. 71-74; Thucydides, i. 5. CH. v.] FOUNDING OF CITIES 65 communities, however, do not belong to the subject of the present chapter, because they were soon united into a complex city state. After these earliest towns had been established in Greece proper, others were founded by Dorians, lonians, and iEolians in the islands of the ^gean Sea, and on the coasts of Asia Minor. The towns thus founded on the two sides of the ^gean Sea advanced rapidly in prosperity, and by the eighth century B.C. many of them had a larger population than their territories could accommodate and support. When this difficulty arose, the Greek towns did not usually seek to acquire adjacent territory to meet the needs of their enlarged popula- tion ; territorial expansion would have been extremely difficult in countries so mountainous as those in which they lived, and, even if it had been easy, it may be doubted whether a Greek town would have wished to hold large rural territory and thus tempt many of its inhabitants to abandon their urban character. As a matter of fact, the Greek towns got rid of their surplus population, as the bees do, by sending out swarms. They gathered together all those who were willing to emigrate, appointed them a leader to act as their queen bee, and then left it to him to consult the Delphic Oracle about the best place to go to, and, when the site was chosen, there to found a new and independent Greek town. Most of the bodies of emigrants thus sent out were successful in their enterprises ; and, within two centuries after the process of emigration began, independent Greek towns had been founded in great numbers in E 66 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. Sicily, Southern Italy, along the Mediterranean coasts of Spain and Gaiil, in Africa, and on the Black Sea. The building of cities by the Italian race is com- pletely hidden in obscurity, and we cannot say that one of them was established earlier and ' another later. The cities of the Italians included the thirty Latin cities together with Eome, and a number of other cities, from Umbria in the north to Samnium and Apulia in the south. The subject of the present chapter comprises the simple cities in ancient history. We shall best settle Which cities ^^^ limits of the subject by noting which were simple, of the ancient cities are excluded from it. We must set aside as alien to the subject firstly, all the Boeotian and the Latin cities, because they placed themselves under Federal governments ; secondly, the towns in Attica, the Phoenician towns in North Africa, and all the cities of Italian origin, because they were joined together into complex city states ; and thirdly,, those cities which have been noted in the last chapter as being intermediate in character between simple and complex cities: they include Syracuse, Gyrene in North Africa, Croton in Italy, and the cities of Argolis. When these have been excluded, all the ancient cities that remain are simple and inexpansive cities : if any of them had been an expansive or conquering city, there is no doubt that its exploits would have attracted the attention of contemporary writers, and some record would have been handed down to posterity. CH. v.] GOVERNMENTS 67 And now I may speak of the governments of the simple city states. In Greece proper the earliest urban governments grew out of the old tribal governments, which were conducted by a g^era- council composed of the king and nobles ments: .,■,,■, . . ^. Oligarchies. With the acquiescence of the common people. In Corinth the process of growth is recorded. The members of the tribal royal family, two hundred in number, all descended from King Bacchis, deposed their kinsman King Aristomenes, and took the control of the state into their own possession, electing one of their number every year to act as president and discharge the functions of king. They were known as the Bacchiadse, and in order to keep them- selves a distinct caste they forbade all members of their families to marry any one but a descendant of Bacchis.1 In the neighbouring city of Megara, in like manner, power belonged in the middle of the seventh century exclusively to certain rich families : ^ and in the other simple cities of Greece proper similar governments must have arisen, since the old tribal governments had disappeared from them at the beginning of Greek history and nothing but govern- ments of nobles could have taken their place. The newer settlements in Sicily and Italy were also ruled in the earliest period of Greek history by bodies of rich men.^ As the settlers in these more recent cities had lived under the rule of the rich ' Herodotus, v. 92 ; Diodorus Sioulus, vii. fragment 9. ^ Aristotle, Politics (Bekker, 1837), v. 5, 9. 3 Aristotle, Politics, v. 13 (Bekker, 1837); Polybius, xii. 16. 68 SIMPLE CITY STATES [CH. v. in their old homes, it is probable that their govern- ments were imitated directly from those of the old cities in Greece proper or in Asia Minor from which they had been sent forth to seek their fortunes. The causes, which led to the abolition of the tribal kingly office in the simple cities of Greece proper, nsition ^^^ *^® concentration of all power in the from tribal hands of the rich, are not fully known, governmen s. j^ ^^^ howcver. Certain that no simple city state has ever lived for any long period under hereditary kingly power of the military type that was common in the tribal age. Among the simple city states of Greece proper there was no tendency towards territorial conquests, and therefore no king was needed as military leader either for aggression or defence. Besides this, it may be observed that divinity doth hedge a king only so long as he is not subjected to the daily and hourly scrutiny of his subjects : when the whole life of a community goes on within the narrow compass of a city, and a king lives among his subjects within the walls, it is certain that all his foibles and shortcomings will be known, and the nobles will come to think he is no better than one of themselves. When the old tribal royalty had been abolished, the three classes that made up the population of a city were the rich citizens, the poor citizens, and the slaves. The slaves were, as a matter of course, absolutely incapable of taking part in public affairs, and the two classes left face to face with one another as possible claimants of OH. v.] OLIGARCHIES 69 political power were the rich citizens and the poor citizens. These two classes everywhere in the small cities of Greece and Italy engaged in contests for power: and it is remarkable that in none of the lesser cities is there any recorded instance of their settling their differences by a compromise or equitable division of power such as is usual both in the com- plex cities of antiquity and in the nations of the modern world. The class that commonly obtained power in a Greek city immediately after the fall of tribal king- ship was, as we have seen, the nobles or rich citizens. It may be assumed that when first the rich class rose to supreme and uncon- trolled authority they governed wisely and well ; they supplanted the long-established tribal govern- ments, and they could not have succeeded in such an achievement if they had not had merits of their own. We know, too, that in the medieval city of Venice a rich class in possession of unrestrained power were just and successful rulers for some centuries. There is then no reason for the assump- tion, which is often made, that the unrestrained rule of a rich class must be an abominable form of government. Among the Greeks the unrestrained rule of the rich began well but ended badly: the rich men were good rulers to begin with, but eventu- ally became oppressive. In the Greek language the name for the exclusive rule of a small body of rich men is oligarchy. Most of the Greek writers use the term in a neutral sense, and denote by it simply the 70 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. rule of the rich class whether that rule is good or bad;^ Aristotle narrowed the meaning of the word by restricting it to mean only the selfish rule of the rich,^ and modern writers have commonly followed Aristotle. I think, however, the term is more con- venient if it has the wider meaning: and I shall venture to speak not only of the bad oligarchy of the Four Hundred at Athens, but also of the good oligarchy of the Venetian republic. In the simple city states of Greece the oligarchies in the seventh century eventually became oppressive governments. The dislike with which Tyranni. . they were regarded must have grown as the poorer classes increased in numbers ; and it led to rebellions of the poor citizens, but not to their immediate admission to political power. The usual course of events was, that some ambitious man pro- claimed himself champion of the poor and induced them to provide him with a bodyguard. He then made an attempt with his bodyguard to seize the acropolis or citadel : if he failed he was killed ; if he succeeded he became a despot, absolute over rich and poor alike. Such a man, beginning as a champion of the poor citizens, and ending as a despot, was known as a Tyrannus, or usurper of unlimited power. The rule of the Tyranni was a necessary phase in the growth of a Greek city ; the poorer classes were too devoid of organisation and experience to exercise political ' For example, Herodotus, iii. 81, 82 ; Thncydldea, v. 31. " Aristotle, iii. 7, 5. CH. v.] TYEANNI 71 power, and therefore when the rich had been deprived of their misused authority, it was inevitable that the man wlio had led the revolt against them should gain a despotic position. Tyrannies then were a very prevalent form of government. The sixth century before the Christian era is, above all other times, the Age of the Tyrannies : there was scarcely a city in the Greek world that did not at some period between 600 B.C. and 500 B.C. live under a government of this kind. Many of the tyrants promoted for a time at least the material well-being of their subjects: they protected the lesser citizens from the rich, and by making property fairly secure encouraged trade; some of them embellished their cities with splendid buildings or strengthened them with fortifications; others were generous patrons of poets and of the arts. In the exceptional case of the Sicilian cities, where the Greek territories were exposed to attack from the Carthaginians, some of the tyrants were most useful as military leaders and champions of the Hellenes ; and all through Sicilian history, from Gelon in 485 B.C. to Hieron in 216 B.C., we meet with a recurrence of able and public-spirited rulers who bear the title of tyrants. Elsewhere in Greek lands the case was different, since there was no thought of gaining or losing territory by conquest : as soon as the tyrants had performed their proper task of putting down the oligarchies and ensuring that they did not rise again, their utility was at an end. All of them in time were corrupted by the enjoyment of unrestrained power. They became 72 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. cruel and grossly self-indulgent, and their rule incurred the abhorrence of the Greek race. Hero- dotus only expresses the general feeling of his countrymen in the description of a tyrant which he puts in the mouth of the Persian Otanes : ' A tyrant,' he says, 'is one who overturns long-established customs, and ravishes women, and puts men to death without trial.' 1 To protect themselves from their subjects the tyrants always hired foreign mercenary troops; 2 but no such precaution could avail them for long in the face of the general detestation with which they were regarded. Their dynasties usually lasted only for one or two generations; the most long-lived of all was that of the Orthagoridse at Sicyon, which lasted a hundred years.^ The fall of the tyrants in the lesser Greek cities occurred generally in the latter part of the sixth Fall of the century before the Christian era. Those Tyranni. [j^ Greece proper were got rid of one by one as occasion served; those in Asia Minor were deposed all at once about the year 501 B.C., at the very beginning of the revolt of the Asiatic Greeks against Persia, probably because they could not be trusted to fight on behalf of Greek independence against King Darius, in whom the petty despots themselves had found a kind patron. The nature of the governments which arose in the lesser Greek cities after the removal of the tyrants is not known to us in any minute detail. We know, however, that ' Herodotus, iii. 80. " Aristotle, Politics, iii. 14, 7. » Ibid. (Bekker 1837), v. 12, 1. CH. v.] DEMOCRACY 73 some of them were called by the Greeks oligarchies, and others deimocracies ; and that in most of the cities oligarchies and democracies succeeded one another alternately until the battle of Chseroneia in 338 B.C. destroyed at a blow the independence of the Greeks. The word oligarchy is of no doubtful meaning: it means the exclusive and unrestrained rule of a few rich men. Democracy, on the other hand, was used by the Greeks in different senses, which I must now try to explain. The Greeks recognised that there was, or thought that there might be, such a form of government as unmixed democracy. The principles of uncompro- an unmixed democracy were these : firstly, mising all citizens were to be equal ;i secondly, ^•"°'=''^'^y- appointments to office were to be made by drawing lots among candidates and not by eleetion.^ The result of applying these principles must be that the poor class of citizens will have the exclusive enjoy- ment of power. As the poor are more numerous than the rich they can always outvote them; and, for the same reason, most of the magistrates designated by the hazard of the lot will be drawn from the poor class. If, then, the principles of unmixed democracy are carried into practice, they give a monopoly of power to the poor class of citizens. But the Greeks also applied the name democracy to other governments, in which there were some ele- ments which savoured of pure democracy and others 1 Aristotle, Politics, iii. 13, 15. 2 Ibid., ii. 11, 7. 74 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. of an oligarchic character.^ In these governments all the citizens were equal in voting power, as they Mitig-ated were in a pure democracy, but magis- democracies tratcs Were appointed by voting and not known in ,ii icii «t some Greek by the hazard 01 the lot. As the magis- states. trates were elected, rich men held most of the offices : they were necessarily conspicuous in the eyes of the voters, and got votes for that reason ; and they were also elected because the habits of their lives had given them some preparation for the work of government. In all the constitutions where magistrates were elected by voting there was a com- promise between the interests of the rich and the poor : the poor gave most of the votes, but the rich held most of the magistracies. In some cases the compromise was made more favourable to the rich by a regulation that certain magistracies could be held- by none but a rich man. We have now to inquire what the Greek writers mean when they say that in some of the lesser But not in Greek cities democracies were established simple cities, after the fall of the tyrants. It is use- less to ask whether they meant perfectly pure democracies: there is not an instance of a pure democracy to be found in all history, and it is not quite certain that such a thing could exist. But we may profitably ask whether the governments called democracies in the small cities were nearer to the ' Aristotle, Politics, iv. 6, 1-4, and iv. 13, 11. In the second of these passages we learn that all the moderate popular governments which Aristotle called Polities were included among the demo- cracies by Greeks before his time. CH. v.] DEMOCRACY 75 ideal form known as pure democracy or to the governments founded on compromise in Athens by Solon and Cleisthenes. I have no doubt that they were so near to pure democracies that they gave the poor class of citizens a substantial supremacy. There is no visible trace in them of government by com- promise. The historians treat it almost as a matter of course that, when one of the governments which they call democracies was established in any of the lesser cities, some of the rich men had at once to go into exile; and this was the case not only in the turmoil of the Peloponnesian War, but also in the more tranquil times which preceded it.^ And there is another and a much weightier argument which leads me to the opinion that the uncompromising form of democracy was the only one to be found in any of the lesser cities. Two of our very best and most careful writers, Thucydides and Aristotle, thought that a popular government founded on a compromise between rich and poor was the best of all known governments, and they would therefore be certain to mention every instance of it that could be found. They describe examples of it in some of the larger and more complex cities, but none in the small cities, and I believe the reason why they mention none is that none existed. The governments, then, that commonly prevailed in the lesser Greek cities were oligarchy, tyranny, and uncompromising democracy. In Greece proper the progress of the lesser cities through these forms ' For example, at Naxos in 502 B.C. Herodotus, v. 30. 76 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. of governments was nearly uniform : they were under oligarchies in the seventh century, under tyrannies in the sixth, and afterwards they oscillated by means of frequent revolutions be- tween oligarchy and democracy. In other parts of the Greek world the course of events was not so unvarying, at any rate in respect of the dates at which the various sorts of government were estab- lished : for example, at Miletus tyranny may possibly have arisen a century earlier than in Greece proper, and it is not certain whether that city was ever ruled by an oligarchy at the beginning of its career. In view of these facts, and others like them, which it would be tedious to cite, it is impossible to say that all the lesser cities went through a certain series of governmental conditions in a definite order ; but it is perfectly safe to assert that the only political systems known to have existed in any of them were oligarchy, tyranny, and uncompromising democracy. The characteristic feature, then, of the govern- ments of the simple city states among the Greeks Class ^^^ ^^^^ power was lodged exclusively in governments, tj^g hands of a class or a person. It would be a great convenience to have a single term to denote governments of this sort, and I shall try to find one. Oligarchy and uncompromising demo- cracy can obviously be called class governments, since they give exclusive possession of power respectively to the rich class or the poor class. And I venture to think that tyranny can also be called a class government : for a tyrant, though he is only a single CH. v.] CLASS GOVERNMENTS 77 person, can, without doing much violence to language, be called a class by himself, since he has the char- acteristics of a class — namely, interests and aims and habits distinct from those of the rest of the community. If I may be allowed to use the word class to mean either a number of persons or a single person having interests, aims, and habits which are not shared by the rest of the community, I may sum up the results of this chapter by saying that among the ancient Greeks the governments of all the simple city states were class governments. The reasons why political power in the simple city states was always lodged exclusively in the hands of a single person or class must now be considered. They may be found in which deter- two characteristics of these cities : in their ^^^f^*'^f exemption from all serious care about thegovem- foreign policy, and the small size of their territories. As they very seldom had reason to make any great effort against a foreign power, it did not matter to them whether all classes were contented and prepared to fight .zealously for the common- wealth. In communities with an active foreign policy, the discontent or secession of a class is instantly felt to be disastrous, because it impairs military efficiency. Not so in the non-belligerent little city states of the Greeks. And, further, the small size of the territories made it difficult for an oppressed class to rise and deliver itself by rebelhon in arms. All parts of the territory were within 78 SIMPLE CITY STATES [ch. v. striking distance of the city, and any armed insur- rection in the country could easily be put down by the class that held the city and the government. The only chance for the discontented was to form a conspiracy in the city itself and seize the citadel. It is true that a large number of revolutions were effected by this difficult method ; but the. dominant class knew the method was difficult, and preferred to run the risk of revolution rather than to descend from their pre-eminence by giving a share of political influence to the discontented. The simple city states in ancient history, no less than the tribal communities, were made rather in- Conciuding stinctively than of careful design, and observations. t]jus resembled natural products. When a tribe gained great wealth the tribesmen surrounded a convenient site with fortifications in obedience to a natural instinct of self-preservation, and it was in obedience to natural instinct that they converted their community into a simple city state. It seems too that the simple cities were all alike in structure. It might then be expected that Nature would allot them one definite form of government, but in fact they might have for their government oligarchy, tyranny, or democracy. How are we to account for a phenom- enon seemingly contrary to reasonable expectation ? Or is it, in fact, not contrary to our expectations ? Are oligarchy, democracy, tyranny, when they occur in a simple city state, really distinct from one another? We can see in the history of Paris during the French Revolution that the passage from any one to any CH. v.] CONCLUDING REMARKS 79 other of the three could be made almost imper- ceptibly. Is it not probable that in the Greek cities also the governments which bear separate names were in truth very closely akin ? TABLE. ANCIENT CITY STATES. KIND OP COMMUNITY. GOVERNMENTS. Simple city state.s. Class governments, namely, 1. Oligarchy. 2. Tyranny. 3. Uncompromising democracy. CHAPTER VI UNION OF GREEK CITIES: ATTICA It is, as we have noticed, difficult for a city to conquer other cities, because each city is a compact community and defends itself vigorously : to consolidate a number of conquered cities into one community with the victorious city is harder still. It has never been accomplished when the dependent cities are separated from the conquering city by stretches of sea : when they are neighbours with adjoining territories, it can be done. The city of Venice conquered cities on the other side of the Adriatic and of the Mediterranean Sea, but never formed them into one community; Athens, Rome, and Genoa conquered neighbouring cities, and consolidated their conquests into single communities. When a new community is founded by the conquest and assimilation of many cities under a single dominant city, it may conveniently be called a complex city state. It is a city state because the whole is controlled from and by a single central city ; and it is complex because, though it has only one nucleus for its government, it also possesses in its dependent towns many lesser centres of population, wealth, commerce, society, and opinion. CH. VI.] UNIONS OF CITIES 81 In every complex city state the dominant city must in its early days have been expansive and belligerent ; it attained its supremacy over the other cities by fighting. The wars that enabled it to conquer neigh- bouring towns must have called for common efforts of all its citizens : and common effort is not likely to be effectual unless all classes are moderately con- tented. General contentment is best secured by giving all classes a share of political power ; and so the cities that conquer other cities usually get an early lesson in the advantages of mixed forms of government. And, further, it may be noticed that, after a complex city state has been made, there is a sort of equipoise between the central city, on the one hand, and the outlying communities of citizens, on the other. It may be that for a time the inhabitants of the central city will try to oppress the outlying regions; but in general the territory outside the city is so im- portant, and the contentment of its population so desirable, that the oppression is brought to an end by compromise, and the people outside the city walls gets its due share of power. The governments character- istic of complex city states in their mature condition are mixed and balanced constitutions, in which every class obtains its fair portion of political influence. The complex city states in ancient history were Athens, Kome, and Carthage. I shall not attempt to describe Carthage, because our knowledge of its history and institutions is most imperfect. Athens and Kome will suffice to give an idea of complex city states and of their governments. 82 UNIONS OF CITIES [CH. vi. In the beginning of complex city states their gavernments are variable, and though in time they _ ^ always get mixed governments, those Governments ./ o o of complex governments do not conform to any city states. precise model. In this chapter and the next I desire merely to depict the varied govern- ments in the complex cities of Athens and Kome, and to show how both eventually acquired mixed forms of government in which rich and poor both participated. The final form of mixed government in both the complex city states of ancient Europe is seen only in the Attic constitutions made by Solon and Cleisthenes, and in the Roman constitution during the first and second Punic Wars. Under each of these constitutions the component parts that made up the governmental system were three in number — the magistrates, the permanent senate, and the common folk. The magistrates were elected yearly by the whole people from the rich class, and were entrusted both with military command and with civil authority ; the senate had the duty of giving advice to the magistrates when desired to do so, and consisted of men chosen for wisdom and experience, with a life tenure of their places in the senate; the common folk took part in the yearly elections of magistrates, in making laws, and in judicature. In the present chapter I shall not attempt to do more than sketch the growth of the Attic constitution till 480 B.C., the date of the invasion of Greece by CH. VI.] ATTICA 83 Xerxes. The subject-matter will be divided under the following five heads: — (1) Prehistoric times; (2) the oligarchy of the Eupatridse; (3) the consti- tution of Solon ; (4) the tyranny of Peisistratus and Hippias ; (5) the constitution of Cleisthenes. Although Attica is one of the largest natural divisions of Greece, it is decidedly smaller than an average English county. It measures about fifty miles from north to south, and Athenst°(i) about forty at the broadest part from Prehistoric . times. east to west. Its area is about seven hundred and twenty square miles, and it has about the same extent of surface as Berkshire, Cambridge- shire, or Oxfordshire. In this small region, destined eventually to do at least as much for the progress of the human intellect as has ever been achieved by any country of a hundred times its size, the earliest inhabitants known to us were Ionian Greeks. They formed several small independent communities, about twelve in number, each contained within a village or small township. Athens had the greatest advantages of situation since its acropolis was of great natural strength, and the citizens had easy access to the sea by the three excellent harbours of Munychia, Zea, and Piraeus. Accordingly, in course of time there arose at Athens a powerful ruler who succeeded in bringing the whole country and its little towns under a single kingly government of the tribal type ; and Thucydides tells us that in his own days the union of Attica under Athens was still regularly celebrated at the public 84 ATTICA [CH. VI. festival of the Synoekia.^ The supremacy of Athens over Attica was probably subsequent to the age of Homer, because Athens is hardly mentioned in the Homeric poems, and never, I believe, in any passage which belongs to the poems as they were originally composed ; but it was long anterior to any period of which we have chronological knowledge, and at the beginning of Greek history Athens is fully established as a complex city state. At Athens, as in other Greek cities, the old tribal kingship was gradually shorn of its powers and prerogatives: before the beginning of chrono- Attica- (2) logical history it had been abolished. OUgarchy From a time somewhere between 700 B.C. Eupatridaeto ^nd 650 B.C. the government was con- 594 B.C. trolled by a permanent council of nobles, or Eupatridse, and its details were managed by nine archons or administrators, who were selected yearly by the council.^ The council consisted of those who were serving or had served the office of archon,^ so that the council in selecting new archons also fiUed up vacancies in its own numbers. Among the nine magistrates, the first in rank was the Archon, who gave his name to his year of office ; the second was the Archon Basileiis, who took over the title and the priestly functions of the old tribal king; the third was the Polemarch, who commanded in war; the ' Thuoydides, ii. 15. 2 Aristotle, Alh. Pol., 8. '■> Plutarch, Solon, 19; Arist., Ath. Pol., 3. CH. VI.] SOLON 85 other six were called Thesmothetse, and probably attended to judicial business.^ The nobles, then, from 650 B.C. or earlier were in exclusiYe possession of power. How they used it when first they got it, is not recorded; by 600 B.C. they were employing it selfishly. They took advantage of the harsh laws relating to debt to deprive the poorer freemen of their lands, or to reduce them to slavery ; and all Attica was seething with discontent and enmity between classes. How it came about that the nobles in the time of Solon were induced to part with some of their mis- used power we are not informed. But it may be observed that Athens was still Constitution expanding by conquest, and had recently ° ° °"' acquired the island of Salamis by conquest from the Megareans, after a sternly waged conflict, in which Solon played the leading part.'^ An expanding city always needs a zealous and united army, both for making conquests and for keeping them; and it seems likely that the motive which persuaded the nobles to make concessions was the desire to obtain the active and willing co-operation of all the citizens in the battlefield. In the year 594 B.C. it was agreed by rich and poor that Solon should be elected archon, and entrusted with power to deal with the existing discontents and devise a new form of government. He began with economic changes, cancelling all debts that had then been incurred, restoring to liberty > Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 3. "■ Plutarch, iSolon, 8-10. 86 ATTICA [CH. vx. those who had been enslaved, altering the law in regard to security for debt : and when this had been effected he proceeded to his political reforms. Solon was the first man who ever planned a government containing the three elements which . have already been noted as recurring in a later Attic constitution and in the Koman republic. The three elements were yearly magistrates, permanent advisory senate, and popular privileges. As the governments composed of these three factors are of great historical importance, it will be well to observe how each factor was defined in the first constitution that ever contained them, and how the founder of it designed that they should act and counteract on one another. In regard to the magistrates Solon ordained that they should be, as heretofore, nine in number ; should keep their title of archons, should bear office for a year, and should all be taken from the richest class of citizens, called Pentacosiomedinini : but he sub- jected them to certain restrictions, intended to prevent them from abusing their power. These restrictions were established by the method of appointing them, and in the power given to certain popularly constituted law-courts of revising their decisions. They were to be appointed by a process in which popular election and hazard both played a part : each of the four ancient tribes, into which the families of Attica were divided, elected from among the richest class of citizens ten candidates for the office, and, from the forty thus chosen, nine were OH. VI.] SOLON 87 taken by drawing lots. In constructing his senate Solon had no difficulty, as there was a senate consis- ting of archons and ex-archons ready to his hand. It was not necessary for him to make any formal change in defining the composition of the senate ; it still continued to consist of archons and ex-archons, but the men who were admitted into it under Solon's constitution had become archons through a process in which their names had been submitted to the public for election as candidates. And as Solon did not need to define the composition of the senate, so perhaps he did not dare to define its powers ; for in later days when it became famous under the name of the Areus Pagus (or in Latin, Areopagus), it seems almost to have had the power of settling the limits of its own jurisdiction. The third element in the con- stitution was furnished by the participation of the people at large in the work of government. The popular institutions of Solon were the courts of justice, the assembly, and a body of four hundred men who acted as a committee of the assembly. The courts of justice, known as Dicasteria, were for the time being the most important : they were courts in which large bodies of citizens, rich and poor alike, sat as judges or jurymen; and, as they were em- powered to hear appeals from sentences pronounced by archons, they had the final judgment in questions of the gravest character. The assembly, comprising all the citizens, had important elective business to do once a year at the selection of archons : for the rest of the year it was probably intended to 88 ATTICA [CH. vi. be inactive. Solon ordered that his laws should continue in force for a hundred years, and thereby deprived the assembly of any chance of being active in law-making. He foresaw, however, that in course of time it would undertake to legislate, and might need a check to prevent it from making unwise in- novations. Such a check he provided in the council or committee of four hundred. For the formation of this council he selected a hundred men from each of the four tribes, and ordered that no proposal should be brought before the general assembly of the citizens until the four hundred had given it their approval.^ The constitution of Solon was a wonderful work of genius. It was evidently too good for the people of Attica in Solon's time; but some of its provisions were not good enough for their descendants in the very highest stage of civilisation that they ever reached. The institutions that seem to have done some injury to the Athenians in later times were the use of hazard in the appointment of archons and the constitution of the Dicasteria. They were, however, good enough, or too good, for Solon's time; and if they were retained, revived, or exaggerated in times for which they were not suited, it was the fault not of Solon but of later lawgivers. The use of the method of chance in the appoint- ment of archons was probably suggested by the religious feeling that the gods ought to have some ' The description of the Solonian constitution is taken from Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 5-13; except the statement that the four hundred were selected by Solon. This is from Plutarch, Solon, 19. CH. VI.] SOLON 89 share in settling who should be rulers : but the gods do not choose as well as men. The Solonian method did not ensure that the very best men in the com- munity should be its rulers, though it excluded any one who was very incapable or unpopular; and, by neglecting to get the very best,' it tended in time to lower the character of the archonship, and, what was worse, the dignity of the Areopagus. The Dicasteria probably answered well enough for such judicial work as was needed in Solon's time ; but they were composed entirely of men unlearned in the law, with- out any professional jurist to guide them, and in later times, when intricate cases came before them, they were apt to be capricious in their judgments. The Solonian institutions remained in full working order for only three or four years : then there arose violent contests about the appointment of archons, which showed that the immediate effect of Solon's changes had been to transfer the chief power to the nine magistrates.^ Turbulence of factions made it impossible to enforce some parts of his constitution ; but other parts of it were probably observed, and the whole served as a foundation for Cleisthenes to build upon. It is evident that the strife of classes which spoiled the working of Solon's institutions led to the restoration of some kind of oligarchy : for if it was not so, there would have been no motive to induce the poorer citizens to accede so readily as they did to the wishes of the demagogue Peisistratus. It was in the year 560 B.c. that Peisistratus succeeded 1 Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 13. 90 ATTICA [CH. VI. in putting down the oligarchy of the Eupatridse. The chief contending parties in Attica were the rich men Attica- U) ^^ ^^^ plain, the men of the seashore, Tyranny of and the poor men of the hill country. Peisistratus. t, • ■ . ^ a j^i • i reisistratus was a young Athenian who had twice won military distinction : having formed a body of partisans, he declared himself the champion of the poor citizens of the high lands. He presented himself in Athens pretending he had been violently assaulted by his political opponents, and requesting the citizens that he might have some men to protect him. The citizens granted his request : he formed a bodyguard of club men, by whose aid he seized the Acropolis and established himself as tyrant. The tyranny of Peisistratus and his son Hippias need not detain us long. It may suffice to point out that it was not so easily established or so irresistible and violent as the tyrannies of the lesser cities. It seems that there is something about an enlarged city state which tends to a balance of power and some- thing like compromise even when a tyranny has been established. There was so much of a balance of power between Peisistratus and his opponents the Eupatridse that they twice succeeded in driving him into exile ; and after he gained his position as tyrant for a third time, there was so much of compromise and moderation in his government that he never entirely abolished the Solonian institutions. It was his constant policy, as we learn from Thucydides.^ to permit nine archons to be elected every year by the ' Thuoydides, vi. 54. CH. VI.] PEISISTRATUS 91 citizens, though he took care that one of the archons should be a member of his own family. His son Hippias imitated his father's moderation, until 514 B.C., when his brother Hipparchus was murdered out of private spite in the foolish and futile con- spiracy of Harmodius and Aristogeiton. The constant opponents of Peisistratus and Hippias were, as a matter of course, the Eupatridas, whose power Peisistratus had destroyed ; and the leaders of the Eupatridse were the wealthy and powerful family of the Alcmseonidse. It was Megacles, head of this family, who on two occasions succeeded in effecting the expulsion of Peisistratus; and it was his son Cleisfchenes who contrived the expulsion of Hippias. Cleisthenes was an exile from Attica all through the reign of Hippias ; he organised several invasions of his native country for the overthrow of the tyranny, but they failed miserably until he suc- ceeded in obtaining aid from a foreign power. The family of the Alcmseonidte was extremely wealthy; they contrived, by well-timed generosity towards the Delphic temple of Apollo, to win the favour of its priestess ; and the priestess in her oracles commanded the Spartans to set Athens free. In 510 B.C. the Spartans resolved to obey the command of the god : the King Cleomenes was sent into Attica with a Spartan army, Hippias was expelled, the exiles restored, and the Athenians were free to establish any constitution that they might desire.^ ' The facts here stated about Peisistratus, Hippias, Cleisthenes are taken from Herodotus, i. 59-64, and v. 62; Aristotle, Ath. Pot, 14 and 19 ; Plutarch, Solon, 30. 92 ATTICA [CH. vi. After the expulsion of Hippias a contest for power arose between Cleisthenes and a man named Isagoras. Attica: (s) Isagoras had been a friend of the expelled cieisthenean tyrant, and it seems that after Hippias constitution, "^ • , t , r t i. so8 B.C.- was gone he wished to found a tyranny 480 B.C. Qf jjjg Q^jj -y^e do not know any de- tails of the contest between the rivals except that Isagoras on two occasions called in foreign powers in support of his designs. On the first occasion a Spartan force, under King Cleomenes, seized the Acropolis of Athens, but was compelled to evacuate it after a two days' siege ; on the second Attica ,was invaded from the west by Spartans and Corinthians, and from the north by Bcsotians and Chalcidians. It seems that for a time the Athenians were in a hopeless plight ; but, luckily for them, some of the invaders had misgivings and doubts — it may be they thought Apollo, who had commanded the liberation of Athens, would disapprove of its enslavement ; in any case, the armament gradually melted away, and by its dispersion or retreat Cleisthenes and his partisans were left in undisputed possession of power.i It is probable that the original design of Cleis- thenes on the expulsion of Hippias was to restore the oligarchy of the Eupatridse: for we are told by Herodotus that it was when he was being worsted in the contest with Isagoras that he resolved to make alliance with the common folk.^ The repeated invasions of Attica must have shown him that it was ' Herodotus, v. 66-76. = Herodotus, v. 66. ■CH. vi.J CLEISTHENES 93 a matter of vital necessity to keep all classes of the people contented and united for resistance to aggres- sors ; and accordingly it is not wonderful that the constitution which he established is a remarkably good example of the mixed and balanced form of government which is found in complex, expanded, and belligerent city states. The recent invasions of Attica showed that the most pressing need of the Athenians was the establishment of a large, zealous, and ^ •^ ' Ten new effective army of citizens : and it seems t"bes defined that this fact determined the character of ^^ '^'""'"i^- nearly all the enactments of Cleisthenes. Before he could have a large citizen army it was necessary to enroll new citizens, and in effecting his desire to widen the citizenship he was led to make changes which altered the whole structure of the community. Up to his time the citizens had been divided into four tribes which are usually known as the Ionic tribes : each of them was a close corporation of families, so that no man could be a tribesman unless his father has been so before him. The men whom Cleisthenes wished to enfranchise were mainly aliens domiciled in Attica, and some were of servile origin : so it was clear they could not gain admission to the four ancient tribes. In order to effect their admission to citizenship, he deprived the Ionic tribes of all political significance, leaving them nothing but their character of religious and social corporations. He then divided the Attic community, for political purposes, into ten tribes, constructed on a new principle, and defined 94 ATTICA [CH. VI. not as containing certain families but as dwelling in certain demes or villages ; and he enrolled in these new tribes, and thereby in the list of citizens, those men whom he desired to adopt into the Attic state. In order to make certain that the new tribes should not serve as rallying points for local factions such as those of the plain, the shore, and the highlands in the time of Peisistratus, he took care that the demes ■which formed a tribe did not all lie in~ one district, but were partly urban or suburban, partly maritime and partly inland.^ After the roll of the citizens had been augmented, the way was clear for Cleisthenes to establish a Army of powerful army of citizens, and to settle citizens. ^.j^g form that the government should assume. His army consisted of ten brigades: each tribe furnished a brigade and elected a general or strategus to command it. At the battle of Marathon in 490 B.C., when the Athenians drove the invader Darius back into his ships, the right wing was formed by a body of troops under the Polemarch, and then from right to left the ten tribal brigades were marshalled in order each under its own general.^ The form of government was modelled on the Solonian constitution, but presented some new features, because since Solon's time new difficulties had arisen and experience showed the necessity of providing against them. ' Our knowledge of the Cleisthenean tribes oomes mainly from Herodotus, v. 69, and Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 21. ^ Herodotus, vi. Ill, whence the words are taken. Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 22. CH. VI.] CLEISTHENES 95 The Cleisthenean constitution distributed the right and duty of taking part in the work of government among the governmental organs which are usually found in the mixed constitutions of complex city states. These three organs in the constitution — the magistrates, the permanent senate, and the common people — will now be surveyed in order. The chief magistrates now comprised the ten generals or strategi as well as the nine archons. All the nineteen officials were chosen by a Archons and purely elective process, and there was no strategi. drawing of lots. Until the battle of Marathon the archons ranked higher than the strategi, and the Polemarch stood before them even in battle. Three years afterwards,^ the Athenians revived the use of the lot in the appointment of archons: from that time the archonship gradually lapsed into political insignificance, and the only important officers were the ten strategi. The senate of the Areopagus was apparently well constituted by Cleisthenes. It consisted of archons and ex-archons : and as archons under the Cleisthenean scheme were- chosen by ■■^°p^&"=- a purely elective method, they were likely to be men of the best ability procurable. When the Athenians in 487 B.C. reintroduced the hazard of the lot into the process of appointing archons,^ they made it certain that the influence and usefulness of the Areo- pagus would in time decline. It is clear they had never realised the value of a permanent senate of 1 Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 22. 96 ATTICA [CH. vi. experienced governors : if they had, they would, when they revived the practice of appointing archons by drawing lots, have taken some precautions to save the Areopagus from being damaged by the change. Had they known anything about the Roman Senate, which already existed when this change was made, they might have transferred the right of member- ship in the Areopagus from the archons to the strategi. If they had done this, the Areopagus would have consisted of men of ability and experience accustomed to high office. As it was, the Areopagus, when the hazard of the lot had taken its full effect on the archonship, was composed of political nobodies. The whole mass of the citizens had nearly the same political rights under Cleisthenes as under Assemblies Solon, but they were more active in the of citizens. ^gg gf them. Provisions were made for holding ten meetings of the Ecclesia, or general assembly of the people, in the course of the year; whereas Solon seems to have intended that it should ordinarily meet only on the one occasion of the appointment of archons. These provisions for more frequent meetings appear in the new regulations about the committee or council of the popular assembly. Solon had fixed the number of this committee at four hundred: Cleisthenes added another hundred members, and the committee is thenceforward knawn as the BoulS of the Five Hundred. Fifty members were taken from each of the ten tribes — whether at this time they were elected CH. VI.] OSTEACISM 97 by voting or taken by the hazard of the lot we do not know — and the fifty members from each tribe enjoyed for a tenth part of the year the dignity of Prytaneis, or presiding officers, in the meetings both of the Five Hundred and of the general assembly; and the name Prytaneia was applied both to their right of presidency and to the term of thirty-five or thirty-six days for which they possessed it.i The arrangements show clearly that it was likely that the general assembly would meet about ten times in the course of a year. It must, then, have been a legisla- tive assembly. We do not know anything about its proceedings ; but it seems quite certain that Cleis- thenes adopted the Solonian rule that no proposal should be submitted to the general assembly till it had been approved by the permanent committee : for that rule appears as a long-established principle in the later part of Athenian history. Besides their work in the general assemblies the Athenian people had other opportunities of political activity. It may be that the Dicasteria, or popular law-courts of Solon, had been permitted to survive under Peisistratus, though it is clear he could not allow them much independence : under Cleisthenes they were in full working order. There were also some rare occasions when the assembled people was called on to act as guardian of the state against any demagogue who might, like Peisistratus, aspire to make himself a ' The existence of the Prytaneise in the Cleistheuean constitution is authenticated by Plutarch, Symposiaca Prohlemata, i. 10. G 98 ATTICA [CH. vi. tyrant, or against such a contest for the chief power as had arisen between Cleisthenes and Isagoras. On these occasions the process used was known as ostracism, or the vote by the potsherds. The public assembly could, without naming any person, order that on a fixed date a vote should be taken in which each citizen might write on a potsherd the name of any man who ought in his opinion to be banished. In order to prevent ostracism from being misused by any small clique of citizens to get rid of an opponent, there was a regulation which mentioned a minimum of six thousand as necessary to a valid vote. Accord- ing to Plutarch, whose authority I accept, it was only required that there should be six thousand voters in all; while other writers imply that there must be six thousand sherds bearing the name of the same man. When this regulation was complied with, the man whose name occurred on the largest number of sherds went into exile for a term of ten years, but did not suffer any further hurt.^ It may be noticed in passing that the process of ostracism was in use not only at Athens but also at Argos, which was in some respects like Athens in structure and constitution. The descriptions that have been given of the magis- tracies, the Areopagus, and the political privileges of the people may suffice to indicate the nature of the central government in the constitution of Cleisthenes ; but it must be observed that he also introduced a reformed system of local government. ^ Plutarch, Aristides, 7. For conflicting statements see Smith, Dictionary of Antiquitien, third edition, article Exsilium. CH. VI.] LOCAL GOVERNMENT 99 Some kind of local divisions and local governors are usually found in an expanded or complex city state. In Attica before Cleipthenes the Local divisions were called naucrarise, and their srovemment. governors naucrari. We know nothing about them except that there were in all forty-eight naucrari^, that each contributed two horsemen to the army and a ship to the navy, and that the naucrari assessed the taxation needed for these purposes, and had some- thing to do with the expenditure of it. . Cleisthenes established his domes as local divisions in lieu of the naucrarise ; in each deme he set up a demarchus, or president of the deme, and the demarchi took over the functions which the naucrari had hitherto dis- charged.^ The details of his scheme of local govern- ment are not known, but it evidently proved a success. In the time of Demosthenes, about a century and a half later, every deme had its assembly presided over by the demarchus ; and these assem- blies were fully organised bodies and had plenty of business to employ them.^ The constitution of Cleisthenes is a clear example of the mixed and balanced governments that grow up naturally in complex city states. It also furnishes an example — as do the rest of the mixed and balanced governments in city states — of that type of moderate popular government to which Aristotle gave the name of Polity. It was popular, since the ' For Nauorarise see Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 20; and Smith, Dictionary of Antiquities, third edition (1891), article Naucraria. ^ Smith, Dictionary of Antiquities, article Dermis. 100 ATTICA [CH. VI. mass of the citizens had a controlling power; and it was moderate, because no class had opportunities for governing in its own interest. Now that the constitutional history of Attica has been brought down to 480 B.C., this chapter may be closed. Soon after this date the central city of Athens was immensely enlarged in area and popula- tion, the country districts and the lesser towns lost their importance, especially during the Peloponnesian War, and from thenceforward Athens belongs rather to the simple than the complex variety of city states. CHAPTER VII UNION OF ITALIAN CITIES: ROME The Romans, in consequence of their geographical position and natural surroundings and the character of their neighbours, had far greater opportunities than the Athenians for conquering cities and assimilating them into one community; and they used them so well that in the third century before the Christian Era a strongly united Roman common- wealth occupied all the central parts of Italy and gave law to the whole peninsula. Until the close of the second Punic War in 201 B.C., the Roman Republic was only an unusually large specimen of a complex city state ; in the next sixty years the body politic rapidly and completely changed its character by annexation of distant territories, and by the year 146 B.C., when the last Punic War ended, Rome was the head of a heterogeneous empire. The present chapter will attempt to give a sketch in outline of the growth of the Roman constitution so long as Rome bore the character of a city state. The subject-matter will be divided into periods each corre- sponding to a certain form of government or politi- cal condition. The periods will bear the following 102 ITALY [CH. VII. titles : (1) The beginnings of Kome, and the time of the kings ; (2) the exclusive rule of the patricians ; (3) the contest between the two orders until 340 b.c. ; (4) the expansion of Rome and the gradual recon- ciliation of the orders, 340-275 B.C.; (5) the united Roman commonwealth, 287-201 B.c. In speaking of these periods it is obvious that I must confine my attention to the most salient points : for if I were to mention the details they would be tedious to the reader, and would swell this chapter to the bulk of a volume. Economy of space may best be practised in speaking of the contest between the orders and their gradual reconciliation : for the details of those two periods are unique in history, and do not lend themselves to the purposes of comparison to which this book is devoted. It will then do no hurt to my design if these details are passed over in silence ; and in speaking of the periods of contest and reconciliation I may be content if I make mention of such facts only as are needed for the understanding of the government in the united commonwealth. o^ (1) The Beginnings of Rome, AND THE Time of the Kings. Italy is for the most part a land of rocks and moun- tains, but its mountain ranges are fewer in number and generally much less formidable in Geography. character than those which divide Greece. The chain of the Apennines runs down the whole length of the peninsula, and is perhaps as difficult CH. VII.] GEOGEAPHY 103 of transit as some of the ranges in Greece; but its offshoots in many parts are rather hills than mountains, and, what is no less important, they do not stand very close together, but leave room for broad plains and open valleys. The plains and valleys of Italy played a very large part in settling the political destiny of the country and in giving it a history unlike that of the neigh- bouring peninsula. The plain of Latium and the adjoining valley of the river Liris exercised a pre- dominant influence over Italian history beyond all the other geographical features of the country, and for that reason it is worth while to describe them in some detail. The plain of Latium, now known as the Campagna, is, roughly speaking, a triangle with its corners at Ostia, Tibur, and Terracina. From Ostia piain of to Tibur the distance is thirty or thirty- Latmm. five English miles: the other two sides of the triangle are each about sixty miles in length. It is edged round with mountains except at one spot : at Prasneste, not far from Tibur, there is a gap in the hills which gives easy access to the long valley of the Liris. The plain and the valley together form one of the natural divisions of Italy; and it is far larger than any of the natural divisions of Greece. The surface of the Campagna is level or gently undulating, except where the isolated volcanic mass of the Alban hills rises to a height of three thousand feet from the middle of it. The hills with plain adjoining offered tempting sites for towns : Tibur, 104 ITALY [CH. VII. Cora, Norba, Privernum were on the sides of the mountains that formed the outer margin of the plain ; Aricia, Alba, Lanuvium were grouped around the Alban hills, and Tusculum was perched on one of their summits at a height of two thousand feet above the adjoining level of the Campagna. All these towns were themselves in strong and defensible positions, but they had lands in the plain which lay open to attack. The usefulness of Kome to the Latins lay mainly in the power of the Koman armies to defend the plain. The site of Rome is formed by several low hills grouped together on the south side of the river Site of Tiber : they were commonly spoken of as Rome. the seven hills, but it would be more natural to call them five. They furnished by far the best position for defending the Latins against the Etruscans. In this strong post it is said that detachments from three neighbouring peoples effected settlements ; and no doubt the tradition is correct, since in most of the earliest Roman institutions, whether religious, political, or military, the numbers that occur are multiples of three. The three components of the original Roman city were the Ramnes of Latin stock, the Titles of Sabine race, and the Luceres. There was an old tradition that the Luceres were Etruscans ; but probably Mommsen is justified in deriding it as incredible.^ The Romans have all the appearance of being a thoroughly homo- geneous people, and this they could not have been ' Mommsen, Rom. Hist., vol. i. p. 45. CH. vii.] BEGINNINGS OF EOME 105 if a third part of them had been Etruscans. The old antiquary Festus says the Luceres came from Ardea ; and it seems likely he is near the mark, since the Rutulians of Ardea were kinsmen of the Latins and the Sabines. The prevalence of multiples of three in the old Roman institutions indicates that in the first instance equal numbers were drawn from the Ramnes, the Tities, and the Luceres to fill the places in the priesthoods, the assemblies, and the army; and the equality of numbers drawn from the three tribes indicates that the union of the three tribes into one people was brought about by voluntary compact and not by force : for if it had arisen through the conquest of two tribes by the third, the conquering tribe would have had a superiority over the other two in the government of the united people. The stories that have come down to us about events in the times of the kings are perfectly worth- less : there is no reason to suppose that ^ .^ '■ '■ Evidence for any one set them down in writing until early Roman shortly after 200 B.C., when Fabius Pictor '"^«t"t'°"=- made a collection of them and published it in the Greek tongue. On the other hand, the descriptions that we possess in Livy and Dionysius of the Eoman institutions in the time of King Servius TuUius must be very nearly accurate; for those institutions left traces of themselves in usages of the constitution which survived till the times when Roman literature was most abundant. The limits of the Roman territory in the time of the kings are indicated by the stories about the reign 106 ROME [CH. vii. and fall of Tarquin the Proud ; and the testimony of these stories, in so far as they bear on geography, f ^^ probably trustworthy, because the old Rome under narrators were under no temptation to t e ings. place events in wrong localities, however much they might embellish them with imaginary details. The stories about the capture of Gabii through the treachery of Sextus Tarquinius, the summons sent by King Tarquin to the Latins to meet him at the grove of Ferentina, and the rule of a Tarquin at CoUatia, all indicate that these places lay on the frontiers of the Roman dominions.^ From the indications thus furnished, and from some others of less note, we may infer that the Eoman territory comprised a strip of land extending along the south side of the Tiber and its tributary the Anio, from the sea to about twenty miles inland, and having a breadth of twelve miles in its Avidest part ; it also took in a small piece north of the Anio but south of the Tiber near Fidenae, and a narrow strip along the north of the Tiber from Rome to the sea, so that the Romans had command of the river-channel.^ Outside the territory directty subject to Tarquin it is probable that he had, as Livy and Dionysius assert, a hegemony or suzerainty over the Latin federation, so that he could dictate its foreign policy and make use ' These stories are told in Livy, i. 50-60, and ii. 19-20. ^ There is a most useful map of the Roman territory after the time of the kings in Pelham, Outlines of Roman History, p. 64. The territory under the kings was slightly larger than that shown in this map ; it took in certainly Gabii, perhaps also Nomentum and Crnstumerium (Livy, i. 38, 4). CH. VII.] THE TWO OEDERS 107 of its armies.^ There had been, long before the time of Tarquin, an alliance on equal terms, between Kome and the Latin federation. The equality between the contracting powers had, we are told, originally been so complete that they had a joint army between them, and the commander-in-chief was appointed in some years by Rome, in others by the Latin federation.^ By the time of Tarquin all traces of the original equality had disappeared, and the King of Rome was master of the Latin forces ; and it is pretty certain that the Latin federation never regained such equality with Rome as to appoint a commander over an army composed of Latin and Roman contingents.^ The population of the Roman territory other than slaves (who were not numerous *) was divided into two orders, the patricians and the plebs. The ^ patricians were the descendants of the thepopuia- original settlers, and they alone had the rights of Roman burgesses ; the plebs included the conquered people of the territory outside the city, and also any persons who voluntarily came to Rome as new settlers. The component parts of the government were three in number : namely, the king, the senate, p^^^^^^ ^^ and the whole body of patrician bur- the govem- gesses. The whole power habitually ™^" ' belonged to the king; but as often as there was 1 Livy, i. 50-52; Dionysius, iv. 4.3-48, especially iv. 48, 1: Tvxiiy Si T^s Aarlvwy riyenovlas 6 lapKvyios. ^ Cincius, » very early author, who wrote during the second Punic War, quoted by Testus, de Signif., p. 241 (Miiller). ■' Mommsen holds this view. Bom. Hist., vol. i. p. 350. -■ Marquardt, Rem. Alterth., Privathben, vol. i. pp. 18. 19. 108 ROME [CH. vii. a vacancy in the kingship, the senate and the bur- gesses rose for the time to a position of commanding influence. The Roman king, like the king in a Greek tribe,^ united all the active functions of government in his own person. He was commander of the army, high priest, supreme judge, and president both in the senate and in the assembly of burgesses. His commands given in any of his capacities were subject to no appeal, unless he voluntarily permitted an appeal to the burgesses. The kingly office is represented by the legends as being always filled by a process of election, and as having never, even in its earliest days, been transmissible by inheritance from father to son ; and it is likely that their representations are correct in both particulars. It is certain that, in some cases, the kingly dignity was acquired by election : for there was a definite method of electing kings, and it was undoubtedly sometimes used, since it left clear traces of its existence in the visages of the republican con- stitution throughout its whole duration. The opinion that the Roman kingship was never hereditary is based on the fact that in the Roman state the three tribes of the Ramnes, Titles, and Luceres were equal with one another. In states where several communi- ties are united on terms of equality there is not, so far as I know, any instance of hereditary kingship ; a,nd on the other hand, the tendency of such states towards elective kingship is witnessed by the position both of ' See page 35. CH. VII.] EARLIEST CONSTITUTION 109 the Doges at Venice and of the President in the United States of America. The senate in the time of the kings was a body of men, not exceeding three hundred in number, named by the king to be his advisers. It could not meet unless the king summoned it; when it had met it could not give advice on any sub- ject except the particular subjects on which the king desired its opinion; and when the advice of the senate had been given, the king was free to follow it or not as he chose. The senate then had no power of compelling the king to adopt or abstain from adopting any course of action. But if there was a vacancy in the kingly office, the senate took the initiative in finding a successor. It named certain persons to act as interreges, or interim kings; they were to succeed one another as kings pro forma, each holding the title of interrex for a few days. The only function that was expected of them was the nomina- tion of a man for the office of permanent king ; and any one of the interreges except the first was empowered to perform this function. As soon as a person had been designated for the kingly office, his name was submitted to the assembled burgesses, who, if they approved him, gave their sanction to his title by a decision known as lex cv/riata} The burgesses were divided into thirty cur ice or 1 Interreges, as is well known, were frequently employed under the republic for filling vacancies in the consulship. The lex curiata was habitually passed to confirm elections of magistrates so late as the time of Cicero. See Cicero, Ad. Fam., i. 9, 25, written 54 B.C. no ROME [CH. VII. wards, and in their assembly each curia had one vote. Hence it was that a decision passed by them was Patrician known as a lex curiata, or a law passed burgesses, jjy tj^e curiae. Their opportunities for political activity must have been very few : for they could not vote on anything unless it had been pro- posed for their acceptance by a king. The plebeians were in some way appended to the curise,^ but without voting power. The most noteworthy feature in the government of Rome under the kings, is that the kingship was purely Elective ^^ elective office. We shall hereafter find kingship, many instances of elective kingship ; and I take this early opportunity of remarking that an elective kingship is not necessarily a weak kingship. The kings of Rome were elective but very powerful ; so were the Roman Emperors, and the Doges of Venice till the twelfth century. Nor, on the other hand, can it be said that elective kings are always powerful: the German Emperors in the fourteenth century were elective but very weak, and so were the Kings of Poland. The foregoing brief statement may suffice to give some idea on the form of government in the kingly Servius period. The political arrangements re- Tuiuus. mained unchanged throughout the reign of Servius TuUius; but he made some changes in the military and social organisation which must now be noticed. They are highly analogous to the changes made by Cleisthenes in Attica, except that they did ' Dionysins, ri. 89, 1. OH. VII.] ARMY 111 not produce any immediate change in the political system. The object of the Servian military organisation was to obtain regular service from the plebeians. In this organisation the wealthiest of the Komans _. ° _ The army formed eighteen centurice or hundreds of made by cavalry : six of these centuries contained ^"''"^• none but patricians, the remaining twelve probably consisted mainly of plebeians. The remainder of the Roman people furnished a hundred and seventy-five centuries for an army serving on foot ; a hundred and seventy centuries were composed of regular combat- ants, two were engineers, two were hornblowers and trumpeters, and one consisted of supernumeraries. The whole arrangement of the infantry was designed for fighting in the order of the phalanx — that is to say, in large masses of men several ranks deep which tried to overpower the enemy by their weight. The design of Servius was to arrange the infantry in four phalanxes. Each phalanx was to have a front of five hundred men and a depth of seven ranks. For making an effective phalanx it was essential to have the best-armed men in the few ranks nearest the front : and this fact dictated the Servian system. Servius was able to provide eighty centuries qualified by the amount of their possessions to arm themselves well, and to fight in the front ranks. These eighty centuries were called the first classis, or ' summoning,' and they filled the front four ranks in the four phalanxes. After them came a second, a third, and a fourth class with twenty centuries each : these were placed in the fifth, sixth. 112 ROME [CH. VII. and seventh ranks, and completed the phalanxes. There was, however, also a fifth class containing thirty centuries : it is clear that Dionysius is right in saying that they did not stand in the phalanxes, because their number exceeded what was required for one rank and was not enough for two. The result of the whole organisation was to divide the Roman people into classes according to military efficiency, and there- fore, incidentally, according to wealth. The first class contained eighteen centuries of cavalry and eighty of infantry : according to Livy, it also contained the two centuries of engineers. The total number of centuries was a hundred and ninety-three, and more than half the total number were in the first class.^ Servius also added to the strength of Eome by building the walls and gates of the city. The wall was of great strength : the remnant of it City walls , . , , , , and four which has recently been disinterred near urban tribes. j.]^g railway Station, is made of great square blocks in layers. The lowest layer, as I have observed by pacing the wall, is thirteen feet thick ; each succeeding layer is thinner than the one below it, so that each side of the wall is cut in steps like a face of the Great Pyramid, but far steeper. The building of the wall may have led him to a ^ The descriptions of the Servian army are in Livy, i. 43, and Dionysius, iv. 16, 17. Even after reading all that Marqiiardt says (ROm. Staatsverw. , edition 1, vol. ii. pages 315-317) I cannot find any serious divergence between the two authors in regard to the general arrangement of the classes within a phalanx. The only divergence even of minor character has reference to the weapons borne by the fourth class. CH. VII.] EXPULSION OF TAKQUIN 113 social change which afterwards had important results. He instituted local tribes as Cleisthenes afterwards did in Attica. The area of the city was divided into four districts, and the owners of the soil in each district, whether they were patricians or plebeians, were formed into a separate tribe. After the good rule of Servius came the tyranny of Tarquin the Proud. The overthrow of the tyranny was brought about in consequence of the Expulsion outrage perpetrated by Sextus the son of of Tarquin. Tarquin against Lucretia, the wife of his cousin Lucius of Collatia. The army of the citizens immediately assumed political functions: they deposed Tarquin, who chanced to be absent from Rome, and then, assembling in their centuries, proceeded to elect two men to be their magistrates, and discharge the functions which had hitherto belonged to the king. The political action of the army was a most natural sequel to the military organisation of Servius, and the two events taken together furnish an exemplification of the general rule that in an expansive city state the employment of the common folk in warfare soon leads to their admission to political privileges. We have already had occasion to notice one example of this rule in Attic history. The Roman example runs parallel with it. In Attica Cleisthenes made his citizen army and gave them political rights at once ; at Rome Servius made the army, and political power fell into its possession as soon as there was a great opportunity for the use of it. 114 ROME [CH. vii. (2) The Supremacy of the Patrician Order, LASTING ABOUT SIXTEEN YeARS. There is no doubt that Tarquin had oppressed both the patricians and the plebeians, and both orders combined to drive him out. But after a few years it was found that the patricians had got all the gain, and the plebeians were worse off than they had been under the tyrant. After the revolution in which Tarquin was expelled the government of Rome contained the three elements Tripartite usually found in an expansive city state, government, namely magistrates, senate, and people. The circumstances, however, in which the Romans were placed compelled them to give unusually large powers to the magistrates : they were surrounded by dangerous enemies, and needed powerful commanders. The result was that though they had got rid of their king, they kept the kingly imperium or supreme command and entrusted it to their magistrates. The constitution, then, was one in which the powers of the magistrates were almost unlimited: and all the magistrates were patricians. The magistrates were two consuls and on occasion a dictator, who held office simultaneously with the Magistrates °°^s"ls, but with Superior power. The almost consuls Were elected by the citizens omnipotent. i . . . m, arranged m centuries. They were succes- sors to the kingly dignity, and possessed the kingly imperium ; but in practice their power was somewhat CH. VII.] EULE OF THE PATEICIANS 115 less than the king's had been. The facts which diminished their power were these : they held office only for a year ; ^ neither of them could inflict any judicial sentence if his colleague protested against it ; - and there was some sort of rule enabling citizens to appeal (jprovocare) from the sentence of a consul to the judgment of the people assembled in centuries.^ A dictator was not elected but named. In time of danger it was usual for one of the consuls, on being requested to do so by the senate, to name a dictator or TYiagister populi, a single magistrate who held the whole of the old kingly imperium for six months. A dictator was more powerful than the consuls, both because he had no colleague to restrain him, and because it was certain that there was no provocatio or appeal to the people against his sentences.* As to the senate, it may suffice to say that it had the same constitution and powers as it had under the kinsfs. The members of the senate were Senate, now selected by a consul : ^ the advice of the senate was now asked by a consul or a dictator : and it still continued to be advice only. It is said that immediately after the fall of Tarquin a consul added a hundred and sixty-four plebeians to the senate ; ^ but it appears that the senate acted steadily in the interest of the patricians. 1 Livy, ii. 1, 7. ^ Livy, ii. 18, 8. ■' Livy (ii. 8, 2) abstains from saying -what the rule was. From his words in ii. 27, 12 it would appear that it was not a very effec- tive restriction on a resolute consul. * Livy, ii. 18, 8. 5 Festus, De Significatu, quaternion xii. 24, p. 254 in Mtiller's edition: P. Valerius Cons, ex plebe adiegit in numerum senatorum 0. et Ix. et iiii. 116 KOME AND MONS SACEE [ch. vii. The only important assembly of the people was the one that was arranged in centuries. Every one of the hundred and ninety-three centuries had arranged in o^e vote ; and as the first class voted first military an(j j^^d a mai'ority of the total number of centuries. . i, , i ■ i i • votes, it usually happened m the election of a consul that the votes of the remaining four classes were not recorded. The assembly of the thirty curiae still continued to exist, but it soon sank into insig- nificance. In this earliest republican constitution of Kome the patricians had all the advantage, since they alone Secession of could hold the offices of consul or the Piebs. dictator. During the life of Tarquin, which was prolonged for fifteen years after his expul- sion, they used their power with moderation ; but as soon as the fear of him was removed they began to behave as the Eupatridse had behaved in Attica. The plebeians, after some vain attempts to obtain justice or mercy, seceded from Kome and established themselves on Mons Sacer, a hill three miles distant, and assumed the character of an independent community. (3) The Contest between the Two Orders, lasting to 343 b.c. The separate existence of the two independent city states of the patricians and the plebeians ThePlebs ,., , , , f -r ■ • was an inde- did not last long : Livy m vague terms pendent state criyes it a duration of some davs. The for a time. ° . . •' separation into two states was obviously disadvantageous. The inhabitants of both were CH. VII.] TWO INDEPENDENT STATES 117 Romans, and all Romans were alike exposed to attack from the Etruscans, the iEquians, and pos- sibly the Latins. So long as they were divided into two states they had little chance of defend- ing themselves successfully : the patricians were generals without soldiers, and the plebeians were an army without commanders. And so it came about that the disunion was speedily ended by voluntary agreement between the two states of Rome and the Mens Sacer. But though the re- union of the two communities was soon effected, the mere fact that the plebs had for a short time been an independent state and only joined itself with the patricians under compact was one which introduced most unusual features into the Roman constitution. The unusual character of the Roman institutions for about a century and a half after the great secession to the Mens Sacer affords a sufficient reason why I should not trouble the was a state reader with their technicalities. There is within the nothing else closely resembling them in all history, and the details are useless for purposes of comparison. But though the details may be neglected, it is worth while to point out how the plebs came to be a state within the state. There are other instances in history where there has been a state within a state, and some of these may perhaps be the more intelligible after a consideration of the position occupied in the Roman republic by the plebs after its return from the Mons Sacer. 118 ROME [CH. VII. The reason why the plebs attained the character of a state within the state was that the union of the communities of Rome and the Mons Sacer union oTthe ^^^ brought about by bargaining between Mons Sacer the two independent bodies, and the plebs insisted that before it would consent to return it must be assured an organisation of its own independent of the patricians. It ordinarily results from a union of states brought about by bargaining that there is a state within the state ; for any of the parties to the bargain which fears that after the union it may be oppressed demands an independent organisation for its own protection, and so comes to be what is known as a state within the state. The union between Rome and the Mons Sacer was hastily patched up and was a clumsy makeshift. It would therefore be absurd to pretend that was like it bears any close resemblance to the a federal elaborate compacts in which the union of union. ... communities m a modern federal state are expressed. Yet it does resemble a federal union in one or two respects which are worthy of attention, though in much of its character it is to be contrasted with such a union rather than compared. One result that usually occurs when communities unite voluntarily after bargaining is that the state Co-ordinate which arises from the union, has not one governments, gypreme government, but has governments in the plural. There must be a government for the conduct of business which affects all the parties to the bargain, such as war and foreign policy; and there CH. VII.] CO-ORDINATE GOVERNMENTS 119 must also be a government for the protection of any of the contracting parties which desires to have such a government. This result occurred in the hasty union of Rome and the Mons Sacer no less truly than in the careful compacts -which found federal states in modern times. There was in the Roman republic after the union a government for managing the affairs common to the whole state, such as war and foreign policy, and its officers were those known as curule magistrates — a term which will be explained shortly. There was also a government for the protection of the plebs, as the plebs desired such a government: its officers were the tribunes and sediles elected by the plebs from out of its own body ; the plebs also, as a state within the state, obtained the right of meeting together for the election of its officers and the discus- sion of plebeian interests. The patricians did not need any separate government for their own affairs : they obtained a monopoly of office in the government which managed the interests of the whole state, and thus the government of the whole state was also a government which attended to the interests of the patricians. There were then only two governments at Rome, and not three. One was the government of the whole state, which in the Latin language was entitled jjopulus Bomanus ; the other was the government of the state within the state, which was known as plebs Romana. The two governments were co-ordinate in the same sense as in the United States the federal government at Washington and the government of New York at Albany are co-ordinate. Neither could 120 ROME [CH. VII. coerce or abolish the other; and it was no more practicable for the government of the populus Romanus to destroy the organisation of the plebs Bomana than it would be in the United States for the federal government to deprive New York of its right to send two senators to Congress. Thus far, then, there was some analogy between the Roman Republic after the end of the great secession _ , and a modern federation. If we try to Terms of n t ■ union ill pursue the analogy any further we find it defined. impossible. In all respects other than those above mentioned the ancient republic and a modern federation stand not in similarity but in contrast. In a federal union the powers of the central or federal officers are carefully limited and defined by expressing in words what acts they may do : at Rome there was no such definition of the powers of the curule magistrates. In a federal union it is settled that all the states which contract to unite together shall take part in managing the federal or central governments : at Rome the patricians tacitly received a complete monopoly of office in the government of the whole state. In a federation there is always a supreme law-court endowed with authority to interpret the exact meaning of the rules which settle what acts the federal officers may do and what they may not : in Rome there could be no such court, for there were no rules to interpret. In short, in a federation all sorts of precautions are taken to guard against conflicts between the co-ordinate govern- ments : at Rome no such precautions were adopted. CH. VII.] DISCORD 121 and for several generations after the great secession the internal history of the republic consists of an endless duel between two evenly matched antagonists, the government of the populus and the government of the plebs. The records that have come down to us about the early years of the strife between the two orders are probably untrustworthy and are certainly , most wearisome to read. It will suffice to amend here to say that after forty or fifty years ^ ^'^'"^' the contest became intolerable, and it was agreed by the two orders to elect ten commissioners, the Decemviri, to be the sole magistrates in the state, to reform the law and to propose a new constitution. The decemvirs of the first year did their work well : those of the second abused their powers and were overthrown through a tumult and a new secession of the plebs. This time, also, the plebeians demanded conditions: it was eventually agreed that the two governments of "the populus and the plebs, which had been put into abeyance during the rule of the decemvirs, should be restored, and left to continue their strife almost under the same conditions as before. A convenient point of time for taking a general view of the two governments of Kome may be found about twenty years after the overthrow of '' •' Governments the decemvirate. The government of the of the Populus whole state had three component parts, p^'^,*''^ magistrates, senate, and an assembly : the government of the state within the state had only 122 ROME [CH. VII. two, namely magistrates and an assembly of the plebeians. The macristrates of the whole state were two consuls, occasionally a dictator for six months, and once in , , p . . every five years two censors. All these Curuie magistrates had the imperium or right to Magistrates. j • j. i r j.i • • r command : m token oi their possession ot it they used a sella curulis or chair of state, and for that reason they were called curuie magistrates. There was, as we have seen, no rule settling that they could make commands only of certain kinds : all of them could make commands of every kind. The commands of a dictator must in all cases be obeyed, unless perchance they were resisted by rebellion. The other curuie magistrates, though they could issue commands of every kind, were subject to a strange restriction, whereby all their commands if issued within certain local limits could be deprived of validity and coercive force. The area within which they could thus be reduced to powerlessness comprised the city of Rome and a precinct extending to a width of one mile outside the walls. When they were out- side the one-mile limit, they were absolute: as soon as they came within it, they were subject to a restriction of a most drastic character, as will shortly be explained. The remaining two elements in the government of the whole state were the senate and the assembly of Senate and the populus. Of the senate I need only Centuries. g^y that it retained the same constitution as it had in the earliest days of the republic, and the CH. VII.] POPULUS ROMANUS 123 senators were still nominated by the consuls.^ The assembly of the populus was the comitia centuriata arranged in a hundred and ninety- three centuries. The patricians supplied only six centuries and had only six votes : the remaining votes, a hundred and eighty-seven in number, were given by the plebeians. As Servius had arranged the peoples in centuries according to military efficiency, and therefore inciden- tally according to wealth, the whole plebeian vote was controlled by the men of substance among the plebeians. The men of substance were yeomen owning the freehold of a farm adequate for the comfortable support of a family and one or two slaves. They were numerically but a small fraction of the whole plebeian population, but they supplied the eighty centuries in the first class of the infantry as well as twelve cen- turies of horsemen. Their ninety-two votes were nearly half the total of a hundred and ninety-three. The four lower classes of the plebeians usually followed the lead of the first class. The assembly, then, was admirably adapted to give expression to the wishes of the most independent and intelligent members of the plebeian order, and it looks at first sight as if it might have removed the grievances of the plebs by electing a plebeian to be consul. There was, however, one circumstance which made it entirely incapable of ^ See p. 115. The duty of nominating senators remained with the consuls for nearly a century and a half after the age of the Deoem- virate, when about 312 B.C. the Lex Ovinia transferred it to the censors. Festas, p. 246 ; Mommsen, i?. Stoa^srecfe, vol. ii. under the head Die Oensur : Aufstellung der Senatsliste (in edition of 1874, p. 395, note 2). 124 EOME [CH. VII. any such innovation. Its president was always a curule magistrate and therefore a patrician, and in his capacity of president he had the power of refusing to receive votes for any candidate whom he declared to be incapable of being elected.^ The government of the plebs comprised only two elements, namely magistrates and a popular assembly. The magistrates of the plebs were tribunes |2) Plebs : ^^^ 8ediles,the tribunes being beyond com- parison the more important. The powers of the tribunes had grown immensely since their first institution. In the original compact after the seces- sion it was merely settled that their persons were inviolable, and they might protect citizens against sentences of magistrates. We know also that the plebs collectively made a vow that they would join in taking vengeance on any one who used force against a tribune; and we can see also that it was understood from the beginning that the tribunes had no power except within the city of Rome and in its precinct, which extended a mile outside the walls. From an origin so seemingly humble the powers of the tribunes had by the time of which I am speak- ing, shortly after the fall of the Decemviri, become very comprehensive. The tribunes had very little power to command, but great power to forbid. Within the one-mile limit, by their intercessio or interven- tion, they could prohibit any command of any other magistrate, and if a command had been given they could deprive it of validity. They had, then, a power ' Livy, iii. 21, 8. CH. VII.] PLEBS ROMANA 125 of annulling any harsli sentences pronounced by magistrates ; and they had a more formidable weapon in their power to prevent the levy of a Roman army. There was no permanent army, and in almost every year a new army had to be enrolled. The enrolment took place on the Capitol/ and so the tribunes could stop the levy if they chose. Besides their intercessio the tribunes had other powers : their power of pro- tecting citizens was so highly valued by the people that they were forbidden to be absent a whole day from Rome, and were bound to keep the doors of their houses open through the night ; they could summon gatherings of the plebs, and these gather- ings could propose resolutions and put them to the vote. The assembly of the plebeians was known as con- cilium plebis. The rural territory of Rome had now been divided into seventeen local tribes, concilium so that with the four urban tribes of P'ebis. Servius there were twenty- one in all. The freehold lands of the citizens were enrolled according to locality in one or other of these tribes; and thus every landowner, whether patrician or plebeian, was a member of some tribe. The concilium plebis con- sisted of those landowners who were plebeians, and in the concilium each tribe had one vote. The concilium elected the tribunes and the sediles. Resolutions when proposed to it were called Roga- tions ; if they were accepted by it they were Plebiscita or resolutions of the plebs. Many doubts about the ' Polybius, vi. 19, 6, and Livy, xxvi 31, 1). 126 ROME [CH. VII. binding effect of plebiscita at different parts of Roman history have been raised by loose state- ments of ancient historians, who at three very different epochs say it was enacted that plebiscita should be binding on all Roman citizens. It is certain that from the first secession of the plebs to the Mons Sacer to the end of Roman republican history resolutions of the plebs were binding on all plebeians ; and it also seems certain, from the success of the patricians in preventing the Licinian Roga- tions, after they had become plebiscita, from having the force of law till the senate had sanctioned them, that, at the time (twenty years after the Decemvirate) at which I am taking my survey of the constitution, plebiscita were not binding on any others than plebeians till they received a sanction from some body which could speak on behalf of the patricians or of both orders together.' The plan of limiting the tribunal power by setting merely local bounds to the exercise of it had the Conflict of result, that while the curule magistrates powers were absolute in the open country, the avoTdeif by tribunes had in the city such a marked setting- local supremacy that they could always reduce limitations. , i .i, , , , government to a standstill, though they could not govern themselves. The arrangement is the more strange because the tribunes, who were supreme in the city, were elected by the country folk, ' The question of the binding force of plebiscita is extremely well discussed by Mr. Straohan Davidson in Smith's 2)ic<. Antiqq., third edition, article Plehiscitnm, vol. ii. p. 437. oil. VII. 1 GOVERNMENTS AT STRIFE 127 who had seventeen votes out of twenty-one in the concilium plebis, while in the election, of curule magistrates, who were absolute in the country, there is every reason to suppose that the townsfolk, owing to superior organisation, took the leading part. We have observed that in the expansive city state of Athens there was a conflict between the privileged class of the Eupatridse and the unprivi- strife of the leged common folk, that the privileged orders, class found it well to make concessions, and that the conflict was ended by the making of a government of compromise. In Kome also there was a conflict between the privileged patricians and the unprivileged plebs ; but the strife was far bitterer than at Athens, because the plebs, though it was excluded from bearing office in the government of the whole state, had a government of its own, and the contest was fought out, not merely between two classes but between two governments. The extreme bitterness of the strife at Kome makes it needless for me to speak of its details, because it was a unique strife, and is useless for comparison with any other. But the motive which induced the patricians to make concessions was the same as had influenced the Eupatridse : they wanted zealous and willing service in the army from the unprivileged class, and could not get it unless th,ey gave them privileges. In order to trace the connection between the wars of the Romans and the extension of privileges to the plebs, it is. necessary to note what the wars were, and when the chief concessions were made. For about 128 REASONS FOR [ch. vii. three generations after the secession of the plebs the Romans, with the aid of contingents from their Reasons for allies the Latins, waged a war nearly compromise, every summer against the Volscians and Jj]quians. These wars did not lead to any con- siderable conquest of territory on either side, but they were exhausting from their perpetual recur- rence. About ninety years after the secession the Romans undertook the formidable enterprise of the capture of Veii, the great stronghold of the Etruscans. It cost them a siege of ten years, and compelled them for the first time to keep the legions under arms, winter and summer alike. In the year 390 b.c.i the Romans suffered the greatest humiliation that ever befell them. A great horde of Gauls came down from the valley of the Po and captured all the city of Rome except the citadel of the Capitol. In the following year the Gauls went away again ; but the Romans learned that the Latins, who had for ages been their allies and in some degree their dependents, had declared that the alliance was at an end. The years that followed must have been years of great difficulty for the Romans, and even perhaps of peril. The Gauls renewed their inroads, though they came no more to Rome itself; the Romans had no Latin contingent to help them ; they could not venture to reduce the Latins to obedience by force ; all they could do in that direction was to threaten the Latin ' I have designedly abstained from mentioning dates before this year, because I do not think the earlier part of the chronology of the Roman annalists is trustworthy. CH. VII.] COMPROMISE 129 city of Tusculum and compel it to accept incorpora- tion, on terms which we do not know precisely, in the Roman commonwealth. After a lapse, however, of some forty or fifty years Rome was strong again, and in the year 342 e.g. it was able to attack the Sam- nites, and two years later to engage in a general war against the Latin federation, which was a greater undertaking than any it had yet attempted. It was during the imminence of this war that the patricians finally withdrew from their attitude of resistance to the reasonable demands of the plebs ; and from the moment they did so, the period of sharp strife between the government of the populus and the government of the plebs was at an end. During the period, then, of about a century and a half between the secession of the plebs and the great struggle with the Latins, the Romans were engaged in a series of wars which steadily increased in magnitude. As their wars grew in scale, so did their need for the zealous services of the plebeian soldiers, and the necessity of making them contented by redressing their grievances. While their wars were petty, the concessions were trivial; but when the pressure of foreign enemies became severe, sub- stantial privileges were granted. There were three epochs in which the patricians yielded something to the plebs. The first occurred in the midst of the petty wars with the Volscians and ^quians shortly after the time of the decemvirs. The second came in 367 e.g. during the period . of the great pressure of foreign danger, when 130 CONCESSIONS MADE [CH. vii. the Gauls repeated their attacks and the Latins refused to give assistance. The third was in 342 B.C. when a great war with the Samnites was in progress, and a greater war with the Latins was near at hand. The grievances of the plebs were too manifold to set down in a catalogue. Some were social, some Grievances economic, and one was political. The of the plebs. political grievance, which was felt more continuously than any of the other hardships, con- sisted in the exclusion of plebeians from all the curule magistracies. It was regarded as an injustice not only by the rich plebeians, whom it shut out from military command and from the highest dignity in the state, but also by the poor, who felt that they were more likely to be treated with consideration by a commander belonging to their own order than they would be under a patrician general. Concessions "^^^ Concessions made by the patricians made by the at the three epochs that have been named patricians. .,-, ■, , ■, Will now be enumerated. 1. During their petty wars of early times they merely yielded on two points, and did not go nearly g^^i far enough to satisfy the plebeians. They concessions agreed that intermarriage between the orders should be legal, and they took a short step, but only a short one, towards remedying the political grievance. This step they took by putting the consulship in commission : instead of two consuls there were to be other officers (three, four, or six in number) called military tribunes with OH. VII.] BY THE PATEICIANS 131 consular power, and plebeians were made eligible as military tribunes. The new arrangement did not please the plebeians, and the division of command between several officers led to diminished efficiency of the army in warfare. 2. In 367 B.C. the patricians agreed to the famous Licinian Kogations. They were called rogations because that was the proper name for ucinian proposals that were first mooted in the Rogations, concilium plebis. These particular proposals were made by a tribune named Licinius, and met with the hearty approval of the plebeian assembly. Two of them were economic in character and were designed for the relief of plebeians who had lost their farms through the invasions of the Gauls and had been reduced to penury ; the third dealt boldly with the political question, and ran to the effect that hence- forth consuls, not military tribunes, should be elected, and that one consul must in every year be a plebeian.^ The proposals for several years continued to be mere plebiscita, without binding force. In 367 B.C. the senate and the whole body of the patricians gave their assent to them, and the plebiscita were turned into laws. In return for this boon the plebeians agreed that the consuls should no longer have the administration of civil justice in the city, and that this function should be transferred to a new magistrate, a praetor, who must always be a patrician.^ 3. The third Licinian Law would have sufficed to ' Livy, vi. 35, 4, 5. '- Livy, vi. 42, 11-14. 132 ROME [CH. VII. put an end to the strife between the orders, if it had been faithfully observed. In several of the years Third between 355 and 343 the patricians were Licinian foolish enough to get it evaded and to July secure the election of two consuls from observed, their own order. In the elections for the year 342, when the Samnite war had already begun, they desisted from their folly, and from that time forth one of the consuls was always a plebeian. 4. The Expansion of Rome and the Complete Reconciliation of the Obdees, 343-275 b.c. The expansion of Rome, which began with the Samnite and Latin wars and continued till 275 b.c., when the Romans were masters of Italy, Expansion •' ' conduced to contributed very largely to make the reconciliation. jj^Qj^jg^^ g^j^^^g ^ United community and to ensure it a well-balanced constitution. In the wars of conquest the common folk furnished the soldiers, and as their willing service was most urgently needed, the consent of the rich was given to all their rea- sonable demands, and indeed to one which seems unreasonable. The conquests put an end to extreme economic inequalities, as large portions of the con- quered lands were distributed among the Roman citizens, so that the destitute, if they were willing to be industrious, could rise to the level of peasant pro- prietors. Lastly, the spreading out of the Roman citizens over a large area, and the consequent formation of new outlying groups of them, tended CH. VII.] EXPANSION 133 to establish that sort of equipoise between the populations of the city and the rural territory which is characteristic of a complex city state, and which ensures in such states an equitable distri- bution of political power among the classes of the community. The task of dealing wisely with conquered com- munities and conquered territory is perhaps the most difficult that occurs in the whole range of settlements politics. The Eomans at the ending of of Romans 1 /. , 1 1-1 ,1 1 and Latins each 01 the wars which gave them the on conquered mastery of Italy performed it admirably, '^"^s. Their plan of dealing with conquered towns was to isolate each of them completely by breaking any ties which had hitherto united them together, to insist that none of them should have any relations with any external community except Eome, and then to decide in each case what the relations with Rome should be. As to the land in conquered communities, the greater part of it had been in private ownership : this they left to its old proprietors ; but whatever had been common or public land they took into their own hands and gave it out to Roman citizens, who were thus tempted to settle upon it. There were, however, certain spots which they treated differently. Whenever a town was of great strategic importance they made a more formal occupation of it, which must have involved some expropriation of old private owners : they established in the place a large body of settlers who obtained advantageous conditions on the understanding that they and their children after 134 ORGANISATION [cH. Vil. them would act as a garrison and hold the place in the Koman interest. If the town thus occupied was on the sea-coast the settlers retained the full rights of Roman citizenship, and could vote at a Roman election and could hold a Roman magistracy ; if the place lay inland, the settlers were not called Romans but Latins: it seems to be certain that the Latin settlers had no sort of Roman citizenship, but they certainly enjoyed such substantial advantages that the Romans had no difficulty in attracting men to the settlements which possessed only the Latin privileges. The relations that were set up between the Romans and the many Italian communities that they con- itaUan quered need not be discussed at length, communities, It may, however, be well to note that in allies, in fact the period now before us the Romans did subjects. jjQt^ except in very few instances, admit the conquered to any sort of Roman citizenship, either cwm suffragio or sine suffragio. It was not till after 200 B.c. that they took to incorporating the conquered in large numbers.^ During the period of expansion they relied on their garrisons to maintain their hold on Italy. The conquered communities were dignified with the euphemistic appellations of civitates fcederatce or socii populi Romani, but in truth they were merely client states dependent on a powerful patron, and were as far from being equal allies of Rome as are the native princes of India from being equals with the British Empire. 1 Marquardt, lidmuche Staatsverwaltung, i, 29-34. CH. VII. J OF CONQUESTS 135 The making and maintenance of a system capable of keeping the conquered peoples in fairly contented subiection to Kome was a work that ,„ , ^ '' . _ Work done needed wise foresight and consistent by the statesmanship. Such foresight and states- ™^*^' manship could not be found except in some per- manent organ of government, and in Rome the only permanent organ was the senate. On the senate accordingly devolved the whole work of planting the garrisons (colonice) and dealing with the client states, and, as the senate performed its task admirably, it followed as a matter of course that the influence of that assembly, which had been great before, now rose so high as to give it a position of pre-eminence in the Roman government. From a comparison of the history of Rome in this period with that of Venice from 1172 a.d. to the end of the Middle Ages, it may be inferred that when a city state undertakes the intricate business of managing dependencies, it needs some permanent advisory body resembling the Roman senate. The Roman senate had probably all the greater authority because it had no power : every magistrate was legally free to neglect its advice, but as a matter of fact its advice was invariably asked and followed in every question of importance that arose in any department of the government. The concessions to the plebeians, which coincided in time with the conquest of Italy, may be briefly summed up. By the year 300 b.c. aU Lex magistracies, as well as the religious Hortensia. dignities of the pontificate and augurship, were acces- 136 > LEX HORTENSIA [CH. vii. sible to plebeians.! Shortly afterwards there was a last conflict between the orders, which was ended in 287 B.C. by the very important Lex Hortensia. We do not know from what causes it arose, because the eleventh book of Livy has been lost; but from an ancient epitome of that book we learn that the plebs was for some reason so discontented that it seceded to the Janiculum, a suburb of Rome on the north side of the river Tiber, but was induced to return by a plebeian dictator, Hortensius. From the jurists of much later centuries. Gains and Pomponius, we learn the nature of the law by which the dictator appeased the discontent of the plebeians. By the Lex Hor- tensia it was ordained that all plebiscita or resolu- tions passed in the concilium plebis should have the force of laws and be binding on plebeians and patricians alike.^ The Lex Hortensia of 287 B.C. marked the end of all discord between the orders. When the strife was ended the plebeians had two advan- was the more tages over the patricians: all offices were favoured open to the plebeians, but the tribuneship and plebeian sedileship were closed against patricians ; and the plebeians in their conciliuvi had the power of legislating for both orders, while there was no patrician assembly that possessed any similar power. 1 Livy, X. 6-8, especially x. 8, 8 and x. 9, 2. ^ The Digest of Justinian, i. 2, 2, 8, in a long quotation from Pomponius. CH. VII.] CONCORD OF THE ORDERS. 137 5. The United Roman Commonwealth. 287 B.C.— 201 B.C. After the Hortensian Law had been passed, the whole body of the Roman burgesses were a single community, all having the same interests and living under a single government. As they had spread themselves over a wide area, and ruled over large populations akin to themselves, whom they might soon think of taking into their own commonwealth, they furnish a remarkable instance of an expanded and expanding city state; and they lived under one of those balanced constitutions which are characteristic of such states. In proof of these assertions I shall give some par- ticulars concerning the structure of their common- wealth, the populations subject to them, and the nature of their constitution. The point of time for which such particulars can best be given lies just before the outbreak of the great war against Hannibal. The territory occupied by fully qualified Roman citizens comprised those parts of Italy where Roman farmers had settled as private individuals, j^. . . and also a few towns along the sea-coast of Roman where garrisons of burgesses had been planted. The districts in which there was at least a good sprinkling of Roman settlers comprised (1) the southern part of Etruria, which became Roman territory after the capture of Veil about 395 b.g. ; 138 CITIZENS AND SUBJECTS [ch. vii. (2) Latium, the valley of the Liris and Campania, in which allotments were made in 338, at the end of the great Latin war ; and (3) Picenum, a large district on the Adriatic Sea, which had been conquered and distributed among the citizens in 232.^ The maritime garrisons were nine or ten in number;^ the furthest distant were Sinuessa, not far from Capua, and Sena Gallica, just beyond the northern boundary of Picenum, both of them more than a hundred miles from Rome. The non-Roman population of Italy was, as we have seen, divided into two classes — Latini and civitates foederatce. The most important of the com- munities that bore the Latin name were thirty-three inland garrisons (colonice) of settlers.' They were scattered over all the middle parts of Italy from Ariminum to Psestum and Brundisium. All the population other than the Latins were counted as allies of the Romans. These allies were expected to furnish troops to the Romans, and were to that extent client states ; but still they were clients whom it was necessary for the Romans to treat in a con- ciliatory way, because it was desirable that they should furnish their contingents willingly, and those contingents should fight zealously; and they were for that reason in a far better position than if they had been tributaries. ' Polybius, ii. 21. ^ Marquardt, Staatsverwaltunr), i. 39. ^ For a list of them see MaiquarJt, Staatsverwaltung, vol. i. p. 49. Antium and Satritniin must be omitted. CH. VII.] GOVEENMENT 139 The work of government in the Koman common- wealth was shared between (1) the magis- ^ ^ ° Factors in trates, (2) the senate, and (3) the fully the Govern- qualified burgesses in their assemblies. '"^"'^' The magistracies were now very numerous : it does not seem necessary to specify the functions of each of them, as they had now ceased to come (i) into active conflict with one another. The Magistrates, distinction between curule and non-curule magistrates was still maintained. The curule magistrates were, as they had always been, those who had the imperium and were qualified to command an army in the field. The most important were the consuls, with occasionally a dictator over them, the censors and the prsetors. The dictator was named by a consul. The other curule magistrates were elected by the centuries. The important non-curule magistrates, the tribunes, and sediles were elected by the con- cilium plebis : the tribunes had the same powers as in earlier times, but, being in general satisfied with the conduct of the curule magistrates, no longer impeded them in the work of governing. The senate was by far the most influential organ in the government, and we must take (2) note of its composition and authority. Senate. The composition of the senate depended on the method of nominating senators. The censors every five years revised the list of senators, adding new names, and, if necessary, removing men guilty of disgraceful conduct.^ Until the battle of Cannse the ' Livy, xviii. Epitome, 140 GREAT INFLUENCE [ch. vii. censors were not bound by any rule or precedent in the choice of new senators, but as a matter of course they admitted men who had distinguished them- selves as magistrates. At Cannse, in 216 B.C., more than half the senators were killed, and it was neces- sary to adopt some rule in filling the vacancies. A dictator, M. Fabius Buteo, who was appointed to choose new senators, admitted all men who since the last census had filled any magistracy, whether curule or non-curule, and all who for distinction in battle had been allowed to adorn their houses with trophies, or had received a civic crown for saving the life of a comrade.^ The precedent which he then set was followed by the censors on future occasions. The authority of the senate may be shortly summed up by saying that it had the control of expenditure Powers of ^^^ ^1^ that naturally went with that the Senate, control.^ A practice had grown up under which no sum of money could be taken out of the treasury (except small sums for the regular and necessary expenditure of the consul) without a decree of the senate. Armed with the power of the purse, the senate controlled all departments of government. Their decrees settled all military expenditure, deter- mined in what regions campaigns should be under- taken, and, if they thought fit, what magistrates should be commanders. They could prolong the command of a general beyond his year of magistracy, '■ Livy, xxiii. 23, 5, 6. - Polybius, vi. 13, 15, and 17. These chapters are the chief sources of our knowledge of the power of the senate. CH. VII.] OF THE SENATE 141 and, when he had ended the war on which he was engaged, could give or withhold the honour of a triumph. Negotiations with foreign states were entirely in their hands, and they directed the whole external policy of the state. The assemblies of the people were three in num- ber : the concilium plebis, the comitia centuriata, and another which I have not had occa- (3) sion hitherto to mention, the comitia Three tributa. popular assemblies. The concilium plebis was what it had been long before, save that the plebs was now a larger body than it had been, and the number of tribes had increased up to thirty-five. The comitia centuriata still comprised a hundred and ninety-three centuries, but had been modified so that its organisation was no longer entirely in- dependent of the division of the people into tribes. The centuries of the first class were reduced from the number eighty, at which Servius fixed them, to seventy, and each of the thirty-five tribes had two centuries out of the seventy. Thus in the comitia centuriata for the election of consuls in 214 b.c. the century that voted first was one of the two that were taken from the tribe Aniensis.^ Probably in the other classes also some arrangement by tribes may have prevailed. The whole number of centuries was, as it had been, a hundred and ninety-three.^ 1 Livy, xxiv. 7, 12; xxiy. 8, 20. ^ Cicero, De Rep. ii. 22, 39, is manifestly speaking of tlie comitia in his own time, and he implies there were seventy centuries in the first class, and the total number was a hundred and ninety-three. 142 EQUILIBEIUM [ch. vii. In the third popular assembly, known as the comitia tributa, both patricians and plebeians were included, and were arranged according to their tribes, each of the thirty-five tribes having one vote. It seems likely that this assembly would be in the main influenced by nearly the same forces as the concilium plebis, but there was one clear distinction between them. The presiding officer in the comitia tributa was a curule magistrate ; ^ in the concilium plebis he was a tribune. All the three assemblies had elective and legislative work. The elections to all the greater magistracies were divided between the centuries and the concilium plebis, according as the magistracies were curule or non-curule ; some lesser magistrates were chosen in the comitia tributa. It is a strange fact that each of the three assem- blies had full and independent power to legislate. Avoidance ^^^ it seems Surprising that they did not of conflicts. pa,ss conflicting laws. We must, however, remember that no law could be proposed in any assembly except by the presiding magistrate; and magistrates were wont to get the approval of the senate before proposing a resolution. In case a magistrate neglected the established custom, and proposed a law which the senate disliked, it was easy to check him : the senate always had influence over a large part of the ten tribunes, and any tribune had power to prohibit the recalcitrant magistrate from putting his proposition to the vote. ' Mommsen, Staatsrecht, vol. iii. p. 322, proves this by quoting a law preserved by Frontinus, De Aquoeductibiis, 129. CH. VII.] OF THREE FACTORS 143 Now that I have finished my sketch of the Roman constitution during the second Punic War, I find that a word of comment may be desirable. In the course of the present chapter an opinion of three has been expressed that the Roman con- factors in the . . government, stitution at that time was a mixed and balanced form of government.^ This opinion has not been universally held ; on the contrary, some modern writers have spoken of the constitution as if it gave power solely to the senate. In support of my view that the Romans had a mixed constitution upheld through a very perfect equilibrium of the magistrates, senate, and people, it is needless to do more than remark that Polybius had no doubt about the matter, and he wrote several chapters to explain how complete was the inter-dependence of the three elements in the government. In regard to the senate, the substance of his words comes to this : the senate, though it had great authority, held that authority subject to the pleasure of the people ; and he proves this by observing that the people, in case they disapproved the policy of the senate, could at a blow deprive it of all its influence. The simple course lay open to them of electing one tribune of their own way of thinking, and that one tribune would be able, by using his right of intercessio, not only to prevent any resolution of the senate from taking effect, but even to prohibit the senate itself from holding a meeting.^ ' See above, p. 137. 2 Polybius, vi. 11-18, especially oh. 16. 144 LIMITATIONS [CH. vii. The Roman city state, in the final form which it attained during the war with Hannibal, gave an Limitations excellent government to the small com- of a city munity of men who enjoyed the full rights of citizens. These men having the jus suffragii cum, jure honorum could vote in the popular assemblies, and were capable of being elected to any magistracy: the government was both orderly and subject to control by the public opinion of the citizens. But was the city state capable of giving good government to all Italy ? We know that in the century after the Hannibalic war it governed Italy very badly, and that early in the next century the Italian allies rose in revolt: the bad government, however, occurred mainly in the time when Rome had acquired provinces beyond the sea. If the Roman dominions had been limited to Italy, was it likely that the city state could give good govern- ment to the whole peninsula ? It was a first necessary condition of good govern- ment through the peninsula that there should be community of interest over the whole area. This first condition was realised, and the Romans recog- nised that it had been realised, when, before quelling the revolt of the Italian allies, they assented in the year 90 B.C. to laws conferring Roman citizenship on all Italians who had not rebelled, or who submitted. There is little doubt that, if the Roman territory had been confined to Italy, the whole peninsula would have attained common interests and received the Roman suffrage earlier than it did. CH. VIII.] OF A CITY STATE U5 But what good would the Italians get from the Roman citizenship? Very little. If indeed an inhabitant of a distant Italian town gained a magis- tracy at Rome he could confer benefits on his native place, and so the jus honorum might be helpful to an outlying place on the extremely rare occasions when one of its inhabitants was promoted to a Roman magistracy. The jus suffragii, on the other hand, except to those places which lay within easy reach of Rome, was absolutely useless. The only use of a right of voting is to enable the voter to influence public opinion and the government. In the Roman state any citizen had a right to influence public opinion, but only on condition that he attended an assembly at Rome : what benefit could the right confer on an inhabitant of Brundisium ? If a fair system of representative institutions had been introduced, the hardships suffered' by the outlying districts would have been remedied, but the Roman Republic would have ceased to be a city state. In a country with a just representative system all localities are equal to begin with, or tend to become so; in a city state supremacy is rooted in one unchangeable capital. In mediseval England, where all localities were equal, representative institutions grew spontaneously; in ancient Italy they could not be thought of unless the city of Rome was prepared to forfeit its supremacy in the peninsula. CHAPTER VIII COMPLEX CITY STATES Every complex city state is formed by the conquest and assimilation of cities. Both conquest and assimilation, where cities are concerned, city states ^^^ tasks of extreme difficulty; neither artificial at g^n be performed in blind obedience to instinct ; both require elaborate planning and skilful design. Since, then, complex city states result from processes needing deliberate design, they are in their origination artificial products. We cannot expect so much uniformity in products of human art as in things made instinctively; and so we have no reason to look for the same uniformity in complex city states as we have found in the forms of tribal communities and in simple city states. But if the making of an artificial object is ex- tremely difficult, there may be very few ways in which it can be made successfully. If there is only one way of making them, the individual artificial objects may be almost as much alike as natural specimens of a single species. Complex city states are very much alike. Whence CH. VIII.] CAUSES OP SIMILARITY 147 comes their similarity ? Are they aUke because there is only one way in which their designers can make them? No; this is not the reason; for at their beginnings they are by no means pre- g^^. cisely alike. Athens at no early stage of subsequently its career bore an exact similarity to Kome. If the two states afterwards became far more ahke, the progress towards a common form must be attri- buted to the working of natural instincts. These instincts assimilated the component parts of each state through social and commercial intercourse and intermarriage, and determined its political constitu- tion so as to suit its requirements. The two states were analogous in origin and structure to begin with ; it is then not surprising that, when they had been subject to the operation of the same natural forces for some generations, they became far more alike, and eventually had constitutions all but identical. It is plain, then, that complex city states are artificial to begin with, but may be naturalised afterwards through the operation of human instincts. Comparison of Rome Rome and Athens proves that they are not all alike in government. alike at their beginnings; but do they all conform to one model and one constitution in their maturity ? If we were to look at Athens and Rome only we should say they do. The constitutions of Athens under Cleisthenes and of Rome in the war against Hannibal were identical in outline. Each state had its magistrates elected every year by the people, its advisory senate with life tenure of the 148 COMPLEX CITY STATES [ch. viii. members, and the assembled people to elect magis- trates and make laws ; there was only a distinction with scarcely a difference in that the Koman citizens met in three assemblies and voted by centuries or tribes, and the Athenians had only one assembly in which they voted as individuals. If, then, we drew a conclusion from Athens and Rome alone, we should say that complex city states, _ though unlike in their beginnings, are sUghtiy compelled by natural laws in their matu- rity to be governed by yearly-elected magistrates, permanent senate, and popular assem- blies. The history of Genoa in the Middle Ages proves that our conclusion would be incorrect, though the true conclusion does not contradict it entirely. Before 1100 a.d. the Genoese had con- quered towns along the coast, as far as Volturi, ten miles to the west of Genoa, and Chiavari, twenty miles to the east ; ^ by about 1200 they had conquered the coast for twenty miles more, as far as Levanto ; by 1241 they appointed officers called Podesta to govern their dependent towns, and called the de- pendencies potestatice.^ By the middle, then, of the thirteenth century Genoa was a complex city state. It went through changes of government, being ruled from 1217 to 1256 by a Podestk, from 1270 to 1290 by two Captains of the People, from 1291 to 1339 1 The limita are settled by Caflfaro, the earliest Genoese annalist. I learned them from passages in hia Annaks Oemtenses, but neglected to note the passages. ° Barthol. Soriba in Mon. Oerrn. Hist, vol. xviii. p. 197, line 41. CH. viii.] MIXED GOVERNMENTS 149 by one Captain, and from 1339 by a Ttoge} All the Genoese constitutions diverged from the constitutions of Athens and Rome. The divergence is sufficiently seen in the final form of government under a Doge. The Doge was elected to hold office not for a year but for life; the councillors did not serve for life, but were frequently changed by popular elections.^ The features common to the governments of Athens, Rome, and Genoa, are these : in each government the executive authority was entrusted to ^jj^g^ an elected magistrate or magistrates ; the governments . , , 1 n universal. executive governor was aided by an ad- visory council of important citizens; and the mass of the citizens elected rulers and sanctioned laws. In all three cities we see a mixed government, consisting of magistrates, council, and people ; but beyond this there is no uniformity of constitution. The peculiarities which distinguish the govern- ments of the two ancient complex city states were evidently caused by circumstances in the peculiarities earlier history of the communities. The in Athens Athenians and Romans, in the mature condition of their cities, did not appoint executive magistrates to hold office for life, because they had made trial of rulers holding for life in the earliest part of their history, and had found them un- satisfactory. On the other hand each of the towns, whose union made up their complex states, was ' The dates are from the Annalists in Mon. Germ. Hist., vol. xviii., and from Georgius Stella in JHuratori, R.I.S., vol. xvii. ■^ Stella in Mnratori, vol. xvii., col. 1074, ool. 1081. 150 ATHENS AND EOME [CH. vm. descended from a tribe or a union of tribes. In the tribes the elders or heads of important families had been councillors for life; and the importance of families and their heads had afterwards been rendered permanent and intensified by the system, perhaps peculiar to the Greeks and Italians, under which each head of a family was its high priest, and might become the religious, social, and natural head of a clan. When kingship was abolished at Athens and Rome, the heads of great families were for a time the only rulers in the childhood of the communities. The heads, then, of the great families held a splendid ancestral and historical position all through the early history of Athens and Rome ; and accordingly, when the cities came to maturity and could shape their own destiny, they only acted in conformity with antecedent practice in giving the heads of the chief families a lofty position as their Areopagites or Senators, and in permitting them to retain office as councillors for life. TABLE. FOEM OF COMMUNITY. GOVERNMENTS. Complex city states (partly Elective magistrates, a council, popu- artificial, partly natural). lar assembly. 1. In ancient history : Magistrates elected for a year, senate Athens, 508-487 B.C. serving for life, assembly single at Rome, 287-201 B.C. Athens, triple at Eome. 2. In the Middle Ages : Magistrate elected for life, council Genoa from 1339 a.d. frequently changed by election, single popular assembly. CHAPTER IX ATHENS During the period of seventy-five years which elapsed between the retreat of the Persians from Europe in 479, and the end of the Peloponnesian War in 404, Athens gradually passed over from the complex to the simple variety of city states. The change was brought about by forces acting in Attica, which, by attracting or compelling the rural population to go and live in the city, destroyed the equipoise between townsfolk and country folk. It is true that the extension of the power of Athens outside of Attica supplied a force that might have acted strongly in the contrary direction, because it might have created important communities of Athenian citizens at a distance ; but, as a matter of fact, it was never very effective in producing such a result, and at the end of the Peloponnesian War its action came to an end. The first event inside Attica that tended to aggrandise Athens was an enlargement of its area. Strong walls were built from Athens to its Enlargement seaport Piraeus and to Phalerum, another of Athens, point on the coast. The area within the walls was a triangle, whose sides towards the land measured 152 MIGEATION [ch. ix. five miles and four miles respectively, and whose side sea-front also measured about four miles. The greater part of this large space was quite fit for being used as building land, and Athens was, there- fore, potentially a city of larger size than Rome ever attained, even when it was the capital of the world in the time of the Emperors. Soon after the enlargement of Athens there came into action a number of forces which attracted the country folk into the city. The Athenians Attractions. were in receipt or a very great revenue from many Greek states, who paid them tribute in return for protection against the Persians. Part of it was spent in embellishing the city with works of art better than any other place in the world could dream of. A large number of the citizens received pay from the state for services in the law-courts as judges or jurymen, in which capacity their duties were never arduous, and were most commonly amusing. The drama at Athens, both tragic and comic, attained to perfection ; its representations, held in a theatre open to the sky, must have been far more enjoyable than the indoor performances that are usual in our northern climate ; the cost of admission to the cheap- est seats was fixed for a time at the low price of two obols, and then at some date before the end of the seventy-five years now under consideration, the whole cost was defrayed by the state. The citizens, too, were both quick-witted and light-hearted, so that Athens was the most attractive place in the world for all who cared for fun, gaiety, and social enjoyment. CH. IX.] FROM COUNTRY TO CITY 153 Soon after the Peloponnesian War began in 432, Attica was ravaged by the Lacedaemonians : there were five invasions before 424, and from , , „ , . , , Invasions. 413 to the end of the war m 404, the Lacedsemonian occupation was continuous. The Athenians could not defend the territory of Attica without crippling their navy, and they resolved that the navy was the more important of the two. The countrj;^ towns and farms of Attica were nearly deserted, and the inhabitants thronged within the long walls which connected Athens with Piraeus and Phalerum. After the end of the war, there must have been some re-migration of the population into the country ; but it does not seem as if the country towns ever recovered their former importance, for we do not find much mention of them in the later literature of Athens. It seems likely that the delights of life in the city had taken a deep hold on the affections of the people, and they were loath to abandon them. It was, moreover, made somewhat easier for the poorer classes to continue to reside in the city when it was decreed that every citizen should receive wages from the state for every day on which he attended at a meeting of the political assembly of the people. It is true that the wages or doles scattered broadcast among the citizens were small individually, but they might when taken together make up a fair augmen- tation of a small income. The daily pay was three obols; the three obols contained only the' same weight of silver as a modern half-franc, but it is likely that they would purchase as much as can at 154 ATHENS [CH. ix. present be bought for two or three shillings.^ Every citizen could receive this pay for about sixty days in the year by being present at the assembly, and all that he got in this way was clear gain. He could also receive the same for attendance at a religious festival and its dramatic performances ; but on these occasions he made but little profit, since two-thirds of his wages were used up in paying for his seat in the theatre. And lastly, as the jurymen or dicasts employed in the law-courts numbered about a third of the citizens, and they were selected by the hazard of the lot from the whole body, every citizen had one chance in three of being selected; if he was, he received his three obols in one way or another all the year round. On the whole, it seems likely that, though the pay from the state was not enough to provide for the maintenance of a family, it would easily suffice to enable a citizen with small property or small earnings to continue to enjoy the lazy and frivolous life of the city, and to escape from the dull and laborious life of a peasant farmer. The general effect of the changes that have been noticed was to concentrate in Athens a population which had been scattered over Attica, and so to destroy, so far as Attica was concerned, the balance between the central city and its outlying communities. In the case of Rome, as was pointed out in the seventh chapter, extension of power and conquest ' Boeokh, the best modern authority on the point, thinks three obols would sufiSoe for the comfortable keep of a citizen, but not for his household. The daily pay of a citizen serving in the fleet was three obols. — Thuo. viii. 45. CH. IX.] DEPENDENCIES 155 gave the city new outlying communities of its own citizens. If the same thing had happened in the case of Athens, the balance between the centre and the superficies would have been restored. How it was that this did not come to pass, we have now to observe. The foreign dependencies of Athens during the seventy-five years from 479 to 404, were of two kinds. Some, and those by far the most Depend- numerous and important, were protected encies. states which governed themselves in everything except foreign policy ; the others, comparatively insignificant, were plantations of Athenian citizens known as cleruchice, or bodies of landowners. The protected states originally came under Athenian influence, not through conquest, but because they re- quested Athens to protect them against Protected the Persians : if I may use the language of states, the Middle Ages, they commended themselves to Athens. From 478 to 454 the Athenians treated them almost as allies on equal terms; the treasury was kept in Delos, meetings of delegates were held in the Delian temple of Apollo to settle the policy of the league, and the Athenians were only so far superiors that they assessed the contributions of the allies, controlled expenditure, and had command of the fleet. In 454 the treasury was transferred to Athens, and thenceforth the Athenians were the masters, and the rest were servants. The servant states were in two categories : three or four of them even after 454 were privileged to send their contri- butions in the shape of a contingent of ships, and so 156 ATHENS [CH. ix. stood in a position analagous to that of the civitates fcederatce towards Rome — they were clients, indeed, but clients whom the patron cared to conciliate ; the rest were mere payers of tribute, and so stood on a lower level than any of socii populi Romani. The protected states, then, were in no sense incorporated into Athenian citizenship. Athens left them to manage their internal affairs as they chose, so long as they were punctual in sending their ships or their tribute ; but, on the other hand, they had no influence whatever over the internal political condition of the Athenian community, and the state did not acquire any complexity of structure because they were its clients. The cleruchice had a different origin and character. When the Athenians made conquests, they followed the same course as the Romans at a Cleruchiae. • c i i i later date, takmg possession of the whole or a part of the conquered land and giving it out in plots to Athenian citizens. It was intended that the new landowners should settle on the estates they had received, and form a garrison acting in the Athenian interest. Wherever this intention was actually carried out, the new settlers were in exactly the same position as the Roman settlers who took lands in Latium or formed garrisons of burgesses on the sea- coast of Italy; they retained their full citizen- ship, could speak and vote in the assembly, and any one of them might be designated by the lot as archon or by election as strategus. It seems, however, that there were only few cases in which settlements were CH. IX. J DEPENDENCIES 157 actually made. Two instances occurred in Eubcea, at Chalkis and Histisea, and there was another in the island of JEgina. All three places were very near Athens, and were convenient residences for Athenian citizens, especially for such as were engaged in mari- time commerce. In all three places settlements took place, and contingents were furnished from Histisea and ^gina to serve in the Athenian force which sailed against Syracuse in 415.^ In these instances, and in another at Potidsea, the Athenian state ac- quired outlying dependencies peopled by its own citizens ; and the cleruchioe thus established fulfilled the purpose for which they were intended. Some, however, of the conquests which were made by the Athenians led only to distribution of land and not to settlements. A good example of such a conquest occurred in the island of Lesbos, which is about half as large as Attica. The island was one of the client states ; in 428 it revolted, and in the following year was subdued. The Athenians divided the whole island, except Methymna which had not joined in the rebellion, into three thousand estates: of these they gave three hundred for the support of the worship of the gods; the remaining two thousand seven hundred were gratuitously distributed to Athenian citizens by means of a sort of lottery. It may have been intended that the prize-winners should go and settle as a garrison in the island; but it is certain that they did not, since in 412, when Lesbos again revolted from Athens, there was no 1 Thucydidea, i. 114, 5 ; ii. 27 ; vii. 57, 2. 158 ATHENS [CH. ix. population of Athenians residing there.^ The whole transaction did not cause any shifting of the Athenian population, but merely put a substantial rent into the pockets of the prize-winners. Their good luck in the lottery established them as a large body of useless absentee landlords, and each of them drew out of his prize a rent of two hundred drachmae. Whether the rents were punctually paid by the un- lucky dispossessed Lesbians we are not informed; but all the absentee landlords had votes in the assembly at Athens, and it may be that they had enough voting power to compel the Athenian navy to collect their rents for them.^ The movements, then, of population between 479 and 404 were within Attica decidedly centripetal, and outside of Attica the centrifugal movement towards the cleruchice was so minute as scarcely to be worth considering. Athens became much more like a simple city state than ever it had been before. In proportion as the state shrank from Attica into Athens, so the government shrank from the Government wide and Comprehensive form which under a class. Cleisthenes had given it into one of the comparatively narrow and exclusive forms which prevail in simple city states. Until the beginning of the Peloponnesian War both the state and the government retained a portion of their complex structure. But from 431 B.C. the state was 1 Thuoydides, viii. 22 and 23. ^ The making of the Lesbian cleruchia is described in Thuoydides, iii. 50. CH. IX.] TEANSITION TO DEMOCRACY 159 reduced to simplicity of structure by the Spartan occupation of the country towns in Attica and the congregation of the whole population in Athens ; and from about the same date the government acquired that simplicity which results from the unquestioned domination of a class. The three kinds of govern- ment which are found in simple city states are, as we have seen, tyranny, oligarchy, and democracy. Athens, when it became a simple city state, never submitted to a tyranny ; oligarchy was adopted only for two short intervals, in 411 B.C. and 404 B.C.; for the rest of the time democracy was the prevalent form of government, except for some half-dozen years after 411 B.C., when there was a government of compromise. From a time not long subsequent to the defeats of the Persians at Salamis and Platsea, it was clear that the general tendency of Athenian government set towards democracy rather than to- wards oligarchy; from that time till 429 b.c. the power of the poor citizens increased and the influence of the rich diminished; and from 429 b.c. till the fall of Athens in 338 b.c. the government, except during short intervals which have just been noticed, furnishes the best example in all history of a demo- cracy of the uncompromising type. It may naturally be asked why the general tendency at Athens, after 479 b.c., set towards an increase in the power of the poor citizens. Aristotle thought it was because the poor citizens rendered signal public service by winning the great victory at Salamis, and afterwards by manning the fleets which won for 160 ATHENS [ch. ix. Athens a hegemony among the maritime powers.^ The cause that he assigned would seem adequate to the ancient Greeks ; but before we accept it as the sole cause we must consider what happened in mediseval Venice. The Venetians won naval victories as the Athenians did, in galleys such as the Athenians used ; the poor citizens of Venice must have supplied at least a good proportion of the oarsmen ; and yet at Venice the poor were always absolutely excluded from taking part in the government. In view of these facts from Venetian history, it seems we must assign some causes for the increasing power of the poor citizens at Athens beyond the one cause which seemed sufficient to the Greeks. Probably an addi- tional cause is to be found in the sudden extension in the area of the city of Athens, caused by the absorption in it of Piraeus and Phalerum. The multitude of seamen naturally gathered, when they landed, either at Pirseus or at Athens; their con- tinued service in the fleet was most necessary to the welfare of the state, so that any demands that they made must be listened to and considered; and as they were congregated in the city they could give a commanding number of votes in the assembly of the citizens. The change from the Cleisthenean constitution to democracy was brought about not by constructing new institutions, but by the decline or destruction of old ones. The three elements in the Cleisthenean government were the magistrates, the senate of the > Politics, V. 4, 8. CH. IX.] TRANSITION TO DEMOCRACY 161 Areopagus, and the common folk. The Athenians took away the political powers of the Areopagus, and then of the magistrates ; and when these two organs of government had been paralysed it followed of necessity that Demos was omnipotent. The Areopagus in the Cleisthenean system corre- sponds to the Senate in the Koman Republic, but the two councils are strongly contrasted in their history. The Senate of Rome was always rising to greater influence; the Areopagus was steadily decadent. The reason for the contrast is obvious. The Romans needed a strong senate because it was the only body well qualified to manage the business of establishing Roman settlements and conducting negotiations with the civitates fcederatce. The Athenians did not need a strong senate because the Athenian settlements outside Attica were unimportant, and the great mass of the client states were not in the position of the civitates fcederatce but mere tributaries with whom no negotiations were needed. The authority of a senate must always depend on the reputation and wisdom of its members ; and so the authority of the Areopagus depended on the character of the men who were or had been archons. In the constitution of Cleisthenes the archonship was intended to be both an important and a dignified office ; but he set up the office of the strategi by its side, and before long the strategi were more powerful than the archons. At the battle of Marathon the command of the Athenian army was shared between the archon Polemarch and the ten strategi ; the L 162 ATHENS [ch. ix. Polemarch was the nominal commander-in-chief, but in a council of war all the strategi had votes and the Polemarch had no more than one vote. The strategi were evidently capable men; they were equally divided in opinion, it is true, but they knew their own minds : five of them, including Miltiades, the hero of the great battle of Marathon, which they shortly won, were clearly in favour of going forward, the others as clearly in favour of keeping back. The Polemarch was a weak man and was talked over (to the right side, it is true) by Miltiades.^ The effect of the splendid victory which the Athenians won was inevitably to exalt the strategi in the public estima- tion, and to lower the archons. The Athenians soon made sure that there should be no doubt which was the superior office. In 487 they passed a new con- stitutional law which made the appointment of archons far more a matter of chance than it had ever been: five hundred candidates were to be selected every year, and out of this large number the nine archons were to be taken by drawing lots.^ From this time forth the archons were not important enough to figure in history. As far as the magis- tracies were concerned the change was a good one, since it was far better that the strategi should be the sole responsible officers than that there should be a conflict for precedency between them and the archons ; but the blow that had been struck against the archons was certain before long to recoil upon the Areopagus. 1 Herodotus, vi. 109, 110. 2 Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 22. CH. IX.] TRANSITION TO DEMOCRACY 163 In 480 the Areopagus obtained a renewal or pro- longation of its political power by a patriotic action. When the Persians under Xerxes had passed over the mountains near Thermopylae, Attica lay at their mercy, and the ten strategi proclaimed that every man must save himself as best he could. The Areopagus, however, provided a large sum of money to meet the expense of manning a large fleet of galleys of war. The Athenian contingent thus provided was more than half of the whole Greek force that over- powered the Persians at Salamis : and the Athenians in gratitude to the Areopagus for the service it had rendered allowed it to have the chief influence in the government for twenty years.^ We do not know what were the political powers of the Areopagus, but they were very large, since they included a general and undefined censorship of morals, and probably some other important kinds of authority which have not been recorded. As the members were taken by hazard, there was no guar- antee that the council was properly qualified to perform functions that required great wisdom and delicacy of judgment; the use they made of their great powers gave dissatisfaction, and somewhere about 458 Pericles and Ephialtes were able to get a law passed whereby the Areopagus was entirely deprived of political authority.^ It continued to exist as a judicial body for the trial of cases of homicide and offences against religion, and the judges in it 1 Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 23. 2 Plutarch, Pericles, 7. 164 ATHENS [Oh. ix. were highly esteemed for their knowledge of the law affecting such cases and for the rectitude of their judgments; but from the time of the law passed by Pericles and Ephialtes they were as completely incapable of taking part in the decision of a political question as are the ecclesiastical courts of justice in England at the present day. The magistracy of the strategi followed the Areo- pagus in its downward course. As long as Pericles lived and was elected as strategus every year, the importance of the strategi suffered no diminution. Pericles was an uncrowned king of Athens, and though he owed his power to his abilities and not to the ofSce of strategus, the office retained its dignity and power because he was one of the holders of it. After his death the strategi were still the first men in the state : in 423 they joined with the Prytaneis in summoning a special meeting of the assembly.^ It was a regular part of their duties to negotiate with foreign powers with a view to drawing up treaties. Nicias, for example, as strategus, took so large a part in the negotiation of the treaty of 421 that it is usually called the peace of Nicias. But in 406 the political power of the strategi Avas suddenly shattered. Eight of their number were admirals in command of a great Athenian fleet and won the important victory of Arginusse, near Lesbos ; several Athenian ships which had been damaged in the action were lost in a storm, and it was asserted that the admirals had been culpably negligent in ' Thuoydide^, iv. 118, end. CH. IX.] TRANSITION TO DEMOCRACY 165 making no efforts to save them. A proposal was made in the assembly that the admirals should be put to death ; the assembly, though it was habitually a law-abiding body, on this occasion forgot itself, and there were very gross irregularities in the proceed- ings. The proposal was accepted, sentence of death was pronounced, and was executed upon all the admirals, six in number, who were in custody.^ The resolution condemning the admirals was passed by the assembly in a mere transient fit of anger against men who may have been in some degree blame- worthy; but though it was adopted hastily it had permanent and momentous results. It led very straight to the deep humiliation of the Athenians, and the surrender of their city in 404. The new strategi of 405 were incapable men and afraid to enforce discipline among the sailors, and all the fleet except a small squadron under Conon, an old and skilful admiral, was captured at ^gospotami. It had also another effect which it is more necessary for me to notice : it proclaimed to every one that the political influence of the office of strategus was at an end. After this date many of the strategi — for example, Iphicrates — were able commanders by sea and land, but it does not appear that the office of strategus gave them any claim to be leaders in the assembly. When the restraining forces of the Areopagus and the strategi ceased to act, Demos, or the mass of the poor citizens, was unchallenged master of the govern- ' Xenophon, Helhnica, i. 6 and 7. 166 ATHENS [CH. ix. ment. His reign had indeed begun on the death of Pericles, but his tenure of power became more certain after he had destroyed the strategi. The machine of government whereby Demos did his work will not need any elaborate description. It was identical with certain parts of the Cleisthenean system, of which a sketch has been already given.^ In the government of Cleisthenes the citizens at large were active in the Ecclesia or general assembly and its committee of Five Hundred, and also in the popular law-courts ; and these parts of his system survived almost unaltered in the time of the demo- cracy. Since, however, two parts of the machine devised by Cleisthenes, namely, the Areopagus and the strategi, had gone out of repair, the parts which remained in working order had the more work to do ; and, since the citizens took pleasure in the process of government, they spent an amount of energy upon it that was far greater than was required by the increase of the business to be done. The work, then, of government was done in the Ecclesia with its committee of Five Hundred and in the Dicasteria. I shall here point out how these bodies were constituted and what work they did. The Ecclesia and the Five Hundred between them General Undertook the whole direction of poUcy, assembly of the making of laws, and the control of eciizens. administration. The Ecclesia still con- sisted of the whole body of Athenian citizens. It held forty ordinary meetings in the course of the ' See Chapter vi., pp. 96, 97. CH. ix.J DEMOCRACY 167 year, and other meetings were summoned when- ever the Prytaneis thought fit. It was supreme over all matters whatsoever except judicature ; but, for the avoidance of revolutionary measures, it wisely allowed its actions to be in some measure controlled both by its own committee and by the law-courts. It was an established rule that no law was to be proposed in the Ecclesia till it had been sanctioned by the Five Hundred ; and laws or resolutions after they had been passed could be indicted before the law-courts on the ground that they were in conflict with some existing law or with the Athenian constitution. The indictment of a law was known as a Graphe ParanomSn, or prosecution for illegality. If the law or resolution was condemned by the law-court, it was ipso facto cancelled ; and, provided that the indictment was brought within a year after the vote of the assembly, the proposer as well as the proposition might be indicted, and if the court decided against him he was subject to a heavy fine. The Graphe Paranomdn was, beyond all doubt, the best bulwark of the constitution, and was more dreaded by revolutionary conspirators than any other form of procedure known at Athens. The only revolutionists who ever succeeded in overthrowing the Athenian democracy began by inducing the assembly to forbid the use of the indictment for illegality.^ The committee of Five Hundred was a committee of the assembly for finance and general purposes. ' This was in 411 B.C. Thucydides, viii. 67, 2. 168 ATHENS [ch. ix. It undertook all the business which could not be conducted in a meeting of the whole body of citizens, and so it came about that the work The Five ^^ *'^^ ^i'^® Hundred was most multi- Hundred, farious. They considered every law and every resolution which any citizen desired to propose in the Ecclesia, and decided whether it should or should not be brought forward. Through the discharge of this function they gained some control over the course of legislation; but it was only an imperfect control, because the proposals which they permitted to be brought before the assembly were not necessarily either rejected or passed as they stood, but could be altered by amend- ments made in the assembly.^ The work they had to do in connection with law-making was a very small part of the whole business they had to transact. The greater part of their time was spent in super- vision of the details of administration. They made a constant inspection of the moneys paid into the treasury of the state, and of the expenditure that came out of it. They had to see that a fixed number of triremes were built every year, to inspect troops, to attend to details in regard to military and naval stores, and to all the organisation of the fleet and the army. Their work in supervising many important branches of the public service was so voluminous that they held a meeting on every day in the year except the public holidays, and they received as ' This is proved by Dr. Sandys in his edition of Aristotle, Ath. Pol. See his note to chapter 29, 3. CH. IX.] DEMOCRACY 169 pay a drachma daily, or double the sum paid for the performance of the less responsible duties of a citizen, such as attendance at an Ecclesia or a law-court, or a theatrical representation. But though the Five Hundred were a general purposes committee of the governing body of the state, they did not possess any such in- fluence as other committees of the kind Hundred have usually attained. The powers noti'kea •111, 1 • Cabinet. Wielded by a general purposes committee of a governing body are ordinarily such as were acquired by the Lords of the Articles in Scotland, or those that belong to a Cabinet in a Parliament at the present time. It would have been entirely incon- sistent with the existence of uncompromising demo- cracy if the Five Hundred had possessed any influence of such magnitude ; and the committee of the Athenian assembly was constituted so that its influence should be reduced to a minimum. A committee of a governing body gains great influence only if the members of it have a long tenure of ofiice and special qualifications for their work. In the Five Hundred tenure of office was exceedingly short: each com- mittee man took office only for a year at a time, and no one could hold the office for more than two years in a lifetime.^ In the appointment of the committee men the special qualifications of candi- dates were absolutely disregarded. It was only required that they should be of ordinarily decent character; the actual appointment was made by » Aristotle, Ath. Pol., 62, 3. 170 ATHENS [ch. ix. drawing lots among those candidates whose private characters were found to bear inspection. The method of appointment by drawing lots was no doubt essential to the maintenance of a thorough- . . . , ffoing democracy. The only other con- Appointment o o j J by lot essential ceivable methods were nomination by to democracy. ^v^ ^i ,. j. • ^ ^■ some omcers, as the strategi, or election by the assembly. Both these methods were un- acceptable in the Athenian democracy. Nomination would have offended against the principle that all citizens were to be as far as possible equal, because it would have thrown a mass of patronage into the hands of the nominators ; and election would have made the committee - men too influential. Election would also have had another result which the Athenians would not have liked. It would have divided the citizens into parties, organised to attain definite political aims ; the citizens would have been bound by the ties which party organisa- tion creates, and Demos would no longer have been free to change his mind as often as he liked. It is a remarkable feature in the Athenian Ecclesia after the Peloponnesian War, that it had no official No official leaders. The strategi had lost their influ- leaders. ence, and the Five Hundred never gained any settled control over the proceedings. The assembly needed some men to be chief spokesmen and leaders in debate ; the men whom they adopted as leaders were professional orators. These orators were only private citizens without any official status, and they were well suited to be the spokesmen of CH. IX.] DEMOCRACY 171 Demos, who wished to be the real master and to be free to indulge all his caprices, because they could be discarded at a moment's notice. The judicial bodies alone were independent of the assembly ; but the judges were taken from the same class as predominated in the Ecclesia. A 1 ^ ~ .,. . , Law Courts. large number of citizens were taken by lot every year to serve as judges; they were divided into bodies varying in number from two hundred to a thousand, and each of these bodies sat as a court of justice to decide such cases as might be brought before them. They sat without any professional judge to inform them about the condition of the law or the relevance of the arguments ; the advocate on either side cited such laws as favoured his conten- tions, and could use any reasoning which he thought likely to influence the court. It does not appear that there was any class of men learned in the law ; no such class was needed where every citizen felt himself competent to vote on every litigation under the guidance of commonsense. It is clear that litigants did not attempt to bribe the judges: the bench of judges was always so numerous that bribery would have been horribly expensive. But the courts were very capricious in their decisions; and in the time of the Peloponnesian War they were strongly influenced by prejudices favourable to the poor and adverse to the rich, so that rich litigants were often fined with undue severity, and the public treasury profited by the fines imposed on them as it did by the tribute from the protected cities. 172 ATHENS [ch. ix. In the Athenian democracy, the poorer class of citizens personally carried on the work of government. They could do this because there was a large population of slaves to do the indus- trial and menial work which was necessary to the welfare of the population. In a state without slaves, as for example in Florence from 1343 a.d. to 1354 A.D., democracy of a kind may exist ; but it cannot be a democracy of the same type as prevailed at Athens. If we compare Athenian democracy with the other class-governments in the simple cities of ancient Estim t f liistory, we see that it was incomparably Athenian superior to most of them. The usual vices eraocracy. ^^ class-govemments are lawlessness, in- stability, and persecution. Athens was almost exempt from all of them. The only case in which the assembly perpetrated an outrageous breach of the constitution was in the sentence which it passed on the six admirals who commanded at Arginusse. The constitution was so stable that in its existence of about ninety years there was only one occasion (in 411 B.C.) when it Avas completely overturned by a purely domestic revolution. Persecution of the rich by the assembly was unknown, and the only kind of serious injustice that they endured arose from the undue severity of the fines imposed on them in the law-courts during the Peloponnesian War. To expect that Athenian democracy should com- pare favourably with the mixed governments of the complex city states, is to ask more than can reason- ably be required of it. The complex city states of OH. ix.j COMPARED WITH ARGOS 173 Attica and Rome were different in their structure from the simple city of Athens, and their governments were constructed for objects which the democracy of Athens did not care about. The conspicuous faults of Athenian democracy, if we compare it with the mixed government of Rome, are two in number: it was extremely inefficient in dealing with foreign policy ; and, although it taught all the citizens to talk well and vote confidently, it did not teach them to act well. The citizens, about fifty years after the Pelopon- nesian War, were extremely reluctant to serve in the army, and they refused to give up the pay that they received for attending religious festivals even when the money was wanted to defend Olynthus against Macedonia. Comparison of Athens and Argos. The change from complex to simple structure which took place in Athens, was not a phenomenon entirely without a parallel. Something of the same kind occurred in the neighbouring city of Argos. When I enumerated in the fourth chapter the expansive and complex city states of ancient history, I made no reference to Argos, because it is incon- spicuous, and I could not have referred to it without tiresome explanation ; but I have no doubt that until after the Persian invasion it had something of the expansive and complex character. It was advan- tageously situated for a moderate degree of expansion ; the ancient city of Mycense was its neighbour in the Argolic Plain, and had no defences except its citadel 174 ARGOS [CH. IX. and its walls. It cannot be doubted that Argos reduced Mycense and the far smaller fortress or palace of Tiryns to some kind of dependence at a very early age ; they must have been deprived of independence before King Pheidon of Argos (who reigned certainly before 600 b.c.) made his rapid but short-lived con- quests outside the Argolic Plain. While Argos had something of a complex character, it had also a mixed form of government: it retained its ancient tribal kingship so late as 480 B.C./ but it was a limited kingship, and the kings, as Strabo teUs us, were insignificant. After the Persian invasion the structure of Argos was altered. The dependent town of Mycense had the audacity to send eighty hoplites to take part in the defence of Greece at Thermopylse,^ though the Argives gave them no permission to do so, and themselves refused to send a contingent. The jealousy of the Argives was roused by this act of independence and Hellenic patriotism, and within a few years they razed the walls of Mycense.^ From this time forth, Argos was a perfectly simple city state, and had such a government as is appropriate to a simple city. The government was an uncompromising democracy. In 371 b.c., or the following year, some rich men were detected in a conspiracy to establish an oligarchy ; the defenders of the democracy armed themselves with bludgeons, and in the Skytalismus, or rule of the club, which ensued, about twelve ' Herodotus, vii. 149. ' Herodotus, vii. 202. ^ Pausanias, ii. 16. CH. IX.] ARGOS 175 hundred of the rich men were slain. The brutalities, however, which the Argives perpetrated on this occasion, were never repeated on any other; and there is good reason to believe that the democracy of Argos was, in general, exempt, almost in an equal degree with the similar government at Athens, from those vices which might be expected to arise from the uncontrolled supremacy of a single class in the population. CHAPTER X HETEROGENEOUS EMPIRE: ROME After the age of city states two great empires came into being. The Macedonian empire acquired by Alexander the Great was extremely short-lived, and as it did not exist long enough to get any political institutions of its own, there is no occasion to say more about it. The Roman empire began soon after the expulsion of Hannibal from Italy, and had a continuous existence till the Turks captured Con- stantinople in the fifteenth century of the Christian era. Between 200 b.c. and 100 e.g. the Romans conquered Spain, Macedonia, Greece, Carthage, Hlyrium, and the structure of greater part of Asia Minor. The aggregate the Roman of their dominions, when these conquests '"^"^' had been made, constituted a heterogen- eous empire, because each of the countries had a distinctive character impressed upon it by ages of past history, and all the countries were dissimilar in character- to each other and to Rome. The quality which differentiates a heterogeneous empire from all other large political bodies is the dissimilarity of the countries which it brings under one government, ira CH. X.J ROME: CITY AND EMPIEE 111 Complex city states, and all nations whether unitary or federal, are formed by the union of like with like, and their parts are soon held together by cohesive and attractive forces which arise naturally and spontaneously between like and like ; heterogeneous empires are formed by the union of unlike with unlike, forces of repulsion act strongly to sever the parts which have been united, and they can only be held together by vigorous coercion. The Komans regarded the conquered countries, which became their subject provinces, as mines of wealth to be worked for the profit of selfishness the conquerors. The exploitation of the of the mines was carried on, not by the Roman '""^"^• state, but by individuals or classes in the Roman community; the wealth, however, which poured from them into the capital city of the empire, demoralised and degraded all classes in the city, and eventually destroyed its republican form of government. So long as Rome was merely a complex city its constitution was founded, as we have seen, upon compromises, wherein every class made Competition concessions to other classes for the main- '""^ spoils, tenance of a strong and equitable government for the good of all. When the wealth of the provinces flooded into the city, every class thought it had not yet got its due share of the spoil, and all engaged in a scramble to get more, and as much more as possible. The Romans till 49 B.C. attempted to rule a hetero- M 178 ROME: CITY AND EMPIEE [ch. x. geneous empire by means of the institutions proper Oni urb n to a Complex city state. The attempt institutions was a failure ; and I believe it led to more ' '^^ ■ ■ widespread misery than any other political blunder or incongruity in the course of European history. To understand the influence of provincial wealth upon Roman society, we must look upon the classes which composed that society after the stream of plunder had fairly set towards the capital. A con- venient point of view may be taken just before Marius was elected, in 107 B.C., for the first time to the consular office. The Roman citizens were divided into two rich classes and two poor classes. The first of the rich The Roman classes consisted of the families which citizens, monopolised the curule magistracies ; the second comprised the great capitalists, known as the equestrian order, because in the earlier times of the republic the rich men had served in the cavalry. The first of the poor classes was the mob of the capital ; the second, now greatly shrunken in numbers from what it had been, took in the small yeomen farmers of the country districts. The curule magistrates got the earliest and the most direct access to the spoils of the provinces. As The curule soon as the new dominions had been ac- magistracies. quired by the Romans it was necessary to increase the number of curule magistracies, because the existing staff of officers was insufficient. The men at the top of the list of curule magistrates had CH. X.] EICH CLASSES 179 been the two consuls and the two praetors. These officers were wanted for work in Italy, and new magistracies had to be devised in order to supply governors for the provinces. Two expedients were adopted in succession with a view of providing pro- vincial governors. In the case of the two earliest provinces, Sardinia and Sicily, which were both acquired before 200 B.C., the necessary governors were supplied by increasing the number of the praetors from two to four, and before the year 108 B.C., which we have chosen as the date of our survey, the number had risen to six. By this time novel courts of justice had been established in Rome, so that three of the six praetors had to stay at home to act as judges, and only three could be employed as provincial commanders. By the same time the number of provinces needing governors had risen to ten, and a second method of providing more magis- trates had to be adopted. This second expedient, which soon after 100 B.C. superseded the first, was the employment of curule magistrates in the pro- vinces after the expiration of the year for which they were elected to office. When a man had finished his year's work in Italy as consul or praetor, he was appointed deputy to the consuls or praetors who followed him in office at home, and was sent out to govern a province with the title of proconsul or propraetor. He was endowed with the same complete imperium that belonged to all consuls and all praetors; and therefore in his province he was absolute military and civil commander over all persons and 180 ROME: CITY AND EMPIRE [CH. x. causes supreme. The rules laid down for his guid- ance by the senate were reasonable and humane enough ; but the senate was too far off to see that he conformed to them, and he could, if he liked, use his authority in the province as a means of enriching himself at the expense of his subjects. It is true that on his return to Rome he was liable to a pro- secution for extortion ; but the judges who decided in such prosecutions were selected, till 122 B.C., from the senators, and the senator's were not extreme to mark what was done amiss, because many of them had already known the delights of provincial governorships, or hoped in the future to enjoy them. After the practice of giving the provinces to pro- consuls and propraetors was fully established, the Curuie consulship and prsetorship were not greatly families. desired for their own sake. In most cases the consuls and praetors, during their year of office, had to perform routine duties in Italy under the supervision of the senate; and it was only in the rare instances when a consul could hope to be commander in a provincial war during his consular year that the consulship was in itself a highly desirable office. But the consular and praetorian magistracies were most eagerly sought in view of that which came after them ; they were the stepping- stone on the upward course to a provincial governor- ship. It so happened that, in the age before the foreign conquests of Rome were made, certain Roman families had, through the merits of their members, frequently furnished the curuie magistrates. When CH. X.J RICH GLASSES 181 the curule magistracies became the sole gateway that gave access to the excitements and profits of pro- vincial governorships, the families which had already attained to curule dignities desired that the gate should be barred against all others; and, as the assemblies which elected the magistrates were now very badly constituted and were amenable to the influence of the rich, the old families generally succeeded in blocking the way against intruders. The curule families (for so they were called) con- sisted partly of patricians and partly of plebeians. There was now no distinction worth noticing between a patrician and a plebeian curule family; but the curule families, patrician and plebeian alike, formed a new and a close body of hereditary nobles. If any man outside the ring of curule families tried to break into their circle by competing for a curule magis- tracy, they spoke of him as novus homo, an upstart, and were generally able to secure that he should be rejected by the votes of the centuries. The marked instances of novi hoTnines who broke through in spite of their opposition were Cato the Elder and Cicero. There were also some few other besides ; but in the main the curule families succeeded in main- taining their position as a close caste of hereditary nobles. The second rich class among the Romans consisted of the capitalists, other than those who had been elected as curule or non-curule magis- jhe trates. These capitalists, as we have seen, capitalists, were called equites. They were not generally ex- 182 ROME : CITY AND EMPIRE [CH. x. pected to perform actual military duties as horsemen, because the allies or client states furnished enough cavalry to meet the requirements of the army ; but, when the citizens elected curule magistrates, the capitalists voted in the eighteen equestrian centuries. The class of rich men who were not magistrates had grown in numbers through circumstances connected with the provinces. When the Komans in the third century before the Christian era acquired Sardinia and Sicily, their first possessions outside the limits of Italy, they found a system of tax-gathering by means of middlemen or contractors already established in those islands. They very naturally allowed that system to continue where it was already in working order, and they afterwards introduced it into their later conquests. As soon as a newly acquired region was made into a province, the senate settled what taxes should be levied from it, and they then sold the produce of the taxes to a syndicate of rich men, who paid a fixed sum to the treasury of the Roman state, and made as much money as they could out of the taxes which they and their slaves collected from the province. The syndicates of tax-collectors, called publicani, were under a strong temptation to exact more than the authorised amount of the taxes; and if they yielded to the temptation they could usually do it with impunity. There were only two means of controlling them: the govern'or of the province could interfere, or the publicani could be prosecuted before a court of justice at Rome. The governor of the province usually winked at the CH. X.] POOR CLASSES 183 doings of the tax-farmers, because he had more sympathy with them than pity for the taxpayers ; and the courts of justice at Rome could not, after 122 B.C., be trusted to treat a rapacious sjmdicate of tax-farmers with due severity. In the year that has just been named, the tribune Caius Gracchus got a law passed which changed the composition of the law- courts which dealt with charges of exaction in the provinces. His law ordained that the judges in these courts should no longer be drawn from the senators but from the equites. From the passing of this law the equites or capitalists obtained such a recognition as a corporate class, that they bore the name of equester ordo, the order of the knights. The gover- nors of provinces were no longer shielded by judges drawn from the curule families to which they them- selves belonged ; but as long as the governor and the tax-farmers in a province shared profits so as to satisfy both, they were usually secure against con- demnation in a Eoman law-court. The poor classes of Roman citizens were the rabble of the city, and the small farmers around it. A poor and idle class was compelled to settle in The poor in the city against its will. The invasion of *-^^ •^'*y- Hannibal drove the yeomen off their farms; some of them took service in the legions, some migrated within the walls. The immigrants into the city, having lost their farms, had no means of support, and the magistrates had to save them from starving. Some of the provinces, especially Sicily and Africa, had a large surplus production of corn. The magis- 184 ROME : CITY AND EMPIRE [ch. x. trates ordered this corn to be brought to Rome and sold it at rates far below cost price. At the same time, finding that the rabble of paupers was a dangerous element in the city, they set to work to arause them with magnificent gladiatorial spectacles. The corn doles and the festivals speedily demoralised the poor residents in Rome, and there was no hope of their recovering their old virtues unless they could be re-established in the country as yeomen farmers. The class of yeomen was by no means extinct. Some of them had gone back to their rustic labours after the defeat of Hannibal; but two The yeomen. causes were at work to prevent them from recovering their old condition of substantial prosperity. One cause was the corn doles, which artificially lowered the price of grain. It was no longer a paying business to grow wheat for sale, and a farmer had no inducement to produce it except for consumption in his household. Yet, however, he might have gained a profit on the production of wine and oil but for the other cause of his impoverish- ment. One form of wealth imported in great quantities from the provinces consisted in slaves. They were not usually hunted down in the provinces themselves, but it was in the provinces that they were brought to market. The rich classes among the Romans had Avide estates of land in Italy ; they tilled them with slave labour. The labour of slaves was cheaper than free labour, because a slave could be worked to death and his place was easily filled with a new slave ; and so the large owners of land could CH. X.] GOVERNMENT 185 undersell the small yeoman in every market. Lati- fundia perdidere Italiam. The organs of government in the Eoman state were, on the one side, the senate, and on the other the plebeian assemblies with their tri- Thegovem- bunes. The curule magistrates during '"^"'' their year of ofSce in Rome do not count, because they were controlled by the senate. The senate consisted entirely of men who had been elected to a curule or non-curule magistracy. All the senators were rich men, and the senate acted steadily in support of the established order, or, in other words, for the main- tenance of private property as it stood, so that they practically defended the rich in the enjoyment of what they had got. Many of the senators had been tribunes, and as tribunes had acted in opposition to the interests of the rich ; but when they were estab- lished in the senate they fell in with the ideas of the curule senators. The plebeian assemblies were no longer like the old concilia plebis. Thirty-one votes, it is true, belonged to the country voters, and only plebeian four to the urban rabble. But the yeomen assemblies, attended irregularly; they were untrained as poli- ticians, and it seems from the votes that they gave that the few of them who came to the meetings must have been influenced by contact with the proletariate of the city The leaders of the plebeians were the ten tribunes, but the assembly of the tribes, as now constituted, was but a broken reed for a man to lean 186 ROME : CITY AND EMPIRE [CH. x. upon, and the tribunes were always personally un- lucky in the attacks that they made against the authority of the senate and the property of the rich. The attack might succeed, but its author perished. The whole of the classes distinguishable in the Eoman world were seven in number : four were those Classes ^^*'° which the citizens were divided, and without the three outside the citizenship were the Latins, the Italians, and the provincials. All these three classes outside the citizenship, and also the Roman farmers, were sacrificed to secure unfair advantages for the three classes who lived in the city of Rome — the curule families, the equestrian order, and the mob. The extreme injustice of social and economic arrangements within Italy arose entirely from an economic source outside of Italy, namely, the wealth of the provinces which poured towards Rome ; and the injustice could never be removed unless that source was stopped up. Attempts were made to remedy economic inequalities within Italy by legisla- tion ; but they suffered the ordinary fate of legislative interferences with economy because they did not strike at the root of the evil, the transference of the wealth produced by the provincials to Roman owner- ship. The two Gracchi in 133 B.c. and 123 B.C. made the only two serious attempts of the kind, by enabling the Roman state to acquire land in Italy and to plant Roman citizens upon it as yeomen farmers ; but the attempts had little permanent result, because the new farmers were soon tempted to sell their plots of ground to rich neighbours, and Italy was again CH. x.J PROFESSIONAL SOLDIERS 187 covered almost exclusively with great estates worked by slave labour. Soon after the year 108 B.C., which we took as the standpoint for our survey, a new class arose in the population of Italy. Marius founded a professional standing army of professional soldiers, so'i^'ers. The influence of this new class upon the fortunes of Italy was the same as was exercised in England by the warriors whom Edward the Third and Henry the Fifth collected into an army for the invasions of France. They could not be always employed in foreign conquest. They were ready to do anything at the bidding of the leaders under whom they had served, and when they returned from foreign service they waged civil wars in Italy. The first war of the kind was begun by the Italian allies of Kome to obtain redress of their heavy grievances and admis- sion to Koman citizenship. The war lasted from 91 B.C. to 88 B.C. The allies obtained the citizenship, which improved their status while serving in the army or suing in a law-court, but did them little good in any political sense, because they could not be present to vote in the plebeian assemblies at Kome. The second civil war began as soon as the first was ended, and lasted for six years. The armies engaged in it were no more fighting for different political aims or principles than the armies that fought for York or Lancaster. The wars arose because rival armies and rival leaders were there, and gain was to be got out of victory. Sulla, who came out the conqueror, used his victory with some judgment, after 188 ROME [CH. X. he had slaughtered the citizens who had favoured his rivals. He could not bring about a happy distribu- tion of property, but he set up a constitution which prevented for a time the endless and useless squabbles between the senate and the tribunes. He admitted a larger number of the lesser magistrates to the senate, and, as it would be hard for the curule families to influence all the elections of these numer- ous lesser magistrates, he probably enabled the people to place men who were really acceptable to it among the ranks of the senators ; at the same time he took away from the tribunes most of the powers which they had often misused. The proconsuls had been the earliest and the most active of the oppressors of provincials. But it was . ^ . possible that a proconsul instead of being A champion c c o of the the spoliator of his subjects should be provinces. tjigjj. j^g^ ^mj f^j-m ruler, the protector of the weak, the terror of wrong-doers, and that his provincials in gratitude for his mercy and goodness should flock to his standard and provide him with an army that could overpower the whole forces controlled by the Roman senate and all the legions commanded by the proconsuls in the other provinces. It did not seem likely that a member of a curule family should engage in such an unusual course of action, or that he should gain the reward of it. Csesar did both. Caius Julius Csesar was appointed in 59 b.c. to be proconsul of Cisalpine Gaul for five years. His appointment was irregular, for it was made not CH. X.] C^SAR 189 by decree of the senate but by a resolution pro- posed by a tribune in a plebeian assembly. Soon after his appointment to Cisalpine Gaul he was also given the proconsulship in Gaul ^^^"' beyond the Alps, of which country the Eomans then possessed only a small part about the region now called Provence. In ten campaigns Csesar conquered Gaul to the Bay of Biscay, to the British Channel, and the Rhine. His army of Gallic provincials was devoted to him, and when in 49 b.c. he had reason to complain of the treatment that he received from the senate, he crossed the river Rubicon at the head of his army and marched in open rebellion into Italy. The whole peninsula submitted with little resistance. Csesar then with his army made a circuit of the provinces around the Mediterranean Sea, to put down the resistance of the Roman generals who were opposed to him. In three years and a half of hard- fought campaigning, Spain, Thessaly, Egypt, Africa, were in turn compelled into obedience, and in May, 46 B.C., Csesar was able to enter Rome as master of the whole empire. The victory of Csesar was won with the aid of an army of provincials, and it immediately altered the status of the provinces in the Roman „ ^ _ Conspiracy world. Hitherto the provinces had been of the curuie at the mercy of rapacious factions of '^*^'^' Roman citizens which strove with one another which should have the largest share of the wealth produced by the labour of the provincials: henceforth the Romans and the provincials were alike subject to 190 ROMAN EMPIRE [ch. x. the will of a single master who paid due regard to the interests of both, and was therefore especially the protector of the provincials, who had hitherto been the oppressed class. But the curule families did not acquiesce in being deprived of the power, which they had long misused, without an effort to recover it, and for a time they made it doubtful whether the empire would continue to enjoy the advantages which Caesar's victory had won. Caesar did not disguise the fact that he was absolute ruler of the empire. He took the title of Dictator, Murder of ^^^ regarded himself as successor of the Caesar. ancient kings. A conspiracy was formed by members of the curule families, and Caesar was murdered at a meeting of the senate in less than two years after he had attained supreme power. The partj' of the murderers could not maintain themselves in power. They gained the aid of some The of the soldiery, but most of the legions avengers, ^ere eager to avenge their beloved Caesar. At the end of the strife of the contending armies it was found that the control of affairs rested with the generals of the Caesarean legions. An agreement was made between these generals by which Octavi- anus, great-nephew of Caesar, became ruler of the West, and Marcus Antonius of the East. The power of these two confederates was subject to no consti- tutional limits or forms, because it rested simply on their own agreement. After Octavianus had conquered Marcus Antonius at Actium in 31 B.C., he thought it wise to make a CH. X.] AUGUSTUS 191 pretence that he was a constitutional ruler set up according to old republican traditions. From the year 27 B.C., when he took the title of Augustus, his rule was a singular mixture "^"^ of real absolutism with pretended limitations. The pretences to which he condescended were judiciously conceived, and were probably suggested by the con- sideration that if he reigned as an undisguisedly absolute monarch he might meet with the fate of his predecessor. Augustus held the powers of all the great magis- tracies, but was appointed to each of them separately and for a term of years. The greatest of veiled these powers were the tribunician, the autocracy, consular, and the proconsular. The tribunes had been protectors of the citizens, and the tribunicia potestas gave Augustus authority to govern citizens in matters that were not military ; the consulare imferiwrn gave him civil and military command in Rome and Italy; and the proconsulare imperiuon made him governor of the provinces and commander of their legions. The proconsular imperium was offered to him in all the twenty- two provinces, but it chanced that in twelve provinces there was no likelihood of war, and no large armies quartered; these twelve peaceful provinces he left to the senate, while he assumed the proconsular imperium only in the provinces of the frontier. The senatorial provinces were ruled by proconsuls appointed by the senate after consultation of the wishes of the emperor , the imperial provinces by deputies of Augustus, who bore 192 ROMAN EMPIRE [cH. x. the title of legati. Augustus discharged the various duties of a sovereign nominally in virtue of the powers of the magistracies conferred on him in republican fashion, but really through the might that he wielded as commander of the legions. In like manner he pretended to govern in accordance with the opinion of the senate, though in truth the senators were ready to express any opinion that would be pleasing to their wise and considerate master. On the death of Augustus in a.d. 14< his stepson Tiberius gave up the practice of being elected ^^^ separately to the magistracies. He took successors of all powers of sovereignty at once, and ugus us. permanently : his successors followed his example. Thus the separate powers which had belonged to the magistracies became indistinguish- able, and all were merged in the single supreme office of Princess. The whole government was vested in the hands of one man, and the force of the army kept it there. Yet the successors of Augustus for nearly two hundred and seventy years, till the accession of Pretended Diocletian, kept up the pretence of foUow- deferenceto ing the advice of the senate. Under Augustus it rose to the dignity of a pious fraud ; under his successors it turned the lives of senators into a sordid farce, often ending in violent death. The senators under the Claudian dynasty were worthy successors of the old curule nobles. They had the desire to misgovern, but not the CH. X.] DISGUISED AUTOCEACY 193 opportunity. The old curule nobles were remarkable for their arrogance: the senators under the empire adopted the kindred vice of crawling servility. The old curule nobles murdered Csesar: the senators might wish to murder Tiberius, but they did not dare. There was one thing they did not fear to do : they were ready to accuse one another of treason. Poetical justice was done to the order of senators in the judicial murders that followed their mutual accusations, though the individual men were inno- cent of the crimes for which they died. The senators as a whole were so corrupt that no fate was too hard for them; but the accusers were worse than the accused. Tiberius and other emperors must have known that the senate could not give honest advice, and yet they let it survive and pretended to respect its opinion. It is hard to account for their policy in this respect, except on the supposition that they desired to keep the wealthy citizens amused lest they should turn to regicide, and also wished to implicate some important body of citizens in responsi- bihty for their public actions. For about a hundred years after the establishment of the monarchy in the person of Tiberius there is very little visible growth of institutions PrEetorian calculated to give regular aid to the cohorts, emperor in doing his work. The only change which led to any institution of the sort was of a military character. In the reign of Tiberius the bodyguard of the emperor, known as praetorian cohorts, a force about ten thousand strong, which had hitherto 194 ROMAN EMPIRE [ch. x. been scattered about Rome in small barracks, were collected into a single camp just outside the north- east corner of tbe Servian wall, which was still the only fortification of the city. After their concentra- tion in their camp their commander, the proBfectus prcetorio, acquired new importance, and the holder of the ofi&ce was naturally one of the emperor's chief confidential servants and advisers. Before the death of Tiberius, the monarchical govern- ment had been established in a form which was varied afterwards only by extremely gradual pro- was neces- cesses, and very slowly. It was obviously ^^^" not a good government, according to the standards of modern times. But a heterogeneous empire cannot have a good government such as a nation generally obtains. An empire, composed of unlike materials, of jarring nationalities, must put up with a very indifferent government, because it has to be held together by brute force, unless it is to undergo the agonies of dissolution by means of long wars between its parts. Among the indifferent forms of government which are possible for a heterogeneous empire.it is clear from the teaching of history that some extremely cen- tralised and absolute government is the least bad ; and in the Roman empire the only possible form of absolute government was an unlimited monarchy. Many of the emperors, like Nero, were blood-stained oppressors in the capital; but even Nero was popular in the provinces, and long after his death the eastern part of the empire cherished a hope that he had survived, and would come back to rule, with Jerusalem for his capital.^ ' Merivale, History of the Romans, ch. Iv., end. CH. X.] THE SUCCESSION 195 The one difficulty which seemed insuperable in the Koman empire was how to find a method of regulat- ing the succession. The difficulty has not , r> 1, ■ ,1 1 , . Succession. been lelt m other heterogeneous empires, as the Spanish empire in America, or the British empire in India. In those empires the nation which founded them by conquest retained its predominance, and the succession in the dominant nation settled the succession in the empire. In the Roman empire there was not any nation nor even any nationality in a position so dominant that it could settle the succession. Those provinces which were most 'often exposed to war, and were the best recruiting grounds, furnished the largest contributions to the strength of the army ; but there were many of the provinces which provided great hosts of soldiers, and there was no means of settling that one of them had more claim than the rest to settle what man should be the ruler. Tiberius, no doubt, hoped that the succession might remain in his own family by hereditary descent. But hereditary succession can never furnish „ •^ . Not heredi- perpetually a series of men equal to the tary for long terrible task which was imposed on a ^' ^ *""^" Roman emperor. The emperor had really to rule by his own will, with scarcely a single official adviser to help him ; the exaltation of the position drove a weak man like Caligula to madness, and no family ever goes on for long without having a weak man as its head. The Claudian house, to which Tiberius belonged, furnished four occupants of the throne ; "Nero, the 196 ROMAN EMPIRE [ch. x. last of the four, became intolerable to the Romans, and it was necessary to have recourse to some method of election. But there was no single recognised elective body ; on the contrary, there were many bodies which might put forward specious claims to be claims of the electors. These competing claimants elective -weve the senate, the prsetorian cohorts, and bodies. ^ . . each of the great armies stationed along the frontier. When in the year 68 a.d. there was a general desire in Rome to get rid of Nero, so many of the bodies which have been mentioned proceeded to election, that within two years six pretenders to the empire had been chosen. Two soon lapsed into obscurity; Galba, Otho, Vitellius paid the penalty of their daring with their lives; and Vespasian successfully fought his way to permanent occupa- tion of the throne. The Flavian house, to which he belonged, furnished as emperors after him his two sons Titus and Domitian. Soon after the death of Domitian, in 96 a.d., a method of providing successors was devised which avoided both the weakness inherent in a Adoption. , , . ., hereditary system and the civil wars at- tendant on election. The successor of Domitian was Nerva, elected by the senate, and therefore disliked by the prsetorian cohorts. To strengthen his tottering throne, Nerva adopted Trajan as his son and successor. It happened, fortunately for the empire, that Trajan and two emperors after him had no son, and the office of sovereign ruler was four times running CH. X.] THE SUCCESSION 197 filled by a process of adoption. The four adoptive emperors — Trajan, Hadrian, Antoninus Pius, and Marcus Aurelius — were all virtuous and capable men, and the period of their reigns, from 98 a.d. to 180 a.d., was the happiest in the annals of the empire. But it was the weakness of the system of adoption that it was not likely to control the succession, unless every emperor died without leaving a son behind him. The conscientious philosopher Marcus Aurelius, unhappily for mankind, was father of Commodus, the monster who for thirteen years polluted the imperial throne. After the death of Commodus, in 193 A.D., elections of rival pretenders by different provincial armies again raised conflicts about the succes- sion which could only be ended by the between arbitrament of battle. The successful ^'^^ ^° ^'^^' competitor on this occasion was Septimius Severus, who founded a dynasty which lasted through three generations. After its extinction, in 235 a.d., till 284 A.D., the imperial dignity was usually conferred by the armies upon soldiers, and often upon soldiers who had begun service in the army as Legionaries or private soldiers. The reigns of the Legionary Emperors were usually short; the soldiers became tired of their commanders, and put them to death ; and during the period from 235 to 284 the horrors of wars to settle the claims of rival pretenders reached their climax. The year 284 a.d. is marked by the accession of the statesman Diocletian. He tried to avoid the troubles 198 EOMAN EMPIEE [ch. x. arising from the disputed successions by a new method ; but before we observe what it was, we must turn back to see what new institutions had arisen in the empire. It is indeed impossible to ascertain how much importance they had acquired before the time of Diocletian, because we have very little information about them ; but yet it is necessary to note that some changes in the administrative system had been intro- duced since the monarchical rule had been established in the empire. Under the earlier emperors, the immediate suc- cessors of Tiberius, all the great administrative offices were of a military character ; the men who In the early „,, , ^ , , . , . , , empire all niied them, the highest placed among the officials were servants of the sovereign, who received military. _ _ ° their orders direct from the emperor him- self, were military officers in command of armies or brigades, though they were rulers over the civilian population in addition to being commanders of the soldiers. In the imperial provinces, where the emperor himself held the proconsulare impermm, the governors were legati, the lieutenants of the emperor ; in the twelve senatorial provinces they were proconsules or consulares, men appointed by the senate subject to the emperor's approval. In Italy there were commanders of military garrisons scattered through the country.^ In Rome the chief admini- strators were the prefect of the praetorian cohorts, and the three prefects set over the city of Rome, over its police (vigiles), and over its corn market. All ' Suetonius, Tiberius, 37. CH. X.] COUNCIL 199 these were military officers, and the spheres of their administrative competence embraced the whole area of the empire. The emperors needed confidential advisers, and it was hard to find them. They were not inclined to give great influence to military com- n rth f manders by admitting them to their secret confidential counsels; to attach weight to opinions expressed in the senate would be childish folly. Augustus, indeed, was not afraid to trust his son-in- law, the soldier and statesman Agrippa; but his successors were less confiding in men of military training. Tiberius chose Sejanus, of equestrian family and civilian education ; Claudius relied on his emanci- pated Greek slaves Narcissus and Pallas ; Nero for a time followed the advice of two Romans, Burrhus and Seneca, but after five years shook himself free from restraint. In the interval between the death of Nero and the accession of Hadrian, some emperor, probably Vespasian, established a council of con- ^^^ council fidential advisers. Hadrian, on succeeding of the to the throne in 118 A.D., found a council ^™p^'''"'' consisting of coTnici and comites, of a few knights and a few senators. It was Hadrian who gave the council its permanent importance by adding juris- consults to its numbers. The jurisconsults whom he introduced had already served in the office of praetor, the highest in the legal profession ; after their pro- motion to be councillors no authority except the emperor's coimcil was permitted to make any change 200 DIOCLETIAN [ch. x. in the Edictum Perpetuum, the authorised code of the Civil Law. From the time of Septimius Severus onwards the councillors received regular salaries. The stipend of a Gonsiliarius was fixed at 100,000 sesterces, containing nearly the same amount of gold or silver as a thousand pounds sterling in our present coinage ; asswmpti in consilium received only three- fifths of the salary of a Gonsiliarius. At the same period 300,000 sesterces was the salary of a Procurator of a province.^ It seems, then, that the stipends of the councillors were fixed somewhat low; but the institution of the council was of great importance because it enabled men of civilian training to rise to high office in the service of the emperor.^ Civilian training rose in the public estimation, and when Cams in 282 a.d. was elected to the imperial dignity, we are informed that he had passed through the grades of civil as well as military distinction.^ Diocletian and Constantino the Great were the founders of a new monarchy no less truly than Diocletian Augustus himself. They transformed the ^"^ imperial dignity from a military office to Constantine . . . the Great. a regularised despotism resting on public 284-337 A.D. veneration for the emperor. Diocletian changed the personal position of the master of the empire; Constantine provided him with a staff' of servants fit to perform the work of administration. When Diocletian became emperor the empire was ' Dion Cassius, liii. 15. 2 On the council of tlie emperor see E. Cuq in Mimoires de Vlnslitut (Inscriptions), vol. ix. ' Vopisous, Oarus, 6, 4. OH. X.] AND CONSTANTINE 201 oppressed by the constantly recurring diflSculties of settling the succession, and of protecting the frontiers against the barbarians. The usual electors of em- perors had for ages been either the praetorian cohorts or one of the armies stationed in the provinces; more recently, on the murder of Aurelian in 275, the decrepit and servile senate had been permitted to raise Tacitus to the throne. Diocletian destroyed the influence of the senate by removing the imperial court from Rome to Milan and to Nicomedia. He disbanded the insolent and indolent prsetorians, and employed for bodyguards two faithful legions re- cruited in his native country, Illyrium. He could not provide against the possibility that an army in the provinces might proclaim a new emperor, nor could he ensure for ever that the barbarians should not cross the frontiers; but he took precautions against both dangers at once by his division of the empire into four parts, and by his rules for regulating the succession. Two parts of the empire, having their centres in Italy and on the Propontis, were least open to barbarian attack; each of these was to be ruled by an Augustus. Diocletian himself from Nicomedia ruled over Thrace, Egypt, and Asia ; Italy and Africa were allotted to the other Aug- ustus, Maximian, whose court was at Milan. Each empire of an Augustus had adjacent to it another quarter of the whole Roman dominions more exposed to attack. For its defence it was the duty of the Augustus to appoint a younger man with the title of Csesar. Diocletian chose Galerius to reign at 202 CONSTANTINE [ch. x. Sirmium over the lUyrian provinces ; Maximian appointed Constantius Chlorus to rule at Treves over Gaul, Spain, and Britain. Each Augustus adopted the Caesar whom he had appointed as his son, and on the death of the Augustus the Caesar had a right to the succession. The two Augusti in their courts at Nicomedia and Milan assumed a ceremony and state unknown Seclusion to their predecessors. To wear a diadem, ^""^ a white fillet set with pearls and encir- magnincence of the clmg the head, had been thought the Augusti. most desperate act of mad Caligula. The wise Diocletian returned from policy to the diadem, renounced the toga, wore robes of silk and gold imitated from Persia, and not a soul murmured; indignation was roused by one practice only — the use of shoes studded with gems instead of the ordinary buskin. The Augustus became almost as inaccessible in his sacred seclusion as an oriental despot; and the fortunate subject who was admitted to the divine majesty was required to fall flat on his face in adoration.^ Diocletian's attempt to guard against wars of succession was a complete failure, because it was Constantine impossible to prevent armies in the pro- the Great. vinccs from investing their commanders with the purple. Two years after Diocletian abdi- cated, wars broke out between competing pretenders ; at one time there were six emperors in the field, and their wars lasted eighteen years. The final winner ' Gibbon, chapter xiii. CH. X.] CIVIL SERVICE 203 was Constantine, son of Constantius CJblorus. He won the western seat of empire in 312 by the battle of Saxa Rubra, and by his entry into Rome over the Milvian Bridge; and in 323 he won the east by the battle of Hadrianople and the siege of Byzantium. Constantine founded a new capital on the Bos- porus, and thereby gave the eastern empire a stronghold which helped it to survive the western empire by nearly a thousand ^f ^lyn ^^^ years. He made Christianity the religion miutary of the state, and thereby gained the aid of the bishops in holding up the tottering empire. In the eyes, however, of students of politics the greatest of his achievements was the severance of civil from military functions of government, and their assignment to a separate body of officials. When the remodelling of the government was completed, the men employed by Constantine as his implements were divided into the Three three classes of the civil service, the services, household, and the army. The civil servants dis- tributed justice, collected taxes, and promulgated the emperor's commands to the population; the household officers attended to the splendour and security of the court, and aided the emperor to compose his laws and ordinances; the army de- fended the frontiers, and in case of need compelled the population of the empire to obey the civil servants, who formed the link of communication between the emperor and the mass of his subjects. 204 CONSTANTINE [CH. X. The chiefs of the civil service were six praetorian prefects ; next under them came thirteen vicarii ; The civU below them a hundred and sixteen rulers service. q£ single provinces. The whole Roman dominions were divided into six prefectures, each committed to the care of a praetorian prefect. Two prefectures corresponded with the empires of Dio- cletian's Csesares ; two more consisted of the cities of Rome and Constantinople; the two that remained comprised the empires of Diocletian's Augusti, with the exception of the capitals. Before the changes made by Constantine there had been only two praeto- rian prefects, endowed both with military command and the power of civil administration. Constantine deprived them of all military authority, and converted them into judges of appeal in their prefectures.^ The vicarii were subordinate to the prefects, and pre- sided over smaller districts known as dioeceses ; the whole empire outside the capitals made only four prefectures but contained thirteen dioeceses. The prefecture which was once the empire of Constantius Chlorus had only one prefect sitting as judge of appeal at Treves; but it had three vicarii for its dioeceses of Gaul, Spain, and Britain. The business of the vicarii most frequently mentioned in the despatches of the emperors is the collection of taxes ; but they must have had other duties too.^ The hundred and sixteen rulers of provinces had com- paratively narrow areas of government. The pro- 1 Zosimus, ii. 32, 33. ^ Oodex Theodosianus, xl., in titulo De annona. OH. X.] ARMY 205 vinces when Octavian took the title of Augustus were only twenty-two; since then provinces had been subdivided till their number rose to a hundred and sixteen. Their rulers bore varying titles: three in Africa, Asia, and Achaia still bore the old name of proconsul; the rest were consulares, correctores, or prcesides. Whatever their title, all were equally subject to their vicarius and their prefect.^ Seven ministers in the imperial household managed the court and aided the emperor in his own work. The chamberlain, the counts of the privy The purse and of the horse-guards and foot- ^lousehoid. guards have titles which explain themselves. The Count of the Sacred Largesses was treasurer of the public revenue. He also was master of the mints and controlled the managers of the factories of weavers, dyers, and seamstresses who in distant pro- vinces laboured for the adornment of the court and its inmates. The Master of the Offices ruled over the armourers and arsenals. The Quaestor was the drafts- man of the emperor's laws and despatches. The ministers, however, of the household all depended for their relative importance less on the performance of their regular functions than on the degree in which they enjoyed their master's confidence. The military commanders were eight Magistri Militura, four with local commands, four retained at ^ Our authority for the civil service and the other branches of Constantine's system is the Notitia Dignitatum. The part relating to Britain was composed not before 370 A.D., because it mentions the province of Valentia, then first made ; the whole must have been drawn up before 406 A.D., when the Romans lost nearly all Gaul. 206 CONSTANTINE [ch. x. court. Below them were eight counts in command of large and important districts : lesser districts were commanded by dukes, whose number The army. i • n f t • amounted m ail to twenty-iive. it is certain that the number of men serving in the army was greatly increased by Diocletian, and possible that the forces were further enlarged in the reign of Constantine. After the changes made by Constantine wars between pretenders became less frequent. The electors The empire ^^ pretenders had in the old time been after Con- the prsetorian cohorts, the senate, or a stantine. . . , -nt .i j • provmcial army. JNow the prsetorian co- horts were extinct, the senate was disregarded, and no provincial army dared to set up a pretender except in distant Britain, the island fertile of usurpers.^ On the death of Jovian in 364 A.D., the ministers of the household, the chief civil servants, and military com- manders formed an assembly well qualified to select a candidate for the empire. The soldiers allowed the great men to deliberate solemnly and at leisure, and when Valentinian was announced as their nominee they ratified his election with enthusiasm. In the provinces, other than Britain, the civil servants were an effective restraint on the ambition of generals. A prefect or a vicarius could not be himself a pretender because he had no soldiers, and if he saw treasonable designs in a military commander it was to his interest to give warning to the emperor. The whole work of government under the emperor ' Fertilis tyraniiorum insula. CH. X.] CIVIL SERVICE 207 was done by the civil service. In the civil service subordination was as rigid as in an army : it must be so in every well-ordered hierarchy of civil po^er of the servants. The prefects gave orders to civil service, the vicarii, the vicarii to the rulers of provinces, the rulers of provinces to lesser officers, and the least officer in the civil service to the non-official popula- tion, high and low alike. The same subordination and transmission of commands appears in every well- ordered civil service. It is present in our own country at the present day ; but with us, if any citizen is aggrieved at the action of a civil servant he can appeal to a law-court independent of the administra- tion, or make his grievance known to the public through Parliament : a Roman subject could only complain to some higher grade in the administrative machine. Throughout the civil service commands were usu- ally transmitted in writing, and every considerable officer was supplied with a staff of scriv- Bureaucracy. eners. The commands of the government when they reached the non-official population were issued to them from a bureau, and if any of them caused hardship there was no power that could alter them except some higher bureau in the service. Since, then, the government was characterised by the supremacy of quill-drivers working in bureaux, it is one of those governments which often bear the clumsy name of bureaucracy. The government was usually careful and just ; but the whole of Constan- tine's methods were expensive. The pressure of taxa- 208 HETEROGENEOUS EMPIRES [CH. x. tion eventually became intolerable. The government, despairing of gathering in the whole amount itself, threw the burden of collection on the curiales, the most substantial burghers in the municipal towns, and made them responsible in their own pockets for any deficit. Their condition became so miserable that a law had to be passed restraining them from escaping their responsibility by selling themselves into slavery. The civil servants were active and ubiquitous, but their activity had the effect of killing the capacity for initiating improvements in the whole non-official population. The Roman empire was purely an artificial product. It did not subsist long enough to be fashioned into a single natural community by the opera- ous empires tion of natural instincts, and its forms of government were assigned to it not by nature, but by the skill and design of its rulers. The same propositions are true of all other well-known heterogeneous empires that have existed hitherto. Hence if we compare heterogeneous empires and compare their governments we shall not discover uniformities arising from natural causes, for there are none to find. At the most we can only discover rules of art criticism, which may enable us to discern which designers of imperial governments did their work well and which did it badly. Art criticism in the world of politics is dull work, and I intend here to compress into a brief space nearly all that I wish to say about heterogeneous empires and their governments. CH. X.] ARTIFICIAL 209 The Koman empire shows us that there is no uniform type of government for a heterogeneous empire. From its beginning early in the ^j^^j^. second century e.g. till the dictatorship of governments /-N I • • T 1 very variable. (Jsesar, each proyincial governor was nearly independent. From Csesar to Diocletian the pro- vincial rulers united military and civil functions, but were kept in due obedience to the emperor unless they felt themselves strong enough to supplant him. From Constantino onward the government was entrusted to civilians kept in subordination to the sovereign and the law. Other governments of empires have been most diverse. Charlemagne's government will be depicted in the next chapter. The govern- ment of the Spaniards in South America resembled the government in the Roman empire before Csesar in leaving the provincial rulers nearly independent. The provinces of the French empire under the Directory were converted into vassal republics, under Napoleon into vassal principalities. Our own empire in India has had many governments devised for it. At the present time both the British possessions in India and the Russian empire are governed under an omnipotent civil service supported by a powerful army. It does not seem probable that a hetero- geneous empire, an artificial product, can ever have a government working so thoroughly in accordance with the desires of the population as the governments which spring up in more naturally formed com- munities. The most that can be looked for in the government of such an empire is that it shall be o 210 AND VARIOUSLY GOVERNED [ch. x. stable, strong, and paternally benevolent ; and these qualities have been found only in the governments of the Roman empire after Constantino, the Russian empire, and the British empire in India. All three governments have been fashioned, so it seems, inde- pendently and without imitation ; but they are alike in their structure, and both the modern governments conform to the pattern which Constantine invented. Note. — The political bodies, which I have called Heterogeneous Empires, are distinguished by Sir John Seeley in his Introduction to Political Science (pages 72-76) as inorganic political bodies. I have preferred to designate them as heterogeneous, because it is always easy to see whether a political body is composed of unlike materials, but it is sometimes difficult to see whether it is organic or inorganic. We may, moreover, doubt whether any political body is inorganic, in the sense of being totally devoid of organs. The Roman empire has as good a claim to be called inorganic as almost any other political body ; but, in whatever way we define the word organ, it is hard to deny that in the Eoman empire, the Senate, the Prastorian Cohorts, and the armies in the Provinces were organs, when they took upon them the power of electing emperors. CHAPTEK XI MIXED POPULATIONS One of the greatest breaks that has ever interrupted the continuity of the history of Europe occurred in the fifth and sixth centuries, when a number of German tribal communities overran Gaul, Spain, and Italy. In the history of political communities the migrations of the Germans into the western provinces of the Roman empire are especially momentous. They destroyed the only important political organi- sation in the western world, and they made the three most civilised countries of the west incapable for centuries of giving birth to any coherent and united communities. In those three countries, Gaul, Spain, and Italy, during seven centuries that elapsed between the beginning of the migrations and the year 1100, there were states indeed or masses of population under independent governments, but none of them were united political communities except three little bands of exiles who took refuge in secluded valleys of the Pyrenean range and the mountains of Cantabria and Asturia. All the other independent states were not communities, because they were made up of populations which had very 212 MIXED POPULATIONS [oh. xi. little in common, and they therefore lacked that quality of coherence which is an essential attribute of a political community. The large states which grew up in Gaul, Spain, and Italy between the years 400 and 1100 were Mixed incoherent because they were made up of populations, heterogeneous and incongruous materials. We have already taken notice in the last chapter of a state composed of heterogeneous materials. It was there remarked that the Roman dominions when first conquered constituted a heterogeneous empire, because each of the countries comprised in them had a distinctive character impressed upon it by ages of past history, and all the countries were dis- similar in character to each other and to Rome. Dissimilarity of populations in different countries ruled by one government was the kind of hetero- geneity which it was important to notice in the Roman empire. This kind of heterogeneity was to be found in some of the states which existed in Gaul, Spain, and Italy in the early Middle Ages: it is conspicuous in the empire of Charlemagne, which took in all Gaul, half of Italy, and a corner of Spain. But in most of the states which arose in western Europe soon after the migrations there was another kind of heterogeneity which we have not yet had occasion to notice. It is well exemplified in the kingdom of the Ostrogoths founded by Theodoric in Italy. In this kingdom the territory of northern Italy had to accommodate two very dissimilar popu- lations whose individual members were scattered CH. XI.] INCONGEUOUS ELEMENTS 213 broadcast over the soil in confusion which cannot be described. The Italians, who formed the population of the country before the Ostrogoths immigrated into it, remained where they were ; but one-third of each man's estate of land was transferred to the ownership of one of the Ostrogothic conquerors.^ In every part of Gaul and Spain nearly the same conditions pre- vailed as soon as the migrations of the Germans had taken place ; and thus mixture and confusion of unlike populations inhabiting a common territory was the kind of heterogeneity which prevailed uni- versally in all the states founded in the early Middle Ages in the western countries of the European continent. The presence of two unlike populations in the same territory was not an entirely novel phenomenon, occurring for the first time in the history incongruous of mankind when the Germans invaded elements, western Europe. In periods that are almost entirely prehistoric we meet frequently with a bare mention of a migration of some barbarous people ; and it is likely that many of the migratory peoples on settling in new abodes did not expel the old inhabitants. We know that in the prehistoric migration of the Spartans they did not expel the Periseki and Helots, but lived surrounded by them. There are also in- stances of mixtures of unlike populations well recorded in ancient historians. A great number of ' Gibbon, ch. xxxix. The thirds of the estates had perhaps been taken away from the Italians by Odovacar and given to his soldiers. If so, they were now taken from Odovacar's soldiers and given to Ostrogoths. — Gibbon, Bury's edition, vol. iv. p. 181, note. 214 MIXED POPULATIONS [ch. xi. Greek-speaking emigrants followed in the wake of Alexander's conquests and gave a mixed population to Asia Minor, Syria, and Egypt. The Germans, then, when they gave a mixed population to western Europe did nothing entirely unprecedented ; and yet the mixture of unlike populations which followed from their migrations was more important in history than any other. It extended over a very large area; it caused the disruption of the older half of that wonderful Koman empire which the world had been wont to revere ; and it was fatal to the existence of the young and hopeful tribal communities of the invading Germans. Besides this, the populations which it joined together in an ill-assorted marriage were more grotesquely incongruous than any others that have been joined in such a union. The subject peoples, the Eoman provincials, were the most civil- ised peoples in the world : the rulers, the Germans, were ignorant barbarians. It is not, then, a matter for surprise that the migrations of the Germans pro- duced effects in western Europe which have already been felt for fifteen centuries, and may probably be felt for as many centuries hereafter. The fact which distinguishes the conquests of the Germans from most other conquests is that they Old ties broke up the political organisation both broken. of the victors and the vanquished. Con- quests and migrations have not always been thus doubly destructive. The conquests of the Spartan immigrants into Laconia destroyed only the com- monwealths of the subjugated Helots and Periaeki, CH. XL] AMORPHOUS STATES 215 but left the Spartan community stronger and more coherent than ever. The immigrations of Danes and Normans into England, although the immigrant kings Cnut and William conquered the whole of the English people, did not destroy the English institu- tions; and though they made the population of England less united than it had been, they did not altogether deprive it of coherence. The migrations of the Germans into Gaul, Spain, and Italy not only destroyed such coherence as the old inhabitants had acquired under the rule of the Romans, but also shattered into fragments the tribal communities of the victorious Germans. The largfe political bodies which grew up in Gaul, Spain, and Italy between 400 and 1100 were not only lacking in the quality of coherence, but Amorphous none of them, except perhaps the empire states. of Charlemagne, had any definite and recognisable structure. As compared with the tribes and cities which were noticed in my first nine chapters, they were amorphous bodies. In the tribal communities and simple cities with definite structure we were able to observe that each kind of structure had a definite form of its organ of government which seemed to have been allotted to it by nature. In the political bodies with mixed populations which existed in the Dark Ages I cannot discover any definite structure, and it does not seem that there was any rule which determined that any one of them should have its organ of government fashioned in one way rather than another. The absence of definite 216 MIXED POPULATIONS [ch. xi. structure in these political bodies, and the absence of any uniformity in their organs of government, will become visible if we pass them before us in a rapid review. In Spain before the migration of the Germans the population consisted of Iberians and Celts who had been accustomed for centuries to live as provincials of the Roman empire. Over this population surged in the Germans : they came in successive waves of Vandals, Alans, Suevi, and Visi- goths. The Vandals, however, in 429 left Spain and betook themselves to Africa. About forty years later the Visigothic king Euric overpowered his rivals in the peninsula. From this time forth till 710 Visi- goths were kings of Spain, residing at Toledo. Their subjects were for the most part Romanised Iberians with some admixture of Visigoths, Alans, and Suevi. We do not know much about their government, but from the frequent recurrence of conspiracies, deposi- tions of kings, and exaltations of usurpers, it seems likely that they lived under the free but disorderly tribal institutions which they had brought with them from Germany, although they were living in circum- stances for which those institutions were ill suited. In Italy the first German immigrants were the Ostrogoths, who effected their settlement in the Italy: Country under their king Theodoric in Ostrogoths. 493. Theodoric did not attempt to bring about a fusion but rather a federation between his Gothic and Italian subjects.^ He kept the Roman ' Hodgkin, Italy and her Invaders, vol. Hi. p. 277 in edition of 1885. CH. XL] SPAIN: ITALY 217 system of administration. At the head of the central government was a Praetorian Prefect; the local administration of provinces in Italy was entrusted to Correctores, as it had been under the Emperors.^ But for the settlement of suits between Goths there was a Comes Oothorum, who was no doubt always a barbarian, and judged between Goths according to the customary Gothic law.^ Theodoric himself reigned with the omnipotence and pomp of a Roman emperor, and all his government was conducted according to Eoman rather than Gothic methods. Theodoric died in 52€. Soon after his death dis- cords appeared in the Italian peninsula. Between 534 and 555 it was conquered by Belisarius it^iy: and Narses, acting on behalf of the Byzan- Lombards, tine empire. The Byzantines ruled Italy for twelve years : in 561 nearly all their acquisitions were taken from them by new German immigrants, the Lom- bards, who were led into the peninsula by Alboin. The Lombards founded a kingdom with its capital at Pavia, and four outlying duchies at Benevento, Spoleto, Friuli, and Trient. These Lombard states were not so entirely incoherent as those which arose in Gaul and Spain : perhaps their small size helped them. In the eighth century it looked as if some of the duchies might in time grow into united political communities, if they were left undisturbed for a few centuries."* The wealth, however, of Italy and the ' Hodgkin, Italy and her Invaders, vol. iii. pp. 301, 313. 2 Ihid. vol. iii. p. 281. ' Ibid. Vols. V. and vi. tell what is known of the Lombards in Italy. 218 MIXED POPULATIONS [ch. xi. name of Rome attracted new invaders into the pen- insula. The Lombard kingdom and three of the duchies were brought under the alien rule of Charles the Great ; and Benevento, the one Lombard settle- ment which remained independent of the Austrasian conqueror, was incorporated in the eleventh century in the dominions of the Norman settlers in southern Italy. In Gaul the inhabitants, before the migration, were Celts who had been subject for about four centuries and a half to the rule of Rome, had lived Gaul. . . . under Roman administration, had adopted the Roman tongue, and been converted to the Catholic religion. After the migration these Roman- ised Celts still constituted the main mass of the population; they were a uniform and deep sub- stratum, over which a thin layer of German immi- grants was spread. The German newcomers were of three different races, and they occupied districts geographically distinct from one another. The Burgundians spread themselves over the valleys of the Saone and Rhone, from Dijon in the north and Geneva in the east, to Avignon in the south. The Visigoths settled in the region between the Loire and the Pyrenees; the Salian Franks covered all northern Gaul from the Scheldt to the Bay of Biscay, with the exception of Armorica or Bretagne, and had for their southern limit the river Loire and the high ground to the north of Dijon, which forms the water- shed between the Seine and the Saone. In the country occupied by the Salian Franks the upper CH. XI.] GAUL 219 layer of Germans in the population was probably not nearly so thin as it was in the lands of the Burgun- dians and the Visigoths. By the year 534, about a century and a quarter after the great migrations into Gaul began, the princes of the Salian dynasty founded by Clovis had received the submission of both the German races who had settled in the south-east and south-west of Gaul, and also of the Kipuarian Franks who had not joined in the migra- tion but had remained in their old home on the banks of the Khine. During the sixth century there were usually three kingdoms entirely situate within the limits of Gaul, and ruled by Salian princes ; there was also a fourth kingdom ruled by descendants of Clovis, which had for its kernel the purely German population of the Eipuarian Franks, but also in- cluded some territory in Gaul with a mixed popula- tion. The complete incoherence of the states ruled by the Salian Franks in Gaul is shown by the incessant shiftings of the boundaries of their ter- ritories. The princes of the Salian dynasty carved up the soil into portions by agreement exactly as they pleased, and a series of political maps of Gaul in the sixth century is as bewildering as a succession of images seen in a kaleidoscope. In each of the partitions of territory a population which had been under a single ruler was divided into parts under different rulers ; but it never thought of remon- strating, because it had no coherence and no desire to have a government of its own. In the seventh century all the kingdoms in Gaul lapsed by inherit- 220 MIXED POPULATIONS [cii. xi. ance to a single Salian ruler, and they accepted their union with the same indifference as the partitions. It is plain, then, that the mixed populations which inhabited Spain, Italy, and Gaul after the migrations , . . , were for a time incapable of forming Incipient '■ . . _ ° fusion of themselves into coherent political bodies. races. -g^^ ^^ process of time a mixed population gives birth to a homogeneous population, if only the two races which make up the mixture will inter- marry. In Gaul and Italy the Germans and the Romans did intermarry, and eventually in each district instead of a mixed population there was a fused and homogeneous single race. The process of fusion was probably not completed in any district of either of these countries till about the year 1100, when it had been going on for seven centuries. But even so early as the end of the sixth century we can see that the union of Germans and Romans through intermarriage was beginning. In northern Gaul there was arising a race born of Frankish and Roman parents whose descendants would in future generations be known as Frenchmen; the valleys of the Saone and Rhone were providing progenitors for a united race who were to be known as Burgun- dians; the south-west was laying the foundations of a future race of Aquitanians; and in Italy marriages of Germans with Romans promised to coming ages some of the homogeneous races which have since then peopled the northern part of the peninsula. But the formation of homogeneous races by inter- CH. XI.J INCIPIENT FUSION 221 marriage had made very little progress in the sixth and seventh centuries. It had, however, begun, and it would probably have led to the forma- „ . tion of many coherent political communi- tion and new ties sooner than it did, but for one circum- "^""i"^^ ■ stance. The formation of a homogeneous race, even when the process is completed, does not lead to the making of a coherent political community, unless the race is left undisturbed. In Spain, Gaul, and Italy the growing races, long before they had attained to homogeneity, were hindered from making any steps towards founding compact political communi- ties either by new migrations, which made a new mixture of populations, or by the action of conquest, which joined many growing races in unnatural union under a common government. The new conquerors were, in Spain, the Moors ; elsewhere the Austrasian Franks under the Pippins and Charlemagne. It seems that the Austrasian conquests arrested and delayed healthy growth wherever they went. The Moorish conquests had the same result in all the area over which they extended ; but in the north of Spain they had the beneficent though accidental result of pro- viding the land with an unmixed population. The effects produced by a new migration and new conquests, after the sixth century, have now to be noticed. We shall observe these effects in Spain, Gaul, and Italy, at various periods between the sixth and the eleventh centuries. Spain was deluged between 710 and 713 with a new flood of immigrants. These new settlers came by 222 MIXED POPULATIONS [CH. xi. way of Africa ; some were Arabs from Arabia, divided into many tribes and into two or more religious and political factions, which cordially de- tested one another ; the rest were Berbers (or Moors) from Africa. The immigrants then suffered from discords and divisions ; but all of them were Mohammedans, all were greedy of winning the wealth of a European country, and they were strong enough to overpower with ease the motley multitude of Visigoths, Suevi, Alans, and Komans, who were subject to Koderic, king of Spain. The whole country except some few mountainous regions was rich. All over the rich part of the country the Mohammedans settled together with the Christians; the moun- tainous regions did not greatly attract them. They treated the conquered Spaniards among whom they settled with extraordinary toleration. Those Spaniards who were willing to accept the Koran were placed on an equal footing in regard to civil rights with the conquerors; those who adhered to the Christian religion retained not only their personal liberty and private property, but their churches, their bishops, their priests, and full freedom for their religious services and worship : in return for these favours they were merely required to pay a special tribute in addition to the taxes levied on the Moham- medans.i In every large town which the conquerors occupied there was probably a Christian congregation. In Toledo, in the first half of the thirteenth century, when Koderic, the archbishop of that city, wrote his ' Lembke, OescMchte von Spanien, p. 310. CH. xi.J SPAIN 223 history, there were six churches which kept to the old ritual of St. Isidore and St. Ildefonso. This ritual belonged to the time before the Moors came to Spain, and the six churches had probably continued to exist through all the centuries of Mohammedan domina- tion.^ But, on the other hand, it seems likely that a majority of the Spaniards accepted the Koran in order to escape the payment of the tribute; there were constant rebellions of Mohammedans against the Mohammedan emir, king, or caliph who reigned at Cordova, and many of them were led by men who had originally professed the Christian religion, but had now renounced it for the religion of Mohammed. The mixed population of Moors and Spaniards in the plains and cities was obviously incapable for ages of producing any coherent political com- „ . munity. But the Moorish conquerors had refugees in neglected some of the mountains. Such *"""■ masses of rocks in the middle of Spain as the Sierra Morena or the Guadarrama could not be the home of an independent people, because they were sur- rounded by flat and rich country in which the Moorish armies moved freely. But the mountainous regions at the foot of the Pyrennees and in Cantabria and Asturia by the shore of the Bay of Biscay, could be attacked by a land force only from the south, and even from the south the approaches were very difficult. In these inaccessible mountain-sides three ' I have read of the six churches in Roderic's history, but cannot now find the passage again. In Granada in the ninth century there were four churches. Dozy, Mussulmans d'Espagne, vol. ii. p. 209. 224 CHEISTIANS IN SPAIN [ch. xi. little bands of exiles, who would not submit to be ruled by Moors, found a safe but most inhospitable refuge. We do not know who these men were ; certainly there were Visigoths among them, for they afterwards called themselves the Goths ; and it seems likely that most of them were of German rather than Iberian origin. The Germans in Spain had been the masters, and were likely to be too proud to endure the rule of Asiatics or Africans; the Iberians had been inured to centuries of subjection under Komans or Germans, and they would probably submit readily to the tolerant and easy-going Mussulmans. The one thing certain is that the exiles immediately set up rulers over themselves, and grew into political communities, with populations held together by a common purpose of uncompromising resistance to the Moors. There was one band of exiles in each of the regions afterwards known as Navarre, Cantabria, and Asturia. They had no towns, and all their pursuits were military, predatory, or pastoral. They were then tribal communities no less truly than the peoples of the Saxons and Angles when first they arrived in Britain. In other respects too they were like the earliest Teutonic settlers in our island. They lived in a country much cut off by nature from inter- course with Europe ; they lived on the edge of the country close to the seaj and when they made conquests further inland they drove the Moors before them and refused to mix with them. As the Spanish refugees were like the English colonists in Britain in tribal condition, in the site of their CH. XI.] AUSTEASIAN FRANKS 225 dwellings, and their relation to the neighbouring territory and its inhabitants, it is not surprising that in the Middle Ages there was a strong resem- blance between the Castilian Cortes and the English Parliament. Gaul in the seventh century, and Italy in the eighth, offered an easy prey to any new conqueror with a compact body of men behind. The only compact and united communities Austrasian on the continent were those tribes in ^'^^'^s- Germany which had taken no part in the migrations, and had therefore retained an unmixed German population. Of these tribes, the strongest and most enterprising was the Frankish people of the Eipuarians or Austrasians ; and so it came about that a Ripuarian Frank became master of central Europe. In the sixth century the Ripuarian Franks, as we have already noticed, were ruled by kings of the Salian house of Clovis. Some of these kings, as Theudebert, Clothachar the First, and his son Sige- bert, were able rulers and warriors, and during their reigns the Ripuarian Franks attained to a sort of hegemony over some peoples in the interior of Germany, as the Thuringians and Bavarians. The realm of the Ripuarian Franks became so powerful that it was an equal rival to all the lands that the Salian Franks had acquired in Gaul, and hence it naturally acquired the distinctive name of Austrasia, the Ost-land or Eastern land. The Austrasians were content to be ruled by the Salian princes till 675, when they were deprived of their able king Sigebert by a 226 AUSTRASIAN FRANKS [ch. xi. brutal murder perpetrated at Vitry, near Arras, in Gaul.i Even after his death his heroic widow, the Spanish princess Brunhildis, retained authority over them during the boyhood of her young son. That son grew to manhood, but died young in 596. Brun- hildis again became regent, but before long the Austrasians grew tired of being ruled by foreigners. At the head of the household of the Salian king in Austrasia was an officer called Mayor of the Palace. The Mayor was naturally a native-born Austrasian, and he was supported by the nobles, who were called leudes. The princes of the Salian house continued to bear the name of king, but by the year 660 all power had passed from them, and the Mayor with his leudes were the true rulers of the Austrasian people. The nature of their government is not precisely known; but evidently it was a tribal government conducted by the Mayor and an irregular council of nobles, and was not very different from that which prevailed at the same time in the English tribes of the Mercians or the Northumbrians. The Austrasian Franks were a large but fairly compact people, living on both banks of the Rhine from the borders of the Netherlands as far upwards as Mainz, and also filling most of the country between the Rhine and the Meuse. It seems that in the early part of the seventh century they devoted most of their attention to their Gallic neighbours on the west. At the end of that century their hegemony over the peoples in the interior of Germany no longer existed ' Greg. Turon., Hist. Franc, iv. 36. CH. XI. J RAPID CONQUESTS 227 in any recognised form. The Thuringians successfully asserted their independence in 641 ; ^ the Frisians, near the Zuyder Zee, and the Suabians in the Black Forest, were not reduced to submission till some time between 687 and 714;^ and the Bavarians not till about 720.^ But though the Austrasians had no regular superiority over the peoples of inner Germany in the seventh century, it is certain that individual tribesmen from Thuringia, Suabia, or Bavaria were quite ready to follow their standards whenever there was a prospect of plunder. The Austrasian Franks in the seventh and eight centuries made more extensive conquests than have elsewhere in European history been made i^apid by so small a people in so short a time, conquests. In 687, at the great battle of Testry (between St. Quentin and Amiens), they conquered all Gaul. In the years from 687 to 730 they overpowered many German peoples to the north and east of their own territory — the Frisians, Suabians, Bavarians, Thur- ingians. In 732, at Poitiers, they repelled the terrible inroad of the Spanish Moors. Between 754 and 803 they conquered Saxony (which lay between the Thuringians and the German Ocean), the northern half of Italy, and the extreme eastern corner of Spain now known as Catalonia. When these con- quests were completed, Charlemagne, the ruler of the ' Fredegar, book iv. ch. 87, in M. O. H. Script. Merov., vol. ii. p. 164. ^ Fredegar, continuation, ih. p. 172; and Lib. Hist. Franc, ib. pp. 323, 324. 3 Oman, The Dark Ages, p. 270. 228 CHARLEMAGNE [ch. xi. Austrasian Franks, was master of central Europe from the German Ocean to Rome, and from the mouth of the Elbe to the mouth of the Ebro. As the conquests of the Austrasian Tranks were effected with a suddenness and rapidity unparallelled Transient ^^ European history, so their empire was empire. conspicuously dsvoid of any natural tend- ency to cohere together. It was not much like any of the other states which have existed in Europe ; it was in its origin and character more like some of the Asiatic empires, and might be compared with the empire of the Seljukian Turks founded by Togrul Beg, Alp Arslan, and Malek Shah, or the Mogul empire founded by Baber, Humayun, and Akbar. It was composed of most dissimilar materials; its organisation was ill adapted for holding it together ; and it was only saved from falling in pieces im- mediately by the great ability and strong character of its rulers — Pippin of Heristal, the victor of Testry; Carl Martel, the hero of Poitiers ; Pippin the Short, king of the Franks in 762 ; and the Emperor Charle- magne. We will now observe how this empire was governed. In the year 800 Charlemagne revived in name, but not in efficient power, the Western Roman Empire. On Christmas Day in that year he was Charlemagne. j 13 t. t> r crowned as Roman emperor by rope Leo the Third in the Basilica of St. Peter at Rome, and thenceforth regarded himself as a legitimate successor of Constantine and Theodosius. His in- auguration fulfilled all the conditions that were ever CH. xi.J CHARLEMAGNE 229 required to validate the accession to power of a Roman emperor; he was acclaimed by his soldiers, and obeyed by his subjects ; nothing more was needed according to the ideas of the old Romans to make his appointment regular and proper. But he had not the aids, instruments, and machinery for holding his empire together which Constantine and Theodosius had enjoyed in such abundance. In the Roman empire cohorts or legions were stationed as per- manent garrisons throughout the provinces, wherever they were needed, to ensure submission or to repel attacks; the army of Charlemagne only existed during the summer months. The Roman emperors had their Praetorian prefects and magistri militum, and below these whole hosts of officers, both civil and military, in gradations from the highest to the lowest, all submitting to the strictest discipline, all having unquestioned authority over every subject who was not an official. Charlemagne had nothing of the kind ; he had for the rule of his huge dominions only his own innate energy of mind and the tribal institutions under which his forefathers had lived in Austrasia. The central government of the empire consisted of Charlemagne himself and of two assemblies in the course of the year which were tribal in charie- character but of overgrown dimensions, magne's mi IT Til 1 government. ihese assemblies were held at any place to which the emperor summoned them. The com- monest places of meeting were some of his large estates or farms in Austrasia near the Rhine. The 230 DISRUPTION OF EMPIEE [ch. xi. meetings, like all tribal assemblies, were held in the .open air, and the great gathering of men was like the encampment of an army. One assembly, held every autumn, consisted only of nobles, and a chief part of its business was to arrange a campaign for the following year ; the other meeting, held in the spring and known as the Camp of May, was attended both by nobles and by all the soldiery, and served as a^ muster of the host before starting on the military enterprise of the year. The local governors all through the empire were nobles. They had large districts to rule, and bore the titles of dukes or counts. The weakest point in the whole government was the want of any sufficient series of officers to serve as a link between the central and the local governments. Charlemagne could not create at once such a gradation of officers for this purpose as the Romans had taken centuries to make: he did the best he could by sending out occasional commissioners from the central government to supervise the work of the local rulers. These commissioners were the Missi Dominici, the Messengers of the Lord Emperor. They usually went in pairs ; bishops were often chosen for the work, and they had ample powers. They presided in local assemblies, looked into all the work of provincial administration, and were authorised, in case of urgent necessity, to supersede any of the counts or dukes and to take his functions into their own hands. Soon after the death of Charlemagne in 814 his empire began to break in pieces and his subjects to CH. XI.] NATURAL COMMUNITIES 231 sort themselves into groups according to their natural afSnities. Louis the D^bonnaire, son of Charle- magne, was powerless to hold the empire Natural com- united, and his reign from 814 to 840 munities was troubled with constant wars waged by fragments of his sons against one another. In 843, at '•'^ empire, the treaty of Verdun, the empire was divided into three independent parts : one was the main mass of Gaul which we may now call France, another was Germany and Saxony, the third Italy with a strip of Gaul. But the disruption did not stop here. Germany, indeed, held together. Its king, Louis the Germanic, was a grandson of Charlemagne of pure German descent. He was a most capable and useful commander of the Germans in their wars against Slavic barbarians, and he kept the Germans and Saxons for the time a united people. In France and Italy the case was far different. There the kings, being Austrasian Franks descended from Charle- magne, were aliens to their subjects, and as aliens were disliked. The local rulers, called counts or dukes, and other owners of estates of lands, had become Frenchmen in France and Italians in Italy from long living among the populations of the countries as neighbours with neighbours. The peoples in France and Italy cared nothing for their Austrasian kings; the dukes, the counts, the landowners, and any upstarts who had become local magnates, wishing to escape, from rendering service to the kings, rebelled against them and received support from the popula- tions among whom they lived. The local rulers, the 232 SAXON EMPIKE [CH. xi. landlords, and adventurers all through France and Italy, became perfectly independent of their kings, and before 950 both countries were broken up into a multitude of independent states generally known as fiefs or feudal principalities. These little princi- palities were formed by the spontaneous action of populations voluntarily submitting to be led by some duke, count, landowner, or adventurer who suited them better than any one else that was ready to hand, and therefore they were far more like political communities than anything else that had been seen in France and Italy since the time of the migrations. Yet one more great series of conquests occurred in the Dark Ages. This time the conquerors were the The Saxon Saxons. We have already noticed that Empire. ^]^g Saxons were conquered (after a most obstinate and gallant resistance), between 754 and 803, by Pippin the Short and Charles the Great, and thus became a dependency — and a most vigorous and powerful dependency — of the Austrasian empire. We have also noticed that in 843, when the empire was divided. Saxony and Germany formed the king- dom of Louis the Germanic. That kingdom held together under Louis and his descendants till the year 899. In that year died Arnulf, a worthy scion of the race of Charlemagne and of Louis the Germanic. His young son, Louis the Child, was allowed to succeed him, but died in 911 before attaining to the strength of manhood. During the reign of the Child the kingdom broke up into its five natural divisions, Saxony, Franconia, Suabia, Bavaria, Lotharingia. CH. XI.] DISRUPTION 233 Among these divisions Saxony was the strongest and the most united, and the Saxons in the tenth century repeated on a smaller scale the exploits of the Ripu- arian Franks in the seventh and eighth. Between 918 and 936 Henry the First, Duke of Saxony, remade the kingdom of Germany. His son. Otto the Great, between 936 and 973 brought northern Italy into his dominions and founded (or refounded) the Holy Roman Empire. The Saxon empire of Otto and his successors was no less incoherent than the Austrasian empire of Charlemas'ne. The government consisted , • ? -. . ■ ,1- Natural only m the emperor and his assemblies communities of nobles : the Missi Dominici were not J°"''"^^ "" Italy. revived. The emperors drew their military forces from Germany. They were not able to convey across the great barrier of the Alps a sufScient supply of German soldiers to control Italy. The Italians had founded a number of towns with homogeneous populations animated, like the Greek towns of old, with an ardent local patriotism; and the Emperor Frederick Barbarossa, after waging many fruitless campaigns from 1154 to 1176, was compelled, in 1183, to acknowledge by treaty that each of the Italian towns was free to govern itself on condition of render- ing some small dues to the emperor when he was present in Italy. At the same time, the attempts of the emperors to be masters of Italy involved them in hostilities with the great rising power of the Papacy, and distracted their attention from their first duty — the maintenance of the unity of Germany. 234 NATURAL COMMUNITIES [ch. xi. Many emperors, as Otto the Second and Otto the Third, cared more for Italy than for Germany. Frederick the Second left Germany for Italy in 1220, and, but for two flying visits in 1235-1237, never went back there, though his life and political activity after 1220 were prolonged for thirty years. The distraction of the attention of the emperors from the affairs of Germany, and the hatred with And in which the Popes regarded them, had Germany, momentous results. In Germany, as in all large mediaeval kingdoms, great authority was delegated to the local rulers, the dukes and counts, and large estates of land came into their possession? The emperors, if they had known their own interests, would have spent their lives in checking the growth of their power. The Popes thought that every- thing which hurt the emperors was advantageous to the Papacy; and they encouraged the dukes and counts in the attempt to attain independence, and the local rulers prevailed against the emperors. In 1250, on the death of the Emperor Frederick the Second, the duchies and counties of Germany ac- quired their independence and became sovereign .fiefs, owing no effective obedience to any one. There is no doubt that the majority of the German fiefs were far more naturally grown political communities than any single kingdom of Germany could have been ; for they remained exempt from subjection to any superior till a new suzerain in Germany was set up in 1866 by the battle of Sadowa. And now I have finished the weary task of depict- CH. XI.] IN ITALY AND GERMANY 235 ing seven centuries almost entirely occupied in the destruction of political communities. In the next chapters we shall observe those communities which either escaped the destructive force of the migrations and conquests, or grew up young and fresh out of the ruins of those which had been overwhelmed. CHAPTER XII SMALL COMMUNITIES IN THE MIDDLE AGES TO 1150 A.D. In the chapter just concluded a survey was made of several large political bodies which arose between the fifth and the thirteenth centuries, and we per- ceived that all these large states were made up of unlike materials and did not hold together easily or permanently. In the present chapter I have to enumerate many small political bodies : all of those which I shall notice were made of homogeneous materials, and were naturally formed and fairly coherent communities. The earliest in point of time were the tribes of the Saxons, Angles, and Jutes in Britain. These English tribes originated in migrations ; but they tribes. escaped entirely from the disintegration which a migrating people generally has to endure, because they expelled nearly all the older inhabitants of Britain from the parts in which they settled, and therefore were colonists of pure race in territories which they kept for their own accommodation.^ ' The Anglo-Saxon language, preserved in its literature, shows clearly that not many Britons lived among the English. The language of the Britons was either Latin or Celtic, or a mixture of Latin and Celtic. The Anglo-Saxon language contains only a moderate number of words of Latin origin, and an infinitesimal pro- CH. XII.] ANGLO-SAXON TRIBES 237 They retained their tribal institutions quite pure. Those institutions are extremely important, because they grew almost without a break into the modern English constitution which has been adopted by many of the nations on the continent of Europe ; but it is not necessary to say more about them at present, because they have already been described in my second chapter. The communities of Spanish Christians, who about 713 took refuge from the Moors in Asturia, Canta- bria, and Navarre, bear a strong resem- The Spanish blance to the tribes in England. Of the Christians, band of exiles who settled in Asturia we have some contemporary records ; they are scanty indeed, but in the main trustworthy ; even the dates that they give from 791 onwards are, beyond a doubt, approximately correct.^ portion of Celtic words. The laws of the Anglo-Saxon peoples also indicate that there was little mixture of populations. The Kentish laws make no reference to Britons ; the first enactments about a Wealh (or Briton) are in the laws of the West Saxon King Ine (about 690), who no doubt had Britons subject to him on the borders of Somerset and Devonshire. ^ Among the authorities we may notice (1) Sebastian of Sala- manca. Immediately after the accession of Alfonso the Third in 866, a chronicle was written under the title Sebastiano Salmanticensi Alphonsus Tertius. As it was addressed to Sebastian, Bishop of Salamanca, it is quoted as Seb. Salm. The most accessible edition is in Migne, Patrologia Latina, vol. cxxix. (2) Sampiro, Bishop of Astorga, 1035-1040. His chronicle extending from 866 to 982 is printed in Florez, Espana Sagrada, vol. xiv. pp. 438-472. (3) Pelayo, Bishop of Oviedo, 1098-1143, wrote a chronicle for the years 982-1109. It is printed in Florez, Espa%a Sagrada, vol. xiv. p. 466 sqq. For the date of Pelayo see Florez, xiv. p. 458. (4) Roderic, Archbishop of Toledo, who died 1247. His history is printed in Ber. Hisp. Scripiores aliquot, Frankfurt 1579, and elsewhere. He 238 SMALL COMMUNITIES [ch. xii. The first leader of the Christians in Asturia was Pelayo. He sheltered his band of fugitives in the ravines which run down fronfi the range of Mount Auseba, through a very short course, to the Bay of Biscay close at hand ; and from the cave of Cova- donga he won a notable victory over the Moslems. His son-in-law, Alfonso the First, was chieftain of the Christians both in Asturia and in Cantabria. He took many strongholds of the Moors, slew their Moslem garrisons, and led away the Christian in- habitants to swell his wandering bands.^ As the Christians grew stronger they were able to have fixed places of worship ; Fruela, son of Alfonso, built a church at Oviedo. They had, however, no towns, and no fixed residence for the king's household. Their first town was Oviedo, which was supplied with some buildings and inhabitants by Alfonso the Second (surnamed the Chaste), who reigned from 791 or 792 to 842 ; he was able to fix the seat ot his government in the town he had made.^ Soon after the reign of Alfonso the Chaste, a few more Christian towns were founded. His successor, next but one, Ordono the First, who reigned 850-866, placed a Christian population in the vacant sites of copies the earlier writers till 1109 ; but his dates till the death of Ferdinand the First, which really occurred 1065, are frequently wrong by about thirty years. (5) The Oeschichte von Spaniew by Lembke, Schafer, and Schirrmaker is a useful guide. Dozy, Histoire des Mussulmans d'Espagne, Leyden, 1861, tells of Spain mainly from Arabic writers. ' Lembke, p. 326, from iSefi. Salm. - Seb. Salm., Migne,vo\. cxxix. col. 1120. 'Iste prius { = primus) solium regni Ovoti firmavit.' on. XII.] ASTUEIA 239 Astorga and Leon, which had been taken from the Mussulmans by Alfonso the First.^ After the ac- cession in 866 of Alfonso the Third, and from then onwards till 1037, many sites were occupied by the Christian kings. Among these sites were Zamora and Toro on the river Douro, and Salamanca further south. They lay exposed to the attacks of the Mohammedans, and were occupied as military posts rather than steadily inhabited as towns. It does not seem likely that anything like town life was to be found in the Asturian kingdom before 1037 except at Oviedo, Leon, and perhaps Astorga. Leon was thought to be a specially secure abode when Ordofio the First occupied it. The place took its name from a Roman Legion which had been per- manently quartered there, and probably the Roman walls were still standing. By the reign of Ordono the Second, who was king from 914 to 924, the seat ot government had been moved into the old camp of the Roman garrison,^ and from thenceforward the Asturian kingdom was known as the kingdom of Leon. That kingdom continued to be a separate state till 1087 ; its territory in the last part of its separate existence reached from the Sierra Guadar- rama (a little north of Madrid) to Finisterre, the north-western corner of the peninsula. The heart of the country about Leon and Astorga was in general exempt from Moorish invasion ; only once in the reign of Bermudo the Gouty, 982-999, it was 1 Seb. Scdm., col. 1120-1122. ^ Sampiro, in Florez, vol. xiv. p. 44S. 240 SMALL COMMUNITIES [ch. xii. ravaged by the Mohammedans.^ Their invasion during his reign was led by an exceptionally able ruler, Almanzor the Vizier. The inroad did not last long. Alfonso the Fifth (999-1027) repeopled the town of Leon, and made its restoration memorable by holding there (seemingly in 1020) a ' council with all his bishops, counts, and rulers, wherein he gave to the kingdom of Leon precepts and laws, which are to be observed until this world shall end.' ^ Of the government of the Asturians during the time of their wanderings among the mountains from _ .. , . .. 713 to about 800 we have no records. Tribal insti- tutions in They must have lived under some of the Asturia. r r j. i • i, x forms 01 government which are proper to tribes: most probably they sometimes adopted one and sometimes another of the three forms possible for such peoples. They had always a king : probably he was sometimes sole commander and ruler, but at other times was aided by a council of nobles, and at others by a folkmoot. When they had a fixed seat of government from about 800 to 914 at Oviedo, and after 914 at Leon, we can just discern some traces of the existence of regular officers and a governing body besides the king. The royal household was controlled ' Pelayo, in Florez, vol. xiv. p. 469-470. '^ Pelayo, p. 470. ' Tunc prsefatus Rex Adefonsus venit Legionem, celebravitque Concilium ibi cum omnibus Episcopis, Comitibus sive et Potestatibus suis, et repopulavit Logionensem urbem quse fuerat depopulata a prEedioto Rege Agarenorum Almanzor, et dedit Legioni prsecepta et leges quae sunt servandje usque mundus iste finiatur [et sunt seriptse in fine Historiie Regum Gothorum sive et Aragonen- sium].' The words in brackets look like an addition of a late copjjat. What is the history to which they refer ? CH. xu.] FIEFS 241 by a Comes Palatii : and in 866 Sampiro mentions a Senatus Ovetensis which put to death a mischievous usurper who tried to take the throne from the young King Alfonso the Third.^ It is probable that from this time there was an established council of nobles, and that the legislative assembly held by Alfonso the Sixth in 1020, which made laws to last to the end of the world, was only an enlarged copy of a smaller council which had met frequently. A small council was obviously useful to the king for the settlement of questions of policy as they arose ; but when a mass of legislation was needed in the nascent state, a larger assembly was more appropriate. When we turn to France, Italy, and Germany we find that in those countries, as well as in England and Spain, many small independent com- smau com- munities arose in the Middle Ages, but "nui'tiesin none of them were of tribal character. Germany, No community is a tribe if it has a strong '*^'^" fortified town within its territory. Everywhere in France, Italy, and Germany, before those countries broke into small communities, strong towns were in existence;, and this fact by itself sufficed to ensure that the small communities should not have a tribal character. But though the small communities in France, Italy, and Germany were alike in not being tribal, they were not alike in their general character. They must be divided into groups. One group will bear the name of independent _fiefs, which denotes the ' Sampiro, in Florez, vol. xiv. p. 438. Q 242 SMALL COMMUNITIES [ch. xii. property of a nobleman who has become an inde- pendent prince ; the other will be denoted by the well- defined term city states. France broke up into fiefs about the year 887 A.D. when the Austrasian King Charles the Fat was deposed. Italy was divided into fiefs about the same time; in 951, however, it was reunited into a single kingdom under the Saxon Emperor Otho the Great, and when the kingdom was shattered in pieces a second time by the defeat of Frederick Barbarossa at Legnano in 1176, the most important of the small communities which attained independence were the city states. Germany did not finally shake off the central power of the emperor till the death of Frederick the Second in 1250. The communities of Germans which arose on his death were all of them independent fiefs, but some contained within their territories important towns which in the fourteenth century acquired independence and thus became city states The small communities, then, which arose in France, Italy, and Germany are divided into independent fiefs and independent cities. No discus- Character- _ '■ isticsof sion of the city states need here be fiefeforthe* attempted because it can more con- most part veniently be deferred. No general de- scription of the independent fiefs is within my power because the records that have been pre- served are too scanty. I do not know how any one of the fiefs either in France or in Germany was governed when first it arose : nor is it clear that any two French fiefs Or any two German fiefs were like OS. Sii/] COUNTY 01^ PARIS Uti one another so long as they remained independent. Similarities between fiefs arose after the twelfth century in France, and at a later date in Germany, when many fiefs sank into dependence under another fief and were compelled to submit to its laws. At the present moment I am speaking of the fiefs when first they arose to independence, and of those fiefs at that time, for the reasons just alleged, I am compelled to renounce the attempt to give any general description. But though the greater number of the independent fiefs in France and Germany were too insignificant to deserve more than a passing notice from The county contemporary chroniclers, some in each o^Paris. country were from their first beginnings placed in a position of pre-eminence, and were therefore better described by mediaeval writers. One independent fief in France, the county of Paris, which grew in the twelfth century into the demesne land of the French king, is of especial importance in mediaeval history, because in the twelfth and thirteenth century it compelled most of the fiefs in Gaul to submit to its authority, and became the most powerful state in continental Europe. The growth, then, of the county of Paris from the ninth century to the twelfth will now engage our attention. It was noticed in the last chapter that when the Germans migrated into Gaul the Salian Franks settled in the northern part of the ^ '^ Francia. country and occupied everything that lies to the north of the river Loire and of the water- shed of the Seine and the Saone except the peninsula 244 SMALL COMMUNITIES [CH. xil. of Bretagne, which remained Celtic. In the ninth century the district in which the Salian Franks had settled was distinguished from the rest of Gaul by the name of Francia; it had a distinct population of its own, derived partly from Frankish and partly from Celtic ancestors many generations back. Aqui- tania, reaching from the Loire to the Pyrenees, had also a distinct population descended from Visigoths and Celts. In Burgundia, which took in the whole valleys of the Saone and the Rhone, the population was probably less uniform. To the south of Macon it was derived from intermarriages of Burgundian and Celtic parents ; in the northern part, from Macon to Langres, there was, it would seem, a large infusion of Frankish blood; if it had not been so, it would be surprising that this region acted constantly with Francia rather than with Burgundia. When the empire established by Charlemagne was divided into three parts at the treaty of Verdun in Capitulary 843, the portion assigned to Charles the of Kiersy. B^ld included all the part of Gaul which was called Francia, all Aquitania, and that part of Burgundia north of Macon which I suppose to have had a Frankish element in its population. During his reign which lasted till 877, all his dominions, whether they were French or Aquitanian or Burgundian, were dividing themselves into independent fiefs; and in his last year, when he was starting to receive the imperial crown from the Pope, he recognised in the famous capitulary of Kiersy that all appointments to the offices of count or duke, and all grants of lands CH. XII.] INDEPENDENCE OF FIEFS 245 from the king, when once made, were irrevocable, and the offices and lands were transmissible from father to son by inheritance. This capitulary assured to the owners of fiefs by legal enactment an independence which they had already enjoyed in practice because the king was too weak to compel their obedience to his commands. Thus the reign of Charles the Bald witnessed the division of his kingdom into very numerous indepen- dent fiefs. But the same reign was also dux Fran- marked by the terrible ravages com- corum, 866. mitted by the Norsemen from Scandinavia on Gallic soil. Their devastations on the Loire and Seine were horribly destructive of life and property ; and all the owners of fiefs in Francia and all their subjects were ready to act together in obedience to any capable leader if only they could be saved from the Norse pirates. For the year 866 Kobert the Strong was appointed by Charles the Bald to be dux or captain- general of the men of Francia in their resistance to the Scandinavians. He was generally obeyed by the owners of fiefs, but unhappily he died within the year. Again, from 885 to 887, the Frenchmen gathered themselves under Odo, Count of Paris, son of Robert the Strong, to defend his city. They were successful, and their success restored to Paris that pre-eminence among the cities and fortresses of Gaul which it had enjoyed in the fourth century under the Emperor Julian. Odo was rewarded for his services. The lords of fiefs in Francia, Burgundia, and Aquitania assembled together and elected him 246 SMALL COMMUNITIES [ch. xii. king over them all;^ and we learn from the good authority of Richer, the monk of Reims, that between 888 and 892 the men who had elected him actually rendered him obedience in regions so far from his own city of Paris as Le Puy, Clermont Ferrand, Limoges, Angouleme, and P^rigord.^ The elevations of Robert the Strong and of his son Odo were experiments in the direction of giving the Frenchmen a single leader in their resistance to the Norsemen, and neither experiment produced very durable results. On the death, however, of Odo in 898, the office which had been created for Robert the Strong was re-established in the person of another corum per- Robert, who was son of Robert the Strong, manent, 898. ^^^ brother of Odo, and this time it lasted through three generations. The king of France after the death of Odo was Charles the Simple of the Austrasian house of Charlemagne. This Austrasian king had no authority of his own except in the neighbourhood of Laon and Reims, and from thence towards the Ardennes and Lorraine ; but the owners of fiefe in Francia were ready to recognise any actions of his which coincided with their own wishes. Charles remade the office of dux, or captain- general of Francia, and gave it to Robert, son of the only man who had ever yet borne it. We know from Richer that Robert was thus made military commander and chief civil minister throughout the region over which his authority extended, but we do 1 Hist. Francorum Senonensis in M.6.H., SS., vol. ix. p. 365. 2 Richer, M.G.H., SS., vol. iv. p. 571. CH. XII.] DUX FRANCORUM 247 not know wliat local limits Charles assigned to his sphere of command. Richer, who is our authority on this point, has a most provoking way of describing geographical limits in Gaul according to the ter- minology of Caesar, who divided the country into Belgiea, Celtica, and Aquitania. Richer understands Celtica as reaching from Boulogne and Soissons to the river Garonne; and he says that Charles the Simple gave Robert the office of dux Gelticce} We do not know whether the word Celtica is merely used pretentiously and wrongly by Richer to denote what ought to be called Francia, or whether Charles the Simple really intended Robert to be ruler over a great part of Aquitania. We do know, however, from notices of events, that the leadership of Robert and other duces, his successors, was effective in Francia and nowhere else. There were in Francia two great fiefs, Flanders and Vermandois, and many lesser fiefs. The owners of the two great fiefs acted rather as allies than subordinates to the dux; the lesser fiefs, the counties of Paris, Orleans, Le Gatinais, Chartres, Perche, Le Mans, Angers, Tours, Blois, were all under the command of the dux, and rendered him faithful service. In Paris the dux was himself owner of .the fief as count; in other fiefs the owner, whoever he might be, was willing to obey the dux, because he was a good protector against the Norman devastators.^ The office of dux borne by the captains-general ' Richer, M.G.H., 88., vol. iv. p. 571. ^ H. Martin, Hist, de France, livre xvi. (vol. ii. p. 505 in the fourth edition). 248 FEANCIA [CH. xii. in Francia was a position of trust created for the public weal, and especially for the purpose of re- sisting the Norsemen. The offices^ of corum duke and count created by Charlemagne powerful jjj g^^ parts of his empire were also originally positions of trust existing for the public weal, but they degenerated in the course of time into mere pieces of private pro- perty or estates of land. It does not appear that the office of dux Francorum ever suffered a like debasement ; it was always a trust held for the advantage of the inhabitants of Francia, and the holder of it was powerful only so long as the people of Francia felt that his leadership was useful to them. They needed him as a leader till 991, and no longer. Till about 940 he was their protector against the Norsemen. The Norsemen in 912, at the treaty of Clair-sur-Epte, accepted the territory to which their occupation gave the name of Normandy, and by about 940 they were a settled people, and more orderly than the men of Francia themselves. After 940 the inhabitants of Francia needed their dux because they feared that the Austrasian king who reigned at Laon might regain poAver over them. They entertained fears on this ground till 991, when the Austrasian dynasty became extinct. In 987 the dux Francorum, Hugh Capet, was elected to the title of King of the Franks. A rival Austrasian king, Charles of Lorraine, was soon set up at Laon; but Hugh Capet in 991 gained pos- session of the citadel and person of his opponent CH. xii.J DUX BECAME REX 249 who soon afterwards died in prison. Thenceforward the inhabitants of Francia were not threatened by any common enemy, and therefore had dux became no need for a common leader. From Rex 987, and 991 the power of the duces, who now declined tin bore the title of reges, declined steadily "°°- in Francia. The owners of the great fiefs took back their complete independence of action, which they had only waived while they needed a leader against a common foe. Many lesser nobles established them- selves as lords of independent fiefs by building strong castles about fifteen or twenty miles from Paris, at Montl'heri, Montmorenci, Luzarches, Beau- mont, Le Puiset, whence they could take toll of merchants who carried commodities to or from the city; and by about the year 1098 Philip, King of the Franks, great-grandson of Hugh Capet, had no authority except in Paris and in a zone of country extending about ten miles from its walls. At the same time William Rufus, Duke of Normandy and King of England, tried to place himself within striking distance of Paris by crossing his boundary, the river Epte, and making an attack on the territory known as the French Vexin.^ But though the territory of the King of the French was reduced to a mere spot upon the map of France, and was threatened by the strong ruler Louis the of England and Normandy, its inhabitants Sixth, were now a compact community, united in habits, aims, and interests; and the strength which they ' Ordericus Vitalis, x. 5. 250 SMALL COMMUNITIES [ch. xji. gained from unity enabled them to repel the dangers which menaced them, and to be the founders of a mighty nation. Their champion and leader was Louis the Sixth, called Louis le Gros, son of King Philip. Louis was associated with his father in kingly power for about ten years, and after his father's death, in 1108, he was sole ruler till 1137. During nearly forty years of vigorous exertions he was supported by the willing aid of the Parisians and the congregations of the neighbouring parishes, who were sometimes led in battle by their parish priests.^ He captured all the castles around Paris, rescued the French Vexin, and kept the powerful Dukes of Nor- mandy within their original boundary, the river Epte. At the death of Louis, in 1137, he was ruler of a kingdom or demesne land reaching from Beauvais in the north to Orleans in the south. His territory measured between these extreme points only about a hundred and sixty miles, and it was not more than about forty miles broad ; but its inhabitants were so thoroughly united in aims and interests that they were able to maintain its independence against all the forces that could be mustered by the English kings in their great continental possessions.^ 1 See the interesting description of the siege of Le Puiset in Suger, Vita Ludovici Orossi, oh. xviii. p. 65, in the edition of Molinier. He says : ' Cum communitates patriae parroehiarum adessent, valida Dei mamis cujusdam calvi presbiteri susoitavit fortitudinis robus- tum spiritum ' ; and then explains how the priest opened a way into the stronghold. ^ The extent of the French king's demesne is known to us from the accounts of the collection of the iaille in 1202, which is printed in the end of Brussel, Usage des Fiefs. It is very clearly shown in CH. XII.] FRENCH KING'S DEMESNE 251 All functions of government, except the judgement of causes affecting the rights of noblemen in their estates, were undertaken in the French demesne during the twelfth century by of the French the king himself with the aid of his king's servants. For the work of central govern- ment and military command he had the help of four great household officers : the seneschal or dapifer was governor of the household and commander in the army next to the king ; the chancellor, the chamber- lain, the butler, had less important duties.^ The right of making laws rested with the king alone, as it had done in the days of Charlemagne ; ^ Louis the Fat did not use this for any purpose but the making of enactments in favour of single religious com- munities or of individual landowners ; his son Louis the Seventh employed it for the first time in 1155 for general legislation which affected certain classes in all parts of the demesne.^ For local government, the king's principal servants were his prdvSts; they attended to the collection of all taxes and payments due to the king, and were criminal judges of first instance for all the population of their localities, except those persons who were exempted by special privilege from their jurisdiction.* It is probable the Droysen, Hand Atlas, map 57. It will be seen from this map, or from perusal of the original authorities, that besides the main block of the demesne, which reached from Beauvais to Orl(5ans, there were outlying pieces of it at Laon, Reims, and Bourges. ' Luchaire, Les Institutions Fran<;aises, §§ 281-284. 2 /iJ Colmerio, Cortes de Leon y de Castilla, vol. i. pp. 142 and 153. ^ Suger, Vila Ludovici cognominto Grossi, 33. 270 UNIONS BY CONQUEST [ch. xiii. ment. If the governors of the French demesne had tried to rule Aquitaine, or the governois of Aquitaine had tried to rule the demesne, discord must have ensued, and the making of a French nation would have been long delayed. In 1152 all danger of an attempt to bring the demesne and Aquitaine under a common government were removed by the dissolu- tion of the marriage of Louis and Eleanor; and from this time forth the demesne was free to pursue its natural destiny of uniting with other iiefs in Francia without any Aquitanian encumbrance. After the death of Louis the Seventh in 1180, the union of fiefs in Francia went on rapidly. The sub- division of Francia into small independent Conquest '■ of Francia,. counties was Certainly not advantageous II 0-1300. ^^ ^-^^ populations. There does not, in- deed, seem to be any evidence that each petty sove- reign was an oppressive or extortionate ruler of his own subjects. He needed the willing services of his fighting men and was compelled to treat them fairly; and as to the servile classes, who were useless in war, there is nothing to show that they were worse off under a count than in the king's demesne. But each petty sovereign might molest the subjects of his neighbours : for example, the lords of Coucy in many generations were no better than robber chieftains, probably liberal to their own band of retainers, but certainly a pest to the subjects of all their neighbours. A prince whose subjects had been robbed was likely either to defend them or to retaliate on the subjects of the offender, and thus the sovereignty of a multi- CH. XIII.] FRANCE 271 tude of petty princes led to very frequent wars. The extinction of the petty sovereigns, and the union of their fiefs under the government of the French king, would put an end to small predatory wars; and there was nothing abhorrent to the feelings of any popula- tion in Francia in a union with the inhabitants of the king's demesne, for all the populations, including the people in the demesne, were alike in race, language, religion, pursuits, customs, and past history. Under these circumstances it is not wonderful that the union of all the fiefs in Francia was effected rapidly, and when once made it was permanent. The means by which the union of Francia was brought about were partly conquest, partly politic marriages. Philip the Second, in 1180, married Isabella of Hainault, and gained with her the county of Artois.^ In 1183 he gained by cession, and then by forcible conquest, three small counties which had belonged to the great house of Vermandois — namely, Amiens, Valois, and a small region round St. Quentin, which was specially called the county of Vermandois.^ Between 1202 and 1204 he made his great conquest from John of England, which added to his territory Normandy, Touraine, Anjou, and the northern half of Poitou.^ This conquest fully quadrupled the size of the demesne, and raised it from being a state of like magnitude with fiefs around it to the dimensions of a very small nation. In 1212 Philip conquered ' Guill. de Nangis, ad ann. 1180. ^ LavalUe, Hi»t. des Franfais, vol. i. p. 347. ' Matthew Paris (Rolls series), vol. ii. p. 429. 272 UNIONS BY CONQUEST [CH. xm. and annexed the counties of Boulogne, Moreton, Dammartin, Albemarle.^ After these acquisitions of the French king, the only fiefs in northern Gaul, out- side the demesne, were a few small counties, as Blois, Dunois, Chartres, Dreux, and the two very large and important counties of Flanders and Champagne. The small counties, except Chartres, continued till after 1300 to be fiefs outside the demesne ; Flanders, being peopled by Flemings, asserted its independence, and did not form part of the French nation ; the annexa- tion of Champagne to the demesne was made certain in 1284 by the marriage of its heiress to the eldest son of Philip the Third, who in 1285 became King of the French with the title of Philip the Fourth. The formation in southern Gaul of a new demesne for the French kings was seemingly the effect of acci- Conquest of dent. Whether the kings were strength- Languedoc. ened by having this new territory is not perfectly certain. In 1209 it chanced that a band of adventurers mainly belonging to northern Gaul undertook, with the sanction of the Pope, a crusade for the conversion or destruction of a sect of heretics called Albigenses who inhabited the Gothic region between Toulouse and the lower course of the Rhone, and were ruled by the counts of Toulouse and Foix and the vicomte de Beziers. The crusaders chose as their leader Simon de Montfort, owner of the castle and lands of Montfort I'Amaury, not far from Paris. The crusaders during the life of Simon were successful : a large part of the heretics were put to ' Guill. de Nangis, ad ann. CH. xiii.J FRANCE 273 the sword, by wholesale massacre (as at Beziers), or by other means : the rulers of the heretical regions were deprived of nearly all their dominions, which were transferred into the possession of Simon. But when Simon chanced in 1218 to be killed at a siege which he was conducting, his son Amaury was not strong enough to resist an attempt of the dispossessed owners or their heirs to recover their dominions. The aid of the French king was requested, and was given in 1224 by Louis the Eighth. The king was successful for two campaigns, and when he fell ill in 1226 and went home to die, his work was continued by Humbert de Beaujeu, whom he left behind as commander of his forces. The war was ended by a treaty in 1229. As the war had been a crusade, the Pope had a large share in dictating the terms, and in the treaty the territory to be divided was described according to ecclesiastical dioceses. All the dioceses which lay immediately to the west of the Rhone from a point half-way between Vienne and Valence to the mouth of the river, and all those along the sea-coast from the Rhone to the Pyrennees, were given as a demesne to the king of France. The new demesne was a strip about a hundred and seventy miles long and about fifty miles broad. It does not appear that the inhabitants dis- liked being ruled by the king of France: most of the old Gothic population had been killed off and settlers from the north had taken their place ; but it must have been a difficult task to rule two regions so far apart as France proper and the southern s 274 UNIONS BY CGNQUEST [ch. xiii. demesne which bore the name of Languedoc. The actual distance, however, was speedily decreased by the annexations to the southern demesne of the fief's of Toulouse, Rouergue, and Quercy, which lay inland from it ; and the mere fact of distance be- came less important because the king reduced the fiefs which lay between his northern and his southern territories to some degree of submission to his authority. By the end of the thirteenth century there remained but few great fiefs outside the two de- pjgfg mesnes of the king. The greatest were outside the ducal Burgundy and Aquitaine, with their demesnes. in- , r. i dependencies: next to these came Bourbon and Auvergne. Champagne was in an exceptional position : it was not strictly in the demesne, but Philip the Fourth was married to its countess, and it was certain before long, if the king wished, to fall into the demesne and come under the king's direct government. Over all the fiefs except Aquitaine the French king had gradually established an effective general control : he did not directly rule their subjects, but he could dictate to their rulers, and sometimes his law-courts even claimed and obtained jurisdiction in their internal affairs. The reason why the rulers of the fiefs submitted to dictation was simply that they were too weak to resist. The kings of France wisely did not use their power to dictate in an offensive manner : they merely insisted that the rulers of fiefs should do homage to the king, that homage should entail some obligations, and that those obligations OH. XIII.] FRANCE 275 should be defined as occasions arose, in the Court of the Peers, of which the rulers of the greatest fiefs were themselves members. The Court of the Peers was an important institution for settling disputes that arose in regard to the great fiefs, and it will be necessary for me to describe its character; but it will be convenient to defer the description of it till after I have spoken of the government within the king's demesne lands. The government in the large demesnes of the French kings all through the twelfth and thirteenth centuries was the same as had existed in the reign of Louis the Sixth for his small in the French territory around Paris : and it therefore ^'"s'^ •' demesnes. stands in sharp contrast with the govern- ments which in the same centuries arose in England and Castile. The king of France had not any regular council of nobles for determining his policy or for giving consent to new laws : he could and did ask any friends whom he invited to his palace what their advice was ; but when he had heard what they had to say, he settled his policy or issued a new law solely of his own authority, as Charlemagne had done.^ There were no assemblies for local govern- ment, except in a few towns which had magistrates of their own and were known as communes ; the governments in the communes gained no knowledge of affairs outside their town walls, and within them the magistrates sometimes governed so much in the interest of the richer class that the poorer townsmen ' Luchaire, Les Institutions Fran^aises, §§ 264-270. 276 UNIONS BY CONQUEST [CH. xiii. were glad to get rid of the privilege of having their own citizens to rule them, and to be governed instead by a prevot appointed by the king and responsible to him. As there were no important local assemblies there were no judges going on circuit, and no representative assembly. The whole work of govern- ment was done by the judicial assembly of the Curia, and by the prdvots and baillis. The Curia of the French demesne gradually changed its character. We may judge from its The French earliest records that it was originally a Curia Regis, court for exercising jurisdiction among the owners of fiefs who placed themselves under the leadership of the dux Francorum. The members of it in the eleventh century were any bishops whom the king asked to act as judges, and a number of vassals holding land in the duchy of France.^ Soon afterwards the king's household servants, the seneschal, butler, constable, and chamberlain, are leading members of the court; and from 1223 on- wards many of the judges are entitled clerici or magistri.^ The household servants had some know- ledge of the law beyond what could be found in an ordinary vassal : the clerici or magistri were skilled jurisconsults. These learned lawyers were no doubt added to the court as assessors to the original judges, because the vassals needed their aid. Before long the assessors did all the work of examining the 1 Langloia, Textes relatifs A I'histoire du Parlement, gives lists of the judges in 1043, 1066, 1112, pages 5, 7, 11. 2 Ibid., ad ann. 1136, 1140, etc. ; 1223, 1257, etc. CH. xiii.] FRANCE 277 evidence and of suggesting the decisions : it cannot be doubted by any one who reads the judgements of the court that they are the work of skilled jurists. In the twelfth century the study of the Roman law was pursued with ardour. The Pandects of Justinian had never been entirely lost to the learned: they are quoted by Ivo of Chartres who died in 1117, and therefore he must have read a copy of at least some fragments of them. Before 1150 a fairly complete copy of the whole work was discovered (it is said at Amalfi in 1137), and other copies thence tran- scribed became accessible to scholars. ^ They were read with avidity not only in Bologna but also in Paris, which was now beginning to have a great and famous university. In 1202 the Curia at Paris, in giving a decision, declares that the reasons for it are derived at least partly from the jus scriptum or Roman law. ^ From this time forth the proceedings of the Curia must have been more than ever unin- telligible to the untrained vassals, and they ceased to attend its sittings in large numbers.^ By the middle of the thirteenth century the Curia, thenceforth usually known as the Parlement of Paris, was a court having trained lawyers among its judges, and empowered to hear appeals from decisions of all judges and all landowners in the two demesne lands of the French kings. Its jurisdiction was also 1 Gibbon, chapter xliv., notes 87-93. 2 Luehaire, Les Inst. Frang. , § 303, note. ^ See the list of the judges in 1298. Langlois, Textes relcU. Parlement, p. 169. 278 UNIONS BY CONQUEST [cH. xin. sometimes admitted by the parties in cases arising outside the king's demesne; about the year 1132 in Artois, which was not in the demesne till 1180; in ducal Burgundy in 1153 ; at Vezelay in the county of Nevers in 1165 and the following year.^ On the other hand, its interventions outside the demesne land were of rare occurrence; its attempts to gain jurisdiction in Aquitaine were successfully resisted by the king of England ; ^ and it seems that for a part of the thirteenth century the proper court for hearing appeals from decisions outside the demesne was not the Curia or Parlement, such as I have described it, but that same court reinforced by the addition of other judges known as Peers of France. Until the reign of Philip the Second, the only local administrations established throughout the demesne were the prdvSts. The area administra- Under the administration of a prevot tioninthe seems to have been, roughly speaking, about equal to what is contained in a modern French arrondissement : the number of prevotes in the demesne, after it was enlarged by the addition of the territories which Philip the Second conquered from John of England, was sixty-seven.^ Above the prevSts the kings of France, beginning with Philip the Second, established a more powerful order of administrators, known in the northern 1 Langlois, Textes, pp. 12, 18, 25. 2 Ibid., page 121. 3 Gasquet, Pricis des Instilutiom de I' ancienne France, vol. i. p. 120, from Bruasel, Usage des Fiefs. CH. xiii.J FEANCE 279 demesne as bailUs and in Languedoc as seneschaux. There were only two seneschaux for the whole of Languedoc, one stationed at Beaucaire, the other at Carcassonne : the baillis in the northern demesne at St. Quentin, Amiens, Sens, were almost as powerful as the seneschaux in Languedoc.^ The French kings took care that the seneschaux and baillis should hold office only during their pleasure, and should be under the jurisdiction of the Parlement de Paris. Until the end of the thirteenth century these pre- cautions were generally successful in keeping the local administrators duly subordinate to the central government. At the beginning of the twelfth century, in the reign of Philip the First, the whole area of France except the city of Paris had been ruled by piefs outside sovereign dukes and counts entirely inde- ^■^^ demesne. ° Z Decline of pendent of the kmg: at the end of the their inde- thirteenth, in the reign of Philip the P^^dence. Fourth, half the country had been merged in the demesnes of the king ; and in the other half nearly all the owners of fiefs had been deprived of some part of their independence. The encroachments on the sovereignty of the counts and dukes outside the demesne were effected by two judicial authorities, the Curia Kegis and the Peers. The Curia Eegis was, as we have noticed, the law-court of the king's demesne. 1 Luchaire, Les Inst. JFrangaises, §§ 294-298; Gasquet, vol. i. pp. 119-124. The baillis of whom I speak were called grands bailUs : there were also, somewhat later, other bailUs on a par with prevdts. 280 UNIONS BY CONQUEST [ch. xiii. In the twelfth century, when the demesne was small and the king's power was not formidable, the Curia was permitted by the Count of Artois, the Duke of Burgundy, and the Count of Nevers, to adjudicate on three suits which arose within their territories. The first of these adjudications was made about 1132; the second in 1153; and 1165-1166 was the date of the third. The suits decided by the Curia between 1132 and 1166 were not of vital importance to the fiefs in which they arose, and the Curia did not claim any right to depose the owners of the fiefs in case they were contumacious. After 1166 for a century it does not appear that the Curia by itself adjudicated on any suits outside the demesne: the work of deciding on such suits was performed during that hundred years at special sittings of the Curia at which some of the Peers of France were present. The definition of the title Peer of France in the thirteenth century is not precisely known. The first Peers of use of the title, that has survived, occurs France. ^^ ^ letter of the year 1171, where it is given to the Archbishop of Keims. In the few lists of Peers in the thirteenth century which have been preserved there always occur the names of some owners of great fiefs outside the demesne, and also of some prelates whose sees might be either within or without the demesne. Whenever a case affecting the rights of any one of the Peers had to be judged, it was necessary that some of the Peers should act as judges.! When Philip the Second had conquered ' Luchaire, Inst. Frang. , § 304. CH. XIII.] FRANCE 281 the possessions of John of England from Poitou northward, he summoned John before the Peers of France : John did not appear, and was deprived in default of appearance of the fiefs which Philip had conquered. Peers were present in 1216 to settle a suit of Erard de Brienne against the Countess of Champagne ; and again in 1224 to judge between Jean de Neelle and the Countess of Flanders.^ In the first half of the thirteenth century it is probable that owners of independent fiefs such as Champagne and Flanders would not oecUneof have submitted to the judgement of the ^^^ ^*^''^' demesne court of the Curia, unless they were pro- tected against unrighteous decisions by the presence of some independent princes like themselves among the judges ; and during that half-century the partici- pation of Peers in the judgement of Peers was a real protection against injustice. But in the second half of the century the number of independent fief- owners had greatly diminished ; the Parlement was allowed to declare that the presence of a single Peer as a judge was enough to give validity to a sentence affecting a Peer; and in 1297 Philip the Fourth created new Peers by his own fiat, two of them being a Count of Artois and a Count of Valois, both holding estates within the king's demesne.^ After these changes had been made the Peers ceased to have any political importance, and the Parlement de Paris, with or without the presence of Peers, gained power 1 Langlois, Textes rdatifs au Parlement, pp. 31, 35, 2 Lavall^e, Hist, dea Fran^., vol. i. p. 472. 282 SURVEY [ch. xiii. to adjudicate in all cases arising outside the demesne, except in Gascony, Flanders, and Bretagne, whose princes or inhabitants were in general able to protect themselves by force of arms against usurpa- tion. In England, Castile, and France some progress had been made by the end of the thirteenth century The con- towards Uniting under a single govern- dition of ment the many small communities com- CaSiie ' prised in each of those countries. In France in each Country a central government had been established with a king at the head of it. Whenever there was a king possessing an un- disputed title to the throne and endowed with some ability, the central government was usually obeyed throughout the country. In Castile the power of the central government had reached its high- water mark in the reign of Fernando the Third (1217-1252), and had ebbed again in the days of the unwise, though learned, Alfonso the Tenth and his success- ors Sancho the Fourth and Ferdinand the Fourth. Both in England and in France, in the year 1300, under Edward the First and Philip the Fourth, the central government was able to control all classes and all local authorities ; but both countries in the fourteenth century under weaker kings were destined to suifer from the insubordination of barons or of ambitious princes of the blood. But though in the three countries which we have been considering the authority of the central government was still some- times paralysed by rebellion, there is no doubt that it CH. XIII.] THIRTEENTH CENTURY 283 - was far better established in 1300 tban it had been two centuries earlier. Each country had been formed through the union by conquest of communi- ties similar in race, language, religion, pursuits, customs, and more or less alike in past history and traditions. Each therefore was a complex and not a simple community; but during the two centuries since the year 1100, all of them had become less conspicuously complex in structure and had made some progress towards unity. They were still very far from being perfectly united nations ; but each of them had so many forces tending to hold it together that we may regard them as imperfect nations or nations in embryo. Although, however, the countries of mediaeval Europe each had, in the year 1300, a single central government, they were not independent ^,_ ° . They were states according to the modern definition not inde- of that term. ' The marks of an inde- P^°^^"*- pendent state,' says Mr. W. E. Hall in his excellent treatise on International Law, ' are, that the com- munity constituting it is permanently established for a political end, that it possesses a defined territory, and that it is independent of external control.' ^ The political bodies existing in the year 1300 were com- munities permanently established for political ends and possessed defined territories ; but they were not independent of external control, because the Papacy frequently dictated the management of their domestic affairs. ' W. E. Hall, International Law, % 1, 284 POWER OF [CE. xiil. The Christian Church was originally a voluntary _. „. . association. Within a few centuries of The Church of Western its foundation its members included the Christendom. 11 i^**i- 1 i*j] whole 01 civilised mankind. The church, in being co-extensive with civilisation, resembled the Koman empire. Civilised mankind, under the empire, was accustomed to An inheritor . , . ,^ ■, from the consider itseli as one secular com- Western munity which, after the reign of Theo- dosius the Great, separated into two, with their centres in Italy and at Constantinople. The two empires gave the two halves of Europe the consciousness that they were communities united by the possession of a common civilisation. In each half the more backward peoples were glad to be included in some sort of community co-extensive with civilisa- tion, in the hope that culture might spread to them. There was then in each half a need of a community of some sort that took in the whole. When the Western Empire fell in 476 a.d. there was no longer a secular community of the west. The only com- munity that took in the whole was the religious community of western Christendom ; and so the church of the west inherited from the empire a position and dignity as a community co-extensive with western civilisation. But the church did not inherit the whole of the power of the empire. Charlemagne founded a new secular empire, and Otto the Great refounded it. As long as there was a secular empire, it might be doubted, whether civilised mankind in the west CH. XIII,] THE PAPACY 285 was bound together by allegiance to the secular ruler, or by membership in the church. Western Europe was a most heterogeneous mass of „ peoples, and could not be kept together, its whole either in a secular or religious union, P"™^"^- except by an exceedingly well-devised government of the kind required in a heterogeneous empire. Whether, then, western Europe was to be joined in a secular or a religious union depended on the rela- tive merits of the governments designed by their secular and religious rulers. The government of the secular empire founded by Charlemagne and remade by Otto the Great was, as we have seen, totally incapable of holding , , _, J !• Government the parts together. The government oi of the the church, on the contrary, was most Western m, 1 • • -,-, Church. admirably designed. The laity m all lands were the subjects, and had no right to an opinion on any religious question nor any influence in church government. The sovereign was the Bishop of Eome. The instruments of government were the bishops and priests, specially trained, transmitting commands, as did Constantino's civil servants, from the central authority to the subject population. The settlement of the succession to the sovereignty gave trouble so long as it was left to the inhabitants of Rome to elect the ruler of the church. In 1059 it was settled that henceforth the electors should be the Cardinal Bishops. They were the best body of electors that could possibly be found ready to assemble quickly on the death of a Pope. 286 SUDDEN DECLINE [ch. xiii. They were the trusted officers of the Pope that was dead, and they knew the business of church govern- ment. In committing the election to the Cardinals the rulers of the church acted as wisely as the Romans when, on the death of Jovian, they allowed his great officers to assemble and nominate his successor. The Popes could not avoid coming into conflict with the kings of the growing nations. The kings claimed to be independent, and the Popes between claimed a power to judge all questions of Popes and morals. While the peoples were in their infancy they cared little for upholding the independence of themselves or their kings, and so subjects often obeyed the Pope in preference to their own king. In consequence, from the ninth century to the thirteenth the Popes could interfere effectively in the government of the growing nations. The culminating point of papal interference was reached during the pontificate of Boniface the Eighth, in the year 1296. France was at the nations. ^^^^ with England, and England with Scot- gained inde- land. Boniface in 1295 had attempted to mediate between France and England and to induce them to agree to a truce or a peace, to be arranged under his arbitration. When the kings of France and England declined his mediation he issued his famous Bull, entitled Clericis Laicos. It began with stating that it was well known that lay- men were enemies of the clergy, and enacted that henceforth all clerics were forbidden to pay any tax CH. xiiL] OF PAPAL POWER 287 to any secular ruler witliout the permission of the apostolical see. This Bull, if it had been obeyed, would have broken up every political community in Christendom : the Pope accordingly thought it prudent to explain it away. But in 1301 Bernard Saissetti, Bishop of Pamiers, being appointed by Boniface his legate in France, tried to rouse the Count of Foix and others in the south of the country to take arms against the king. Philip the Fourth arrested Saissetti: Boniface replied by the Bull Ausculta Fili, in which he asserted that the Pope was far above all kings, and from that position he did not recede. In 1303 the aged Pope was dragged out of his country palace at Anagni by Guillaume de Nogaret, the trusted minister of the king of France, with the aid of Sciarra Colonna and his band of Italian ruffians ; a month later he died. Three years later the seat of the Papal Court was removed to Avignon, near to the southern demesne of the French king, and the power of the Popes to interfere with the rising communities of Europe was destroyed. CHAPTER XIV NATIONS IN THEIR YOUTH : MEDIiEVAL CONSTITUTIONS By the early years of the fourteenth century the three growing nations of England, Castile, and France had acquired settled forms of government which lasted without much change till the end of the Middle Ages in the second half of the fifteenth century. In the present chapter I proceed to depict in outline the chief features of the constitutions of the three countries. In all the large states of the Middle Ages the most important organ of government was the king. Kings had joined small communities together by conquest, and kings held them together. In my sketch, then, of the government of each country I shall begin with the kingly prerogative and dignity. In England the growth of the kingly power can be traced from its first beginnings. The ofiicer who England: led to the shores of Britain a band of The King. Qgrman settlers was, in the first instance, merely an ' ealdorman ' or ' heretoga ' ; he was, there- fore, a commander-in-chief, and he was also the leader or patron of a body of sworn comrades.^ After ' Chapter ii. page 36, OH. XIV.] MEDIEVAL CONSTITUTIONS 289 the settlement was effected the commander took the title of cyning, or man of the kindred. The first functions, then, of an English king were those of commander-in-chief, head of the comitatus, and man of the kindred. By the time when Ethelberht reigned in Kent in the days of Augustine, we see from his laws that the king was personal protector (mundbor) of his more immediate dependants, and if any of them were slain, the king, by reason of his protector- ship {mund or Tnundbyrd), received a payment of fifty shillings to compensate him for the loss of the services of the slain man. It is plain, moreover, that in other parts of England also the king was personal protector of his immediate dependants ; for when the West Saxons in 823, 921, 924 made conquests in parts of England outside of Wessex, the conquered peoples chose the West Saxon king as their mundbor, or as their hlaford (bread-giver or patron) and their mundbor.^ In the reign of Edmund (941-946), at the council of Culinton, it was enacted that all men (including this time the men of Wessex), should swear that they would be faithful to King Edmund as a man ought to be faithful to his dominus : that is to say, to his hlaford? From this time, then, the king was personal protector of all his subjects both within Wessex and outside ; and in case of homicide, whether accidental or designed, the first part of the retribution that fell upon the slayer was that he had to pay compensation to the king for the death of a ' Anglo-Saxon Chronicle, under the dates, ^ Concilium OuUntonense ; Thorpe, Anc. Laws, p. 107. T 290 MEDIEVAL CONSTITUTIONS [CH. xiv. person who was in the king's protection (mund)} The king, then, in recovering his compensation became the keeper of the peace: for all men knew that he who killed a subject would be compelled to pay the compensation (man-bote) to which the king was entitled.2 In the reign of Cnut (1016-1036) the firmly-rooted notions or doctrines that the king was the personal protector of all Englishmen, and the general keeper of the peace, gave rise to practical legislation in strict accordance with those doctrines ; and it was enacted that in all Wessex whenever any important oft'ence against the peace (homicide, house- breaking, highway robbery, neglect of service in the fyrd or militia, harbouring of outlaws) was com- mitted, the prosecutor must be the king or some officer appointed by him.^ At the end, then, of the Anglo-Saxon period the king was commander-in-chief, the patron and friend of the nobles his comrades, the man of the kindred, the personal protector of all his subjects, the keeper of the peace, and the prosecutor in all important criminal trials. All honest or decent folk looked up to the king as their natural protector against oppres- sion and wrong, and the relations between the king and all classes of his subjects were far more sincerely friendly in England than anywhere else in western Europe. The Norman Conquest made some changes in the 1 Concilium Oulintonense ; Thorpe, Anc. Laws, p. 107; Edm., See. 7. ' Reare man cy ningea munde, ' 2 See Stubbs, Const. Hist., § 73. ^ Cnut's Laws, ii. 12, in Thorpe, Anc. Laws, p. 164. CH. XIV.] ENGLAND • 291 king's prerogative. The new line of kings kept all the powers of their predecessors, and added to them the right of being the universal The Norman landowners; but on the other hand the ^"^ss- nobles, their tenants-in-chief, had been imbued with the ideas that prevailed in France, and knew nothing of friendship with the king, and desired to violate the peace of which he" was the protector. The kings, in their efforts to protect themselves, to preserve the peace, and prevent wrong-doing, invented much new machinery of government (as the exchequer, the circuits of justices, the king's select council), and they exerted themselves to keep it at work. In con- sequence of their activity in making innovations, the kings came to be the initiators of all reforms and the doers of all unappropriated work. They had the right to undertake and perform all functions not yet allotted to definite officers ; and it was this right of inventing new functions and seeing to the perform- ance of them that gave a vital and prolific power to the kingly dignity.^ We may sum up the kingly functions at the begin- ning of the fourteenth century. The king was the man of the kindred, commander-in-chief, the pro- tector of his subjects and of the peace, the prosecutor in criminal trials, the universal landlord, the restrainer of turbulent nobles, and the friend of nobles who kept the law, the initiator of improvements, and the doer of all work not yet allotted to definite officers. 1 It is from Stubbs {Const. Hist., § 229) that I adopt the words ' vital and prolific power. ' 292 • MEDIEVAL CONSTITUTIONS [ch. xiv. These functions would have made the king's power unlimited, but that the Assembly of Estates con- trolled the king's action, now diminishing, now in- creasing the speed and force of his activity in the same way as the governor of a steam engine acts in regulating the velocity and horse-power. The word Estate, when used as a political term in the Middle Ages, implied all the qualities that are The word usually implied by the word class, and ' Estate.' Q^g quality more. An estate was not only a class, defined socially and economically by having certain pursuits, or possessions, or interests, or civil rights, but it was also a class endowed with political privileges. I do not know that the word was ever used as a political term by any Englishman in the fourteenth century; an early use of it occurs in a passage of Thomas de Walsingham which was pro- bably written about 1420, and there are a few instances of its employment in the Records of the Privy Council under the Lancastrian Kings.^ The three estates in England, the bishops and great abbots, the secular peers, and the local com- A mbi f ^^^ities organised in shires and boroughs, Estates in were well qualified to exercise through "^ ^" ■ those of their members who met in Parlia- ment an effective and gentle control over the king. All three estates had the same interest in regard to the imposition of taxes, for all paid taxes of the same kinds, namely, those on moveables and on trade ;^ ' Walsingham, ad arm. 1399: omnibus s Constitution population in military service, though of the year scarcely as yet in a single army; con- quest of territory outside France was begun in the summer of 1794 at the victory of Fleurus. Under these circumstances the French desired to set up a 378 DIRECTORY [CH. xvii. single government for the whole nation. In the summer of 1795, which fell in the year iii. of their new era, they constructed a new constitution, which is named sometimes after the year of its origin, sometimes after the Directory which formed its executive organ. The legislature this time was in two chambers : there were two hundred and fifty Ancients (men over forty years of age) in the upper chamber ; the lower and more powerful chamber was the Five Hundred. One-third of each chamber was to be renewed by popular election every year. The executive was to consist of iive Directors; every year one Director was to retire, and his successor was to be elected by the Ancients from candidates nominated by the Five Hundred. The revulsion of public feeling against the violent deeds of men like Bobespierre and his followers was Intervention extremely strong. There was reason to of the army, ^i^:^^]^ ^-^^^^ if election was left unfettered, a legislature would be chosen to undo with violence in favour of the rich what had been done with violence in favour of the poor. To guard against this danger the framers of the constitution, sitting in their Con- vention, resolved that in the first elections of the new legislature two-thirds of the Ancients and two- thirds of the Five Hundred must be chosen from the members of the Convention. The bourgeoisie of Paris rose in revolt against the provision which limited their free choice; the soldiers in the army, drawn mainly from the poor, did not intend that the work of the Kevolution should be undone. The Conven- CH. XVII.] ITS DEFECTS 379 tion called into Paris a division of troops, under young Napoleon Buonaparte, with artillery, on the 5th of October 1795, in the Republican month of Vend^miaire; the revolt of the bourgeoisie was quelled, and the new constitution was established. The constitution of the year iii. was well designed to serve as a stop-gap, and the government of the Directors, the Ancients, and the Five Military Hundred ruled in France with less crying despotism, injustice than had been usual for generations. But as it was a purely civilian government and the soldiers were the greatest power in the country, it could only subsist so long as the generals were evenly balanced in power and jealous of one another. The practical weakness of the civilian government was seen in the following way. The legislature was entirely renewed in three years; the Directors in five. Hence new legislators synchronised with old Directors, and quarrelled with them in those days of rapid change in opinion. There was always some ambitious general ready to help the Directors, but never any to defend the legislature. At the request of the five Directors, in 1797, the legislature was purged after the manner of Colonel Pride by General Augereau. In 1799, at the request of the Directors (now only three), the legislators were dispersed by General Buonaparte. In the following year Buonaparte, by his brilliant campaign of Marengo, won a clear predominance among the generals. In that year he was First Consul, and four years later he was Emperor of ^the French. Under his military despotic rule the French people 380 UNITY OF FRANCE [ch. xvii. won victories with rapidity never known before in Europe, and then suffered crushing defeats; but in victory or defeat they all gloried or all lamented together, and at the fall of Napoleon France, though terribly weakened, was a united nation. CHAPTER XVIII UNITARY NATIONS : THE DECLINE OF DESPOTIC GOVERNMENTS In the last chapter we have seen how England and France, between the fifteenth and the nineteenth centuries, became homogeneous nations. Had space permitted, I might have shown how a like process took place in other European peoples. In proportion as more peoples became homogeneous, fewer peoples had any use for despotic kings. In the early part of modern history the possible uses of a despot were threefold. He protected his subjects from internal strife : he might lead them to conquest : he defended them against invasion. As each state became homo- geneous, it became safe against internal strife without adopting the violent remedy of maintaining a despot. And further, while many states were becoming homo- geneous, other changes were making conquests and invasions more difficult and less alluring. Conquests are more difficult because the states of the modern world make coalitions to protect the weaker states ; and they are less alluring, because any state, which annexes an alien population to itself by conquest, forfeits the advantage of being homogeneous, which most states have learned to value. Thus no nation 881 382 DECLINE OF [CH. xviii. that is thoroughly homogeneous has any reasonable use to make of a despot. Most of the nations have now become homogeneous, and in those nations despotic governments have, as might be expected, ceased to exist : a few nations, as Spain, Italy, and perhaps Belgium, are not yet perfectly united, but they do not suffer from any disunion sufficiently serious to induce them to submit to the arbitrary rule of a king. England was the first of the unitary nations to get rid of despotic government. After the destruc- tion of the Spanish Armada, the English despotic had no occasion tor it. I here was no government livelihood of serious internal strife ; they in England. _ _ . did not desire conquests in Europe; against invasion the sea and their ships protected them. Meanwhile the new gentry had risen to be capable leaders of the people, and they made their voices effectively heard for the redress of grievances. Elizabeth, in 1601, actually showed that she was no longer despotic when she gave way to the remon- strance of the House of Commons on the mischiefs, of Monopolies. The Stuart kings restored despotic authority which Elizabeth had begun to relinquish, and, though it was now needless, made it more intense and more oppressive than the government of any Tudor sovereign. The work of destroying the king's despotic power and making a new form of government was under- taken by the new nobility and gentry with the aid of the people, and was done in three stages. (1) Between CH. XVIII.] DESPOTIC GOVERNMENTS 383 1640 and 1689 Parliament acquired the power of con- trolling administration. (2) From 1689 to 1742 poli- tical parties were organised in the Par- liament, and the Cabinet was established, of its removal, (3) From 1760 onwards Parliament, '^^o-iSss- Parties, and Cabinet were shaken in their stability by the attempts of George the Third to undermine their position; but from the Reform of the Representa- tion in 1832, and especially from the retirement of Sir Robert Peel in 1835, it is an established fact that the House of Commons can drive any Cabinet out of office ; and though it does not openly determine who shall govern the country, it determines who shall not. The period of the Long Parliament, the Civil War, and the Restoration finally settled that Parliament alone can sanction taxes. In the reign of Charles the Second, who was always want- Control by ing money. Parliament for eighteen years ^^'^''^X"*' made remarkable progress in power. It met nearly every year ; it controlled not only taxation but expenditure; and by reviving the process of impeachment it gained the means of punishing ministers who broke the law. But from 1678 to 1681 it was ruined in the public estimation by the factious folly of the Whig Party in regard to the pretended Popish Plot, the Exclusion Bill, and the candidature of Monmouth for the succession to the throne. From 1681 to 1688 something very like despotic monarchy was re-established. In the Revolu- tion of 1688-1689 Parliament declared the throne was vacant and elected a king. They made very few 384 ENGLISH PARLIAMENT [CH. xviii. changes in the constitution; they definitely settled the principles, hitherto disputed, that there was no standing army in time of peace without leave of Parliament, and that the king had no general power to dispense with penal statutes ; they did not even make the judges independent of the crown, but left that needful reform to be made in 1701 by the Act of Settlement. Their action, however, sufficed for their purpose. Parliament never passed the Mutiny Act for more than a year at a time; if the Mutiny Act expired, the king's command over his soldiers expired with it. The king had to summon a Parlia- ment every year, and frequent meetings enabled the Parliament to control administration. Parliament in 1689 got the power to control administration, but did not know how to use it. The members were divided into Whigs and (2) . . . Parties and Tories : some ministers of the crown were the Cabinet, Tories, others were WhisfS ; and each mini- 1689-1742. . . ster had a policy of his own. Under such circumstances there could be no stable majority for the proposals of the king's government : one minister in making a proposal might appeal to a majority, another to a , minority ; and besides this there was no means of knowing how voting would go, because some members of the Houses of Parliament owed one allegiance to the king and another to their party. In 1695, for the first time, all ministers were chosen from one party — the Whigs. But this did not serve to ensure ministers all of one party for the future, because when one minister was defeated in a vote CH. XVIII.] AND CABINET 385 his colleagues did not resign with him. Between 1702 and 1710 on several occasions isolated Whig ministers were driven to resign : their places were taken by Tories who became colleagues of the remaining Whigs. A Cabinet in the modern sense of the word was founded between 1720 and 1742 by Sir Robert Walpole. He founded it by dismissing from the ministry any one who tried to have a policy of his own apart from the rest. He thus made a Cabinet united under himself, all having the same policy, and all jointly responsible; or, in other words, all going out of office together if one of them is defeated. The Cabinet has been proved by experience to be a singularly good instrument of government in a unitary nation with representative insti- ,,> tutions : indeed, the invention of it is in F'"^' estab- . . , . . lishment of such nations second in importance only pariiament- to the invention of representative assem- ^^ control blies. Unitary nations have, or ought to Cabinet, have, only one government which is ^^ °"' ^^" omnipotent. That it may be omnipotent, it is necessary that legislature and executive shall act in harmony. This was ensured by Walpole's Cabinet system of government. The Cabinet was the ex- ecutive; but it was also a committee of the party which predominated in the legislature ; and it served as a link between the two great organs of the govern- ment which had to act in harmony. It is not, however, surprising that a hereditary sovereign should dislike Parliamentary control, Party 2b 386 DECLINE OF [ch. xviii. organisation, and a Cabinet in harmony with Parha- ment. It is a combination of factors which deprives him of all political power except what he may get by his influence with ministers. George the Third did his best to sap the foundations of the power of Parliament, of Parties, and of the Cabinet, mainly by the use of pensions, sinecures, and a secret service fund. He was singularly successful till about the end of the eighteenth century. But in the early part of the nineteenth century many alterations made members and ministers more attentive to the opinion of the people and therefore less amenable to royal influence. The Industrial Revolution, begun towards the end of the eighteenth century, had raised up a great class of manufacturers and merchants as rivals to the country gentlemen; and it had congregated large populations in towns, full of wealth and of bustling activity, but not as yet represented in the House of Commons. Political discussions, suggested at first by the French Revolution, but illuminated rather by the happy results of popular institutions in America than by their dismal failure in France, convinced all those who suffered by oppressive laws and government that they would continue to suffer unless they were represented in the deliberative assembly. The labouring classes, who suffered most severely, were in a temper which led them into some rioting and violence and might lead them into insurrection. The manufacturers, too, and the mer- chants, desired to have a share in choosing represen- tatives. Eventually the demand for a reform of the CH. xviiT.] DESPOTIC GOVERNMENTS 387 representation was so general that tlie House of Commons and King William the Fourth were con- vinced it must be gratified; the resistance of the House of Lords was overborne, and the Reform Bill became a law. Since then the House of Commons has been exempt from royal interference, and has been able at its pleasure to compel the Cabinet to retire from office. On the Continent the decline and removal of despotic governments was a result of most intricate processes. It is in general true that in Decline of the eighteenth century these governments despotic were losing their activity and vitality: on the even in Prussia and Austria they became Continent, torpid after the deaths of Frederick the .Great and Joseph the Second. In all countries outside France they were discredited, in the early years of the nine- teenth century, by their inability to protect their subjects from Napoleon; nothing happened in any of these countries to endow them with new vigour, and they have accordingly died a natural death from internal weakness. In France active despotic govern- ments were established in 1804 and again in 1851; but their aggressive proceedings brought on them chastise- ment from European powers, and amid the calamities which they caused the French nation was placed under governments of a different character. In Spain the Bourbon kings sank into feebleness as their predecessors the Hapsburgs had done. Napoleon destroyed the Bourbon kingship by en- trapping the king and his son at Bayonne. He tried 388 UNITARY NATIONS [CH. xviii. to make his brother Joseph king of Spain, but was foiled by the resistance of the Spaniards and the Spain: English. In 1812 a constitution copied Naples. from the foolish French Constitution of 1791 was introduced into Spain : by 1820 it had pro- duced its natural results in civil war and anarchy. In 1821 the Carbonari at Naples tried to set up a similar constitution in place of their decadent despotism. Both in Spain and in Naples military interventions from outside were ordered by the four great powers Avhich formed the Holy Alliance : they destroyed representative institutions and set the kings free from parliamentary limitations, but could not cure their governments of their inherent feebleness. Despotic governments in France were proved by the examples of Louis the Fourteenth and Napoleon France ■ ^° ^® dangerous to Europe. Accordingly, the Charter in 1814, when the European sovereigns had overthrown Napoleon, they did not allow his successor Louis the Eighteenth to be a despot. Before they permitted him to enter Paris he had to issue a charter defining the future con- stitution of France. The issue of the Charter of 1814 was most potently conducive to the welfare of Europe. It set up on the Continent the first pattern of representative institutions that could do their work. It was imitated very closely from the contemporary English constitution. The French king was not made so dependent on his ministers as the English king : thus Louis had the privilege of joining the Holy Alliance because he could give his personal CH. XVIII.] NEW CONSTITUTIONS 389 adherence, while George, Prince- regent of England, was excluded because he could not. The French legislature was this time constituted in two chambers, one mainly hereditary, the other elective. The electoral franchise was granted more liberally than it then was in England, being extended to all men who paid three hundred francs yearly in direct taxes. The new French Parliament was free from the abuse of pocket boroughs which in the old English Parlia- ment was crying for reform ; but, on the other hand, there were no classes in France so well qualified to give counsel to the people as the upper classes in England proved themselves to be after 1832, when the system of elections had been amended. The strength of the French constitution was proved in 1830, when King Charles the Tenth, on trying to destroy it, was immediately forced to flee the country. The accession of his distant cousin Louis Philippe made no change in the constitution except that the electoral franchise was extended to those who paid two hundred francs of direct taxes. The French Charter of 1814, or, what was much the same thing, the English Constitution, was largely used as a model after 1830 in making con- Numerous stitutions on the Continent. It was copied imitations, between 1830 and 1840 in Spain; in Belgium and Holland soon after their separation; in 1850 in Prussia; and in 1848 in Piedmont, then called the kingdom of Sardinia. The introductions of the new constitutions call for no remark except in the cases of Spain and Piedmont. Ferdinand the Seventh of Spain in 1833, 390 UNITARY NATIONS [ch. xviii. being near his end, and having no children but daughters, desired the abohtion of the Salic law, which excluded them from the succession. To attain his ob- ject he summoned the Cortes. After his death in 1833, in a long war for the succession between his daughter Isabella and her cousin Don Carlos, both claimants had to promise constitutional goTcrnment in order to get support. Isabella was eventually successful in the war, and Spain gained a constitution on the English model. In Piedmont in 1848 the king and his son desired to be aided zealously by their subjects in a war against Austria, and to gain their aid King Charles Albert gave them a constitution. The war brought nothing but defeat to the Piedmontese ; but Victor Emmanuel, son of Charles Albert, maintained the constitution. II re galantuovio was rewarded for his good faith towards his subjects : he was chosen king of nearly all Italy in 1859, and of the rest in 1866 and 1870. All Italy is now ruled under the constitution which Charles Albert established in 1848 in his Piedmontese dominions. Of all the new constitutions the French alone was overthrown. On the expulsion of Louis Philippe in France : 1848 the French established a Republican renewed government according to the ideas which had prevailed in 1792 after the destruc- tion of the old kingship. In this Republic the assembly and the ministers were unable to control the Parisian proletariate : accordingly they desired to have a President to be single head of the executive government. Probably they were moved to this CH. xviii.J FRANCE 391 desire because a President is a strong and useful head of the executive in the United States of America. They resolved that their President should be elected, as the American President practically is, by universal suffrage. But if they thought that a method of election which works well in America, would work in the same way in France, they were much deceived. In the Federal American common- wealth the powers of the President are narrowly limited by the constitution, and the greater part of the executive work is done by the governments of the component states in the union : in the unitary state of France the head of the executive had all the powers not specially appropriated to the Parliament or the judicature. The French perhaps thought they were electing an officer like the American President by the method used in America ; in truth, they used the same method but elected a very different officer. The man of their choice was despotic almost immedi- ately : three years later he was elected by universal suffrage to be Emperor of the French with the title of Napoleon the Third. After the fall of Napoleon the Third in 1870 a new constitution was required. Its construction was begun in 1871 and was completed in France- the next thirteen years. This constitu- the Constitu tion resembles the Charter of 1814 and the English Constitution in providing two chambers of legislature and a Cabinet responsible to the legis- lature. It differs, however, from both in two important particulars. There is not in the existing French 392 SCANDINAVIAN [CH. xviii. form of government any Hereditary Sovereign, so that the functions performed by Hereditary Sovereigns in other countries are entrusted to an elective officer : the officer to whom they are committed is elected by the chambers of legislature to serve for seven years, and is entitled President of the Republic. The other divergence from the Charter of 1814 and from the English Constitution affects the relations between the executive and the legislature. The President of the Republic has not the power to dissolve the chamber of deputies unless the upper chamber assents to the dissolution. The effect of this regulation has been that the Cabinet has been more at the mercy of capricious assemblies of deputies in France than in most of the other unitary nations of Europe. In my sketch of the rise and decline of despotic governments, Denmark, Norway, and Sweden have not yet been noticed. They lay aloof at Scandinavian most times from the main course of na ions. European events, and their governments grew and changed according to their needs, as our governments in insular England have done, without much imitation of other nations. But in them also there was a culmination of kingly power followed by its decline. In Sweden a strong kingship was established by Gustavus Yasa in 1523, and was raised to greater power by some of his successors ; in Denmark- Norway the power of the nobles was broken in 1660, and the king for a time became autocratic. Now in all the Scandinavian nations power has been transferred from the Hereditary Sovereign to ParUa- CH. XVIII.] NATIONS 393 meats and Cabinets. In Norway, which against its will was placed under the King of Sweden by the Congress of Vienna, the king's influence is less than in other countries, and even the Cabinet is weak as it is in France. In Denmark and Sweden the government is in the main similar to that under which we live in England. CHAPTEE XIX UNITARY NATIONS: MODERN CONSTITUTIONS All unitary nations, now that they have become fairly homogeneous, are living under governments of a common type, characterised by the presence of a powerful representative and deliberative assembly or Parliament and a Cabinet responsible to the Parliament; and these governments, which we may best call parliamentary, have been so far successful, that all of them, except those of France, 1814-1848, and of Prussia, 1850-1866, have hitherto been main- tained in power as being more conducive to the welfare of their subjects than any that could be substituted for them. These facts do not prove that governments of this kind must arise in unitary nations, because many of the governments have rather been adopted by imitation than produced spontaneously by natural growth ; but they do show that such governments meet the needs of the nations when once they have been adopted, and do not jar on anything in the nature of those communities. The general characteristics of the governments of modern unitary nations are too familiar to need description, because we in England have been living under one of these governments longer than any 391 OH. XIX.] PARLIAMENTARY GOVERNMENTS 395 other people. It is, however, not alien from my pur- pose to point out that unitary nations, from being simple communities, have special require- ments to make of their governments, and requ'irements have adapted them to fulfil those require- of unitary ments : for we shall see hereafter that federal states, in the same stage of civilisation and progress, have different needs and therefore different political institutions. At the same time, we may observe how the unitary nations have varied in the details of their constitutional arrangements.'^ Every unitary nation was originally a composite state formed by the union of many weaker communi- ties with one stronger community : the sing-jg weaker communities, in submitting to supreme union with the stronger, submitted also to be ruled by its government, and a single government ruled the whole composite state. The component communities in the union were near neighbours and sufficiently alike in character to grow towards closer union; if they had lived far apart, or been uncon- genial, they would have separated, and no nation would have been formed. As the composite state grew towards perfect union, it learned the advantages of having a single government, and after it has united into a single community it desires to keep them. As it is a single community united by common growth, and not a bundle of communities joined 1 The moat convenient books of reference on modern govern- ments are Dareste, Oonstitutions Modernes, and Demombynes, Con- stitutions Europdennes. 396 SUPEEMACY [ch. xix. together by a bargain and by common interests, as federal states are, it is able to realise its desire. It is, then, a primary feature in the institutions of unitary nations that a single government is supreme. It is desired in unitary nations that the govern- ment shall be as strong and effective as it can be Controlled made, subject to the sole limitation that by the it shall not be able to thwart any settled and deliberate desire of the whole com- munity. The government must have separate organs to perform its deliberative, executive, and judicial functions, and they must be sufficiently independent to do their work properly; but the community desires that the organs shall work in general harmony and with a minimum of conflict. To attain this end One organ is chosen out to be superior to the others, and to speak to them in case of conflict in a tone of authority. In bygone centuries the superior organ was the executive, because it was most able to maintain union. Now that union is attained, the superior organ is the ParUament, because that is the organ most certain to conform readily to any settled wish of the community; and so a second feature in the governments of unitary nations is that the Parliament can, in case of need, speak to the other organs of government in a tone of authority. The division of a Parliament into two independent chambers ensures the consideration of every new law by two separate authorities. It was seen to pro- duce good results in England ; and undivided Parlia- ments when tried in France and in Spain produced, CH. XIX.] OF PARLIAMENTS 397 as we have seen, disastrous results. Divided Parlia- ments have accordingly been established in nearly all nations, whether unitary or federal. In unitary nations alone it is found necessary chambers that one chamber should be far stronger ""equal . in power. than the other. In these nations the Parlia- ment is the controlling organ : it must therefore be strong enough to keep in general obedience its only formidable rival, the executive ; and it is most effect- ively made strong enough for this purpose, if one of the chambers has a far larger share of power than the other. The necessity of making the two houses unequal in power is proved by the course of events in England during the first eighteen years of the reign of Charles the Second. The two chambers were then equal in power : they engaged in endless drawn battles about privilege, and the executive escaped from their control.^ In modern unitary nations it is intended that the executive shall not escape from control, and the Parliament shall in general command its obedience ; for these reasons one chamber is made strong and the other compara- tively weak. The strong chamber is that which is called the lower: it draws its strength from the fact that it is elected by a very large number of voters, and is entitled to speak in their name. And so the third distinctive feature of governments in unitary nations is, that they never allow the upper chamber of Parliament to be equal in power with 1 Hallam, Constitutional History, ch. xiii. , on the cases of Skinner and Shirley. 398 REPRESENTATIVE [ch. xix. that which is elected by the mass of the popula- tion. There are fourteen unitary nations. Ten of them stand apart from the rest, being situated in western or northern Europe, and having had for nations ccnturies none but Europeans as their numera . ]2eig];i]3ours. These ten are Great Britain with Ireland, France, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Belgium, Holland, Denmark, Norway, and Sweden.^ They are the chief unitary nations, and have governments not deviating greatly from a common type. The remain- ing four are Greece, Roumania, Servia, and Bulgaria. They are smaller than most of the others, and were under the misrule of the Turks till the nineteenth century : it is more difficult and less instructive to study their constitutions than those of the older European nations, and it will not be necessary to advert to them further beyond remarking that Roumania alone of the four has a second House of Parliament. In all the ten chief unitary nations there is a single supreme government; the Parliament has larger authority than the other organs, and the Variations , i i • c i i in their lower chamber is more poweriul than organs of ^]^q upper. These facts serve to define government. ^ '^ the character or the governments, but not to describe them nor to show how they are constructed. It will then be worth while to notice 1 Prussia and the other German states, so long as they were separate, were unitary. As they are now members of a federal union, they no longer have supreme governments of their own. GH. XIX.] OHAMBEES 399 the machinery employed in constructing the Parlia- ments and executive governments : in doing this we shall be led to observe that upper chambers vary largely in their structures, and that in France and Norway the predominance of the Parliament over the executive government is more accentuated than in other nations. The business of a modern Parliament is to deliberate on public affairs, to sanction laws, to impose taxes, to constitute all governing agencies both Parliaments. central and local, and to exercise a general supervision over the work of government. As the influence of the Parliament is almost boundless, it is recognised in the chief unitary nations that it ought to be divided into two chambers in order that every measure may be considered by two independent authorities. We have now to observe how the chambers are constituted in the nations of western and northern Europe. In all countries the lower or more powerful chamber is elected by a large fraction of the adult male population. In Great Britain and „ Ireland we have six and a half million sentative voters out of a total population of forty- one millions ; and in many continental countries the proportion of voters to total population is nearly the same as in our own country, namely, about one to six or seven. In France the franchise is given more liberally, to a fourth of the population; in Italy, where many are without any political education, much more sparingly, to one-fifteenth. It does not 400 UPPER [CH. XIX. seem, however, that the difference between France and Italy in the diffusion of the suffrage makes much difference in the position of their representative chambers. In both countries, the labourers with permanent residence and regular wages are included among the voters and form the greater part of the constituencies. In continental countries the elected representatives are usually men who have to make their way in the world ; in England they have already made it, or have had it made for them by their fathers and grandfathers. In France deputies receive a salary of nine thousand francs from the state, in Sweden and Norway a slightly smaller sum; in many countries, for example Italy, they are unpaid. The proper function of an upper chamber is to give a second and independent judgment on laws Upper submitted to it by the lower chamber, and chambers. ^^ prevent foolish laws from being carried hastily. As it is to give a separate judgment, it should not be a mere second edition of the lower chamber, and ought not to be constituted by the method of election by a very large mass of voters, which is employed in making lower chambers. As it is not elected by the mass of the people, it can never be strong enough to contend for long together by the mere expression of its will in combat with the lower chamber; and, for reasons already expressed, it would be mischievous if the upper chamber were equal in mere force to the lower. But the upper chamber ought to have the power to get the ear of the public, and to ensure that its judgments shall be CH. XIX.] CHAMBEES 401 listened to with attention. It cannot issue commands that must be obeyed : there is the more reason that it shall be able to judge rightly and to persuade by reasoning. That it may be able to perform its func- tions of judging and persuading, it needs that its mem- bers shall be men of wisdom and experience, careless of popular clamour, capable of thinking clearly and reasoning so as to carry conviction. To find mem- bers of such qualifications for the upper chambers has been the general desire of the makers of modern constitutions : very various expedients have been adopted to attain it, with varying degrees of success. In Italy the upper chamber is, as far as possible, a copy of the ancient Roman Senate. It consists of members nominated by the king to be Their senators for life, and selected by him from forms, men holding high official status or possessed of con- siderable fortunes : to these are added the princes of the blood, senators in their own right. From the history of the Roman Senate we may conclude that an assembly of peers for life, nominated by the executive but not transmitting their dignity to their sons, is more likely than any other to have the qualities demanded of a modern upper chamber. But also it is improbable that any continental people except the Italians, who pride themselves on being successors of the old Romans, would consent to live under an upper chamber selected entirely without their own intervention. In France, Belgium, the Netherlands, Sweden, and Norway, the members of the upper chambers are all elected. Attempts have 2c 402 UPPER [CH. XIX. been made to differentiate the upper chambers from the lower by varying the method of election, by lengthening the tenure of office for senators, or by selecting them from the wealthy citizens. For example, in France the senators are elected by local governing bodies who are themselves elected by the people ; they serve for thrice as long as the deputies in the lower chamber, and they vacate their seats not all together, but a third of them in every third year. In Belgium they are elected by the people directly, but have a double term of service, and are chosen from the rich class. The efforts of continental nations to get an elected upper chamber unlike the lower do not seem to have been successful. The most careful plan tending in that direction was that which the French devised ; but the French senate, as the years go on, becomes constantly less dis- tinguishable in its views and policy from the chamber of deputies. In Norway no attempt to keep the chambers distinct in character has been made: a Parliament or Storthing is elected by the people, and the members when elected divide themselves into upper chamber, Lagthing, and lower chamber, Odels- thing. The Norwegians are a remarkably law-abiding people ; but in spite of this excellence in their char- acter it was found to be unlucky, in the impeachment of eleven ministers in 1883, that there was so little distinction between the accusing chamber and the chamber of judges. In Spain, Portugal, and Den- mark the upper chamber is partly elective and partly nominated by the king. CH. XIX.] CHAMBERS 403 Of the English House of Lords I need say but little, because it owes its surviyal to singular circum- stances in our history, cannot be imitated T^e English elsewhere, and cannot well be compared Peers. with any other upper chamber. The upper classes in England from the time of the founding of new noble houses by the Tudor sovereigns have had a singularly good record as social and political leaders of the people, and therefore our upper chamber is permitted still to consist almost entirely of hereditary legislators. It has no voters, and therefore no direct force, behind it : even its freedom to choose its own policy is precarious, since the executive government can change its majority into a minority by a creation of new peers. Yet it often dares even in modern times to differ in opinion with the mighty House of Commons, and to refuse or delay to sanction its most important projects. If it makes a mistake and is involved in a conflict with the settled opinion of the people, the penalty is tremendous : in 1832, when it made such a mistake in regard to the Keform Bill, it was threatened with a creation of new peers, and did not regain its influence for a generation. In order to perform its proper function of giving an inde- pendent judgment on measures which have passed the lower house, it needs in its members a remarkable degree of prudence, experience, independence of indi- vidual character; but, as its members succeed by inheritance, three-fourths of them at least do not p,ossess the qualities of good legislators. The difficulty has been surmounted by natural selection : the peers 404 CABINETS [CH. xix. who are not well qualified to legislate stay away from the sittings. Those who remain perform with marked success their proper functions as critics of the Commons and persuaders of the people. The greatest trial of their capability occurred between 1892 and 1895 when bills for changing the government of Ireland were passed by the House of Commons and submitted to the Lords. Whether the bills were good or bad in themselves need not here be con- sidered : it is, however, perfectly certain that the Lords were right in rejecting them, because their judgement has been confirmed by the verdict of the people expressed in two subsequent general elections. Our English House of Lords, being based on heredi- tary succession, has the weakest of all possible consti- tutions; but by the simple process of leaving the work of legislation exclusively to those members who can do it well, it has attained a greater degree of influence than the upper chamber in any other unitary nation. The executive branch of government in a unitary nation has to do all the work which the Parliament does not perform itself nor entrust to the Executive _ '■ govern- judicature. It has to command the f^nctfons'^"^ armed forces, to execute laws and judicial and sentences, to collect the taxes, to preserve the peace, and to conduct negotiations with foreign powers. The executive organ in a unitary nation is such a Cabinet as that which Sir Robert Walpole constructed in England. The digni- fied sovereign selects the Premier, almost always OH. XIX.] CABINETS 405 from the party which has a majority in the repre- sentative chamber, and leaves him to choose his colleagues. If one minister is driven to resign by an adverse vote in the legislature the rest go out with him, except in the rare cases when the one minister has disobeyed the instructions of his col- leagues and can be repudiated. In a unitary state with representative institutions the executive is under the general control of the Parliament. As the community is all one and is to be ruled by a single supreme relations government, it is desirable that the two to the chief organs of government shall act together in easy harmony. This harmony is ensured by entrusting the executive functions to a Cabinet whose members have seats in the deliberative assembly, so that the deliberative and executive organs are linked together.- The two organs are not fused into one, but they are made interdependent. The executive government is always dependent on the deliberative assembly, because it can be dismissed from office by an adverse vote: the deliberative assembly is in some degree dependent on the execu- tive in those countries in which the dignified sove- reign has the power of dissolving Parliament. In those countries ministers, if defeated in Parliament, can appeal to the electors, and the possibility of a dissolution dissuades members of the ParHament from voting against ministers on frivolous grounds. The value of the power of dissolution in protecting ministers is shown by the experience of two countries 406 PARTICIPATION OF CABINETS [ch. xix. in which it does not exist. In France, where the Parliament cannot be dissolved without the sanction of the upper chamber, there were thirty-five successive ministries between 1871 and 1895. The instability of the Cabinets was no doubt partly due to the division of the people and the Parliament into many small groups ; but the inability of the Cabinet to appeal to the electors was also a contributory cause. In Nor- way the Storthing is elected for three years and cannot be dissolved : the executive ministers cannot be members of the deliberative assembly, and cannot attend its sittings ; they merely present to it the laws which they desire to see passed, and having done so must immediately withdraw from the hall where it is assembled. These arrangements, combined with the result of the impeachment of eleven ministers in 1883, have reduced the Norwegian executive govern- ment to a position of humble dependence on the Storthing.^ It is well worthy of remark that the most important work of a Parliament in the nineteenth and twentieth The centuries is not the same as it was in the weightiest eighteenth, when England alone had a business of -r^ ,. a n t-. l- • n a modern Parliament. Ail Parliaments in all ages Parliament (Jq j^j^g work of giving or refusing their isnotlegis- t> & b lationbut assent to new laws, and therefore have deliberation, legislative functions. Some Parliaments also do the work of effective deliberation on the policy of the nation ; but this work is permitted only to those Parliaments which are sufficiently strong ^ Demombynes, Constitutions Europ^ennes, vol. i. pp. 145-161. OH. XIX.] IN MAKING LAWS 407 and independent to insist on doing it. The English Parliament in the eighteenth century was neither strong nor independent ; it was seldom permitted to deliberate with decisive effect on the whole policy of the country; its chief work was legislative, and it was, appropriately designated as the legislative assembly. Now all Parliaments are strong enough to deliberate effectively on all subjects of policy. Their deliberations and their votes determine what policy shall be adopted ; above all, they practically determine who shall be Prime Minister. Since Parliaments have attained the power of practically determining by their debates who shall be Premier, their chief functions are deliberative. They still give or refuse their assent to laws: indeed, many more new laws are needed than in older times, and. the laws are more elaborately drawn up. But the Parlia- ments entrust the greater part of the work of law- making, as they entrust all administrative work, to the Cabinet. A modern Parliament is always able to dismiss a Cabinet from office : the members of a Cabinet are expected to be experts in law-making, and there is no reason why they should not be allowed to manage the making of new laws in their main outlines, so long as they give general satisfaction to Parliament. It is true that all the work of law- making is done in Parliament, but it is misleading at the present day to speak of Parliament as the legislative body, in contradistinction to the Cabinet which is called executive, because it leads us to forget that the course of legislation (except in Norway) is 408 JUDICATURES [cH. xix. habitually regulated by the Cabinet through its influ- ence over its supporters in Parliament. On the other hand, the work of deliberation on public policy, and especially on the question whether a Cabinet shall continue in office, is peculiarly the work of Parlia- ment. Most of the deliberation on such a question is done outside the walls of the House, in the medit- ations of individual members, aided by interviews between members, and by interviews of members with their constituents. The result of private. de- liberations is seen in collective deliberation within the House, and is manifested in speeches and votes ; but the work of deliberation is done by the members themselves and cannot be delegated to any body, least of all to the Cabinet whose fate is to be determ- ined. We may, then, properly speak of a modern Parliament as a deliberative assembly, because de- liberation is that part of its work which its members cannot delegate to the Cabinet ; but we ought also to speak of it as the deliberative assembly of the nation, because its deliberations have the peculiarly moment- ous effect of determining who shall do the work of government.^ The third organ of government is the judicature. It is no longer in any state active as a controlling or formative agency as was the Parlement Judicatures. de Paris in the Middle Ages and even our own Curia Kegis in the twelfth century. Hence the importance of the judiciary in political construction ' On the 'government-making machine' see Sir John Seeley, Introduction to Political Science, pp. 201-292. CH. XIX.] JUDICATURES 409 is, as Henry Sidgwick says, rather profound than prominent.^ Yet the existence of upright and fear- less courts of justice is essential in modern unitary nations always to the welfare of the people, and some- times to the safety of the great controlling organs of government; and for these reasons it is necessary here to take notice of the conditions required for the maintenance of an efficient judicature. A law-court to be efficient needs to be sufficiently informed of the law, and in giving judgement to be free from bias of interest, fear, or favour. The instruction of the court in the provisions of the law has been easily provided. In unitary nations the executive appoints the judges, and naturally selects the most distinguished lawyers. The immunity from bias has been more difficult to secure; for it cannot be attained unless the judges, juries, and witnesses are made safe against intimidation exercised either by the executive government or by any faction or class interested in their decisions. In England the courts are protected against inter- ference on the part of the executive by the famous clause in the Act of Settlement, which provides that judges shall not be liable to law-courts dismissal except upon the address of both ^o™ inter- Houses of Parliament ; but they are still more effectively defended by the general control exercised by the Parliament over the executive government. It would be tedious to inquire on what tenure judges hold office in all the countries ^ Sidgwiok, Elements of Politics, p. 457. 410 JUDICATUEES [CH. xix. of the continent, nor do I think it a matter of first- rate importance to find out. In all unitary nations the Parliament controls the executive, and I do not know that in any case since the modern constitutions have been established the executive as a whole has interfered to prevent the course of justice. The protection of the law-courts from intimidation by a faction or class is far more difficult; but it cannot be secured by any possible constitution of the judicature. In one case which has actually occurred, no change in the constitution of the law- courts would have sufficed unless the judges had been given the command of the whole armed forces, which would have been manifestly absurd. The law-courts cannot be put in command of any physical force adequate for their safety against intimidation ; and therefore their protection must be left to the care of the executive and the Parliament. Minor cases of intimidation, at least of witnesses and jurors, have occurred in districts not united in sentiment with the rest of the nation : thus in Ireland peasants, and in southern Italy brigands, have interfered with the course of justice. In these cases the Parliament and the executive have been compelled to intervene actively, for fear lest the districts in question might become entirely ungovernable. A far more formid- able case of intimidation occurred in France almost in the last years of the nineteenth century, when jurors in the capital city of the country had to fear what they might suffer from the general staff of officers in the War Office, and from the whole French CH. XIX.] JUDICATURES 411 army which might possibly be in sympathy with the general staff. In this case the Cabinet and the legislators were probably as much frightened as the jurors.i They must have known that if the War Office, which by the constitution was subject to the executive, could act as it pleased, the authority of Cabinet and Parliament was at an end ; and yet for months after the intimidation of jurors had been perpetrated, the Cabinet did not dismiss the officers of the general staff nor take any steps to save them- selves. No doubt they feared that, if they did, some general would make a pronunciamiento after the Spanish fashion. Eventually in 1899 the French nation obtained in Waldeck-Rousseau a resolute Premier, and in General Gallifet a loyal Minister of War, who restored obedience in the army, and thus protected the law-courts from being terrorised. In this case then, as in others, the safety of the courts depended not on the constitution of the judicature but on the action of the executive controlled by the Parliament ; and so it must always be, because the employment of physical force is impossible for the judicature, but is a commonplace duty with the executive. In many continental countries the framers of constitutions feared that the constitutions themselves might be hastily altered. To guard against this possibility they declared that certain enactments were parts of the constitution as distinct from ' For the evidence of intimidation of jurors at the trial of Emile Zola in February 1898, seeF. C. Conybeare, TheDreyfus Case, p. 247. 412 CHANGES IN [ch. xix. ordinary law, and ordered that in the future they should not be altered except by a procedure which proved that the alteration was the delibe- Alterations • i ^ i ■ t ti i • in constitu- rate wish 01 the community, in Jieigium, tions. |-Qj, example, the following procedure is ordained. The chambers can resolve that a certain stated provision in the constitution ought to be altered. The chambers are dissolved immediately, and new chambers are elected. The new chambers cannot alter any provision except the one designated by the old chambers; and they cannot effect the change unless two-thirds of the members of each chamber are present, and there is a majority of two- thirds in each chamber.^ In France if the two chambers both declare that the constitution ought to be amended, they meet in a joint session at Versailles, and then bear the collective name of National Assembly. The National Assembly can make any change provided it receives the votes of an absolute majority of all the senators and deputies.^ In England we do not draw any formal distinction between those laws which are parts of the constitution and those which are not ; and the formalities required for the passing of the most trivial law are so effective that no more are needed for the alteration of any law however fundamental. In every unitary nation there is a dignified sovereign. He is so necessary for maintaining the status of his nation among the powers of the world ^ Dareste, Gonst. Mod., vol. i. p. 74. ^ Demombynea, Const. Europ., vol. ii. p. 28. CH. XIX.] CONSTITUTIONS 413 that in France after the fall of Napoleon the Third, when no suitable hereditary sovereign could be found, an elective dignified sovereign was Dignified improvised with the title of President ^°'^^'^^^s°s. of the Republic. The dignified sovereign is not usually a working organ in the government : he is rather the ornament, the face, and mouthpiece of the community in its dealings with foreign powers. It is his constant business to watch the current of events, and he never goes out of office as ministers do ; he may therefore, if he has a long reign, know the prudent course by experience or feel it by instinct better than any of his ministers, and so his opinions, expressed to his ministers in the form of advice, may have the strongest influence in shaping the policy of the country. In some countries, especially in Italy under Victor Emmanuel, it is generally believed that the king in modern times has been far more than the adviser of the ministers : in other countries the king is there ready for all emergencies, and, in case the government by Parliament should break down, he would almost certainly be restored to some part of the powers which kings exercised before the modern constitutions were established. Now that we have finished our survey of the modern unitary nations, we may inquire whether the similarity of their governments is due to the action of natural laws or to caprice or nations, to unreasoning imitation. If the nations Results of ° inquiry. are of natural growth we may expect that their governments will be determined by natural iu UNITARY NATIONS [ch. xix. laws: if they are artilicial, their governments also may be assigned to them by individual caprice or design. We may, then, first inquire whether the modern unitary nations are themselves made by the action of natural instincts according to natural laws. Italy alone among the nations can claim to be of natural growth from the very beginning: its parts came together spontaneously between of natural 1859 and 1870 and placed themselves ^'^° ' under a common government. All the other nations were at first artificial products of con- quests. But all the old nations, except Spain, have now been completely unified, so that it is incon- ceivable that any part would willingly separate from the nation to which it belongs. Unification of this kind cannot possibly be produced artificially, and must be a result of the action of natural instincts. I conclude, then, that the unitary nations have been brought into their present condition by the action of natural instincts, and in that condition they are of natural growth. The nations are also alike in their structure and habits. They are of large size and yet are thoroughly Of the same Coherent communities : all their localities species. are equal in political rights, and none is predominant as Rome was in the Roman republic; each has a single supreme government, and their populations are nearly alike in industrial organisa- tion and in .material and intellectual civilisation. They are, then, alike in so many particulars that we CH. XIX.] OF NATURAL GEOWTH 415 must regard them as belonging to a single natural species. Some, however, o'f the nations have had a far longer life than others under purely natural condi- tions, and free from artificial interference : „ , ^ , But not of and as nations they are the seniors. Eng- the same land is the oldest of the nations. The ^^^' artificial work of uniting communities by compulsion was finished for England with the Norman Conquest, and the whole people had grown into a naturally united nation by the time of Queen Elizabeth. In other countries the artificial process of conquest went on far longer : in Spain till the time of Ferdinand the Catholic, in Sweden till the rise of Gustavus Vasa, in France till the end of the wars of religion. The continental countries, then, started far later than England on a career subject only to those natural forces which tend to unification, and few or none of them had attained to the condition of perfectly united nations before the beginning of the nineteenth century. We cannot say that all the modern governments of unitary nations on the continent were of spon- taneous natural growth. In Denmark, .^.j^^.^ Norway, and Sweden it is probable that governments they grew as spontaneously as in England, because those countries formed important assemblies of estates in the Middle Ages, and from the estates modern Parliaments easily grew by natural transi- tion. In the other continental nations modern parliamentary governments were imitated from 416 THEIE GOVERNMENTS NATURAL [ch. xix. England. The insular people became a united nation earlier than any other, and as the other nations became united they imitated the example that England had set. The governments, then, of these continental nations are not of spontaneous growth, and yet it seems clear that natural laws have deter- mined what governments the nations shall have. In some of the countries that have adopted parlia- mentary institutions by imitation attempts have been made by sections of the people to change the institutions, but all of them have failed: and it seems justifiable to believe that they have failed because parliamentary institutions alone are suited by nature to the unitary nations in the present phase of their existence. CHAPTER XX VOLUNTARY UNION OF EQUALS: THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA It has been observed already (at the beginning of the thirteenth chapter) that all the large states which occur in mediaeval or modern history were originally composite, being made through the union of many small communities. The union might be brought about either by compulsion or by the voluntary agreement of the small communities. We have already discussed compulsory unions and have seen that they form sometimes a complex city state, some- times a large nation under one supreme government, sometimes a heterogeneous empire. We now proceed to consider voluntary unions of communities, to observe which of them produce composite states, and to ascertain the various kinds of composite states which can result from voluntary unions. Voluntary unions of states, if we take the word union in the widest possible sense, are of three kinds. (1) A number of states may agree to act together for common defence without unions of •1 ■ . /o\ A communities, having a common government. (2) A number of states, approximately equal in size and power, may agree to set up a government common 2d 418 VOLUNTARY [ch. xx. to all of them : when this occurs a voluntary union of equals is effected. (3) It may occur that states marked by great disparity in magnitude may, of their free will, agree to live under one government, so as to make one state. In this case we have before us a voluntary union of unequals. The effects produced by the three kinds of volunt- ary unions have to be considered. (1) An agreement of states to act together for common effecteof defence without establishing a common voluntary government may perhaps in common parlance be called a union, but we are engaged in studying unions which make new states, and therefore a union which does not bring com- munities under a common government is not a union that has any interest for us. A remarkable instance of an agreement of states to act together without setting up a common government is furnished by the compact made between three Swiss cantons in 1291 and subsequently joined by other cantons. Their compact proved to be very durable, but it was merely a permanent alliance between states which remained separate and independent till 1481, when, as we shall see in the next chapter, they acquired a common government and became a composite state. (2) Voluntary unions of equals are far more interest- ing to students of politics than any other voluntary unions: they are the only unions that have ever produced those symmetrical federations which we must regard as the only typical Federal States. (3) Voluntary unions of unequals have perhaps occurred OH. XX.] UNIONS 419 frequently in all ages of history. None, however, of importance took place till after the beginning of the eighteenth century. Since then we may note among unions of this kind that of Scotland with England, which made the kingdom of Great Britain, and those of the German States in 1866 and 1870-1871, which founded the North German Federation and the German Empire. The union of unequals had as its result in Great Britain a unitary state, but in Germany a federal state. Hence we may see that the investigation of willing unions of unequals is no easy matter, and we shall do well to defer attempting it till the twenty-second chapter. In the present chapter, and in that which follows, I shall attempt to exemplify some characteristic qualities of those normal and typical federal states which are founded upon typical voluntary unions of equal communities. Federal •^ '- states. The federal states thus fashioned are the Achaean League, the United Provinces of the Nether- lands, the Swiss Federation, and the United States of America. The Achsean League does not teach us much about federations which cannot be more easily learned from more modern examples ; the Nether- lands had a most intricate history whose windings I cannot attempt to follow; and therefore the only federal states that I shall describe in some detail will be, in the present chapter, the United States of America, and, in the following chapter, the Swiss Federal Eepublic. The characteristics of federal governments arise 420 FEDERAL [CH. xx. from their having been made by voluntary agree- ment between independent states. The union of the states is generally suggested by the need isticsof of defence against a common enemy, or federal against a power which threatens them all. governments. . ■ i i The contractmg states wish to have a common government to wield the powers necessary to the common defence, and possibly, for convenience, a few others; but each state wishes that all other powers should belong to a separate government of its own. The powers entrusted to the common government are most carefully limited, and its sphere of action defined in the compact which sanctions the union: all other powers are tacitly or expressly reserved to the governments of the contracting states. The compact which sanctions the union is the constitution, and, as it is the result of a bargain between states, it cannot be altered except by methods prescribed by the original contracting states and embodied in the compact; and these methods naturally put great difficulties in the way of changing its provisions. The result of the whole is that there is no supreme government controlling all persons in all their relations, but many co-ordinate governments: namely, one federal government to manage certain defined matters of common interest, and one govern- ment in each component state to manage the business of that state. The powers of each govern- ment are determined expressly or tacitly by the constitution, and thus, though there is no supreme government, there is a supreme constitution. CH. XX.] GOVERNMENTS 421 It is obvious that the terms of the bargain which founds a federal union might be varied almost indefinitely. There are, however, as I Twoim- noticed in the Introduction to this volume, po^ant T'arieties two methods oi making a federal union, of federal which have been found especially useful "'"°"' and have been often adopted.^ For the study of the United States, of Switzerland, and of some other federations, it is necessary to explain what they are and how they are distinguished. The terms of the federal compact may found either a loose union or a close union. A loose union is founded, if the common government of the contracting states is empowered to act only on the governments of the individual states, but not on their subjects; a close union is established, if the common government can lay effective commands not only on the govern- ments but also on the subjects of the component states, requiring them to perform certain duties, as, for example, to pay taxes. In a loose union the con- spicuous feature is the presence of many component states; in a close union the one collective state attracts more attention. The Germans have lived in a union so loose that perhaps it was no union at all, and they now live in a union so close as to leave little separate action to the governments of the com- ponent states. Their language accordingly supplies appropriate terms to denote the two kinds of union. A loose union is called a Staatenbund, a bundle of many states ; a close union is a Bundesstaat, a state forming collectively a bundle. ^ See page 3. 422 LOOSE UNION [ch. xx. The states which contracted together to form the United States of America, were thirteen colonies The United founded or acquired by England in the states of seventeenth century. During that cent- America. •' , ° Loose union, ury they were of various characters, and 1781-1788. ^gj.g j^ga^j-jy ig(. alone by England. After 1700 they were made more alike. Each colony had a governor appointed from England, and it had a legislature elected by the inhabitants.^ In 1776 the colonies declared themselves independent of England, and in the following year they made the plan of a common government to provide for their common defence : it was, however, agreed that the common government should not receive its powers till all the thirteen states had acceded to the union, and it was not till 1781 that the assent of the last was given.2 The Articles of Confederation of 1781 established no more than an extremely loose union. The only organ of the common government was a Congress, to which each state sent delegates not less than two nor more than seven : each state had only one vote, and the delegates were more like ambassa- dors than members of a governing assembly.^ The Congress could determine on peace and war, and had the sole right of making treaties.* It could, on the concurrence of nine votes out of the thirteen, appoint commanders of the army and navy ; but in levying troops it could only send each state a requisi- 1 Woodrow Wilson, The State, articles 832-862. ^ Johnston, History of the United States, section 271. ^ Articles of Confederation, art. 5, printed in Brjce, Americaii Commonwealth, Appendix to vol. i. ■* Art. 9. CH. XX.] CLOSE UNION 423 tion to raise its quota, and to appoint the regimental officers.^ For the payment of the armed forces the Congress could agree, as occasion required, that the several states should within a fixed time contribute to a common treasury sums in proportion to the value of the land and buildings in their territories, but it could not lay any tax on their subjects.^ Immediately after the common government was established, the governments of the several states began to disregard its requisitions, and in view of the possibility of renewed war with Great Britain or with some other power, the United States felt they must join in closer union and establish a common government which could not only request governments but Could compel citizens to contribute to the common defence. The close federation which still unites the states of the American Commonwealth was drafted in 1787, and took effect two years later. The close federa- character of a federation is always deter- *'°°' '789- Powers of mmed mainly by the amount of the the Federal powers entrusted to the common or Government, federal government. In America the powers allotted to the federal government are partly necessary to the common defence and the maintenance of the union, partly given for convenience; and they are distributed among its three organs. Its legislature has the powers, necessary to the common defence, of declaring war, raising and regulating armed forces, defining and punishing piracies, suppressing 1 Art. 9, Art. 7. ^ Art. 8. 424 CONGEESS [CH. xx. rebellions, and taxing and borrowing for tHe common defence and general welfare; it has also, for con- venience, the duties of regulating commerce, natural- isation, coinage, weights and measures, post office and post-roads, copyrights and patents. The execu- tive has the necessary powers of commanding the armed forces, making treaties with the assent of the upper house of the legislature, and of taking care that the laws (made by the federal legislature) are faithfully executed ; it has also the powers, necessary or convenient, of granting reprieves or pardons for offences against the United States, of appointing, with the assent of the upper house, judges, ambassa- dors, and officers of the United States, and of sending messages from time to time to the legislature. The judicature has to decide in all cases arising under the constitution, and is therefore the interpreter of the meaning of its provisions; it has other jurisdic- tions naturally associated with its great function of interpreting the constitution, and it is the judge in cases arising under the law of nations.' It is necessary, as we have seen, in a federal union that there should be many co-ordinate governments, , . , , one more in number than the component Legislature _ ^ and executive states : thus in the American Common- co-or mate. ■^Q^i^;]r^^ -^[^^^ forty-five states, there are forty-six co-ordinate governments. The founders of the union carried the multiplication of co-ordinate powers still further by making the federal executive co-ordinate with the legislature. Their action may ' Constitution of the United States, Articles 1, 2, 3. CH. XX.] PKESIDENT 425 have been founded in a belief that in all states the executive and legislative powers should be independ- ent ; but it has certainly been conducive to the maintenance of their constitution. Unitary nations, as we have observed, desire that their central govern- ment may be as strong as possible, and to that end make the legislature and executive dependent on one another, but give superior authority to the legislature. In the United States it is desirable that the federal government shall not be too strong, lest it should get the constitution altered to its own advantage. The legislature and the executive are made co-ordinate, and as far as possible independent of one another ; and their isolation from one another helps to ensure that the federal government shall not transgress the limits imposed by the constitution. The head of the executive is a President, elected to hold office for four years, under a method of voting which is now practically identical with _, election by all the adult males in the executive Commonwealth. He is not responsible °^^^°' to the legislature, except that he may be impeached for treason, bribery, or other high crimes and mis- demeanours : no adverse vote of the legislature can shorten his tenure of office by a day. He has seven ministers to help him with his work, but they are responsible to him only and not to the legislature. They are disqualified from sitting in either chamber, and the legislators do not exercise personal influence on them nor they on the legislators. The President, moreover, is protected against legislation which he 426 SENATE [CH. xx. disapproves by possessing a power of veto, which however, does not avail against a majority of two- thirds in both the Senate and the House of Repre- sentatives. The division of the legislature into two chambers is in the United States not only desirable (as it is in unitary nations), in order to ensure a Legislature. • i , • j- second consideration oi every measure, but is almost inevitable, because both the govern- ments and the populations of the component states ought to be represented in the federal legislature. The legislature accordingly, which bears the name of Congress, is divided into the Senate and the House of Representatives. The Senate is a small assembly of ninety members, elected by the legislatures of the component states ; the senators are elected to serve for six years, and a third of them vacate their seats every two years. The component states, whether large or small in area and population, have govern- ments entitled to debate with each other as equals, since the original union was made by a compact among equals; accordingly every state government is represented in the Senate by two senators, and the constitution provides that no state shall ever be deprived of its right to have two senators without its own consent. The American Senate, as it represents governments co-ordinate with the federal government, bears little resemblance to the upper chambers of unitary nations. One very important difference may be noted. It is not intended in the United States that the federal legislature shall be stronger than CH. XX.] REPRESENTATIVES 427 the federal executive, and therefore there is no reason why the chamber which represents the popul- ation should be stronger than the other : the Senate, as a matter of fact, has at least as much influence as the other chamber. The House of Representatiyes is elected to serve for two years by the populations of the states in the union, with members in propor- tion to their sum of inhabitants : New York State had recently, and probably has still, thirty-four members, while six small states have only one member each, the total number in the House being something between three hundred and fifty and four hundred.^ The House of Representatives has the sole right of initiating money bills; but, on the other hand, the Senate has the control over appointments, and therefore over the distribution of the greatest mass of patronage to be found in the world ; and no treaty with a foreign power is valid unless the Senate approves it by a two-thirds majority. The legislature is provided with as good safeguards for its independence as the President. As nothing can shorten the President's tenure of office delations except death or condemnation on impeach- between , Pill J- legislature ment, so the tenure ot the chambers oi and Congress cannot be shortened in any way, executive, since there are no provisions for their dissolution. The legislature and the executive go on their several ways almost independent. The President is indeed under an obligation to take care that the laws are faithfully executed, but, if he neglected it, there ' Bryoe, vol. i. p. 125. 428 COMMITTEES [ch. xx. would be no means of enforcing it except by impeach- ment. The isolation of the legislature and of the executive is rendered still more complete by the provision which disqualifies ministers from being members of either branch of the legislature. This provision has had consequences well worthy of attention. As neither the President nor his ministers are members of the legislature, there are no government bills, and the two Houses of Congress have Committees. , no official leaders. The President can in his messages to Congress suggest legislation in any given direction, but all the members of Congress are what we in England call private members, and every bill must be a private member's bill. The bills pro- posed are extremely numerous : in one session they have been known to amount to nineteen thousand. They cannot all be considered in the whole Senate or the whole House, and some method of weeding must be employed. In unitary nations the process of weeding is done in various ways, but mainly by the Cabinet, which in almost every case can kill a pro- posal instantly by advising the majority to vote against it. In the United States the work 'of weeding out useless or mischievous proposals is entrusted to small committees. In each chamber of the legisla- ture about forty-five or fifty committees are appointed: the number of members in a committee is usually eleven or nine, rarely as few as three or as many as sixteen. Each committee has bills of a certain class referred to its consideration : thus there are com- CH. XX.] COMMITTEES 429 mittees for proposals relating to the army, to the navy, and to foreign affairs. The most important of all are the Committees on Appropriations, which control the expenditure of the federal revenue.^ In the United States, as in England, every statute has to pass in each house through the stages of first reading, second reading, committee, re- port, and third reading. But the first committees and second readings of every bill are °"P''°'^^'*'"'^- taken as a matter of course, and the debating is done in committee. The deliberations of the committees are usually secret: the hearing of witnesses by a committee is done with open doors, but is not gener- ally reported in the newspapers. A committee after considering a bill deal with it as they think fit: if they make no report to the House which appointed them, the bill is defunct ; if they report it, with or without amendments, the bill comes on for third reading in the House which sent it to the committee. Both the Senate and the House of Representatives are less well informed of the condition of affairs in the executive departments than are the chambers of legislature in a unitary nation, because they have no ministers present among them to answer inquiries; and accordingly both Houses are inclined to accept the opinions of their committees and pass their bills into laws with little or no debate. One effect, then, of the system of the committees is that very little debating on laws comes to the ear of the public. A ^ Bryce, American CommonweaUh, vol. i. p. 156; Woodrow Wilson, The State, sections 1061-1074. 430 SUPREME [ch. xx. second result is that the chairmen of the more important committees form a second set of ministers. The constitution has forbidden Congress to employ the executive ministers as the leaders of their legis- lative work, and the Houses have been compelled to invent leaders. The committees of the Senate are elected by the Senators, committees of the other house are nominated by its Speaker, who also names the chairman of each committee. The chairmen act in some small degree as a link between legislature and executive, since they can ask questions of the ministers and are entitled to receive answers; but, as the answers are not given orally and in public, communications between the two great organs of government have to pass through narrow channels easily choked with red tape, and there is no such perfect understanding between them as arises in unitary nations from the practice of entrusting to cabinet ministers the work both of commanding the executive business and of guiding the law-makers by their presence in deliberations. The American Commonwealth, comprising forty- five states, has not only forty-six separate legislatures, but also forty-six separate constitutions Judicature. , . . , , and rorty - six separate statute - books. Cases necessarilyarise in which these constitutions and systems of law come into conflict. For example, one of the states makes a new law, and some one affected by it pleads that the state had no power to make it ; or two persons of different states are suitors in a case, and each wishes to be judged by the law of his own CH. XX.] COURT 431 state. For the settlement of all cases of conflict of laws, and for some other purposes which have already been indicated, Federal Courts of justice have been established. There are sixty-five in all — one Supreme Court, nine Circuit Courts, and fifty-five District Courts. The principles for settling cases of conflict are that the Federal Constitution overrides everything which conflicts with it, and that laws made by Congress, provided they are made under the powers given to Congress by the constitution, override all other laws. For the application of these principles it is obviously necessary for the courts to settle what the constitu- tion means, and what powers it has given to Congress ; and therefore the Federal Courts are the interpreters of the constitution, and settle what is in accord with it and what is not. The framers of the constitution and their successors have desired that the judges in the Federal Courts should be independent and impartial, and their decisions should command universal respect, and they have succeeded admirably. The judges in all Federal Courts are appointed by the President with the sanction of the Senate, and they can be removed only on impeachment. They receive adequate salaries, though not nearly as high as the judges in our own country: in the Supreme Court each judge receives ten thousand dollars, in the Circuit Courts six thousand, and in the District Courts five thousand. It is strange in the eyes of citizens of unitary nations that the Federal executive in America 432 AMENDMENTS [ch. xx. has not any locally distributed force to carry out decisions of the Federal Courts in case of resistance. In unitary nations the central executive can com- mand the services of local police against all law- breakers ; in America the Federal executive has no control over the police in any state or any county or town. Each of the sixty-five Federal Courts has merely a United States Marshal attached to it, to carry out its judgements. He has no force of men with him, but may ask aid of all good citizens, or in case of need can get the help of a body of Federal troops by applying to Washington.^ The framers of the Federal constitution foresaw the possibility that changes in it might be desired either by the Federal Congress or bv the Amendments , . , "^ . ^ . , -^ . of the legislatures ol many states m the union. Federal ^j^fj ^j^Qy prescribed methods of procedure Constitution, ^ ,. ^ for each of the two cases. Hitherto all expressions of a desire for change have come from Congress, and therefore only one of the two pro- cedures has ever been used. The requirements under this form of procedure are, firstly, that the Senate and the House shall agree to the proposed change as if it were an ordinary law, but with a majority of two-thirds both in the Senate and in the House ; and, secondly, that the change shall be approved in three-fourths of the states in the union either by their ordinary legislatures or by conven- tions elected for the sole purpose of considering the amendment. It is obvious that under this procedure 1 Bryoe, vol. i. p. 231. CH. XX.] AMENDMENTS 433 no amendment can be carried, unless it is supported by an overwhelming preponderance of opinion ; and therefore the American Commonwealth has the most rigid constitution in the world, in marked contrast with our own country whose constitution is the most flexible. The fifteen amendments which have been passed hitherto have generally tended to give larger powers to the Federal legislature, and it seems likely that future amendments must, by defining things now indefinite, tend in the same direction. It is, then, improbable that a desire for change will ever be expressed by the legislatures of the states in the Union, and it is not necessary to describe the procedure laid down for an unlikely contin- gency. The work of government in the American Com- monwealth is divided in very unequal proportions between the Federal authorities and the The states authorities constituted by the several '"the Union, states in the Union. The share allotted to the Federal rulers at Washington is very small, and the part retained by the component states is very large. Any one of the component states is very like an independent unitary nation, except that it has no concern with foreign affairs, or army, or navy, and cannot impose duties on import or production. Every citizen of a civilised state is affected by law or government or their agents at every turn of his life; but an American citizen must feel constantly that he is governed by his state, and will scarcely know that he is governed at all by the Federation, 2 E 434 COMPONENT [CH. xx. unless he reflects that the Federal legislature imposes the Customs duties, and thereby affects the prices of imported commodities. As the governments of the component states retain in their hands all the functions not allotted to the Federal rulers, it is impossible to give a state ^ . , . n • governments: complete summary 01 their work m a their short space. But it is easy, without functions. f _ . attempting exhaustive enumeration, to show that the matters under their control are many and weighty. They have to make their laws on all concerns except the few which are assigned to the Federal Congress. Some of their laws, not often needing reconsideration, will relate to the great subjects of crime, property, contract, and marriage; others, needing readjustment on occasion, will deal with the constitution of local and municipal govern- ments, education, sanitary precautions, medical di- plomas, and kindred subjects; others, frequently made and re-made, will define the privileges accorded to individual trading or industrial companies. Each state must also have law-courts to adjudicate on all cases except those which come before the Federal Courts, and it must have an administrative staff to see to the execution of the laws, and this adminis- trative staff will include as an important item a force, or rather forces, of police appointed by the cities and townships within the state. Each state is free to choose any form of govern- ment other than monarchical. The states have for the most part chosen governments which bear a strong CH. XX.] STATES 435 family resemblance to those which they had in the eighteenth century when they were English colonies. They have their executive governments, their legislatures, and their judicial governments: systems. The executive work is usually ^eir , . 1 , , . . structure. entrusted to a governor and mmisters chosen by popular election for a definite term of ser- vice. The legislatures are usually constituted in two chambers, a Senate and House of Representatives, both elected by the population. The legislatures are the most important part of the state governments, but the constitutions of many states show that it is desired they should not be too active; and we can readily see that less legislation is needed in a com- paratively new country than in the crowded popula- tions of European states, and tinkering of the laws for the sake of doing something would be mis- chievous. In most states no man can be elected to serve in the legislature by any district except that in which he resides, so that the most capable men are often excluded from candidature ; and in many states long sessions of the legislatures are discouraged by a rule that members are paid for attendance for a fixed number of days, and if they attend for a larger number they attend gratuitously. The judges are usually elected by the inhabitants of the district within their jurisdiction, to serve for a definite number of years. Judges thus elected must neces- sarily be wanting in independence, especially towards the end of their tenure of ofiice ; their position must expose them to the temptation of yielding to popular 436 TAMMANY [CH. xx. clamour, but it is believed that they are restrained from corrupt judgements to please individuals by the good example set by a Federal Court present in every state, and by the professional opinion of barristers. The divisions for local government usually bear the names of townships, counties, and cities. In New England townships were founded by the Local ..,,.,„, •' ^ governments, origmai coionists before they were massed TheTam- together into the colonies of Massachus- many Ring. ° sets, Connecticut, and the rest ; ^ and this may be the reason why local divisions are left to carry on their own business without any intervention of the executive officers of the state governments. The state legislatures make or sanction the forms of government in all local divisions, but the state governors and ministers do not control the working of the governments. In the great cities the results of these arrangements are noteworthy : the cities have become almost independent city states, since they receive nothing from the outside except their constitutions. And though they receive their con- stitutions from the legislatures of their states and keep within the letters of their charters, it does not follow that their ostensible government is their real government. The legislature of New York State originally gave New York City a charter intended to place the government under the control of all classes of the citizens in the hope the city would be governed for the benefit of all. But the government was of a kind not usually maintained permanently in a city 1 Wood row Wilson, The State, sections 999, 1000. .CH. XX.] TAMMANY 437 exempt from external administrative control : cities thus uncontrolled usually have governments managed, not by all classes, but by some narrower body, as we have seen in our survey of simple city states. In New York City the Tammany Society was, and is, a mere association of private citizens. It was originally founded in 1789 for social and charitable purposes ; somewhere about 1840 or 1850 it aspired to get control of votes and offices in the city, and it suc- ceeded. To explain its methods would be tedious; but it may be mentioned that the mayor was elected by the citizens, and judges together with police commissioners were, under some of the charters of the city, elected by the citizens, under others appointed by the mayor ; and when once Tammany controlled enough votes to turn- the scale in elections it was able to employ judges and police for persecuting its opponents and rewarding its friends. Some of the 'bosses' of Tammany Hall about 1870 made great fortunes by diverting millions from the city treasury into their own pockets, but they were on the whole faithful in protecting any one who paid them black- mail by subscribing to the funds of Tammany. It is obviously impossible in any large unitary nation that any private association should get control of a city, because the whole nation has one supreme government which controls everything : in America, New York State is not big enough to control New York City. Hence the citizens, to free themselves from the rule of Tammany, have had to trust to their own exertions. They succeeded at the last election 438 CONCLUDING [CH. xx. of mayor; but it cannot be expected that Tammany will be easily killed. It has a position just analogous to that of the Parte Guelfa in Florence; and the reader will remember that, though the Florentines set themselves free from the Guelf captains at the great revolt of the ciompi, within fifteen years they were again under the rule of a small clique of men who resembled the captains in all important particulars.^ This chapter may be ended with a few general remarks on the political organisation of the American Concluding Commonwealth. It seems that the remarks. governments of the forty-five states are comparable in many respects with those of many small unitary nations ; but the Federal government is totally incommensurable with any unitary govern- ment. We measure governments together by com- paring organs which perform the same functions. The American Federal government has no organ co-extensive in functions with any organ in a unitary state, though it has organs denoted by the same names. The American President and the Premier in a unitary nation are both called head of the executive, but the President controls only a fraction of executive government, and does not control law- making; the Premier controls the whole executive government, and, so long as he is in office, settles the course of legislation. The American Congress and the English Parliament are both called legis- ' Tammany is described vividly by Mr. Bryoe, eh. Ixxxviii. [My remarks were written before the election of 1903.] CH. XX.J REMAEKS 439 latures, but Congress legislates on few subjects, Parliament on all ; Congress suffers no man to advise it, Parliament daily asks and takes the advice of the Premier; Congress cannot shorten the President's term of office by a day, while Parliament can at pleasure dismiss a Cabinet by refusing to sanction its proposals. But where comparison is impossible contrast is easy. The total work to be done by governing agencies is probably about the same in professional England and in the United States: if Politicians, there is any difference England needs more governing because it is old and overcrowded. Yet in England the work is given to one government : in America it is divided among forty-six. Work done by one agency is done easily : when it is distributed among many it becomes laborious. One general election in England settles the course of government for a few years : in America elections of executive officers and legislatures have to be managed frequently both in the whole union and in each of its component states. In England a man can enter political life without abandoning professional or other pursuits : in America political life is so laborious that no one can undertake it without giving his whole time to it. If a man gives his whole time to public work he must be remunerated ; and so the men who manage govern- ment in America are generally professional politi- cians, men who make a livelihood by public work. There is no doubt a class of rich men who could afford to wotk for no pay ; but there are two reasons 440 CONCLUDING [CH. xx. why they seldom do it. The division of work among many governments limits the sphere of action of each government, and makes its business less inter- esting: for example, no legislature in America has business so interesting as the English Parliament, which can dismiss the Cabinet from office ; and the extremely laborious character of political life in America acts as a deterrent on men who have no need to engage in it as a means of earning a livelihood. As the work of Congressmen is less interesting to themselves than the work of Members of Parliament, Debates in ^^ ^^ ^^^° ^®^^ interesting to their consti- Congress not tuents. In England a very large part of the population is eager to read Parlia- mentary Debates and to scrutinise divisions, because a vote in Parliament may cause a change of ministry or an appeal to the electors. In America no vote in Congress can shake the stability of the executive, and therefore the proceedings in the legislature meet with little attention from the population at large. The English method of government trains the people to study the deliberations in Parliament and to attend to the arguments of their legislators; the American method leads the citizens to concentrate their attention on popular elections. In both countries public opinion acts on the rulers and gets its way, quickly or slowly : in England it acts from day to day by comments on the work of Parliament expressed in newspapers or in local meetings; in America it acts periodically, and is expressed at CH. xx.J REMARKS 441 elections by the number of votes recorded for differ- ent candidates for the executive and legislative posts in the forty-six governments in the Common- wealth. The American Constitution has undergone few formal changes since its foundation ; but practically the union is far closer than it was. Rail- ^. The union roads and telegraphs have brought distant has grown states near together. A part of the states "^ °^^''' waged a great and successful war to prevent a secession ; and in protecting the union from disruption they learned to value it. The distinction which severed the southern states from the north has been nearly ended by the abolition of slavery throughout the Common- wealth. Fifty years ago a man might be a Bostonian first and an American afterwards; now every man is an American citizen first and last, and the diver- gences between members of different states, as for example between the men of the east and the men of the west, arise rather from divergent economical interests than from attachment to the states in the union to which they severally belong. Throughout the history of the Americans from the Declaration of their Independence progress has been steadily made from the condition in which they were many states scarcely joined by any tie, to their present condition in which they are one state with many members which act in constantly increasing harmony with the whole body. CHAPTER XXI VOLUNTARY UNION OF EQUALS : MODERN SWITZERLAND The ancient Achaean League and the mediseval Swiss Eidgenossenschaft bear very little resemblance to the United States because the powers allotted to their central governments were never accurately defined. I shall pass over these two ill- defined Federal states with a brief notice, and then proceed to consider the modern Swiss Federation which is like the United States in miniature. The ancient Achaean League, founded in prehistoric ages by exiles who fled from before the face of Dorian Achaan invaders, was dissolved between 323 and League. 284 B.C. by the Macedonian kings Cassan- der, Demetrius Poliorketes, and Antigonus Gonatas.^ Between 284 and 250 B.C. a new league was formed and was joined by many Greek cities. There was a common government for the management of war and foreign affairs. The legislature in the common government consisted of a general assembly and a standing council of about a hundred and twenty members ; and its executive organ consisted of a strategus, or minister for foreign affairs, with some lesser officials called demiurgi. We do not know ' Polybius, bk. ii. oh. 41. 442 OH. XXI.] ACH^AN LEAGUE 443 how much power of commanding individual citizens of cities in the league was entrusted to the central gOYcrnment.^ The Swiss did not form a Federal state till 1481, and then they formed it by accident. Three cantons, Uri, Schwyz, Unterwalden, formed an Medisevai alliance in 1291. The alliance proved to Switzerland, be permanent, and was joined by several more cantons at intervals : but it was no more than an alliance. Each canton was a perfectly independent state, and conducted its foreign affairs by ambassa- dors who had instructions from their cantons. In 1481 some of the ambassadors broke their instruc- tions and acted as they thought fit;^ by so doing they changed the meeting of the ambassadors into a common government for the cantons which they represented. Soon afterwards, for example in 1512, the central government was a council which received ambassadors sent by foreign powers to the Swiss Federation, and settled what answers should be given to them.^ The power of the council to control the cantons was not properly defined, the troubles about religion dissolved the Federation, and till 1798 the cantons remained disunited. The French Directory intervened forcibly in Switzerland, and placed the country under the government of a unitary republic after the French ' Further details about the Aohteaii League are given in a brief form in Political Institutions of the Ancient Greeks, p. 114, by the author of the present work. " Oeohsli, Quellenhuch %ur Schweitzergeschichte, pp. 199-202. 3 Ibid., pp. 261-266. 444 SWISS [CH. XXI. model. The Swiss cantons abhorred being deprived of their ancient self-government: in 1802-3 Buona- French parte as First Consul restored it to them, interventions, and formed the people into a very loose confederation of cantons. In 1847 a few cantons, attached to the Roman Catholic creed, seceded and tried to form a Sonderbund or separate Federation. They were defeated, and in 1848 the Swiss formed a close Federation, whose central government was still further strengthened sixteen years later. Switzerland is a Federal state on a very small scale. It has three million inhabitants ; in area it is equal Modern to half of Ireland or Scotland, or to a Switzerland, threc-hundredth part of the United States. It is prevented from forming a unitary state by physical environment and by racial, lin- guistic, and religious divergencies. Many of its cantons are separated by almost impassable ranges of mountains: two-thirds of the people speak German, a quarter speak French, an eighteenth Italian, and a few have a language called Romansch; three-fifths are Protestants and the remainder Roman Catholics. There is, however, much that tends to draw the cantons together. The inhabitants are mainly small landed proprietors, strong, hardy, in- dustrious and independent, so that they are alike in pursuits and character. The commercial interests of all are identical; they have behind them the memory of heroic efforts made by their forefathers in defence of their independence; and the cantons, if separate, would be too small to deal on anything OH. XXL] FEDEEATION 445 like equal terms with any of the European powers. Under these circumstances it is not surprising that a Federal government has been established. The character of the Federation must, it is obvious, be determined by the amount of power conceded to the central government. Division of powers „, ° . ^ Character of among many governments is not carried the modem out in Switzerland to the same extent as ^ ^^^ '°"" in America: it would be absurd in so small a territory, and many of the cantons could not well perform some of the functions which are safely left to the governments of the large states in the American Commonwealth. In consequence the central govern- ment has to control more departments of business in Switzerland than in America; there is not the same anxiety lest the central government should en- croach, and therefore the central executive and legis- lature are not made perfectly independent ; and the small Swiss Kepublic is not so sharply distinguished from unitary states as the great Commonwealth beyond the Atlantic. The central government has three organs for legislation, executive work, and judicature. The Parhament legislates on all the subjects nil m Central (except patents) that belong to Congress government, in America, and on many more. It makes ^^g'siature. laws relating t© great public works, such as railways and the embanking of rivers and torrents ; it controls forests, fisheries, shootings, universities, sanitary regul- ations, medical diplomas, employment of children; it makes rules about vagabonds, and can order the 446 SWISS [CH. XXI. expulsion of foreigners who imperil the public safety.^ The legislature is in two chambers as in America; the chambers are renewed every three years. The lower house, called Nationalrath, has a hundred and forty-five members, elected in the cantons in numbers proportional to the populations; the upper house, called Standerath, has forty- four members, two elected by each of the cantons. The executive work is done by a board of seven Executive ministers, called the Bundesrath. These organ. ministers are not so independent as the American President, because they are elected by the two houses of the legislature. They are elected by every new Parliament at the beginning of its three years, and when once they are elected, the Parliament has no power to dismiss them. There are, however, provisions which tend to promote harmony between the executive and the legislature : the ministers are allowed to be present and to speak at the sittings of the Parliament, and even to suggest amendments to the measures proposed.^ There is also a Federal Court of Justice, but it is not nearly so important as the Federal Court in America. The judges are elected by the Parliament, which has power to determine the duration of their tenure and their salary.^ It has the sole jurisdiction in suits between cantons, but, as the powers of the cantons are restricted, the 1 The Swiss Constitution, articles 23-27, 3], 33, 34, 37, 68, 70. - Woodrow Wilson, The State, articles 533-537. ^ Constitution, article 107. CH. XXI.] CONSTITUTION 447 disputes which can arise among them are not so intricate as the questions that arise through conflict of different systems of laws in the American Common- wealth. Four of the cantons (Uri, Unterwalden, Glaris, and Appenzell), or parts of them, are living under the oldest constitutions in the civilised world.^ „ Government Their government is a folkmoot, which of the , ■ .1 ■ 4. 1 i Cantons. meets once a year in the open air, to elect officers, impose taxes, and sanction laws. The re- maining eighteen cantons have representative assem- blies, but even in these cantons the inhabitants have a direct influence in initiating laws by ' Imperative Petition,' and a veto on new laws, because they can demand that they shall not take effect till they are confirmed by a plebiscite in the canton. The peoples of the cantons are exceedingly well suited for ruling by plebiscite ; the cantons are very small, and property is evenly distributed. Great care is taken to safeguard the political rights of the individual Swiss citizen. If a householder moves from one canton into another, he instantly becomes a citizen of his new canton on showing that he has a house situated in its territory. Till 1891 the Swiss Constitution placed impedi- ments in the way of alterations in the Federal law and constitution. Till then it was the rule that all new laws and changes in the constitution should be initiated by receiving the approval of the two chambers of legislature, but changes in the constitu- ' Demombynes, Constitutions Europ^ennes, vol. ii. p. 474. U8 REFEEENDUM [CH. xxi. tion should never become law unless they were con- firmed by a plebiscite, and other new laws should re.--^ main invalid till submitted to a plebiscite, Alterations ■ r i ■ ^ t ■ ■ i ■ i ■ t in the Federal if thirty thousand citizcns desired it. In Law and Con- ^j^g plebiscite, the Confirmation was not stitution. ■■■ given unless the new law or change in the constitution was approved by a majority in all Switzerland, and by majorities in a majority of cantons. The law or the change in the constitution to be submitted to a plebiscite was called Keferendum, because it had to be referred ; subsequently it seems that the plebiscite was called a referendum. The plebiscite was found to be an efficient guard against hasty changes, and in 1891 the Swiss had such confidence in it that they allowed it to pronounce on proposals not initiated in the legislature. Since then any fifty thousand citizens may formulate a change in the law or the constitution, their- proposal must be submitted to a plebiscite, and if it is approved by majorities both in all Switzerland and in a majority of cantons, it takes its place in the statute book. The perniission given 1891 to private citizens to initiate new laws has had no startling results. Up to the year 1900 three proposals had been privately initiated ; two will serve to show how the plebiscite acted as a protection against some dangers but not against others. In 1894 it was proposed that every Swiss citizen should have a right to adequately remunerated work. Property is very evenly dis- tributed in Switzerland, and therefore the burden of paying remuneration for w.ork which could not earn CH. XXI. J POPULAR INITIATIVE 449 -wages in the open market would have fallen on the very numerous class who support themselves by doing work for which employers are glad to pay. The proposal was rejected by a large majority.^ In 1893 it was proposed to regulate slaughter-houses and to make it impossible for Jews to obtain meat which their ceremonial traditions permitted them to eat. The proposal hurt no one except a nationality which had often been persecuted, and it was accepted by the required majorities in Switzerland and its cantons. If we survey the history of Switzerland in the nineteenth century it is obvious that the union has been made far closer than it was. Till ^^ The union 1848 it was doubtful whether the people has grown formed one state or many states. In 1848 ^ °^^'^' they obtained a common government capable of enforcing commands on individual subjects; the kinds of commands which the central government , could enforce were more numerous than in the United States of America, and the sphere of activity left to the governments of the cantons was restricted within narrow limits. Since 1848 changes have been made; every change that has in any way altered the relations between the centre and the parts, has given additional power to the central government. The permission given to private 1 The only two good discussions known to me of the Popular Initiative in Switzerland, are contained in two articles by Miss Lilian Tomn. One is published in the Progressive Rerieio for July ] 897, pp. 345-357 ; the other in the Go-operative Wholesale Societies' Annual for 1900, pp. 337-356. 2 F 450 UNION STEADILY CLOSER [ch. xxi. citizens to propose new laws does not obviously alter the relations between the centre and the parts ; but certainly it does not in any way strengthen the governments in the cantons. Switzerland, like the United States, has moved steadily along the path from Staatenbund to Bundesstaat. CHAPTER XXII MODERN UNIONS OF STATES We have now passed in review all those kinds of states which occur most frequently in the history of the world taken as a whole. "We have examined in some detail all the types of simple states; and among the composite states we have paid some atten- tion to those formed hy conquest in the Middle Ages, and to two important states formed or completed in modern times by the voluntary union of equals. There remain for our consideration some composite states formed by conquest since the end of the Middle Ages, and some formed in modern times by processes which have not yet engaged our attention. It wiU be well also to notice that there have occurred in modern times some unions of states which were intended to produce composite states, but did not attain the end which their founders proposed. In the present chapter I shall give some indication of those composite states which have not yet been noticed, and of those unions of states which have failed to form new states. The chapter will treat of nothing but unions of states, and it will therefore tend to clearness if I begin it by enumerating the ways in which unions of states can be effected. 451 452 KINDS [oh. xxii. The kinds of unions observed hitherto are two: (1) Unions by conquest, or, in other words, compulsory- Unions of unions, in which the compulsion is ex- states can ercised by the strongest party in the att^pred^in union; (2) voluntary unions of equals, four ways. ^o these two kinds we must now add two more: (3) compulsory unions of states ordained by other states not themselves parties to the unions ; and (4) voluntary unions of unequals. We have, then, in all, four kinds of unions. In the course of modern history unions of all four kinds have taken place. The undoubted instances of the second • kind (voluntary unions of equals) have all been noticed in the last two chapters. Nothing then remains for us to do but to consider instances of the other three kinds of unions, and to examine what contribution (if any) each kind of union has made to the formation of modern composite states. Conquests of territory have been many and great in the modern history of Europe ; but they have not ,, . been so effective in making new states as Modern ° unions made might be expected from their number y conques . ^^^ magnitude. Throughout modern history states have been more mature than in the Middle Ages, and it has generally been impossible to make a permanent union of states unless they are marked out for union by similarity of character and history. Charles the Fifth, Gustavus Adolphus, and Napoleon were great conquerors, but their con- quests generally remained separate states because they were too dissimilar or too distant for imion. GH. XXII.] OF UNIONS 453 The states of modern Europe whicli have been con- spicuously successful in uniting conquered states with themselves, are France under Louis the Four- teenth and Prussia. Louis the Fourteenth acquired large pieces of territory on his north-eastern border ; their inhabitants were all converted into loyal French- men, and still, with the exception of Alsace and Lorraine, remain incorporated with France. Prussia has been entirely made by conquests ; and all parts of Prussia, except the provinces acquired from Poland, appear to cohere firmly together. The conquests, then, of Louis the Fourteenth and of the Prussians resulted in the formation of coherent states ; but they stand alone. There are indeed two other unions of territories in modern Europe deserving of notice because their effects have been permanent. Eussia and Austria acquired portions of Poland, and still hold them ; but they have not succeeded in inducing the inhabitants to coalesce with their other subjects. There has been a period in modern history when unions of states have been ordained by other states not themselves parties to the unions. . T • 1 • 1 Unions These unions were designed to suit the of states, convenience of those states which planned ordained by other states. them, or of Europe as a whole, without any regard to the wishes of the communities immedi- ately affected by them ; and they belong to the period from 1700 to 1815, when the better states- men were dominated by the ideal of the Balance of Power, and the modern conception of Nationalities had not yet been formed. In most cases they 454 KINDS [OH. xxii. joined dissimilar communities under a common yoke, and in these cases they have failed to form durable new states. The Treaty of Utrecht joined parts of the Spanish dominions with Austria, and the Congress of Vienna gave Belgium to Holland, and Norway to Sweden. The unions decreed at Utrecht have all been dissolved: Belgium broke loose from Holland after fifteen years ; Norway and Sweden never had a common Parliament, and now their only bond of union is that they have the same King and the same Minister for ^Foreign Affairs. All these cases show that a mere decree issued by the Powers of Europe did not suffice to bind dissiTnilar communities in permanent union. On the other hand, if similar communities are joined together at the command of an external Power, permanent states may be formed. In Germany, in 1801-1803, the states till then owned by ecclesiastical princes or imperial knights were joined, at the command of Napoleon Buonaparte, with larger German states; and the arrangements then made in regard to them have generally remained in force to the present day. The whole result of my consideration of unions ordained by external Powers is to show that, in regard to the making of new states, they have the same effect as unions made by con- quest. If they are unions of dissimilar communities, they are afterwards dissolved ; if they are unions of similar communities, they are permanent. It will then be needless for the future to make any distinc- tion between unions made by conquest and unions ordained by external Powers. They can all be put cai. xxii.] OP UNIONS 455 together in a single class under the title of unions effected by compulsion. Voluntary unions of unequals often occurred in the Middle Ages : it happened frequently that the owner of a small fief coTumended himself and his „ , , Voluntary l9,nd, for protection, to a neighbouring unions of prince, or to a neighbouring city. In the "°^^" annals, however, of the Middle Ages unions of this kind are inconspicuous, because the communities affected by them were of minute dimensions. In modern times states large enough to be counted in the second or third rank have found that their com- paratively small proportions have exposed them to disadvantages or dangers, and have voluntarily sought and obtained union with more powerful neighbours. Voluntary unions of smaller states with larger states led, in the eighteenth century, to the establishment of the Kingdom of Great Britain, and in the nineteenth founded the Kingdom of Italy and the North German Federation, which has since grown into the German Empire. At the beginning of the eighteenth century the Scots had many reasons for thinking that union with England would be preferable to their exist- g^otiand and ing condition of semi-dependence. They England, were a strange mixture of many races, and the existence of their Parliament only ensured that power to misgovern should be passed backwards and forwards from one faction to another. But they were chiefly influenced by consideration of their poverty. They could not escape from it unless they 456 GEEAT BRITAIN [CH. xxii. had free trade with England: and England would not grant free trade without union. In 1702 the Parliament of Scotland empowered Queen Anne to name Commissioners for Scotland to negotiate about union with other Commissioners named for England, in accordance with an Act of the Parliament of England. When the Commissioners met, the Scots betrayed a desire to have co-ordinate governments for Scotland, for England, and for Great Britain, according to the federal plan of government which existed in the Netherlands; but the Englishmen would not assent to any union except under a supreme government.^ The conditions were settled according to the wishes of the stronger party to the union. In the eighteenth century Great Britain was a unitary state, and it is now a unitary nation. In 1858 Napoleon the Third made a verbal agree- ment with Cavour that, in case of a war waged with Italy, i8s9- a reasonable pretext by Piedmont against 1870. Austria, he would aid Piedmont, provided that he received as his reward Savoy and possibly Nice. In fulfilment of his engagement he entered North Italy in 1859, and fought and won the battles of Magenta and Solferino. After this he immediately signed preliminaries of peace with Austria at Yilla- franca, consenting that Austria should keep Venetia, that the petty despots of Tuscany and Modena, dependants of Austria, should resume possession of their dominions, and only stipulating on behalf of the Italians that there should be an Italian Federa- tion, of which Venetia under Austrian direct rule, ' Stanhope, Reign of Queen Anne, oh. vi. end. CH. XXII.] ITALY 457 •with Tuscany and Modena under their despots, should be members. The Piedmontese, and especially their great statesman Cavour, desired something better than a federation in which Austria would control most of the votes : and their wish was grati- fied. The peoples of Tuscany and Modena in a quiet and orderly manner organised small armies sufficient to keep out their despots : Sicily and Naples, in 1860, under the lead of Garibaldi expelled their Bourbon King Francis the Second : the whole Italian people desired union under Victor Emmanuel, and a single Parliament for the whole kingdom. By 1861 almost the whole peninsula was a single state : Venice was added in 1866, and Rome followed four years later. Italy has been formed through the voluntary union of many unequal states ; and in accordance with the wishes of Piedmont, the strongest party in the union, it is a unitary state under a single government. Germany, as we have already noticed, broke up in 1250 on the death of the Emperor Frederick the Second, and the small communities Germany, which had grown up among the Germans 1250-1866. became sovereign states.^ They were too small to stand alone conveniently. In 1273 Rudolph of Hapsburg was elected as Emperor, and from the fourteenth century to the outbreak of the Thirty Years' War in 1618 the German states formed an extremely loose confederation, having for their common government a Diet under the presidency of an elected Emperor. From the end of the Thirty Years' War to the fall of Napoleon the states of ' See page 242. 458 GEEMANY [oh. xxii. Germany were separate sovereignties, without any common government. In 1815 they agreed to form a Deutscher Bund. It was nominally a loose con- federation, but it scarcely deserves the name, because the Diet, its only common organ, was powerless. From thenceforward, however, a general desire for closer union arose among all the Germans except the Austrians. Till 1866 the jealousy of the Austrians made closer union impossible. ^^By far the most powerful German princes were the Emperor of Austria and the King of Prussia. Austria and ^^'^ ^^^^ ^^ ^^^^ ^^^^ '"'^^^ jealoUS Prussia, rivals. The dominions of the Emperor were extensive, but were inhabited by many jarring nationalities. The Prussian state was of moderate size, but most of its provinces, though not yet perfectedly united, were tending towards unity. In 1850 the Prussians thought, prematurely, that they were thoroughly united, and obtained from their king a constitution which established for Prussia such a Parliament as is suited to a unitary nation. Prussia was not yet a coherent community, and its new Parliament was not capable of restraining a strong executive government. Its incapacity was shown after 1862, when Bismarck became Minister-President. In 1864 and 1865 the Parliament refused to vote the taxes, but Bismarck succeeded in collecting them. During the two years in which Bismarck ruled Prussia in defiance of its Parliament, Austria and Prussia were engaged as allies in the conquest and occupation of Schleswig- CH. XXII. J GERMANY 459 Holstein. In 1866 they quarrelled about the dis- position of their conquests : war was declared between them, Austria was defeated at Sadowa, and was ex- pelled from the German Bund. The states in North Germany voluntarily joined in a close union under the title of the North German Federation. The new composite state made in 1866 was founded through a voluntary union of unequals, but it had a federal character. The inequality between 1 , _ . North Ger^.^ its members was extreme, rrussia was ^-^n PederaT opposed in arms by Hanover and Hesse- *'°"' ^^^^ Cassel during its war with Austria: it speedily annexed them, and they became parts of the Prussian state. When these annexations had been made, the population of Prussia comprised three-quarters of the inhabitants of North Germany ; the other- quarter was divided among twenty small states of which Saxony was the largest. Although the disparity among the members of the new state was so great, Bismarck decided to treat the small states most generously, and to found a federal state in which they were liberally endowed with political rights. The reasons which influenced him are not perhaps as yet perfectly known, but we can see some of them. It was probable that any harsh dealings with the lesser states might be used by Napoleon the Third as a pretext for interference. It was certain that if small states gained no advantages on joining - the federation, the states in South Germany, Bavaria, Wirtemberg, Baden, Hesse-Darmstadt, would never apply for admission among its members. Besides 460 GERMANY [ch. xxn. all this, Bismarck knew the rulers of the small states from his long experience as Prussian representative in the Diet of the old Bund at Frankfurt. The small states were naturally grown communities, their governments were such as they produced naturally, and among their rulers were men with whom Bismarck was willing to work. And, lastly, Bismarck was already pledged to the establishment of a representative assembly for all Germany, because the King of Prussia by his advice had solemnly promised it before the beginning of the war with Austria. He knew from his experience of the Prussian Parliament that Germany could not provide such representatives as would be required to make an effective popular assembly. He was not willing that his representative assembly should wield the boundless power of an English House of Commons : it was wiser to take as his model the American House of Kepresentatives which is kept in check by the Senate. He must, in fact, construct an influential Upper Chamber of Legis- lature ; and the natural way of constructing it was to entrust the nomination of its members to the govern- ments of the component states in the federation.^ In the course of the great war waged in 1870-1871 between Germany and France, the four states in South Germany, Bavaria, Wirtemberg, Empire, Baden, and Hesse-Darmstadt, asked and I 70-1 71- obtained admission to the federation. The North German Federation took the name of ^ The documents and speeches, from which every estimate of Bismarck's public life and policy must be formed, are collected in Hahn, FiXrst Bismarck. Students of modern German history have CH. XXII.] GERMANY 461 the German Empire, but its constitution remained unaltered in its general principles. The German Empire is a federal state; but it differs from other federal states because Prussia contains more inhabitants than all the other component states put together, and ^f the'cer-" because the strongest organ in the govern- ™^° Empire, ment is a hereditary soyereign. There are twenty-five states in the Empire : each has a government of its own, and there is also a central or federal government for regulating matters which concern the whole Empire. The character of every federal state is mainly determined by the extent of the powers entrusted to the central government. The central government in the German Empire is far stronger than the corresponding organ in any other federal state. It has all the powers exercised by the Federal Government in the United States, and many others of extreme importance in addition. It defines and enforces the obligations of every German subject in regard to military service; it makes the civil and criminal law, including all law that relates to meetings and newspapers ; and, lastly, it has the power of altering the constitution, subject only to the limitation that no alteration can be made, if in the Upper Chamber of the Legislature (the Bundesrath) fourteen votes out of fifty-eight are opposed to its enactment.^ reason to be grateful to Mr. J. W. Headlam for the excellent descriptions of the chief events and of the German constitution contained in his Bismarck ('Heroes of the Nations' Series). ' Dareate, Oonstitutiojis Modernes, vol. i. pp. 135, 136, 158. 462 GEEMAISTY [CH. xxn. The central government has its executive, legis- lative, and judicial organs. The executive govern- ment is vested in the Emperor and his Central ^ Government: Chancellor. The King of Prussia, from Executive. ^^^ ^^^^ ^-^^^ ^^ jg j^j^^g^ -g Qerman Emperor. He commands the armed forces, and makes treaties; but to declare war, if not merely defensive, he needs the consent of the Bundesrath. The Chancellor, appointed by the Emperor, is his adviser, and is President of the Bundesrath. The legislature consists of two chambers, the Bundesrath and the Keichstag. The Reichstag is a representative chamber, consisting of three hundred and ninety-seven members, elected by all adult male German subjects. There is nothing in the written constitution to prevent it from being a powerful assembly; but hitherto it has not exercised any strong control over the Empire. The Bundesrath consists of councillors named by the governments of the twenty-five states. Each state has a definite number of votes. There are fifty-eight votes in all : Prussia has seventeen. Each state may name any number of councillors not exceeding the number of its votes; but in every division all its votes must be given on the same side and collectively. Of the two chambers the Bundesrath is much the more powerful. It is composed of experienced states- Tjjgt^o men; its debates are secret; and it is Chambers. closely linked with the executive govern- ment, as the Parliament is in England, because the CH. XXII. J GEEMANY 463 Chancellor is its President. The Reichstag is broken up into many small groups ; and hitherto the groups have not shown much power of cohering together. Both chambers have, under the constitution, the right of proposing new laws; but the Bundesrath is far more skilful than the Reichstag in drafting them, and its proposals have the support of the Chancellor. The Bundesrath is practically by far the most power- ful assembly in the Empire; and the Reichstag has to content itself with a limited opportunity for criticism, with the power to amend or reject bills, and to refuse its assent to the imposition of new taxes.^ All the remaining agencies of government in Germany are of minor importance. The judicial organ in the central government is a law- _^ court belonging to the three old Hanseatic groverning cities of Lixbeck, Bremen, and Hamburg, ^s^^""^'^^- which are component states in the Empire. The work of interpreting the constitution, which in the United States of America is assigned to the Supreme Court, is done in the German Empire by the central legislature, which has the power of amending the constitution, and can therefore add new clauses to settle its interpretation ; the only function of the High Court of Appeal which sits at Ltlbeck is to try accusations of high treason against the Empire.^ The component states in the Empire have their separate constitutions and governments; but the ' Headlam, Bismarck, pp. 296-300. 2 Constitution of the German Empire, articles 74, 75 : printed in Dareste, Constitutions Modernes, vol. i. pp. 157, 158. 464 AUSTRIA [ch. xxii. sphere of action of their governments is confined within somewhat narrow limits by the great extent of the powers exercised by the central government of the Empire. Nevertheless it seems incontestable that the Prussian minister Bismarck showed great generosity towards the lesser states in Germany, when in the consultations which made the constitu- tion of the Empire he distributed among them forty- one votes in the Bundesrath, and only retained seventeen for Prussia. Voluntary unions of unequals in modern times have founded two diiferent kinds of composite states. The union of Scotland with England Voluntary /• -i t ■ i i • /. unions of lounded a Unitary state, and the union oi unequals. ^j^g Italian states with Piedmont founded Conclusions. another state of the same nature; but the union of the German states with Prussia founded a federation. We can only account for the divergent results produced by unions of weaker with stronger states by observing that, in every case, the nature of the union has been determined according to the wishes of the strongest party to the union. Before closing this chapter on modern unions of states, it is necessary to inquire whether any union The relation "^ Austria and Hungary under one of Austria government has occurred in recent times, to ungary. ^^^ whether the two countries are now separate states or are joined into a composite state. It is an undoubted fact that for four or five years before 1867 they were as truly separate states as Scotland and England before their union. Can we CH. XXII.] AND HUNGAEY 465 assert that the agreement made between them in 1867 joined them into a composite state of federal character, or must we regard it as amounting only to the conclusion of an alliance between two separate political bodies ? In 1867 Austria and Hungary agreed that, under the Pragmatic Sanction of 1723, they were subject to the same sovereign, the head of the house of Hapsburg ; that in future they would have the same Ministers for Foreign Affairs, for War, and for their common Finance. They further made an agree- ment, subject to revision at the end of ten years, which determined the proportions in which they would contribute to their common expenditure: from 1868 for ten years 70 per cent, was paid by Austria, and 30 per cent, by Hungary; from 1878 Austria paid 68-6 and Hungary 81-4.i The ways and means of raising the contributions of the two countries were left to be settled by the legislature of each country for itself, and were in no sense a matter of common interest or of common regulation. There were, however, some matters which required concordant legislation for the whole of Austria and Hungary : the chief item among them was obviously appropriation of supplies. The settlement of these matters was entrusted to two Delegations, chosen by the legislatures of the two countries, and each con- sisting of sixty members. Each Delegation was to sit and debate by itself on the propositions submitted to it by the Ministers for Foreign Affairs, for War, 1 Dareate, Oonstitutions Modernes, vol. i. p. 333, note. 2g 466 AUSTRIA [ch. xxii. and for Finance. The Delegations were to exchange communications in writing of their decisions; if, after three interchanges of communications on any matter, they did not agree, either Delegation could demand that they should meet together in a Plenary Session, and, without discussion, settle the matter by vote.i There is no doubt that for purposes of international law the agreements made in 1867 amounted to a union of Austria and Hungary, because Hungary, they Settled that in making treaties with ummary. £Qj.gjgjj pg-virers the two Countries would act together. It is therefore right and proper that in treatises on international law. these two countries are described as being joined in a Personal Union or a Real Union. But it does not follow that they have a common government in any sense that would imply they are one state. They cannot be one state unless they have a common government, which can issue commands either to the governments or the subjects of the two countries. Neither the Emperor- King nor his three ministers are empowered by the constitutions of Austria and Hungary to issue commands of their own authority. The Delegations, while they sit separately, are not one governing agency but two. If indeed they should join in Plenary Session, they would be a common legislature for the composite state of Austria-Hungary; but ^ For the whole of the arrangements made between Austria and Hungary in 1867 see Dareste, Constitutions Modernes, vol. i. pp. 328-3.57. OH. xxii.] AND HUNGAEY 467 I do not know any instance of their junction, and am under an impression that, at least in recent years, no Plenary Session has been held. If this impression is correct, it follows beyond a doubt that Austria and Hungary are separate states under separate governments. CHAPTER XXIII SUMMARY Now that I have completed my survey of Political Bodies and their Governments I wish to recapitulate its results. But before doing this it may be well to digress for a moment into a notice of certain words with different shades of meaning, by which political bodies, or some of them, have been designated. All the objects of our investigation have been political bodies. A political body is any group of men, or group of groups of men, joined together by the one fact of living under one government. A coTriTnunity is a group of men joined together by common aims and interests; and we can speak of any political body that is not a heterogeneous empire as a community. A state is a political body having an equal status or standing with those political bodies of its time which rank highest in power and civilisation. We can then quite rightly speak of the modern nations and empires and of the ancient republics as states. We should be departing from the common usage of words if we gave the name of state to a mere tribe either of the present time or of past ages ; for tribes have no formal negotiations with one another, and therefore have no idea of status. 463 CH. XXIII.] SUMMAEY 469 It seems incongruous, too, if the Roman Empire is called a state at the time when it was lord of the civilised world ; it could not condescend to think of status when it possessed universal dominion. But though the term state is not properly co-extensive with political body, I have ventured sometimes to use it almost as if it were. It was impossible to employ on every occasion a cumbrous combination of an adjective and a noun derived from different languages; and wherever I have wished to speak of political bodies collectively, without pointed refer- ence to tribes or heterogeneous empires, I have given them the shorter name of states. We have divided states into two classes according as they are simple or composite. A simple state is one community; a composite state is ^. made by union of communities. The four simple kinds of simple states are known as tribes, ^ ^ ^• simple city states, independent fiefs, and unitary nations. (1) A tribe is a community, having a territory and government of its own, living mainly in the open country, knowing little or nothing of town life, and devoting itself to pastoral, agricultural, or military pursuits.^ (2) A simple city state ' is an independent community of townsmen, living in a waUed city, and having no large extent of rural territory, so that the city is the sole centre of popula- tion, society, wealth, and government.^ (3) An inde- pendent fief is the property of a nobleman who has become an independent prince.^ (4) A unitary 1 See pages 18, 266. ^ gee pages 56, 58. ^ gee page 242. 470 SUMMAEY [OH. xxiii. nation is a large homogeneous community, thoroughly united in common aims, interests, and sentiments, and living under a single supreme government.^ The results of our investigation and classification of simple states have proved to be fairly satisfactory. _ . (1) Tribes have been divided into three Governments ^ ' of simple classes according as they are poor or rich or aggressive, and each class has uniformly a certain kind of government which is not found elsewhere. (2) Simple cities have been separated into two classes according as they employ slave labour or free labour; each class has only a few kinds of government, and they are not found any- where but in that particular class of cities. (3) Inde- pendent fiefs have necessarily been left unnoticed, because we have no complete information about their characters or governments. (4) The remaining class of simple states, the modern unitary nations, all conform to a single type, and all have the same kind of government, which is not shared by any other political communities. Composite states also have been classified. They are always formed by union of lesser communities ; Kinds of ^^^ ^^^^ ^^^^ ^^^^ *^° great classes accord- composite ing as they are founded on (1) compulsory union, or (2) voluntary union. (1) Com- pulsory union may join together like communities or unlike communities. If it joins like communities, and they are cities, the resulting composite state is a complex city state. If it joins like communities, ^ See pages 394, 396. CH. xxiii.] SUMMAEY 471 and they are rural in character, the resulting state is like the mediaeval kingdoms. If it joins unlike communities the resulting state is a heterogeneous empire. (2) Voluntary union joins together some- times states of equal power, sometimes unequals. If the states joined together are equals, the resulting state is always federal. If they are unequals, the resulting state may have a federal or a unitary character according to circumstances. We have divided composite states into classes, but ■we must confess that not one of those classes conforms invariably to one type of govern- _ •' J s. c Governments ment. There is always a large element of of composite deliberate design in the making of com- posite states ; they are therefore more artificial than simple states, and more variable in their methods of government. (1) The states made by conquest or compulsion are complex city states, mediaeval kingdoms and their like, and heterogeneous empires. The governments of complex city states present analogies with one another but do not conform to a single type. The governments of mediaeval king- doms are varied in form and seem to defy classifica- tion. The governments of heterogeneous empires are even more multiform; here, however, it is not the state that makes the government, but the government that makes the state. Governments of the kind known as bureaucratic make empires of exceptional strength and durability. The strong empires made by bureaucratic governments are all nearly alike, and form a sub-class of states conform- 472 SUMMARY [cH. xxm. ing to a definite type. (2) The states made by voluntary union have all been federal, except Great Britain and modern Italy, which became unitary nations. These two unitary nations made by the willing union of their parts do not differ in any way from the unitary nations which have grown up from states formed in distant centuries by conquest. Of the governments of federal states I must speak with some reserve, because there are some which I have not discussed. If I had examined them all I should have found that they possess some features in common ; but the government of the United Nether- lands would, I imagine, have presented some strange divergences from other federal governments. On the other hand, there are two eminent forms of federal states, known respectively as loose confedera- tions and close federations. We have found that the governments, if so they may be caUed, of loose confederations are all characterised by extreme weakness in the common government, and a near approach to independence in the governments of the component states. The governments of close federations may diverge very widely ; among them are numbered both the frankly republican government of the United States of America, and the almost monarchic government of the German Empire. My recapitulation has been very brief, and, if taken by itself, not very lucid. The reader may probably wish to refer back to the passages in the preced- ing chapters which give the justification and ex- planation of its statements. For his convenience CH. xxm.] SUMMAEY 473 I append a tabular summary in two columns, with refer- ences to pages. In most parts of the table (see next page) the first column contains the names n , , • , P 11 n Tabular 01 the kinds of states, and the second summary for indicates the character of their govern- convenience ° of reference. ments. In the part, however, that relates to Heterogeneous Empires, where, as we have just seen, government is primary and the character of the state secondary, the order is reversed; the first column indicates the nature of the government, and the second the qualities possessed by the state which that government has brought into existence. TABLE OF STATES AND THEIK GOVEENMENTS DIVISION I.- KINDS OF STATES. 1. Tribes. a. Poor Tribes. -SIMPLE STATES GOVERNMENTS. b. Eich Tribes. Uniform. Assembly of king, elders, and people (pages 17- 26). Uniform. Council of king and elders (pages 25-31). c. Aggressive Tribes. Uniform. King only, as com- mander-in-chief (pages 39, 40). Class governments. Limited to three forms — (1) Oligarchy. (2) Tyranny. (3) Democracy (pages 62-79). Limited to few forms. The rulers are a group of classes (pages 311-341). Unknown (pages 242, 243). Uniform. A Cabinet, a Parlia- ment, and a dignified Sove- reign, who reigns but does not rule (pages 394-416). 2. Simple Cities. a. With slaves. b. Without slaves. 3. Independent Fiefs, 4. Unitary Nations. 474 475 DIVISION II.— COMPOSITE STATES KINDS OF STATES. 1. Unions made by compulsion. A. Unions of like States made by compul- GOVERNMENTS. One supreme government. sion. a. Complex States. City king- NoT Uniform, but not ex- tremely variable. Elective magistrates, a council, popu- lar assembly (pages 80-150). Various (pages 288-308). b. Mediaeval doms. B. Unions of unlike States made by compulsion. HeterogeneousEmpires, GOVERNMENTS. KINDS OF STATES. (1) Bureaucracy with Durable Empires (pages 176- strong military force. 208). (2) Other governments. Empires various in form, but always transient (pages 209, 210). KINDS OF STATES. GOVERNMENTS. 2. Voluntary Unions. A. Voluntary unions of Federal. Many co-ordinate equals. governments (pages 419, 420). 476 DIVISION II.— COMPOSITE STATES (contmued) KINDS OF STATES. GOVERNMENTS. a. Loose confederations. The central government weak (pages 422, 423). b Close federations. The central government com- paratively strong (.pages 423-450). B. Voluntary unions of unequals (of rare occurrence). 1. Great Britain, 1707- UnitaryStates (pages 455-457). 1801. Italy from 1859. 2. Germany from 1867. A Federation (pages 457-464). APPENDIX^ HYPOTHESES OF A UNIFORM ORIGIN OF POLITICAL BODIES AND GOVERNMENTS Many speculative thinkers have conceived an idea that there must have been some uniform process which origin- ally gave birth to all primitive political bodies aild to all primitive governments. Hooker, Hobbes, Locke, and Rousseau all argued in favour of their hypotheses of a uniform origin. It is now universally admitted that their hypotheses are disproved by known facts, and it is needless for me to consider them. The attempt (to which I referred in my text), to discover a uniform origin of political organi- sation from observation of ancient customs imbedded in the institutions of peoples who afterwards attained to various degrees of civilisation, was made by Filmer in the reign of Charles the Second, and was repeated about fifty years ago by Sir Henry Maine. We may confine our attention to Sir Henry Maine's researches and conclusions. His researches have led to a great increase in our know- ledge of primitive social customs, and among his conclusions are numbered both a theory of Primitive Family Discipline and a theory of an Origin of Government. As primitive social customs and family discipline are not themselves a part of my subject, I need not mention anything that has been discovered or written in regard to them except what affects governments and their origins or forms. The ancient customs to be noticed are these. It is a perfectly established fact that, among the Romans under 1 See page 7. 477 478 PATRIAECHAL [app. the kings and the Republic, the father of a family was the sole owner of property, except what his sons earned in the service of the state, and in family discipline he was far „ . ... more uncontrolled master of his wife and his Primitive ■ i n i customs adult sons and adult unmarried daughters than known from a modem parent is of a child ten years old.^ evidence. ^g ^j,g ^qJ^j -^y (Jajus, the great Eoman jurist, that he had never heard of fathers of families possessing these extreme powers in any people outside Rome, except the Celts who had settled in Galatia. But though the Roman family despotism, known as Patria Potestas, never existed except among the Romans and Galatians, it is certain that in some other peoples adult sons were in some degree subject to their fathers. The books of Genesis and Exodus prove that their writers knew of peoples in which adult sons had to obey their fathers in some respects ; and there are indications, which I have not been able to study but which I believe to be trustworthy, that some kind of subjection of adult sons to their fathers has prevailed among the Hindus, the northern Slavs of Russia, and the southern Slavs of the Balkans. Sir Henry Maine made and published some most interesting researches into the customs of the ancient Irish, which included most intricate arrangements for the acquisition of family rights, but were by no means equivalent to a simple system of paternal command and filial obedience. It was shown by the researches that in some ancient peoples fathers had some control over the doings of their adult sons. Sir Henry Maine and his followers primitive inferred by analogy that in other peoples, paternal about whom we have no evidence, a similar family system prevailed. I do not think any solid argument against their inference can be founded on the fact that in modern uncivilised peoples mothers and not fathers are the owners of family property 1 For the evidence see Marquardt, RSmische AUerthwmer, Privatlebm, vol. i. pp. 2-6. APP.] THEORIES 479 and the transmitters of ownership to their children. Mr. Lewis Morgan in his Ancient Society expresses a probable opinion when he says that where Matriarchate came first Patriarchate might easily follow. It seems, further, that the existence among the Romans of paternal superiority over adult sons yields a fair presumption of its existence among the Greeks, and the supposition that it prevailed among the early Greeks gives the only reasonable explana- tion of many of their later customs and sentiments. I take it, then, that some kind of Patriarchate in regard to family property and discipline existed among the forefathers of the two great ruling peoples of ancient history, and to some degree among those two peoples in the ages when they are known to us from contemporary evidence. But this fact is of minor importance in the history of the whole of Europe if there was no Patriarchate among the Germans, the founders of the greatest medieval and modern states. I think it is proved that there was none. It is certain the rigid Patria Potestas of the Romans did not exist among the Germans. The Roman Potestas made it impossible that a title to inheritance could be derived from or through a woman. Tacitus tells us that, if a German died without leaving children, the next claimants to his succession were his brothers, his father's brothers, and his moiAer's brothers. ^ A mother, then, among the Germans could transmit a title, and the strict Roman Potestas with its concomitant, ex- clusive agnatic succession, did not exist. On all this I lay no stress : it is not likely that any one would ever imagine that the Germans had ever lived under a complete system of Roman Patria Potestas. But there are other facts which I think important because they convince me that the customs of the Germans, from the earliest times of which we have information, did not give fathers any power to control their adult sons in their persons or property. About 400 A.D. the Gallic provincials were Roman citizens, and the family-relations of most of them were regulated 1 Tacitus, Oermcmia, ^. 20. 480 PATRIARCHAL [afp. by the Roman system of Patria Potestas. Soon afterwards German peoples settled among the Gallic provincials as masters and rulers. If they had brought with them any patriarchal custom giving fathers control in private rela- tions over their adult children, that custom would have combined with the Patria Potestas already prevalent in Gaul, and the mixed population in the country would have lived either partly under the German custom and partly under the Roman, or under some system intermediate between the two. As a matter of fact, the French lawyers could write puissoMce de phre en France n'a lieu, and I see no reason to doubt that they could have written it as truly in the age of Charlemagne as in any subsequent period. Sir Henry Maine's hypothesis of a uniform Origin of States and Governments rests on the belief that a patri- Theorv of ^rchal system of Family Ownership and Disci- an origin pline was widely diffused, if not universal, of govern- among primitive peoples at some stage of ""^ their existence. He supposes that families expanded into bodies politic by processes of multiplication of descendants and adoption of sons, and that when the expansion had occurred the father of the family became king or chief of the political body, or that the government was closely imitated from the rule of a patriarch over his family. This method, however, of creating political government where none had existed, could only be prac- tised by a people who had lived under a patriarchal system of private family-relations. If my reasoning in the last paragraph is correct, the Germans had no such system of family-organisation, and therefore among them there was no patriarchal origin of government. The chief states of mediaeval and modern times were founded by Germans, and therefore the governments of those states owed nothing to a patriarchal origin. If so much is. established, I do not care to discuss origins of government in other states. But it may be useful to remark that among the Romans, who lived under the strictest Patria Potestas ever known, no APR] THEORIES 481 truly political institutions are proved to have a patriarchal origin. The Roman kingship had no such origin, because the kings did not succeed by inheritance but were elected. The senate was hardly patriarchal, because the senators were nominated. If the curiae had been patriarchal, their names would have been as conspicuous in records as the names of the patrician gentes, and it could not have been thought that a curia contained about ten gentes and a hundred families, because patriarchal bodies must vary greatly in the pace at which they multiply the number of their offshoots. Lastly, the patrician gentes, as the Cor- nelia and the Papiria, were undoubtedly patriarchal in origin. The gentile names were most conspicuous : the Gens Cornelia contained sixteen great families, with many sub-divisions, while some gentes contained only one family. The gentes, then, as they had conspicuous names and varied greatly in size, exhibited both the marks which distinguish patriarchal institutions. But, in times known to history, the individual gentes were not political institu- tions ; and we do not know that they ever had been political. It is, no doubt, possible that before the tribes of the Titles, Eamnes, and Luceres were formed, the heads of patrician gentes may have been heads of minute political societies ; but, even so, they furnish a solitary instance of a patriarchal Roman institution which may once have been political in character. 2h INDEX AoHiEAN League, 442. Areopagus, 95. - Argos, 173. Aryans, 11. Athens, Attica. See City States, Ancient. Augustus, 190. Austria, relations of, with Hungary, 465. Belgium. See Nations, Unitary: also 398, 402. Bureaucracy, 207. CaiSAE, 188. Castile. See Spain. Celts, prehistoric, 15. Charlemagne , his empire and govern- ment, 228. City States, definition, 56 ; origin, 56 ; simple and complex, 58. See City States, Ancient ; City States, Complex ; City States, Medieval ; City States, Simple. City States, Ancient — Athens before 480 B.C. ySeeAttica. Athens after 480 B.C., 151-173; structure of the state, 151 ; democracy in, 158-173. Attica, prehistoric, 83 ; under EupatridiE, 84 ; constitution of Solon, 85 ; Peisistratus and Hippias, 91 ; constitution of Cleisthenes, 92. Eome, geography, 102; complex character in prehistoric times, 104 ; under kings, 107 ; seces- sion of the Plebs, 116; the Republic, 116-142; Senate, 135- 143. For subsequent history of Rome, see Empire, Hetero- geneous. City States, Complex, 80-150 ; con- clusions regarding, 146. City States, Mediaeval, origin of, 309 ; diverse characters, 311 ; in Germany, 309, 341 ; in Italy, 309. Florence after 1282, government of the Trade Guilds in, 317 ; the seven Greater Arts, 318 ; organs of government, 319 ; Priori, 320 ; Greater and Middle Arts, 321 ; anticipation of elec- tions, 322 ; use of the lot, 323 ; Tyranny, 324 ; the Middle and Lesser Arts, 325; Parte Guelfa, 326 ; ammonizioni, 328 ; wealth of Florence, 329 ; incompetence oftheguildsmen, 331 ; captains of the Parte Guella, 332 ; the Ciompi, 334; their insurrec- tion, 338 ; extinction of Guild- government, 339 ; character- istics of Florence, 340. Genoa, 148. Venice, origin and site, 343 early government, 344 ; Doges, 345 ; new seat of government 346 ; distant dependencies, 347 the Great Council, 349 ; con^ tentment of the people, 350 new dependencies, 351 ; skilled rulers, 352; Pregadi, 353 484 INDEX Quarantia, 353 ; closing of the Great Council, 354 ; Council of Ten, 355; Decline of Venice, 356. City States, Simple, definition of, 58 ; in Greece, 62-79 ; in Italy, 311, 316; in Germany, 341. Gleisthenes, 92-100. Constantlne the Great, 200. Constitutions. See TaWe, 474. Democeacies, 73-79 ; 161-173. Denmark, 392, 393, 398. Despotic governments. See Tyr- anni ; Empires, Heterogeneous ; Nations, Unitary ; England ; France ; Spain. Diocletian, 200. Empires, Heterogeneous, artificial and variously governed, 209 ; characters of, determined by their governments, 473. Empire of Charlemagne, 228. Empire, Roman, at first under an urban constitution, 176 ; Julius Csesar, 188 ; Augustus, 191 ; despotic government, 193 ; dis- puted successions, 195 ; Council of the Emperor, 199 ; govern- ment of, under Constantine, 202. England, made by union of Anglo- Saxon tribes, 258 ; conquered by the Danes and the Normans, 259 ; institutions of, under Norman and Angevin kings, 261 ; pre- rogatives of the kings in the Middle Ages, 288 ; great power of the Tudor sovereigns, 365 ; new houses of nobles and gentry in the age of the Tudors, 368 ; their usefulness in local govern- ment, 369. For subsequent his- tory, see Nations, Unitary. Estate, deiinition of the word, 292. Estates, assemblies of, in England, 292 ; in Castile, 296 ; in France, 301. Federal States. See Unions of equal communities ; also of un- equal communities. Fiefs, independent, 232, 241, 274. Florence before 1282 a.d., origin, 312 ; industrial organisation, 312 ; early government, 313 ; Ghibelines and Guelfs, 314; exile of the Ghibelines, 315. For subsequent history, see City States, Mediaeval. France, mediaeval, a kingdom sepa- rated off from the empire founded by Charlemagne, 231 ; indepen- dence of fiefs in, 241, 244 ; county of Paris, 243 ; Dux Francorum, 245 ; became Rex, 249 ; growth of the king's demesne to 1300 A.D., 270 ; Curia Regis, 252, 276 ; kingly power in the Middle Ages, 299 ; towns, 302 ; clergy and nobles in the Middle Ages, 304 ; weakness of the States-General, 304. France, modern, condition of, in the seventeenth century, 370 ; new noblesse, 370; intendants, 371 ; privileged orders, 372 ; enmity between classes, 373 ; the Great Revolution, 374 ; redistribution of property, 374 ; constitution of 1791, 375 ; disruption of the state, 376 ; Paris after the disruption, 377 ; constitution of the year iii. , 378 ; intervention of the army, 378 ; military despotism, 379 ; unity of France, 380 ; charter of 1814, 388 ; Republic of 1848, 390 ; renewed despotism, 390 ; con- stitution of 1871, 391. Francia, 243 ; merged in the French king's demesne, 270. Franks, Austrasian, 225. Franks, Salian, 218. Gaul, German races in, 218. German Empire, modern, 460. Government, the first origin of every, unknown, 7 ; conditions INDEX 485 necessary to the existence of, 8-12. Governments. See Table, 474. Hungary, relations of, with Au- stria, 465. Italy, under the Lombards, 217 ; City States in, 309-366 ; modern, see Nations, Unitary, and Unions of unequal commimities. Julius C/bsae, 188. Kings. See Prerogatives. Languedoo, 272. Lex Hortensia, 135. Louis le Gros, 250. Makius, 187. Migration of the barbarians, 211. Nations, Unitary, origin and char- acter, 358 ; extension to con- venient boundaries, 359 ; progress towards unity, 360 ; despotic governments — in Spain, 362 ; in France, 364; in England, 365; decline of despotic governments in, 381 ; stages of that decline in England, 383 ; control by Parlia- ment, 383; parties and the Cabinet, 384 ; end of despotic government in England, 385 ; decline of de- spotic governments on the Conti- nent, 387 ; in Spain, 388 ; in Prance, 388 ; the charter of 1814, 388 ; political requirements of unitary nations in modern times, 395 ; their modern constitutions, 395-416 ; their single supreme governments, 395 ; controlled by Parliaments, 396 ; Parliaments (in large nations) in two chambers, 397 ; the chambers of unequal power, 397. Unitary nations enumerated, 398 ; their repre- sentative chambers, 399 ; upper chambers in continental nations, 401 ; the English peers, 403 ; ex- ecutive governments, 404 ; modem Parliaments rather deliberative than legislative, 406 ; participa- tion of Cabinets in making laws, 405 ; judicatures of unitary na- tions, 408 ; alterations in consti- tutions, 412 ; dignified Sovereigns, 412 ; unitary nations of natural growth, 414 ; of one species, 414 ; but not of the same age, 415 ; their governments natural, 416. North German Federation, 459. Norway, 398, 402, 406. See also Nations, Unitary. Oligarchies, 67-70. Ostracism, 97. Papacy in the Middle Ages, 284. Paris, 243, 377. Parlement de Paris, 300, 372, Parliament, mediaeval English, 266 ; character and powers, 294. Parliaments, modern, 383-408. Patriarchal theory, in regard to private family discipline, 478 ; in regard to government, 480. Peers, English, 403 ; of France, 280. Plebs Romana, 116-142. Prerogatives of kings in medifeval England, 288 ; in Castile, 295 ; in France, 299. Roman law in the Middle Ages, 276. Rome. See City States, Ancient ; Empires, Heterogeneous. Sbrvius Tullius, 110. Slavs, prehistoric, 15. Solon, 85. Spain, under the Goths, 216 ; under the Moors, 221 ; Christian refugees in, 223 ; early Christian kingdoms in, 238 ; decline of the Moors in. 486 INDEX 266 ; kingdom of Castile and Leon, 266 ; its institutions, 267 ; kingly power, 295 ; Cortes, 296 ; union of kingdoms in, 359 ; despotic government in, 363. See also Nations, Unitary. Sparta. See Tribes. State, usage of the word, 468. States, provisional olassiiication of, 1-6 ; simple and composite, 2, 469; Table of States, 474. See also City States, Empires, Nations, Unions of communities, of equal communities, and of unequal communities. Sweden, united under Gustavus Vasa, 392 ; modern constitution of, 393, 398, 400 ; imperfect union of, with Norway, 454. Switzerland, ancient, cantons in, 254 ; history of, see Unions of equal communities made by voluntary consent (2). Tammany, 436. Transvaal, 46. Tribes, definition of, 16 ; tables of, 37, 64 ; modern uncivilised, 11 ; prehistoric Aryan, 13 ; ancient German, 13, 17-20, 32-36; Spartan tribe, 20-25, 40-46 ; Achsan tribes, 26-28; Anglo-Saxon, 28; tribes formed by coalescence, 39 ; aggressive, 40 ; slave-owning, 40- 48 ; federated, 49 ; in Asturia, 240 ; conclusions about tribes, 51 . Tyranni, 70. Uncivilised peoples, 8. Unions of communities effected by compulsion, 255, 453 ; unions of tribes, 39, 258 ; of small rural communities, 249, 265, 270 ; of modern states, 452, 453. Unions of equal communities made by voluntary consent, or Federal States, 419 ; general characteristics of, 420 ; Staaten- bund and Bundesstaat, 421. (1) Achaean League, 442. (2) Switzerland, mediaeval, 443 ; modem, 444 ; powers of Federal Government in, 446; legislature, 445 ; executive, 446 ; judi- cature, 446 ; the cantons, 254, 447 ; alterations in the law and the constitution, 448 ; Beferen- dum, 448 ; Popular Initiative, 448 ; steady tightening of the union, 449. (3) United Provinces of the Nether- lands mentioned, 419. (4) United States of America, in loose confederation, 422 ; in close federation, 423 ; powers of Federal Government in, 423 ; Legislature and Executive co- ordinate, 424, 427 ; President, 425 ; Congress, 426 ; Commit- tees, 428 ; Federal Judicature, 430 ; amendments of the con- stitution, 432 ; the States in the Union, 433 ; their govern- ments, 434 ; Tammany, 436 ; professional politicians, 439 ; debates not widely read, 440 ; steady tightening of the union, 441. Unions of unequal communities made by voluntary consent, 455 ; union of Scotland and England, 456 ; of Italian states, 456 ; of German states, 459 ; North German Federation, 459 ; German Empire, 460 ; its constitution, 461 ; chief organs of government, 462; lesser governing agencies, 463. United States of America. See Unions of equal communities (4). Venice. See City States, Medijeval.