iiii mmm. Ici Strata. Netn ^arlt ■'-'^■ The date shows when this volume was taken. „ ^ To renew this book copy the call »No. and give to f" the librarian. t ;.; HOME USE RULES 1 .2. '■ A I? if. *^ books subject to recall ■^ -^ A.11 borrowers must regis- ter in the library to borrow books for home use. All books must be re- turned at end of college i7 y "TSSil Fi X. ^^*' ^°^ inspection and ^ _ repairs. *aSit' y^imited books must be ' I 111 tiii'l '1' ' i^^l iferurned within the four week limit and not renewed. Students must return all books before leaving town. y"' Officers ^ould arrange for j^^ _ the return oj books wanted during their absence from , town. Volumes of periodicals ^••"" and of pamphlets are held in the library as much as '.*■' possible. For special pur- > poses they are given out for a limited time. Borrowers shpuld not use their library privileges for the benefit of'other persons. Books of special value - and gift books, when the ;„ giver wishes it, are not allowed to circulate. Readers are asked to re- port all cases of books marked or mutilated, A deface books by marks and writing. Cornell University Library HE 271.W44 Indians demand !{},[, ,|,HlBSHIl1m 3 1924 022 937 076 Cornell University Library The original of this book is in the Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924022937076 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION BY WILLIAM ERNEST WELD, M. A. SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN THE Faculty of Political Science Columbia University NEW YORK 1920 PVV^S'A v% Copyright, 1920 BY WILLIAM ERNEST WELD PREFACE Much is being written and spoken from public plat- forms in India, chiefly by Indian students of economics and politics, in favor of retrenchment in railway construc- tion. Some decry the breaking v)p of the village unit and the consequent destruction of the old domestic industries. Others feel that railways have made possible the exporta- tion of wheat and so have contributed to the rise in the prices of wheat in India. The more thoughtful of the con- servatives admit that railways have been a blessing to the country, but are of the opinion that the expenditure of funds for railways should be greatly decreased and the money turned into other channels; e. g., expended for edu- cation or irrigation, or to subsize other industries. The writer, during his residence of more than eight years in India, has often felt that many of those who oppose the expansion of the transportation system, have done so with- out a comprehensive understanding of the country's need. It was with this thought in mind, and at the suggestion of H. Stanley Jevons, University Professor of Economics at Allahabad, that this study was undertaken. The actual writing of the dissertation was not begun until the writer returned to America and entered Columbia University. He is greatly indebted to Prof. E. R. A. Selig- man for his encouragement and valuable suggestions during the entire course of the preparation of this study. He also desires to express his sincere thanks to Prof. H. R. Seager and to Prof. T. W. Van Metre for reading the manuscript and for helpful criticism. Mr. Charles W. Reid, of 42s] 5 6 PREFACE [426 the Highways Transport Committee o'f the Council of National Defense, has very kindly placed the files and the bulletins relating to motor transport in the United States at the writer's disposal. The help, both direct and indirect, which the writer has received from his wife is the cause of his greatest indebtedness. CONTENTS Introduction Need for extension of the means of transportation . . India's poverty and the possible causes . . Undeveloped resources of India . The backwardness of education ... The village as the economic unit and domestic industry Means of transport a prerequisite for industrial development PAGB 9 10 13 IS 18 CHAPTER I The Economics of Transportation Origin of the need for transportation . . 21 Elasticity of the demand for transportation ... 24 Effects of bulk and weight of goods upon demand for transport 28 Distance and the demand for transportation 31 Perishable commodities and the demand for transportation . . 34 The quantity demand for transportation 39 Demand for transportation of passengers 44 The elasticity of the demand for passenger transport 45 CHAPTER II Historical Sketch of the Means of Transportation in India Waterways ..... ... 53 Roads ... 58 Railways, 1843 to 1870; 1870 to 1880; 1880 to 1914 . . 62 CHAPTER III Some Effects of the Past Development of the Means of Transportation upon the Economic Life of the People of India The beginning of the dissolution of the village as the economic unit 80 The equalization of prices 86 Famine prices . 91 The beginning of large-scale production . . 96 427] 7 8 CONTENTS [428 PAGE CHAPTER IV India's Need for Transportation Poverty and the demand for transportation .... 100 Character of country's produce and the demand for transport . 103 Conditions on which India's quantity demand for transport depend 104 India's demand for passenger transportation 106 Lardner's Law of Squares no CHAPTER V Methods of Meeting India's Need for Transportation Provincial Departments of Transportation . 112 Motor transport for India 118 Summary of Conclusions 127 INTRODUCTION It is the writer's purpose, in the chapters which follow, to show India's need of more and better facilities for trans- portation. The problem will be regarded from the eco- nomic, rather than from the technical or the fiscal point of view. Methods of construction and maintenance of trans- portation facilities, public or private ownership of the same, rate- making and classification are subjects which will be consciously excluded. We are interested in what has hap- pened in the past, chiefly for the sake of the future. The advisability of the extension of the means of transporta- tion will be discussed, rather than the need of a different regulation of what the country already possesses. There are certain broad economic factors which affect the devel- opment of transportation facilities; and these, when de- veloped, exert a reflex influence upon the economic factors. It is our intention . to study these factors and influences, and their economic results. In dealing with the factors concerned in the economic life of India, the needs of the people will ever be kept in mind. The question is not whether railways will make a profit, but whether India can afford to be without them. The welfare of the people, rather than the dividends of this or that transportation company, must be our chief concern. But profits are not to be despised, for if the investors judge that a proposed railway can never pay a profit, they will refuse to supply the necessary capital. The Government of India might guarantee a certain rate of interest on the capital invested, as has been done so many times in the history of Indian railways, and so persuade the reluctant investor to supply the necessary funds. Or the Govem- 429] 9 lO INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [430 ment might build the railway, as it has sometimes done in the past, and either operate it or lease it to a company. But if the road is built and operated at a financial loss, the result upon the people is the same, whether a " guaranteed company" or the government builds it — the deficit will have to be paid from the public treasury, and the burden of taxation must be heavier. At first sight, we seem to have injured the very ones whom we hoped to help. But the burden in taxation is relative to the ability to pay. While the per capita taxation in India is very small in amount, the burden may be heavy. India's inability to pay is very great, so that no expenditure by Government seems justi- fied unless it decreases this inability to pay. The first public expenditures to be made should be those which would en- able the people to pay the increase in taxes and have the largest surplus, whether this be expressed in health, wealth or happiness. Every self-respecting government must ask itself this question : " What expenditures will be most beneficial to the people ?" No one who knows India would call the average Indian prosperous. So much has been written regarding the pov- erty of this country that the world is well persuaded of its reality. Careful investigations have been made and many statistics recorded ; but there is still much to be done in the study of family expenditures in the different classes — especially in the villages. Village conditions varj- with the quality of the soil of the surrounding country, the possibil- ities of irrigation, the extent to which the cultivators are in debt to the village money-lenders, and the means of trans- portation. If a study of village conditions is to have scien- tific value, the area of land and the number of families in- vestigated must be sufficiently great to render the conclusions reliable with reference to that particular locality or district. This kind of investigation requires effort on the part of a ^3i] INTRODUCTION II considerable number of people, all of whom have been previously trained as to what facts to look for and record. After the study has been made, the conclusions may be true for the area covered in the investigation, but may not be typical of the conditions in other parts of India. One of the studies made in recent years which seems to have been made with care, was that of an Indian Civil Service officer in Bengal, who feels that the results are fairly typical of conditions throughout India.^ If the estimate errs, it is probably on the side of optimism. One of the tables pre- pared by Mr. Jack and his staff is as follows : Family Income in Fakidpur (5 members in a family) Those living in Annual Income Dollars Comfort 49% of families Rs. 365 $122 Below comfort 28%, of families Rs. 233 $ 77 Above indigence 18^2%. of families iRs. 166 $ 55 Indigence 4^%, of families Rs. IIS $38 (Rs. is the abbreviation for rupees. Three rupees approximate one dollar) . Mr. Jack then turns to the question of family expenditures in Faridpur District.^ It is to be noted that the expendi- 1 Jack, J. C, The Economic Life of a Bengal Distrkt (Oxford, 1916), p. 81. ^ It is interesting to note how the two lists of expenditures bear out Engel's conclusions with reference to Saxony, published in 1857. He concluded that with increased incomes, there would be a smaller relative percentage of outlay for food; the percentage of expenditure for cloth- ing would remain about the same; the percentage for rent, lodging, and for fuel and light would remain the same; and that higher incomes would show a much greater percentage of outlay for sundries. The percentages given below are based on the total expenditures in the two lists : Percentages of total Percentages of total outlay for those in outlay for those in comfort extreme indigence Food 62 74 Clothing 10 10 Rent and Repairs 12 8 Sundries 16 8 The difference in rent percentage might be due to the inclusion bjc 12 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [432 tures in each class do not equal the entire income for the year. /Ions 0/ Expenditure Amount spent annually by Amount spent annually by tamily in comfort family in extreme indigence Fopd i s d £ s d Rice 800 400 Salt 28 2 Oil 8 o 4 Spices 5 o 2 o Fish 10 3 Pulses 10 3 Vegetables 4 ^ Milk and Butter 6 2 Other Necessities Betel nut 4 ' Kerosene oil 2 8 o 6 Tobacco and Molasses 5 o Clothes I 13 4 13 4 Household Utensils .... 3 o 2 o • Petty House Repairs ... 10 o 3 Rent 7 8 2 6 Local Taxation 2 o 6 Medical Expense 15 o 2 6 Furniture 10 o Thorough House Repairs 100 S Domestic Festivities and Entertainment 15 o 5 o Unaccounted for 7 11 8 16 8 TotaU 24 5 o 7 10 o From these tables one can form a fairly accurate concep- tion of the poverty of the people of India. This is not due, as might be supposed, to over-population. It is due in part to an uneconomic distribution of population. Many other explanations, however, have been given for the economic weakness of the country; namely, the benumbing force of Mr. Jack of the rent for the land cultivated by those living in the house. The difference in repairs to the house would account for a part of the divergence. The poor make their own repairs. 433] INTRODUCTION 1 3 caste, the lack of a universal language, the crime of hoard- ing, the debility of the people owing to the trying climate, the terrible ravages of plague, cholera and famine, the lack of " Permanent Settlement " of the land throughout India, the lack of a high protective tariff, the so-called " Drain " from India to England, the exportation of wheat from India, and the lack of universal and compulsory education. Each of these reasons has been offered by educated Indians at different times and places. There is no single solution of the problem of poverty in India. In its origin, the pros- perity of a nation depends upon its natural resources and upon man. That the natural resources of India are suffi- cient, if properly developed, to maintain the three hundred and twenty millions of people in as fair a measure of com- fort as is enjoyed by most of the peoples of Europe, is rarely if ever questioned. India's resources are great, but they are not developed. If it is true that the resources if India are not developed, we are driven one step farther back to find the cause of the nation's poverty. Both official and unofficial opinion admits two things: first, that the farmers and cultivators should benefit by the advances in modern methods of agriculture ; and secondly, that the country is greatly in need of other forms of industry besides agriculture. Two-thirds of the people are directly dependent upon the soil. Of the two needs mentioned above, it is our purpose to put especial stress on the second — the need of new industries which must be carried on along lines used in the factory produc- tion of the West. That such industrial development has not already occurred in India has been due to either a lack of desire or a lack of ability on the part of the Indians themselves to make the most of the natural resources of the country. It has been true in the past that the thoughts and the desires of the leaders of the people have not been along 14 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [434 industrial or commercial lines. Besides this fact, the ex- perience of the people for centuries taught them to respect an uncertain future, and men learned that the way to have wealth was to hide it. Foreign invasions, inter-state wars and civil strife led the people to take as little chance as possible in an uncertain future. In the large centers of trade this lack of confidence in the future is beginning to pass away, but it still lingers in the villages. The educated people realize, as never before, that factory production must come to India. The lack of desire to develop the resources is gone, but the lack of ability is still present. Much of the industrial capital that has been invested has been that of foreigners, and the industries have had foreign manage- ment. The factories that have been started by Indians with Indian capital and under Indian management have usually failed. Some of them have been reorganized and have failed the second time. There are some conspicuous ex- ceptions ^ but they are few in number. The underlying causes of the failures are evident: first, a lack of technical knowledge of the commodity produced and its methods of production; secondly, a lack of realization of the impor- tance of skilled and experienced foremen, and an unwill- ingness to pay a sufficient salary for such leadership in order to obtain and hold it. A secondary cause is the in- ability to compete in the open market with goods made abroad, chiefly in England, Germany, Java and Japan. 1 The most outstanding exception is that of the Tata Iron and Steel Co., Ltd., which was registered in August, 1907. It has had a splendid career. Before the corporation was launched, Rs. 550,000 was spent in investigation. The average number of employees for 1917 was 10,225, including both men and women. The annual report of the Company for the year ending June 30th, 1919 showed a net profit of Rs. 11,000,000. The causes of this phenomenal success seem to be: abundant supplies of iron ore and coal, the willingness to pay well for skilled management, a great demand for the output, and wise and careful management. The company voluntarily reduced the labor shifts from 12 to 8 hours. 435] INTRODUCTION 15 India imports goods from other countries in considerable quantities, but much of the total does not compete with goods made in India. The commodities, in the production and sale of which the country feels the effects of foreign competition most strongly, are cotton goods and cotton yam, silk, sugar, glassware, matches and small articles of hardware. Indigo would have to be included were we not considering more recent years. The decline of the natural indigo industry began with the putting of synthetic indigo on the market in 1897. This decline has been consistent until the outbreak of the War brought about at least a tem- porary revival of the industry. The most important im- ports are cotton goods and cotton yarn.^ These two items comprise 35.3% of the total imports. If sugar, most of which comes from Java, be included with the two just mentioned, then the percentage of the total for 1916-17 becomes 45.6%. The distressing fact, regarding these three most important of India's imports, is when viewed from the standpoint of natural resources, that India is well equipped to produce them all. Cotton grows readily in the country, and India was first in the field in production and exporta- tion of cotton goods in very early times. As for sugar, this country is the largest producer of sugar-cane in the world, yet the imports of manufactured sugar are increas- ing, and the indigenous production is barely holding its own. The explanation most frequently given for the nation's economic weakness is lack of education. Education is very necessary for India's progress. So far, all of the agencies of education, whether religious or governmental, have scarcely made more than a beginning. The reason why a system of education has not been developed which is com- mensurate with the need, is a much discussed point; and 1 Indian Year Book (Bombay, 1918), p. 269. 1 6 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [436 the Government of India has, on this account, received a considerable amount of blame, both in India and in Eng- land. To enter into the question of the allocation of re- sponsibility would take us too far afield, and besides, we are more concerned about the future than the past. The proposals for constitutional reform made jointly by the Secretary of State, the Right Hon. E. S. Montagu, M.P., and the present Viceroy of India, Lord Chelmsford, have not been welcomed by many of the Indian leaders, because they are considered to be much too moderate in the devolution of powers, and in the granting of home rule. The point of transference of authority is to begin with the Provincial Governments, and the devolution is to be pro- gressive. It is too early to draw conclusions as to the re- sults of this transference of authority, but in one particular we can be reasonably certain — there will be an expansion of the educational system. The Indian leaders are pledged to such enlargement of the present scheme as will make education within reach of the masses. In this the leaders will have the support of the entire educated community of India. The evidence of this can be found in the debates before the Viceroy's Council and in the discussions which preceded the presentation of the so-called Gokale Bill in 1 91 3 when feeling ran high among the educated classes. It will be a long, up-hill task to educate the masses in India, for the difficulties are fiscal, social and economic; but the effort should be and doubtless will be made in the near future. A number of writers and public speakers, in both Eng- land and India, appear to hold the opinion that universal elementary education would, of itself, solve the problem of India's economic weakness. This can not be taken for granted. The histories of the most advanced nations do not prove to us that economic strength has alwaj'^s waited 437] INTRODUCTION 17 on education; but rather that some degree of economic de- velopment has frequently led the way and pointed out the indisputable advantages of education. Might it not be as true to say that the lack of general education in China and India has been due to the fact that the peoples of these nations have not really grappled with the problems of de- veloping their natural resources, as to say that the resources have not been developed because of the lack of education ? Again, India's own experience in education has led many careful observers to question the proposition that the eco- nomic development of the country has been waiting for education. There are, in round nimibers, 8,000,000 stu- dents under instruction, including the boys and girls in both public and private institutions. Thirty years ago there were 3,340,000.^ During the last generation we have seen a gradual increase in the number of students in the schools, and we have had some opportunity to study the reaction of this training upon the economic life and the industrial de- velopment of the country. While the degree of expansion of the industrial life during these thirty years would be an uncertain measure of the effects of education upon indus- trial development, yet we have a more accurate way of judging; namely, by the number of students who enter occupations which bear directly on this important matter of developing the natural resources of the country. A well- known writer on Indian subjects says on this point : No native of India, educated solely in his own country, has yet produced any work of original merit in any of the subjects taught in our colleges, nor has our teaching brought forth fruit in the application of western science to Indian problems. Indian history and Indian archaeology have been enriched by few contributions from Indian students, and little has so far 1 Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 425. 1 8 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [438 been done by natives of the country to adapt and apply the ex- perience of the west to the development of the material re- sources of India.^ While that part of the above statement relating to the con- tributions to general knowledge by Indian students, should be called in question, yet the latter reference to the lack of contributions made by the college graduates towards the development of the material resources of the country is all too true. The majority of the graduates go either into the legal profession or into Government offices, both of which vocations are filled to overflowing. Only a few of those trained in school and college return to the soil, and the majority of those who do, are landowners. Very few go into business, whether in the form of manufacture or of trade. Our conclusion must be, therefore, that the development of the resources should at least keep pace with the growth of the educational system. There is an interaction of forces between educational and material progress, each assisting the other. To understand India the western mind must realize that village economy still lingers there. Small entering wedges have been driven which tend to break up the village as an economic unit, but the dissolution has not yet taken place. The situation is not unlike that which obtained in Europe under the domestic system of production. There is this difference, however, that in India, agriculture is the main industry. The time was when India possessed considerable domestic industry in the form of cotton weaving, but for- eign competition has practically put an end to it. Even re- mote villages have been entered by foreign cotton goods. 1 Strachey, Sir John, India, its Administration and Progress (London, 1911), p. 281. 439] INTRODUCTION 19 The factory-made gocxis of England are both smoother and cheaper than those produced in India by the remnant of the domestic system/ That these industries which formerly flourished in the homes have disappeared, is a real grief to many of the friends of India. There has been an effort on the part of such well-known and popular leaders as Mr. Ghandi and Mr. Polak to revive them. While their intentions are ex- cellent, their efforts are worse than futile. India cannot contend against the inevitable. She must take her place, as Japan has done, in the ranks of organized production. Even if the Swadeshi Movement should succeed in binding a large part of the people together into a consumers' monop- oly for Indian goods, yet domestic industry would not live.* There are already 266 mills for the weaving of cotton goods in India, which number is an increase of 49 over the number of ten years ago. There will be many more in the future, and sooner or later factory production in India will drive domestic production out of the field. In short, it will not be a case of the domestic system competing against for- eign goods, but the domestic system against the factory system. The village, while still remaining a unit in production and in most of its consumption, now imports foreign cloth and to a less extent, sugar. These commodities, as well as others, must be paid for by the hard-earned fruits of the 1 " The essence of the domestic system consists in the fact that while the workman still owns his own tools and conducts the work in his own home, often with the aid of his family and in connection with some agricultural activity, he no longer disposes of the finished product." Seligman, E. R, A., Principles of Economics (New York, 1916), p. 93. ' The 'Swadeshi Movement is supported by Indians who are particu- larly zealous for India's industrial progress. One feature of the move- ment is that its members refuse to buy any other goods than those produced in India. 20 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [440 soil. If all the land were wonderfully fertile, and the mon- soon rains absolutely dependable, then it might be advan- tageous for India to give its entire attention to agriculture and to import other commodities from abroad. But this is not the case. Modern methods of agriculture and irriga- tion will help to strengthen India's economic weakness, but modern industries are necessary to furnish a balanced eco- nomic life.^ A portion of the vast population can be spared from agriculture to develop the industrial life of the nation. There is one prerequisite for the extensive development of the material resources of India ; namely, adequate trans- portation facilities. History shows us a double possibility as to the relation existing between means of transportation and industries: sometimes the industries may be said to have created the means of transport, as in the early history of railways in England; it is more common to find that facilities of transportation have made industries possible, as was the case in the development of the western part of the United States. If industries are to bring railways into existence, they must be fairly well developed and managed by wise and experienced men who are able to control large amounts of capital. This is not the situation in India, where industrial development is stunted, and captains of industry few, and capital very timid in showing itself. So, means of transportation must precede industrial development if the country is to take its place among the progressive na- tions. Something has been done, but much more needs to be done. The necessity of adequate means of transporta- tion for industrial development appears, whether the ques- tion be attacked from the point of view of economic theory or from that of practical life. Both of these points of view will be discussed in the following chapters. ' Cf. Fairbairn, Henry, The Political Economy of Railroads (London, 1836), p. 106, et seq. CHAPTER I The Economics of Transportation Transportation may be defined as the carrying of per- sons or goods from one place to another for the sake of a material reward. Transportation has come into existence as a means of partially overcoming the limitation of man due to the distance between localities. The economist is in- terested in the overcoming of distance for gain. This gain may be either direct or indirect. Direct gain will be in the form of profits to the owners of the means of transporta- tion. Indirect gain is realized by those who use the means of conveyance, either for the shipping of goods or for the conveyance of themselves or their agents. If direct gain is impossible, then the means of transportation must be built by governments or public-spirited individuals, in order to obtain the indirect gains. There should be, in the course of time, a reflex action from indirect gains toward direct gains. The need for transportation has arisen from the unequal distribution of the natural resources of the earth. Because of this unequal distribution of natural resources, the com- modities produced in dififerent localities differ in kind, qual- ity and quantity. This unequal distribution is expressed in different physical characteristics : the difference in the phys- ical and chemical qualities of the soil and sub-soil, the dif- ferences in climate, the differences in elevation and the differences in the location and character of the water supply. These four physical characteristics are to some extent mutually related to one another, but taken together they are the natural causes of the differences in kind, quality 441] 21 22 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [442 and quantity of the goods produced in different localities. Then when man is taken into account, with his differences in intelligence, training, tastes and skill, the diversity of the production of different localities becomes still more pro- nounced. This inequality of the apportionment of material re- sources to different localities has had a great influence upon the distribution of population. The primary force which first led men to settle in different localities was the search for material goods with which to supply their physical wants. In the early stages of man's history, it was more usual for him to go to the things which supplied his wants, than it was for him to have the commodities brought to him. When man reached the more stationary stage, and began to till the soil, he naturally selected the locality where the natural resources were most abundant. In his weak- ness, he needed all the assistance from Nature that he could obtain. Later, many other things entered into his choice of a home : the desire for religious or political freedom, the attraction of a settled commimity, love of family, and other considerations. But of the various influences affect- ing the distribution of population, the economic one is the most important, if long periods of time be considered. The share of the individual is dependent upon the ratio ex- isting between natural resources and the number of people who share in them. When the individual share becomes small, we see some shifting of the population. The final development which affects the location of men and so reacts upon the demand for transportation is the use of capital in production. It is true that a certain degree of development of transport must already have taken place or modem capitalistic production could not have been brought about. But given this amount, the demand for transpor- tation is greatly increased by the investment of capital. 443] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 23 If the need for transportation depended solely upon the unequal distribution of the world's natural resources with the resulting distribution of population, the demand for transportation would be much easier to satisfy than it actu- ally is. Capital invested in factories and transportation facilities has led to a localization of population and mate- rials at certain centers, which are frequently near the nat- ural resources or motive power required.^ Facilities of transportation were required to make this degree of local- ization possible; and further means of transport will be re- quired to maintain the development of the industries. But there is a strong tendency to localize certain industries at points of artificial rather than geographical advantage be- cause the former are becoming more important than the latter. .As far as the costs of transportation are concerned, the choosing of a place of artificial advantage is attended by certain savings in one direction and certain increased expenditures in another.^ If the factory is built in prox- imity to the source of the most necessary raw material, the other materials of production have to be conveyed to this place of more or less accessibility, and the finished product has to be shipped from this place to the distributing cen- ters. On the other hajid, if the factory is located in a large industrial center there will be an increase in the cost of transportation of the chief raw material, which may, however, be ofifset by savings in the costs of transportation of the other materials of production. But the important '^ This localization of industry is due in part to other accruing ad'- vantages, in which transportation plays only an incidental part. These other advantages will not be discussed here. Vide, Ely, Outlines of Economics, 3rd ed. (New York, 1917), pp. 128-129. 2 Vide TrafHc Geography, Ketchum, E. 'S. editor (Chicago, 1915), Introduction, p. 3. An explanation is here given of the reasons why Gary, Indiana was chosen as the center of the U. S. iSteel Corporation. 24 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [444 reduction in most cases, is found in the transportation costs of marketing the finished product. The comparative costs of conveying the raw material and the finished commodity- will play an important part in deciding whether an artificial or a natural location is to be chosen. THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION Transportation may be divided according to the objects to be carried, into two classes : freight and passenger trans- portation. Passenger traffic may again be divided into those who travel from an economic motive and those who travel for some other reason. The transportation of goods will first be discussed, with special reference to the elasticity of demand for their transportation. The cost of a finished commodity may include : ( i ) the price paid to the producer, at the place of production; (2) the cost of conveying the article from one place to another.^ The latter includes not only the price paid for actually con- veying the article but also the interest on the money paid to the producer as the price of the commodity, such interest being proportionate to the length of time elapsing before the commodity is delivered to the consumer. To this must be added the insurance charges against loss or damage dur- ing transport. It does not follow that these charges are always paid by the consumer. Transportation, therefore, is as much a feature of production as agriculture or manu- facturing; and in the long run, the demand for commod- ities will determine the demand for transportation facilities. THE DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION OF GOODS The subject of the elasticity of demand for transporta- tion with reference to its relationship to the elasticity of demand for goods may be approached from either of two 1 Vide Lardner, D., Railway Economy (New York, 1850), p. 30, et seq^ 445] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 25 sides: the effects upon the demand for transportation of changes in the prices of commodities not due to trans- portation costs; and the influence of increases or de- creases in transportation rates upon the demand for com- modities. The elasticity of demand for goods is gov- erned by certain well-known principles: luxuries have a more elastic demand than necessities; novelties have a higher degree of elasticity than the things we are accus- tomed to enjoy, especially if the use of the latter has be- come habitual; the demand of poor people has a greater elasticity than the demand of the rich; and when there are substitutes for a commodity, the elasticity of the demand for it is increased. As transportation is one of the factors in the cost of production, it follows that if the price of a commodity increases and the amount demanded decreases, the demand for transportation will also decrease. So the demand for transportation is indirectly subject to all the different influences mentioned above, which affect the elas- ticity of the demand for commodities. This reaction will not make itself felt at once with all commodities. In short periods of time, if there should be an increase in the amount of a commodity demanded, because of a decrease in the price, the effect upon the demand for transportation would depend upon the amount and the location of existing stocks, and the extent to which the existing factors of production could be made to increase their output without delay. In longer periods of time, if the increase of demand remained constant, sufHcient time would have to elapse to allow new forces of production to make their contribution to the supply, before the full demand for transportation facilities would be felt.^ When we approach the subject of the elasticity of de- ^Vide Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics (London, 1916), p. 374, et seq. 26 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [446 mand for transportation from the other side, viz., the result of an increase in the rate for carrying commodities upon the demand for the commodities themselves, the situation is more complicated. An increase in the rate or cost of transportation will mean an added expense in production, which will tend to raise the price at which the good is offered to the consumer. All that has been indicated above as to the elasticity of demand for commodities will apply here. If the demand measured in the amount of the com- modity decreases, there will eventually be a proportionate decrease in the demand for transportation. The effect of an increase in the rate of transportation upon the final price of the commodity will depend upon how important a part transportation plays in the produc- tion of the commodity.^ A great diversity appears when various commodities are examined to discover the part transportation has played in their production. In some cases the entire value of the commodity to the consumer is due to transportation; as in the case of sea-weed cast up on the shore by the tides, and from there hauled to a nearby farm to be used as fertilizer. Again, the value of material in its original place may be a minus quantity; that is, the commodity may be a nuisance, and after being transported may be sold to the consumer for less or more than the cost of the transportation. This is common in large cities where the city refuse is sold for fertilizer.^ But to turn to the more important situations of economic life, we find modem industry so highly complex and specialized that produc- tion is carried on in separate units of production, each of which makes its contribution towards bringing the mate- rials into a finished state. The means of transport form ^Vide Knoop, Douglas, Outlines of Railway Economics (London, 1913), p. 18. "Lardner, D., op. cit., p. 29, footnote. 447] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 27 the connecting links between them. To obtain that part of the final cost price of a given commodity which is due to transportation, we must estimate the total cost of convey- ing the goods from unit to unit, and from the final unit to the consumer. If this were the only contribution made by transportation to the cost of production, the estimate could be made of that pirt of the cost which is due to transpor- tation charges, even though the finished commodity con- tained a number of different materials. But to know the complete part played by transportation, we are compelled to measure the contribution made by transportation within each unit or factory. Here we are not only concerned with the actual materials that go into the finished commodity, but with the part played by transportation in assisting both capital and labor. Each machine in each factory along the line of progress of a particular good, from the point of origin to the point of consumption, has its own line of de- velopment, with units of production located on it, in which transportation has played its part in making the use of capital possible, and in bringing labor to the place where work is to be done. It has been noted that the demand for transportation tends to fluctuate with the varying demands for commod- ities at varying prices. It has also been pointed out that a change in the rate charged for transporting goods will tend to cause a change in the final demand for transportation in accordance with two factors : ( i ) the extent to which transportation plays a part in their production; and (2) the elasticity of demand for the goods concerned. To con- tinue the analysis, it should be known what elements are inherent in the transporting of goods which make the con- veyance charges an important part of the cost of produc- tion. Three of these elements are : the ratio existing be- tween bulk and value, the distance goods are carried, either 28 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [448 in their finished or unfinished state, and the importance of the time element as seen in the case of perishable commod- ities.^ In examining these elements, the intention is to keep the subject of the demand for transportation in the foreground as much as possible. However, there is no such thing as economic demand independent of a price, and there is no such thing as elasticity of demand independent of varying prices. As changes in the rates of transportation influence the cost of production of commodities, and so affect the prices at which they are put on the market, the result is that the demand for the commodities as well as for transportation is affected. Therefore, it is necessary to understand these factors which play an important part in determining what portion of the cost of production is due to transportation charges." THE EFFECTS OF BULK AND WEIGHT UPON THE DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION If transportation is required in the giving of form, time or place utility to commodities whose bulk or weight ' is great, in proportion to value, the cost of the transportation ^ To these three factors a fourth might be added : the increased charge made by railways for articles of high value. The charge is quite independent of the bulk of the goods, and is independent of the actual cost to the road of carrying the particular goods. It is levied according to " what the traffic will bear," but is supposed to react favor- ably upon other rates. The extent to which it does so react, is im- portant to the economist as well as to the maker of rates. However, for this study, it is not of great economic significance. 2 Rate-making and differential charges are not our chief interest here. We are willing to take the rates and their changes for granted in order to focus the attention upon the effects of higher and lower rates upon the demand for transportation'. ' The two characteristics of freight, i. e., bulk and weight, might well be treated separately, but the use made of the conclusions permits treat- ing them together. They affect the cost of transport in a similar way. 449] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 29 is likely to be an important part of the cost of the com- modity. This is intensified when " distances are great." Even though " exceptional rates " are made to favor this kind of goods, yet it remains true that the cost of convey- ing the goods will be an important part of the total costs.^ Quarried stone, gravel, lime, slate, iron ore, coal, lumber and many forms of agricultural produce are examples of commodities, the price of which may be much greater at the place where the goods are to be used, than at the place of origin. Much of this difference in price can usually be attributed to the costs of transportation. The effect of reducing the cost of transportation by in- troducing more effective means, or of lowering the rate on existing means of transport for commodities whose bulk or weight is great in comparison to value, may be consid- ered in either one of two possible ways: the lowering of the price in the market of those goods which would have been transported, if the cost of conveyance had not been decreased ; and the shipping to a new market of those com- modities which could not have been shipped with profit, if the rate had not been reduced.^ In the first case, the goods would have been shipped even if the rate had not been lowered; so there will be under competitive conditions a reduction in price of the goods equal to the reduction in the rate or the cost of transporta- tion. This reduction in price will bring about an increase ' In this connection, it is necessary to distinguish between the original forms in which the material of a commodity exists, and the later forms. When the process of production continues in a series, it may be the case that other factors besides transportation are the chief determinants of value; e. g., transportation is an important element in the value of steSl rails, while it has much less importance in determining the value of watch-springs. " Vide Colson, C, Railway Rates and TraMc, translated from 3rd ed. (London, 1914), p. i49- 30 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [450 in the amount of the commodities demanded and so affect the demand for transportation. The increase in the amount of goods which markets are wiUing to buy at the lower price will depend upon the elasticity of demand for the commodities; and the demand for transport will be also, in the long run, proportionately increased. So with respect to the transportation of heavy or bulky commodities, the economic forces operate in the same general way as upon other goods, the difference being one of degree. As trans- portation costs are such an important factor in the costs of bulky or heavy goods, it is evident that any substantial decrease in the costs of conveying them would result in a greater reduction in price than would be the case with goods whose bulk is relatively less. Therefore, if two com- modities have equal value and equal elasticity of demand, but the value of one is in compact form and the other is not, a general reduction in the cost of transportation should create a much greater increase in demand for transport of the bulky commodity than for the transportation of the other. In the second instance, the demand for transportation of goods which would not have been consigned if the costs had not been lowered, is a net increase in the total demand for transport. The extent of the increase in the demand for transportation will depend upon the demand for the commodities at the price at which they can be put upon the market.^ This price, in the case of great bulk to low value, will materially depend upon the extent of the reduction in the rate of transportation. In case of future reductions in the costs of transporting goods, we will have the same cycle of causes and effects as outlined in the paragraph above. The part that has been played in the industrial develop- 1 We are presupposing a sufficient supply to meet the demand at this price. 45 1 J THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 31 ment of nations, by such reductions in the cost of trans- portation, has been very great. There are two outstanding reasons for this fact : the reductions in cost have been great, because the modern means of transport are so much more efficient than the more primitive ones ; ^ also, the closer to its original source a good may be, the more likely is its bulk or weight to be great in proportion to its value. Primitive people do not extensively apply capital and labor to the product of the mine and soil, and so add value to the original material. The result is that a large part of the production of undeveloped nations is likely to be bulky in ratio to its value. Yet we have seen above that it is this kind of goods which is most afifected by reductions in the cost of transportation. As such commodities are the very basis of industrial development, and cannot be evenly dis- tributed over the country, their conveyance becomes the absolute prerequisite for such development. DISTANCE AND THE DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION The varying distances which goods must be carried affect the market prices of commodities and so cause a reaction upon the demand for transportation. This subject is not to be considered independently of the previous one; viz., bulk or weight in ratio to the value of the goods ; but the former is coordinate with the latter as one of the variable factors which influence the demand for goods, and in- directly, the demand for transportation. We have seen at the beginning of this chapter that the goal or object of transportation is to overcome the limita- tions due to distance, which have come into existence be- cause of the unequal distribution of the natural resources of the earth, and have been intensified by the inequalities 1 Vide Kirkaldy, A. W. and Evans, A. iD., History and Economics of Transport (London, 1915), p. 3. 32 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [452 of the distribution of population and capitalistic invest- ment. In no industry has science made greater advances than in those which seek to overcome distance, whether on land, on the sea or in the air. Yet it is still the case in transportation, that additional distance means increased ex- pense,^ although usually the increased expense is not in proportion to the distance. Even though the charge per ton-mile for long hauls may decrease with the increase in the distance, yet where the commodity is at all bulky (in proportion to value) , transportation costs usually constitute a considerable part of the costs of the commodity. A decrease in the cost of transportation over long dis- tances, whether by the introduction of better facilities, or by lowering the rate of existing means of transport, will have the same effect as in the case of bulky or heavy goods: under competition, the degree to which the price of the goods will be lowered will depend upon the amount of the reduction in transportation rates and the importance of transportation in the production of the goods. The greater the part played by transportation in determining the price of the commodity in any market, the greater the effect the reduction in transportation costs will have in lowering the price of the commodity.^ The more the price is lowered ^ The application of the '" postal principle " is, of course, an ex- ception to the general statement made above. Where the " zone sys- tem " is used, another* exception might be pointed out within the zones. Sometimes under competition the long way does not mean a more expensive way. But these are exceptions which could never become the rule. Vide Kirkaldy and Evans, op. cit., pp. 124, 125 ; also Colson, C, op. cit., p. igo, et seq. ' To take a purely hypothetical illustration where distance counts ; if a pair of shoes, made according to the modern machine system of pro- duction and territorial division of labor, cost in the market, $10, and 50% of this cost is due to transportation charges on the hides from Argentina, and domestic shipping charges, then a 10% reduction in the transportation charges would result in lowering the price of shoes to 453] ^-^-^ ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 33 the greater is the quantity demanded. The increased de- mand for transportation will depend upon the degree of response on the part of the consumers to this decrease in the price of the commodity, whether it be great or small. The diminution of the cost of transportation and the consequent reaction, through the demand for goods, upon the demand for more transportation, will have certain €ffects upon the intensity and extensity of the market for the goods concerned. It may cause an increase in the dis- tance which the goods are carried, or an increase in the quantity of goods carried for a certain distance, or both.^ If the reduction in the cost of transportation be consider- able, the market for those goods in the production of which transportation is an important factor and the demand for which has some degree of elasticity, will be extended over a wider area. An extreme example of the lowering of costs of conveying goods would be the substitution of a railway for an ordinary dirt road and animal-drawn carts or wagons. The goods will then flow from the places of origin to the places of greatest demand along the railway. The distance to which the market will be extended will be dependent upon what the consumers are willing to pay, in- cluding transportation charges, to become possessors of the goods. If the new line of railway, in the illustration above, is built through a country in which the means of transport are limited to the new line, then the market will be ex- tended by the length of the line, provided the cost of trans- portation and the costs of production are not prohibitive. $9.50. But under the old system where hides were produced at home and tanned locally and made up by the village shoe-maker, the trans- portation costs might be only $%. of the total costs. In this case, a 10% reduction in transportation costs of a pair of shoes selling for $10 would lower the market price to $9.95. ' Lardner, D., op. cit., p. 254. 34 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [454 If the reverse is true, and the country through which the railway runs is closely filled with effective " feeders " and spur lines, then the market will not be extended in the simple ratio of the new radius of the railway but in the ratio of its square.^ Therefore, no country has really pro- vided itself with sufficient means of transport which has limited its operations to the building of trunk-lines. PERISHABLE COMMODITIES AND THE DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION The distinguishing characteristic of goods of this class is that the time element is predominant. Because of this fact, the demand for transportation in general, and speedy transportation in particular, is very great. Of the four requirements for effective transport, i. e., cheapness, speed, regularity and safety, the first three apply in a special way to the need of conveyance for perishable goods. The chief classes of goods of this sort are fruit, vegetables, milk,, eggs, meat and fish. The need for cheap transportation is due to the fact that most of the articles are necessities.^ 1 Let us conceive of a section of trunk-line connecting two terminals, which are 90 miles apart. This section is ideally equipped with " feed- ers," running at right angles to the main line and furnishing transpor- tation facilities, at the same rate as the main line, to all the surrounding country. At one of the terminals, a commodity is produced, to obtain which the consumers are willing to pay the original costs plus 90 miles of transportation, but no more. The market for the goods would then assume the form of a triangle, bisected by the main line, with the base of 180 miles at the terminal where the commodity is produced, and the apex at the other terminal. The area of the triangle would be equal to the length of the section of trunkline squared. Cf. Roscher, W., System der Volkswirthschaft (Stuttgart, 1887), vol. iii, p. 374; also Marshall, Alfred, Industry and Trade (London, 1919), p. 27. * The reasoning here is the same as in the case of taxation. ' Modem governments do not tax necessities. A high rate for transportation of necessities would have the same effect upon the poor, as that of the old English " tolls " on conveyances. 455] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 35 Regularity is required by both producer and consumer, for the former will not produce a surplus of milk, eggs and vegetables unless he is reasonably sure of a regular market. The consumer needs these articles as daily food. Speed is the outstanding requirement for long hauls, and this has been only partially reduced by the modem methods of cold-storage, canneries and refrigerator cars. The addi- tional expense to the transporter of such goods arises from the necessity of giving the right of way to them, coupled with the inability to combine such commodities in a train- load with goods which are to be hauled more slowly. This additional expense may be due to the use of special cars. The speed factor seems to have been neglected until re- cently in the analysis of operative costs, at least in the United States.^ Approaching the subject of the demand for transporta- tion from the side of the producer of perishable goods, we find him laboring under a double difficulty. Firstly, he is not able to accept slower substitutes for rapid transit if the cost of the latter is very great. If he is unable to procure cheap, rapid and more or less regular transportation for his surplus produce of perishable goods and is unable to find a local use or market for it, his loss is immediate and total. He is limited in his choice of the means of trans- portation. Secondly, he is not able to bargain effectively with the agents of transportation because of the perishable quality of his goods. This is due to the fact that the prices of such goods are, at any one time, more influenced by the demand than by the cost of production. If the packing and shipping charges, and the commissions of the whole- ' Vide Cunningham, W. J., The Accomplishment of the U. S. Railroad Administration in Unifying and Standardizing the Statistics of Operation, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social iScience (Philadelphia, November, 1919), p. 46, et seq. Mr. Cunningham here treats of the time element in operating statistics. 36 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [456 saler and retailer should be greater than the price the con- sumer will pay for definite quantities, then the producer will not ship his goods ; for the difference between the sell- ing price and the marketing costs would only increase his loss on the costs of production. But if the marketing ex- penses fall slightly below the price at which the goods can be sold, then the producer will ship the goods in order to reduce, as much as possible, his loss on production costs. Because the producer is not able to play the future off against the present, the demand for transportation for per- ishable goods is more insistent and less elastic than for other goods.* The consumer's demand for the goods under discussion, in so far as they are necessities, tends to be inelastic. But as the most imperative needs of the individual are met, his demand for more of any commodity acquires a greater degree of elasticity. The upper reaches of the demand- curves for milk, eggs, vegetables and some meats are likely to be steep, while they tend to flatten in their lower extent. Having purchased some, the buyer questions the advisabil- ity of purchasing more at the existing price. In advanced countries, substitution is so commonly practised in the case of f oodstuflfs that only in one or two instances can the demand said to be highly inelastic. While realizing that the elasticity of demand for perishable commodities differs with the different kinds of goods, and with the wealth of the consumers, yet it can be said that the amounts demanded of them all do change considerably with variations in price. As the demand for transportation is dependent upon the quantities of the goods demanded at different prices, the effect of the lowering of the costs of transportation upon the demand for conveyance would in turn depend upon the importance of conveyance charges in determining the mar- - Vide Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics, pp. 348-349. 457] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 37 ket prices of the perishable goods. What would be true in the United States, as to the importance of transportation charges in influencing final prices, would apply with even more effect in the majority of other countries.^ But it is unsafe to make any general statements regarding the trans- portation costs of different goods. Each commodity must be examined by itself. However, some idea of such costs may be gained from the study made by some Harvard University students, under the direction of Prof. Carver." The table compiled by them has been adapted to the point tmder discussion: the part played by transportation in in- fluencing final prices (see next page). The only conclusion which can be safely drawn from such scanty data is that there is a wide variation in the part played by transportatioii in determining the market prices of goods. Even when the goods are of a less perishable character, as in the case of apples and potatoes, the differetlce between the costs of the long and short hauls is very evident. The percentage of the price paid by the consumers of Georgia strawberries, due to transportation, is doubtless caused both by the perish- able character of the goods and the distance between Georgia and Boston which intensifies the danger of deterioration. 1 The Interstate Commerce Commission's figures for the comparative rates of different countries a,re quoted by Prof. T. N. Carver in his Readings in Rural Economics (Nevir York, 1916), p. 715. The average rates per ton mile therein quoted are as follows : Great Britain (in cents) 3.2, France, 2.2, Germany, 1.64, and U. iS. .866. The ton-mile rate for all of India, including the narrovir gauge, for 1915-16 was only .75. Vide Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 243. ' Selections have been made from the list of perishable goods. In other cases the figures could not be used because of inability to dis- tinguish between commissions of the middlemen and railway charges. In estimating the percentage of the total cost to the consumer due to conveyance charges in the case of milk, the cost of delivery to the doors of the consumers was included. For the complete list, Vi4e Cari^er, op. cit., p. 330, et seq. 38 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [458 Percentage Product Where produced Where consumed Price received by producer Price paid by consumer The differ- ence of Consumer's Price due to Trans- portation Apples . Marlboro, Mass. . . Boston . . $2.25 (bbl.) $7-50 $5-25 4.6% Apples . Wenatchee Valley.Wash. Chicago. . $i.4S (bbl.) $8.00 $6.55 7-6% Milk . . Montgomery Co., Pa . Phila. . ■03t (qt.) .08 •04I- 31-3%' Milk . . Worcester, Mass. . . Boston . . ■02f (qt.) .08 ■ osi 31-3% Potatoes. Aroostook Co., Me. . Cambridge, Mass. .50 (bu.) .90 .40 17.2% Potatoes. Mass. . . . Cambridge, Dressed Mass. . .55 (bu.) .go •35 S-5% turkeys. Northern New York. Boston .25 (lb.) •38 ■13 2.6% Straw- berries. Georgia . . Boston . . .08-. 14 (box) •IS-- 25 .07-.11 44-4^ poultry. Eastern Mass. . . Boston . . ■19I (lb.) ■33 (lb.) •i3f 14-4%' If in America, transportation charges form such an im- portant part of the difference between what the producer receives and what the consumer pays for perishable goods, the need of reducing the costs of transport in the Orient is very much greater, for three reasons : in the first place, the eastern coimtries have not the close reticulation of efficient means of transportation, such as England and America possess; again, the bulk of the product of oriental coun- tries is agricultural, and much of this product is perishable goods; also, the heat of the climate causes the danger of deterioration of perishable goods to be much greater than in western countries. ' Two cents per quart are charged for delivery. ^ " shipping and selling commissions '' are put together at .04^. Of the balance .09, the wholesaler received .04 and the retailer .05. 459] ♦ "^HE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 39 We have seen in this study of the elasticity of the de- mand for transportation how the amounts demanded of a commodity vary with prices and so react upon the demand for transportation. Whatever lowers the cost of produc- tion and decreases the price will tend to stimulate the de- mand for transportation according to the degree of elas- ticity of the demand for the commodity. But more specifi- cally, the lowering of the cost of transportation of such a commodity will, by decreasing the cost of production, tend to stimulate the demand for transport in proportion to the part played by transportation in the production of the com- modity. The importance of the service rendered by the means of conveyance varies with bulk, distance, and time elements. But the quantity of goods which is affected by the de- crease in the cost of conveying them may not be suflficiently great to justify the building of new and better means of transport. To use figurative language, so far we have discussed the effect of raising or lowering the flood-gate of price upon the rapidity of the flow of goods above the gate ; we have not discussed the size of the stream. Under what conditions will the demand for transportation be large enough (as well as elastic enough) to justify the invest- ment of large sums of money in modern facilities for transportation? This is the next problem to 'be discussed. THE QUANTITY DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION By assuming a locality so small that the demand for transportation within itself can be accotmted unimportant, we can then say, the quantity demand for freight transpor- tation of any locaHty is dependent upon the total demand of the locality for the production of all other localities, together with the total demand of all other localities for the production of the one. If the bounds of the locality be 40 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [460 extended, assuming the non-existence of any trade barriers, a part of that which was external becomes internal trans- portaton, but the total demand for transportation remains unchanged. According to the teaching of the Classical School of Eco- nomics, the value of the goods which are produced within the locality and shipped abroad is equal to the value of the goods which are brought into the locality.^ But there is no such equality in the demand for transportation, as the elements of bulk, distance and time make it impossible. The total demand of any commimity for the production of the others from which it receives goods, and hence for their transportation, will vary with some broad general characteristics. Firstly, it varies with the number and the density of the population. The larger the population and the more com- pact it may be, the more will distance become a factor in supplying the wants of the people.^ This is due in part to the fact that the pressure of population upon the natural resources is soon felt, especially for food supplies, and people are driven further afield to find adequate sustenance.* Secondly, the intensity and variety of human wants is a very important factor in determining the quantity of the demand for transportation. The demand for goods outside the locality may be either for the purpose of consumption or of production. The simplicity of the wants of oriental peoples has frequently been offered as the chief reason for the backwardness of their industrial life. In this instance, the idea of consumption is in mind. It is believed that the *Mill, J. S., Principles of Political Economy (New York, igo6), vol. ii, p. 149. 'Roscher, Wilhelm, op. cit., pp. 356, 357. » Cf. Cooley, C H., Publications of Amer. Economic Association, vol. ix, The Theory of Transportation, p. 73. 461] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 41 per capita production is small because the level of wants is low. It is also true that the standard of wants is low, be- cause of a small per capita production. Of the two, the second is the more important. The best possible way to increase the wants of men is to give them a surplus. Trans- portation plays an important part in increasing the surplus of the consumer by giving him access to special markets for buying certain goods ^ as well as by allowing him to sell his goods in a wider market. The effect of education upon human wants is twofold : it increases the variety of human wants and so stimulates production; it also increases the efficiency of production and so makes possible the satisfaction of the increased number of wants. The quantity of the demand for trans- portation is likely to be affected in both cases, for the ' greater the variety of human wants, the further afield will men be compelled to go to satisfy them ; and the greater the surplus produced, the greater the quantity demand for transportation, in order to market this surplus to the best advantage. Thirdly, the quantity demand for transportation varies with the extent to which the locality has learned to prac- tise division of labor in production. If territorial division of labor is in force, so that the locality gives itself to the production of the goods for which it is best equipped be- cause of the possession of raw materials, motive power, 1 " Die ' verkehrschaffende ' Wirkung aller zweckmassigen Transport- verbesserungen beruhet darauf, dass sie durch bessern Rapport zwischen Bediirfniss und Befriedigungsmittel sowohl den Gebrauchswerth, als den Tauschwerth des Volksvermogens erhohen. Wenn ^.. B. abgelegene Walder, Steinbruche u. s. w., die bis dahin gar keinen prasenten Werth batten, durch Anlage eines Kanals, einer Eisenbahn, in ihrer Nahe sofort sehr werthvoll werden, so braucht darum nichts anderes an Werth zu verlieren, sofern eben neue, bisher schlummernde Bediirfnisse erst durch diese Befriedigungsmoglichkeit geweckt worden sind." Roscher, W., op. cit., vol. iii, pp. 373-74. 42 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [462 efficient supply of labor, and markets close at hand, the de- mand for transportation is greatly increased. In fact, terri- torial division of labor without the means of transport can- not come into existence. Because a locality gives itself to the production of those commodities which it can best produce, it is dependent upon other localities for the other goods which it requires, whether they be for the purpose of consumption or of production. This is the source of the first increase of demand for transportation, which is due to territorial division of labor : the greater the localiza- tion of industry, the greater the demand for transportation to convey other commodities which the consumers in the community of the localized industry demand. The second cause of an increased demand for transportation is that the goods whose production is so localized will have to be shipped a greater distance than when their production was scattered over the country. Territorial division of labor has increased production; and the size of the national dividend has been still further enlarged by the application of industrial and technical divi- sion of labor, machine production and trained management ; so the per capita surplus is greater than before modem methods of production were introduced. A portion of this surplus will be spent for commodities, either for the purpose of consumption or of production, which will in- crease the demand for the means of transport. This is the third cause for the increase in the demand for transporta- tion, due to modern division of labor. Fourthly, an added demand for transportation is caused by the fact that in the modem system of production it is highly desirable that both labor and capital should flow to the point of greatest need. By need is meant that require- ment of the progress of civilization that those resources be developed which give the highest rate of return, either 463] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 43 directly or indirectly. Sometimes, as in the case of some of the coal-fields of England, the need was so great that it was able to develop its own adequate transportation facil- ities. In other cases, as in the western part of the United States, the development of the natural resources followed the "introduction of the means of transport. But in each case, the means of transport was a necessity in order to allow the more advantageous uses of the factors of pro- duction. Aside from the fact mentioned above,^ that the means of transport are required to furnish an outlet for the produce, it is a well-known fact that labor and capital do not flow freely to inaccessible places. Just as transpor- tation increases the velocity of circulation of money,^ so is it also a necessity to enable the forces of production to seek the locality of greatest advantage. The result is a greater demand upon the means of transport within a locality be- cause of the increase of production of the new source over the old, and the increased demand in response to the fall in price. Therefore, the country or locality which possesses these four characteristics — a population of considerable density, wants developed above the mere physical necessities, a mod- ern system of production under division of labor and machine production, and a free flow of capital and labor to the points of greatest advantage — will have a large quan- tity demand for transportation. A locality lacking these characteristics will not have such a demand. Excluding 1 " The flow of investment of resources for future needs consists of two streams. The smaller consists of new additions to the accumulated stock, the larger merely replaces that which is destroyed." Marshall, Alfred', Principles of Economics, 4th ed., pp. 604-5. 2 Fisher, Irving, Elementary Principles of Economics (New York, 1919), pp. 201, 202. 44 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [464 mere density of population as distinguished from the con- centration of population in cities, each one of these char- acteristics requires for its development the presence of ade- quate transportation facilities. It is as logical to say, with reference to backward countries, that such modern forms of production and consumption are non-existent because of the lack of the facilities of transport, as to say that the means of transportation are not improved because of the lack of higher wants and modem methods of production. THE DEMAND FOR THE TRANSPORTATION OF PASSENGERS In the classification of transportation with reference to the objects carried, the distinction was made between goods and passenger transportation.^ There are certain ways in which these two demands differ from each other. The transportation of goods from one place to another is one step in the production of commodities, and so bears a close relationship to manufacturing. Passenger travel is fre- quently a complete end in itself.^ Another difference ap- pears in that the passenger is concerned only with what the company charges him, and is not distressed over what others are charged. This is not the case in goods trans- portation, for while the shipper does not bear the cost of the conveyance of the goods, yet there is a possibility of his being undersold by some competitor, who enjoys a better freight rate than himself.^ Because of this indiffer- ence, there is no wide-awake body of specialists, which con- ^ Cf. supra, p. 24. 'Marshall, Alfred, Industry and Trade, op. cit., p. 462. ' Vide Woolley, Robt. W., How Freight Rates Should be Made, in The Annals of the American Academy (November, 1919), p. 162. Mr. Woolley here says, " It is not exaggeration to say that more than 90 per cent of the complaints brought by shippers before the rate regulat- ing bodies, rest upon dissatisfaction with the relation between rates rather than upon the measure of the rates.'' 465] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 45 cerns itself about passenger rates as is the case in freight rates. In many respects, passenger traffic is much more exact- ing than freight traffic/ Speed, regularity, safety, comfort and convenience are all demanded by the passengers in varying degrees. Furthermore, in order to catch and hold certain kinds of passenger traffic, cheapness is also neces- sary ; for example, in the case of the season tickets in Eng- land or the monthly and family tickets in the United States the compajiy " commutes " a certain portion of the regular charge. There is one further distinction between passenger and goods traffic, virhich seems to be based on social distinctions. In the passenger service, railways sell special tickets to certain people at a reduced price. In England, cheap tickets are issued to workmen, and season tickets to school children, students and apprentices under eighteen years of age.^ In America, by the use of certificates, clergymen are able to purchase railway tickets at half fare. There is nothing found in goods traffic rules which would correspond to this social basis of discrimination. THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND FOR PASSENGER TRANSPOR- TATION It is evident that the elasticity of demand for passenger transportation is, in many cases, independent of any com- modity or its production. It reacts directly to the fluctua- tion in fares. For this reason, it is necessary to divide those who travel into two classes : those who travel for a money profit ^ and those who travel for some other pur- pose.* •Johnson and Van Metre, The Principles of Railway Transportation (New York, 1916), p. 1&2. ''Knoop, Douglas, Outlines of Railway Economics, p. 225. 3 Cf. supra, p. 24. *C/. Knoop, op. cit., p. 20. 46 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [466 Those who have an economic motive in traveling may be divided into three general groups, each of which reveals a certain degree of elasticity in its demand. The first of these is the commercial class, which travels to produce or sell goods. The elasticity of the demand of this class for passenger service will depend upon the percentage which passenger fares form of the total cost of producing the goods. If the fares are only a small portion of the total expense, there will be little diminution of travel if the fares are raised, or little increase if they are lowered; that is, the demand for transportation will be inelastic. But if trans- portation fares form a large proportion of the costs of goods, and the demand for the goods is elastic, then an in- crease in the fares will cause a decrease in the demand for transportation. This would apply to those who sell goods or collect debts on a commission basis, and in so doing are responsible for their own expense account. In such cases, however, the percentage of costs due to fares diminishes, as the amount of business transacted increases. If members of the commercial group are fortimate enough to be selling a commodity which is a necessity, then an increase in the costs of travel will not reduce the demand for transportation, for the increase of cost will be shifted to the consumer of the good in the form of a higher price. The demand for transportation of this class is given a greater degree of elasticity than it would otherwise possess, because of the many business evasions of travel, or substi- tutes for it. For example, a firm in order to avoid the expense of sending out traveling salesmen, may use the mails to send their customers catalogues with drawings and descriptions of the goods to be sold. The sending of sam- ples and models is also common. Then the telephones and telegraphs are at the firm's disposal. Advertising in the 467] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 47 papers and through the mails tends to make the demand for transportation for passengers of this class more elastic. The second group of those who travel for economic reasons is comprised of those who live some distance from their place of work, and use the means of transportation to go to their work in the mornings and return home in the evenings. Therefore, there is a demand for a regular, cheap and convenient service to make it possible for those who work in the cities to live in the suburbs. The rail- ways, electric lines and motor buses have catered to this demand. There are reasons why " commuters " prefer the suburbs to the city: cheaper rents, better surroundings or a com- bination of both. On the other hand, there is the expense of travel, the expenditure of time, and the possible incon- venience in commutation. The transportation companies are competing against the landlords in the cities, and if the fares are too high or the inconvenience too' great, this traffic will dwindle. Therefore cheap tickets are sold, and special trains are run for the benefit of this group.^ The elasticity of demand for this kind of transportation is stronger in the case of the poorer people than with the rich. Because of this fact, in England special working- men's trains have been established, made up of third-class carriages, which carry the workers at a very low figure. 1 This form of demand for transportation raises some interesting problems as to the costs to the companies. The advantages to the rail- way organizers over other forms of traffic are : regularity, both in time and amount, so the company is able to run full trains all the time; the small amount of baggage carried; and the small amount of supervision and work required in the offices. The disadvantages are : a " peak load " each morning and evening, with idle rolling stock the remainder of the day; frequently strong competition from other companies; and short- distance hauls. For a melancholy picture of the situation in London, £f. Williams, S. C, The Economics of Railway Transport (London, 1909), p. 24s, et seq. 48 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [468 One other element adds to the elasticity of the demand for this traffic as far as any one company is concerned. Close to a large city, competition usually exists, either between railways or between a railway and an electric line, or a motor-bus Une, or water transportation; so that any one company cannot raise its rate without losing traffic to some other; and because decreasing the cost operates strongly, any company hesitates before raising the fares. Another group of those who in contributing to the de- mand for passenger transportation have an economic ob- ject in so doing, is composed of laborers who pass from one place to another, in order to sell their labor in the highest market. As the natural and artificial forces of production are unevenly distributed over the earth, there are greater relative demands for labor in some localities than in others. Because the supply of labor has never per- fectly adapted itself to the varying opportunities of pro- duction in different places, the rewards of labor vary with localities. Man is slow to seek his highest advantage by moving from place to place, for many reasons: love of home, ignorance of where his best advantage is to be found, indifference and inertia, and frequently because of his inability to meet the expenses of transporting himself, his family and his goods. Effective means of transport greatly encourage mobility of labor. The demand for transportation due to geographical mobility of labor, is very real and important, both from the point of view of the general welfare of society ^ and of the 1 It is beyond the scope of this enquiry to discuss the increased welfare of peoples, which is due to mobility of labor. However, three elements are outstanding in their importance, in this connection. Firstly, mobility of labor brings about a greater adaptability of human powers to pro- duction, by increasing the choices of occupation. Secondly, -the appli- cation of labor to the places of greater natural or artificial resource in- creases production. Thirdly, the strain of furnishing articles of con- 469] THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 49 special welfare of the laborers themselves. Some of this mobility of labor is seasonal, as the response of the East to the call of the West, at the harvest time in the United States. At other times it is spasmodic, as in the rush of men to the places of fresh discoveries of gold or oil. But by far the most important part of this demand for trans- portation is the steady and unobserved flow of labor to the places of higher wages, or of greater reward for its efforts. Campredon explains the remarkable development of the resources of the western part of the United States by pointing out the part that the railways have played in making it possible for men and materials to reach the re- sources of the West.^ Another aspect of the need for transportation facilities in order to increase the mobility of labor, is to be observed in times of interruptions of industry; e. g., epidemics, strikes or lockouts, famines and fires. In this connection, Francis A. Walker says : ^ Deal the heaviest blow you can with a hammer into a bin of barley, and you will not injure a single grain, though the "hammer be buried to your hand, because every grain moves freely from its place, and the mass simply opens to receive the intruding substance, and closes around and above it. Lay one of the grains upon a rock, and your blow will smash it into a paste. ... In the nature of the case, blows must fall, from time to time, upon every industrial community or class. Whether these be due to wars or failures of the harvest, or to sumption is reduced in places where nature has been niggardly, or capi- talistic production backward, by reducing the number of people depend- ent upon these resources. A large labor supply is of advantage only when the development of natural resources has kept pace with the growth of population. 'Compreddn, Eugene, Role Economique et Social des Votes de Com- munication (Paris, 1899), pp. 53-66. 2 Vide Walker, F., Political Economy, p. 264. 50 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [470 conflagrations and floods, or to the shifting of commercial de- mand, or to vicious legislation, labor has an ample security against deep and permanent injury, so long as its mobility is unimpaired. On whatever spot the blow may fall, complete freedom of movement, from place to place and from avocation to avocation, will cause the original loss to be distributed over the industrial body, while the forces of repair and restoration will immediately set to work to make good what has been taken away. The demand of laborers for means of conveyance to new fields of labor has some degree of elasticity, especially in countries where distances are great. One important factor in increasing this elasticity is the lack of savings for such an emergency on the part of the laborers themselves. Fre- quently they do not seek a new field of labor until their savings have been spent. In countries and localities where the people are poor, the difference between cheap and more expensive transportation may be sufficient to make labor much less mobile than it otherwise would be. It is not so much a question of lower or higher rates on the railways,^ as it is the difference between the old form of conveyance and the modem means of transportation. On the other hand, the feeling of expectancy of a much greater income in the new locality than was received in the old, will tend to increase the inelasticity of this demand. The immigrant who comes to the United States would not be kept back if the costs of transportation were doubled; he might be delayed until the larger sum was accumulated, but he would come sooner or later. Besides those who travel for purposes of business, or 1 In England and in most of the countries of Europe, the fares are levied according to classes. The lowest class fare is low enough to permit any but the indigent to travel. Vide Knoop, Douglas, op. cit., p. 22s, et seq. 471 J THE ECONOMICS OF TRANSPORTATION 51 from some economic motive, there are many who travel for non-economic reasons. There are some non-economic mo- tives for travel which are social in character, which fur- nish evidence of a high degree of inelasticity of demand; e. g., travel to attend the funeral or wedding of a friend or relative, or in the performance of some religious or patriotic duty. In such cases the sense of social or relig- ious duty is stronger than economic considerations. But the larger part of those who travel for non-economic motives do so for pleasure. The demand for transporta- tion, when it is caused by the search for pleasure and rest, is highly elastic. This is due to competition in a two-fold form. First, there is competition between dififerent com- panies which are bidding against each other, each company seeking tO' induce as many people to use its facilities as possible. The cause of the strength of this kind of com- petition for the traffic of those seeking pleasure or vacation resorts is due to the fact that the prospective travelers have a wide range of choice as to destination. In business travel, this is not so. The pleasure-seekers may travel in any direction, by land or water, to that destination which will offer the greatest opportunity of rest and enjo5mient, at the least expense.^ This competition between companies is further complicated by the fact that when people travel for pleasure, they take more thought of comfort and conveni- ence than when traveling for business reasons. Railway and steamship companies advertise reduced fares ^ and im- usual comforts and luxuries in order to draw patronage away from their competitors. ^ Vide Elliott, Howard, "An Address to the Annual ^Convention of the American Association of General Passenger and Ticket Agents," delivered at Copley Plaza Hotel, Boston, Mass., September i6th, 1914. ^ Cf. Weyl, Walter E., The Passenger TfaMc of Railways (University of Pennsylvania Series of Political Economy and PubUc Law, No. 16) , (Philadelphia, 1901), p. 63. 52 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [472 The second form of competition with which the trans- portation companies are faced in securing the traffic of those bent on pleasure, is that of increased comforts and pleasures at home in lieu of the enjoyment of a vacation spent away from home. The individual may conclude to build a sleeping porch to his house, or a pagoda in his garden instead of visiting a mountain or seaside resort. In London and New York, the theatres which are kept open during the summer months compete with the railways and steamship lines for this patronage. Because of these two forms of competition, and because pleasure travel is a luxury and must also compete against future wants which are uncertain to the consumer, the demand for this kind of transportation is the most elastic of all. The expenditure of a commodity for pleasure arises from its surplus spending power. In general, the quantity of the demand for pleasure-travel increases as the surplus of incomes over living'expenses increases.'^ But localities vary, as do individuals, in the use made of this surplus. Custom, social distinction, tendencies to thrift, and many other things affect the quantity demand for this form of transportation. Yet there can be little doubt that the claim of careful students that a reduction of fares would greatly increase the amount of passenger traffic, not only for dis- tinctly pleasurable purposes but for all purposes, has reason- able justification. Both Prof. Johnson and Dr. Weyl are persuaded that the increase of passenger traffic in the United States, due to the decrease in the fares, would in- crease the net revenue of the railways.^ '■ Cf. Williams, iS. C, op. cit., p. 247, et seq. 2 Vide Johnson and Van Metre, op. cit., pp. 198, igg ; also Weyl, Walter E., op. cit., p. 21. CHAPTER II A Historical Sketch of the Means of Transporta- tion IN India Transportation facilities within any country are usu- ally classified under three heads: waterways, roads and railways. Waterways may further be divided into navi- gable rivers, navigable canals and coastal navigation. Roads have usually been classified according to their con- struction, having a regard for the materials used in the road-bed, and the covering or paving of the same. To-day it is necessary to consider the service rendered by different kinds of roads in the light of the vehicles which will be used on them. Motor transport is rapidly causing a reconsid- eration of the relation that formerly existed in the minds of people between roads and railways. Railways may be divided into trunk lines and subsidiary lines or " feeders ". They may also be classified according to the width between the rails, as broad or narrow gauge. waterways In considering the subject of waterways in India, the first class to be noticed is that of navigable canals. These are of two kinds : those which are for navigation only, and those which are also used for irrigation. It is ob- vious that the chief advantage in having canals which serve both the purposes of irrigation and of navigation is that of reduced cost. On the other hand, there are difficulties in constructing the canals that they may successfully serve both purposes. Irrigation canals should be as high as pos- 473] S3 54 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [474 sible above the plains to be irrigated, and the current should be strong, so as to quickly replace the water drawn from the canal for irrigation. Navigation canals, on the other hand, should be on low ground with a current so slow that boats may go in either direction without difficulty/ Again, irrigation canals are independent of large cities and trade centers while canals used for transportation only are de- pendent upon them.^ It is also true that when the rains fail, the water in the canals is likely to be so low that boats are not able to navigate them.'' For these reasons, while India has a remarkable supply of irrigation canals, very few of them are used for navigation. In Madras Presidency there are two important systems of irrigation canals which are almost entirely navigable. They are the Godaveri and Kistna systems. The former has a total length of 506 miles, 493 miles of which are navigable. The Kistna system has a total length of 372 miles, all but 40 miles of which can be used for transpor- tation purposes. The total number of boats which use the two canals is about 80,000 per annum. The average annual receipts are $46,100.* While this sum is about equal to the working expense of the navigation, yet the Govern- ment has been able to make the land assessment of the irrigated tracts higher than it could have been made had the people been without this cheap means of transportation. Mr. MacGeorge estimates for the year 1890-91 the net revenue earned on the capital outlay in the Godaveri delta as 12^^%.'* There is one other irrigation canal in Madras ^Vide MacGeorge, G. W., Ways and Works in India (London, 1894), p. 131. ^Imperial Gazetteer of India (London, 1907), vol. iii, pp. 354-5. ^Cf. Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 252. *Rate of exchange is here taken at 32.5 cents. 5 MaoGeorge, ibid., p. 191. 475] HISTORICAL SKETCH 55 Presidency which is used for navigation — the Kumul- Cuddapah. It is igo miles in length and has two railway connections. No dues are charged, but the canal is little used as a means of transportation. In Bengal there are three large systems of irrigation canals which are used for navigation: the Orissa Canal system, 280 miles in length ; the Midnapore Canal, 72 miles long; and the Son system of 218 miles. The canals are used only to a limited extent and the receipts do not cover the operating costs due to navigation. One cause of the moderate use made of these canals is the competition of railways which were constructed after the canals. Since the Agra Canal was closed to navigation in 1904, the United Provinces of Agra and Oudh has only two navigable canal systems ; namely, the Upper and the Lower Ganges canals, with a total extent of 275 miles. In spite of the fact that there is connection with the Ganges River at Cawnpore, there is little through traffic to Calcutta. There is, however, considerable local traffic. The traffic receipts amount to less than $5,000 per annum, which amount covers about one-half of the working expenses of navigation. In the Punjab, the navigable canals are the Western Jumna and the Sirhind. The total, length of the navigable canals of the former system is 207 miles, while that of the latter is 180 miles. The traffic on each system is insig- nificant. Aside from the canals which have already been men- tioned, there are a few others which are used entirely for the purpose of navigation. Chief among these is the Buck- ingham Canal, which has a length of 262 miles and lies in the Madras Presidency. The expense of maintenance is very great and the traffic is moderate. In the same class is another system of canals in Bengal, which is known as 56 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [476 the Calcutta and Eastern Canals. These canals connect the river courses of the deltas of the Ganges and the Brahma- putra, and counting both the river channels and the canals, the total length of the system is 735 miles. There is a large traffic and the income is considerable. This system may be considered the most successful of the navigable canals of India, whether regarded from the point of view of tonnage or receipts. In Burma, the Government maintains two canals for navigation: the Pegu-Sittang and the Sittang-Kyaikto. The receipts from the former are about $47,000 per annum. The general conclusion regarding navigable canals, whether in combination or for navigation only, must be that with a few exceptions, the people have not been eager to use them as a means of transportation. No one of the systems has been able to show a profit. During the years in which the railways of India were operated with a recur- ring deficit, there was much discussion as to the advisa- bility of extending the construction of canals as a means of transportation. It is now known that canals are not to be the solution of the country's transportation problem.^ Apart from the combination of rivers with canals, rivers in India have formed, since early times, waterways for transportation. Near the mouths of some of the great rivers the traffic is still heavy. But the actual service ren- dered by the great rivers, as ways for transportation, is not as great as one would expect, considering the length of the streams and the volume of water which passes through them. The reason is to be found, in part at least, in the peculiar physical characteristics of the river valleys and the concentration of the country's rainfall. The streams usually occupy wide valleys and have low marginal 1 Cf. Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 252. 477] HISTORICAL SKETCH 57 banks of alluvial soil. Before the coming of the monsoon rains, the streams in many cases dwindle to mere threads. After the rains are well under way the rivers become tor- rents and frequently overflow the low banks and spread out over the river valleys. When the rains have ceased and the streams have settled back into definite channels, they are found to be tonsiderably changed in current, depth, and even direction. Much silt is washed down from the moun- tains, which affects the navigable character of the streams, especially at the lower reaches. As regularity, speed and reasonable safety are characteristics of an effective system of transportation, river transportation in India leaves much to be desired. The leading rivers of the country, which are navigable for long distances throughout the year, are the Ganges, the Brahmaputra, and the Indus. The Ganges can be consid- ered navigable as far as Cawnpore, at least for small boats, but the river traffic from Calcutta to that industrial city is not great. The Brahmaputra is navigable as far as Dibru- garh. The Indus is " constantly navigable as high as Dera Ismail Khan, . . . 800 miles inland." ^ The Goda- vari, the Kistna and the Mahanadi rivers permit naviga- tion a considerable distance above their deltas, but they are little used for transportation. In Burma, the greatest use is made of rivers for navigation. The Irrawaddi can be used as a waterway for boats of some size for a distance of 500 miles. Considering India as a whole, it may be said that the proof that river-ways do not adequately meet the need for transportation of even those people who live close to the banks of navigable streams, is to be found in the effects of river and railway competition. Before the E^t Indian 1 Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 361. 58 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [478 Railway was built from Calcutta to Delhi, certain towns and cities along the banks of the Ganges river had attained some degree of importance as river ports, but they have now lost much of their former prosperity.^ Probably the chief service rendered by the river waterways is to be found in the irregular local shipping, by small country boats, which are propelled by oars or by poles, or are towed by men pulling from the banks. Much of this shipping must go unrecorded, although its total must be great.^ The total value of the coasting trade for 1916-17 amounted to £y6 million. The pre-war quinquennial aver- age was £y:^ million. The share of each province for 1 916-17 was as follows: Bombay, 35.2 per cent; Burma, 27.5 per cent; Bengal (including Bihar and Orissa), 17.8 per cent; Madras, 10.3 per cent; Sind, 9.2 per cent.* ROADS By the modern use of the term road is meant a way which is provided with a smooth and hard surface and easy grades, with permanent bridges over the streams, and which possesses adequate drainage. India has a supply of such roads, which are termed " first-class " roads. Be- sides these, there are the " second-class " roads, and still lower down in the scale the " fair-weather " roads. A second-class road may be one of two sorts. It may 'be ' Mirzapur, in the United Pronvinces, between Benares and Allahabad, is an example of such decline. ^ Vide Accounts of the Trade Carried by Rail and River in India, published annually by the Government of India. In the prefatory note to this report, a statement is made of the manner in which the statistics of river-borne traffic are gathered. With reference to the boat trade, it is explained, " The boat traffic is registered at certain selected river stations by clerks, who collect the required information from the boat- men and forward the returns to the provincial officers." ' Vide Review of the Trade of India, Parliamentary Papers (London, I9i8),p. 33- 479] HISTORICAL SKETCH 59 properly embanked and surfaced, and of the same width as a first-class road, or possibly narrower, but it lacks per- manent bridges. Again, a second-class road may be banked and drained but may lack both a hard surface and bridging. All that can be said in favor of the fair-weather road is that it is scientifically laid out, ditches have been dug at the sides, bushes and trees have been cleared away, and the banks have been graded at the approaches to the streams. These roads are of service for about eight months of the year.^ Roads of the first class did not exist in India until about 1840.^ The native princes did not build roads of this sort. They were content to plant trees along the tracks used as roads, occasionally to fill in depressions, and to build cara- vansaries (sarais) at the halting places. The Moghul kings did build some noble bridges, a few of which are still standing; as the Gumti Bridge at Jaunpur. Some of the rajahs of Assam built high embankments (bunds) to avoid the floods, and ran roads along the top. Such was the road that Rajah Rudra Singh built over a century ago, between Jaipur and Jankana, a distance of seventy miles. Even many years after the establishment of British rule in India little attention was paid to roads. In 1818 an effort was made to improve the tracks that existed by put- ting convicts to work on them, but little seems to have been accomplished.^ To Lord William Bentinck (1828-1835) is due the credit of being the first ruler to consider seriously the construction of a first-class highway. This road now connects Calcutta with Delhi and Peshawar, and has be- come famous in history and story as the " Grand Trunk Road." This monument of enterprise and determination ' MacGeorge, G. W., op. cit., p. 66, et seq. 2 Cf. Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 402. ' MacGeorge, op. cit., pp. 72-3. 6o INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [480 has a complete length of 1500 miles; and for some years it was the greatest road of its kind in existence. Through- out its entire course it is raised above the flood line and is well bridged. Trees have been planted at intervals of 50 or 60 feet. Camping places and " rest-houses " have been provided every ten or fifteen miles. The exact cost of the road is not aibsolutely certain, as the construction extended over two decades, and as part of the road was built by famine-relief and convict labor. Exclusive of bridges, the cost per mile has been estimated to have been £500.^ Until the railway was built, which practically parallels it, the Grand Trunk Road had such heavy traffic that the metal- ling had to be renewed on the average every six years. Another important trunk line, known as the " Great Deccan Road," was begun in 1856. One terminus was at Mirzapur, where it made a connection with the Grand Trunk Road. From this place it was carried southeast to Nagpur by way of Jubblepore. At the completion o£ Nagpur's ccmnection with Bombay, India had first-class metalled roads, extending across the peninsula from Cal- cutta to Bombay. Another fine road, which was built in the early days, was that which runs from Bombay to Jhansi and Agra. This was begun in 1840, and when complete had a length of 735 miles. From these early and successful efforts at road-building, progress continued, with the result that in 1870 many of the great trunk lines for trade and military purposes had been completed. Much of the progress achieved during these years was due to a change made in the administra- tion and control of road^building. Up to 1855, the con- struction of roads was in the hands of Military Boards — 1 MacGeorge, op. cit., p. 84. 48 1 ] HISTORICAL SKETCH 6 1 one for each presidency. The actual work of construction was committed to the authorities of the different provinces in which the roads were buih. While the power of the Military Boards to supervise was great, their power to ad- minister and exercise financial control was limited. The natural result was a great confusion. When the Punjab was annexed, a department was organized for the con- struction of all public works within its territory. The re- sult was so satisfactory that the Military Boards were abandoned and a Public Works Department was created in each province. The Central Government created a Public Works Secretariat, to have general control over the Public Works Departments in all the provinces. Such was the birth of the Public Works Department to which India owes so much. From 1855, the construction of new roads was carried on in a more economical and scientific manner.^ The progress of roadbuilding has also been furthered by another act of decentralization. The authority and respon- sibility for " maintenance and improvement of local com- munication '' have been delegated to district and sub- district boards. Usually the control of the main trunk lines remains in the hands of the provincial governments, and it is only the subsidiary lines which have been com- mitted to the district boards. The general result of this decentralization has been an increase in the number of first and second class roads within the provinces. There is a paucity of statistical data regarding the ex- tent, costs of construction and maintenance of roads. Con- cerning this scarcity, the Imperial Gazetteer of India at- tempts an explanation : The collection of statistics regarding roads in India has never received much attention, for their classification, the circum- i Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 406. 62 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [482 stances under which they are constructed, the demands which they meet, and the funds available for their up-keep vary so greatly in different parts of the country, that there is no com- mon object to be served by their compilation/ The available figures give the length of metalled roads, at the close of 1902, as 37,000 miles, and the total length of the unmetalled roads as 136,000 miles.^ Both of these figures relate to roads which are maintained in condition, either by the governments of the provinces or by local bodies. The effect of railway construction upon the demand for trunk roads which parallel the railways has been to decrease the demand for the trunk roads. Long hauls over these roads are no longer profitable where railways are available for the same destination. The service which remains for such trunk roads to perform is to make possible the short hauls between places located on or near the roads, and to facilitate traffic to the railway stations. In general, it may be said that the effect of railways upon the demand for trunk roads has been to decrease the demand for the latter, but to increase the demand for roads as feeders for the railways.* RAILWAYS In the last division of the means of transport in India — railways — ^an interesting history is to be found, whether regarded from the political or from the economic point of view. The earliest proposals to build railways in India seem to have been made about 1843. Politically, the time was not propitious for such undertakings, as the country had not yet recovered from the effects of the wars in'Sind; ' Vide, vol. iii, p. 410 ; Cf. MacGeorge, op. cit., p. 104. ^Gazetteer, op. cit. • Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 407. 483] HISTORICAL SKETCH 63 and the Government, under Lord Hardinge, was already in difficulties with Ran jit Singh, which were soon to result in war in the Punjab. But England was just entering on the period known as the " railway mania," and in spite of the political outlook, the promoters of the plans for Indian railways were able to get a hearing in England.^ It seems to have been understood from the beginning that the capital would have to be raised in England, and that the construc- tion and management of the railways would have to be carried out by private companies ; and " that the novelties and unknown difficulties of their (railways) introduction into so distant and backward a country would be sufficient to inspire the general public with certain distrust in the speculation." ^ The Honorable Court of Directors of the East India Company had grave doubts as to the feasibility of railways for India. Companies were being formed and plans drawn, and submitted to the Court of Directors. These plans included a scheme whereby the Indian Government would guarantee a certain rate of interest on the invested capital.^ In May, 1845, the Court of Directors sent a de- spatch to the Govemor-'General of India, in which was expressed some degree of conviction as to the desirability of railways for India. But the Directors also expressed fear that the difficulties were insurmountable. They felt that the income from the railways would have to be drawn chiefly from the transportation of goods and not from pas- sengers. It was also feared that the floods, the violent winds, the destruction wrought by insects and vermin, the ill effects of spontaneous vegetation upon timber, earth and masonry, would make the building and operation of railways in India impossible. ' Vide Bell, Horace, Railway Policy in Iiidia (London, 1894), p. i. ^ MacGeorge, op. cit., p. 300. ^ This was a plan which was then in successful operation in France. 64 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [484 To enquire into the whole situation, Mr. Simms, an engineer, was sent out from England, and two military- engineers in India were associated with him. In February, 1846, Mr. Simms made his report, in which he dealt with the relations which he thought should exist between the Government and the companies. He felt that it might be advisable to guarantee a small percentage on the capital to be invested in the railways. The military engineers, in their part of the report, said that there were no reasons why railways might not be built and operated in India as successfully as in Europe. When this report came before the Governor General's Council, Lord Hardinge was not present. The Council took action and decided that the grant of free land to the railways should be approved, but that a guarantee of in- terest was not advisable, and that the Government should have a large amount of control over the companies and over the work of construction and operation of the rail- ways. Lord Hardinge issued a statement of his own later, which was much more generous to the railway companies. He was inclined to favor a guarantee of interest to the companies. It was not until 1849, after months of discussion in England and India, that the preliminary legal agreements were signed with the two leading companies : the East India Railway and the Great Indian Peninsula companies. The final contracts soon followed and contained the following stipulations : ( i ) " The design and execution of certain railroads in India are intrusted to joint-stock companies." (2) "The Indian Government guarantees interest on moneys duly raised by companies and paid over to Gov- ernment, controlling at the same time their expenditures and operations." ^ The companies, therefore, had an ab- ' Quoted by MaoGeorge, op. cit., p. 307. The rate of guaranteed inter- est ultimately became five per cent. 485] HISTORICAL SKETCH 65 solute guarantee of 5% on all the capital which was author- ized to be paid into the treasury of the East India Com- pany. (3) At any time the companies wished to surrender the railroads, on giving six months' notice, they could re- quire of the Government a repayment of the actual capital spent on the roads, plant and rolling stock. (4) The Gov- ernment promised to furnish to the companies all land re- quired for the railways, free of cost for ninety-nine years. (5) The railways were to carry the mails free of charge, and troops and military stores at a reduced rate. (6) The Government could purchase the roads at intervals of twenty- five years. Because of the highly favorable terms given to the rail- way companies, no difficulty was experienced in obtaining sufficient capital to develop the railway enterprise.^ Two trial lines were undertaken : one from Bombay to Kaliyan,^ a distance of 33 miles, and another from Calcutta to Pan- dua, a distance of 37 miles. Both of these lines were open for traffic before 1855. This was the actual beginning of railways in India. During the time when the experimental lines were being built there was much discussion as to the best method and 'The clause in the contract which has been subject to the most criticism is that one which guaranteed interest to the investors. It is generally admitted that the plan had two serious defects: firstly, the rate of interest was higher than necessary; when once it was proved that railways could be built and operated in the country, money could have been obtained at a lower rate. Secondly, the system practically encouraged wasteful expenditure, for the more capital " called up," the greater the return at this high rate. The efforts at justification attempt to show that India did get the railways, at a rapid rate, independent of the hampering influence of a fluctuating budget. Vide Connell, A. K.. The Economic Re-volution in India (London, 1883), pt. ii, passim: Chesney, Sir George, Indian Polity (London, 1894), 3rd ed., p. 302, et seq., also, Bell, Horace, op. cit., p. 59, et seq. 'This line was open for traffic, as far as Tannah, twenty miles from Bombay, on the i6th of April, 1853. 66 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [486 policy for the construction of railways in the country. After many different plans had been proposed, some of which were wise and some foolish, the Government real- ized that a definite line of action would have to be taken if India was ever to be blessed with effective means of trans- port. Lord Dalhousie put out at this time his justy famous minute of 1853. He pointed out the economic and political benefits which would follow the joining of the important cities with trunk lines of railways, and the connecting of each of the interior cities with its most natural port. The trunk lines proposed by him were as follows : one from Calcutta to Lahore, one from Bombay to North India, one from Bombay to Madras, and another from Madras to the Malabar coast. These proposals were accepted by the Court of Directors; and before the close of 1859, the Gov- ernment had sanctioned the construction of 5,000 miles of railroads, and had guaranteed interest on capital amount- ing to £52,500,000 sterling.^ The gauge originally adopted for Indian railways was a compromise between the 7 feet gauge then in use in Eng- land and the 4 feet 8yi inch gauge more commonly used. Mr. Simms advised a compromise gauge of 5 feet and 6 inches.* At that time the popularity of the broad gauge was great in England, and it was thought that any gauge less than 5 J^ feet would not insure safety against cyclones." Lord Dalhousie accepted this conclusion and 5J^ feet be- came the standard gauge for the railways. The cost of the lines which were built before 1869 was very great. This was due in part to the system under which they were constructed and in part to peculiar difficulties in- herent in the nature of the work. The defect in the sys- ^ Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 366. * Cf. supra, p. 64. 'Vide Indian Year Book, igi8, p. 231; also, Bell, op. cit., p. 119. 487] HISTORICAL SKETCH 67 tem has already been referred to.^ The difficulties were due to the lack of skilled labor in India, the need of im- porting materials and machinery from England, the phys- ical peculiarities of the climate of the country, the ten- dency of the rivers to flood, and perhaps more important than all, the fact that experience was lacking in the best way to overcome these difficulties. Added to these obstacles, the expense was increased and the work delayed by the Indian Mutiny of 1857. Railways were also hindered in their construction by the depreciation in the gold value of the rupee, concerning which difficulty Sir John, Strachey says, " The earnings of all these works are in silver, but the greater part of the interest on the capital expenditure, the annuities paid in respect of guaranteed railways pur- chased, and nearly the whole of the payments to guaran- teed companies, have had to be paid in gold." ^ Because of these unfortunate conditions and circumstances, the open lines which were built before 1870, cost on the average £17,000 per mile.' It had become evident to the Government of India that if India was ever to have adequate means of transportation, a policy involving less expense would have to be adopted. With this in view. Lord Lawrence took up the question of the future of railways, and in a very able minute, dated March 1869, he made proposals which were to bring the country into its second period of railway development; I. e. from 1870 to 1880. Lord Lawrence strongly advo- cated that in the future, new railways be built by the direct agency of the State and with State money. He then went on to say : 1 Cf. supra, p. 65, footnote. 'Vide Strachey, Sir John, India, its Administration and Progress, p. 255; also, Chesney, op. cit., p. 312. 'Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 231 ; Gazetteer, op. cit. p. 369. 68 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [488 For a poor country, economy is one of the essential conditions to be complied with, and its requirements may be as rigid as any of those imposed by physical conditions. Wholly to reject rail- ways for a country which is not able to support lines of the most costly description is quite unreasonable; and if, on a further examination in detail of the probable cost and returns of any of the lines, which otherwise seem desirable, the expense of the ordinary gauge seems prohibitory, while lines of the narrow gauge would be financially practicable; I should consider it a most mistaken view to reject the narrow gauge line.' The Secretary of State (the Duke of Argyll) agreed to the proposals made by Lord Lawrence, that narrow-gauge railways be built and that they be built by the State, with capital raised by the State, either by borrowing or taken from revenues. The Government of India was well aware of the evils attendant upon a break in the gauges of a rail- way system, but it considered that the circumstances de- manded a narrower and a cheaper gauge. The metre gauge was finally adopted. The responsibility of borrowing cap- ital for the new railways was undertaken by the Secretary of State, who borrowed the money in London, on the security of the Indian revenues. During this period of ten years the Government never paid a higher average annual rate of interest on the capital borrowed than 4%.^ Pri- vate enterprise was not encouraged to construct railways, and the only roads that were constructed were built by the State. The first narrow-gauge railroad, as well as the first State road, was the Rajputana Malwa Railway, the main section of which was begun in 1873 3^"^ finished in 1879. ' Quoted from Bell, op. cit., p. 22. * For one year only (1879-80) was the average annual rate as high as four per cent. It seems that the Government now began to receive — as the Duke of Argyll phrased it — " The full benefit of the credit which it lends." 489] HISTORICAL SKETCH 69 The urgency of the need for more railroads, especially for those of a protective character, led later to a change in this policy of State Construction of Railways. During the years from 1874 to 1879, India experienced a series of famines, which were of a very serious character. There was great loss of life by starvation and disease. In Madras, Mysore and Bombay, more than four millions of people are said to have died in the years between 1876 and 1878.^ Surgeon-General Balfour in speaking of the famine of these years says, " No past famine has been more intense than that of 1876-78, so none may exceed it in the future." " When the Famine Commission of 1880 made its report, it was pointed out that the State could not supply the capital rapidly enough to give the country the protection against famines, which the previous years had shown were so urgently needed. It was the opinion of the Commission that 5000 additional miles of railroads should be provided as soon as possible, and that the country could not be said to be out of danger until it possessed a total mileage of 20,000.' The actual mileage which existed by 1880 was as follows : * Broad Gauge Afeire Gauee Special Gauge Total Up to 1870 4210 45 4255 Between 1870 and 1880 2352 1865 22 4239 Totals 6562 1865 67 8494 The third period of the development of railways in India began after a long discussion between the Government of India and a Select Committee of the House of Commons. ' Bell, op. cit., p. 29. 'Balfour, Edward, The Cyclopedia of India (London, 1885), vol. i, pp. 1075-76. ' Vide Bell, op. cit., p. 29. * Adapted from the Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 370. •JO INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [490 when it was finally decided to return to joint-stock com- pany enterprise in some instances, and to maintain state undertakings in other instances. So in this stage, we have the two forms carried on together, the State being some- times the builder of the road, and a company the operator,^ or the State both the builder and the operator, or again, the joint-stock company becoming both the builder and the operator. In 1882, the Southern Mahratta Railway com- pany was organized, on the basis that the company supply the capital and operate the railway, but that the owner- ship be vested in the State. A guarantee of 4 per cent for seven years was given, and afterwards the rate was to be reduced to 3j4 per cent. The company was to receive one- fourth of the net profits. At this time a determined effort was made to induce companies to undertake the construction of roads without a guarantee of interest, and the Bengal and North Western Railway was undertaken on this basis. Three other com- panies were also so organized, but one became bankrupt and the others now operate under a guarantee.^ By 1880, 8494 miles of railway had been built in the Native States, of which mileage 6562 were broad gauge, 1865 were metre gauge and 67 were special gauges.- The policy followed in the building of railways in Native States has varied. In some instances, capital has been taken from the revenues of the States in which the railways were built; and in other instances, the Government of India has loaned money to the States. In yet other cases, the Gov- ernment of India has been responsible for the guarantee of interest to a company which has supplied capital to the States. In Mysore State, there has been a combination of two methods: a part of the funds has been provided by ' Vide Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 229. 'Ibid., p. 229. 49 1 ] HISTORICAL SKETCH 71 the State and part has been loaned by the Southern Mah- ratta Railway Company, on the guarantee of the Govern- ment of India. ^ Another feature of the development of the railway sys- tem of India is to be found in the assisted companies, which first came into existence with the Southern Mahratta Rail- way in 1882. By the terms of the contract, the assisted companies had two distinct works to do. They raised the necessary capital to build the roads, and passed these funds over to the Government. The State paid four per cent in- terest on the amount raised. The company also became responsible for the operation of the road after its con- struction. In the case of the Southern Mahratta Railway, the Government allowed the company one-fourth of the net profits. On much the same plan, the Bengal Nagpur Railway in 1883, and the Indian Midland Railway in 1887, were undertaken. The Government is the owner of the railways, and guarantees to the companies a certain rate of interest on the capital, while the latter are encour- aged to economical operation of the roads by grants of a specified percentage of the net profits. The company does not take the risk of the enterprise, so for this reason the term " assisted company " is not a happy one.^ Closely allied to this form of assistance was the contract entered into in the construction of the line of metre gauge, connecting Assam and Chittagong. In this instance, the company raised a part of the capital, and the Secretary of State the balance. The Government of India guaranteed interest at the rate of three and one-half per cent for five years, and afterwards at three per cent. The contract pro- vided that the surplus be divided between the State and the company, in proportion as each had contributed towards the total capital. ' Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 372. " Vide Bell, op. cit, p. 86. 72 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [492 Owing to the changes in policy, the building of railways went forward with greater rapidity. In the quinquennial period from 1883 to 1887 inclusive, the total mileage of all gauges which was opened to traffic, reached its max- imum — ^423 1 14 ; which was greater by 33 per cent than had been opened in any previous quinquennial period/ This great increase was due in part to the improvement in the financial condition of the country. It was at this time that the Government's limit for borrowing for railways was raised from two to three crores." In 1893, the rebate system was introduced as a subsi- diary policy. The adverse exchange rate so increased the Government's liabilities in gold that the building of rail- ways, either by State agency or by the system of guar- anteed interest was greatly hampered. The rebate system avoided the necessity of a gold subsidy; for companies conducting branch lines were offered a " rebate " on the gross earnings on all traffic interchanged with the main line, so that the total profits of the branch-line company should yield a dividend of 4 per cent. The rebate was, however, limited to 10 per cent of the gross earnings from such traffic." " Three companies only were organized under this system, for the terms were not sufficiently at- tractive to call out capital. In 1896 an absolute guarantee of 3 per cent was offered to companies, together " with a share of surplus profits, or a rebate up to the full extent of the main line's net earnings in supplement of their own net earnings, the total being limited to 3J/2 per cent on the 'MacGeorge, op. cit., p. 415. 'The term crore is used in books on Indian finance to mean that Indian money is the unit ; i. e., the rupee. A crore is equal to 10,000,000 rupees. When the term lakh is used, Indian money is also referred to. A lakh is equal to 100,000 rupees. " Vide Gazetteer, op. £it., p. 371. Cf. Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 229. 493] HISTORICAL SKETCH 73 capital outlay." ^ The result has been that a number of subsidiary lines have been built under one or the other of these options, but neither the subsidy as offered in 1893 nor that of 1896 has been highly successful in calling out a large supply of capital for investment in railways. An effort has been made by the Government of India to encourage Provincial Boards to undertake the raising of funds for the purpose of railway construction within their own territories. The hope has been that in this way the main lines might be provided with sufficient feeders to meet the need for transportation facilities. The attempt has not been crowned with a great degree of success. As has been mentioned,^ the Government of India, when entering into its agreement with the guaranteed companies, retained the right to purchase the railways at intervals of twenty-five years. The Great Indian Peninsula Railway might have been purchased in 1874. But in 1869 the Sec- retary of State for India began negotiations with the com- pany, in the course of which the promise was made to forego the purchase of the line for another period of twenty-five years, providing the company would consent to the making of a new contract, which should contain, among other things, the stipulation that all surplus profits above five per cent should be divided equally between the Gov- ernment and the company. The company gladly accepted this offer. ^ Later the same form of contracts was granted ^Gazetteer, op. cit., p. 371. 2 Cf. supra, p. 65. • It is difficult to understand why the Secretary of State thought it wise to enter into this new contract, rather than purchase the line. It is generally accepted that the Government of India was the loser. That it was a mistake in policy was the firm conviction of the Indian Govern- ment at the time, and it sent in a vigorous protest to the Secretary for India, but before the protest reached its destination, the new contract had been consummated. Vide Bell, op. cit., p 25, et seq. 74 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [494 to the Madras Railway and the Bombay, Baroda Railway companies. The first railway to be purchased by the State was the East Indian Railway, in 1879. The method used in mak- ing the payment for the railway was by the granting of annuities. The price of the stock was taken at the average for the previous three years, which was £125, on which valuation the annuity was calculated to be £5-12-6. The line was made over to a new company for operation. Ac- cording to the plan, the Government will redeem the whole cost of the line in seventy-three years. The operating com- pany receives one-fifth of the net profits. Between the years 1880 and 1891 the company received an average sum of Rx 168,540,'^ as its share of the net profits. The rail- way has been a source of revenue to the State, and the ad- vantages resulting from its purchase are generally unques- tioned.^ The following facts have been published regard- ing this railway, covering its history through the fiscal year 1915-1916: "The open mileage is 2,719.05; under con- struction or sanction, 94.18; total 2,813.23. Total capital outlay (on 2448 miles), 7,150 lakhs; gross earnings, 1051 lakhs; net earnings, 639 lakhs; percentage of net earnings on capital outlay, 8.95 ; gain to the State, 239 lakhs." * Other leading roads which were originally owned by guaranteed companies, but have been purchased by the State, can only be mentioned. The Eastern Bengal Rail- way was bought in 1884, at which time it was amalgamated with the Northern Bengal State Railway. The Sind- Pun jab-Delhi Railway was acquired in 1886, and was amalgamated with the Indus Valley State Railway and the Punjab Northern State Railway, imder the name of the '/&id., p. 79- ' Vide Strachey, op. cit., pp. 252-3. '■Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 238. 495]' HISTORICAL SKETCH 75 North- Western State Railway. The Oudh and Rohilkhand Railway was purchased by the State in 1889, and has been operated by the State. The Great Indian Peninsula Rail- way was finally acquired by the Government in 1900, and was made over to a company for operation. The Madras Railway was acquired in 1907 and was amalgamated with the Southern Mahratta Railway. Before the Great War, the last statement of policy for railway construction was issued by the Railway Board of the Government of India from Simla, on the 14th of No- vember 1913.^ The heading of the order has significance, as indicating the special need of the time, and the policy considered most advisable (by the Government) in meet- ing the need. It was as follows : " Terms on which the Government of India is prepared to consider offers for the construction by the agency of private companies of branch lines forming feeders either to State lines worked by the State or to railways worked by companies." The terms offer financial assistance to companies either in the form of a guarantee of interest or of a rebate to the branch line from the net earnings of the main line from traffic inter- changed with the branch line. The rate of guaranteed in- terest is 2)4 per cent per annum on the paid-up share capital, and is subject to the condition that " all surplus profits which may be earned by the company, after paying interest on the paid-up share capital at the rate of 5 per cent shall be equally divided between the Government and the company." ' This guarantee was offered where the State was working the main line. The rebate was of sim- ilar character to that offered in 1893,^ with the exception ^Vide Accounts and Papers, Parliamentary Papers, 1914-16, vol. xlviii. Appendix 30, p. S34, et seq. ^Accounts and Papers, op. cit., 3 (vii) (a) p. 535. ^ Cf. supra, p. 72. 76 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [496 that the combined net earnings of the branch line could make up an amount equal to 5 per cent on the paid-up share capital, instead of 4 per cent, as formerly. Some conception of the effects of the frequent changes in policy which have been summarized in this chapter can be obtained from a study of the following list, which shows the different agencies which have been or are being em- ployed in the construction and operation of the Indian railways : ^ 1. Lines built and operated by guaranteed companies 2. State lines operated by the State 3. State lines leased to companies for operation 4. Lines built and operated by assisted companies 5. Lines owned and operated by Native States 6. Lines owned by Native States and operated by com- panies 7. Lines owned by Native States and operated by the Government of India 8. Foreign lines.'' For a number of reasons, the railways of India have not paid a profit from the very beginning. Some of these reasons have already been mentioned in discussing the reasons for changes in policy in railway construction. The most outstanding reasons for the early deficits might be summarized as follows : — ( i ) the great expense incurred in the construction of the early lines;' (2) the deprecia- tion in the gold value of the rupee;* (3) the protective lines were built in some cases for military purposes, and ' Vide Bell, op. tit., pp. 242-3. 'The foreign lines have a total mileage of 74 and are three in number ; the most important of which is the West of India Portuguese line. 3 Cf. supra, pp. 66, 67. ■• Cf. supra, p. 67. 497] HISTORICAL SKETCH jy in others for protection against famine; some of these were not expected to become self-supporting; (4) the un- developed state of the country and the consequent lack of immediate use of the lines, either for passenger or for goods traffic. It is not unusual for backward countries to learn very gradually the advantages to be obtained from the use of railways. Therefore, it was not until the year 1900 that the rail- ways began to show a profit to the State. The following years brought a great increase in the annual net receipts which came to the State, which averaged in the four years between 1904-5 and 1907-8 about £2,000,000.^ Owing to bad harvests in the year 1908-9, there was a big deficit, but since that time there has been a rapid increase in the net receipts accruing to the State. The fiscal year ending March 31st, 1913, showed a gain to the State from its connection with the railways of £5,490,000. The percentage of the net earnings to capital outlay on all the railways of India has shown considerable fluctua- tion between 1904 and 1914. The following table tells the story: The Percentage of Net Earnings to Capital Outlay — - All Railways in India 1904 1905 1906 190; 5.86 1908 4-33 1909 4.8i tgio 1911 5-87 1912 1913-14 6.00 6.07 596 5.46 6.77 6.19 The general progress which has been made in railway building in India prior to the War, the extent to which the ' Vide Indian Year Book, op. cit., p. 230. 'Accounts and Papers, Parliamentary Papers, 1913-14, vol. xlviii. "Administration Report of the .Railways in India," vol. i, p. 4. 78 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [498 lines are rendering service to the people of India, and the relation existing between total capital outlay and the net earnings for the year 1913-14 is evidenced by the table shown on page 79.^ ^Accounts and Papers, Parliamentary Papers, 1913-1914, vol. xlix, "Statement exhibiting the Moral and Material Progress and Condition of India during the years 1913-14," p. 73. 499] HISTORICAL SKETCH 79 I S> "■« g S 1 S. ^ ci- o c Percent! of Ne ]^arnin on Capi Outlay Open Li On 00 1- ^ x6 fo (*i -"d- -^ r>. t)- m rn y = S u fo tn '^ -^ NO po fo po 00 \0 u-> ■«*; K- N Ol rn 00 00 CN \r^ir\ OC^OO ^j C ■■" ^ t rnOO rC vo ^o 00 w a^ rC •LTt 00 NO y'c-B '> S3^ 'n 00 « to ON ■-< t^ rv. »y^ Ti- m 10 ^ k- ^_ rt ir; CO 00 po n Th pn rt u ip u ■^ ^ C4 *s "d- ro t^ m pn 00 rC~~ Working Expen^es including Steamboat Service r*l <^ vO ro p^ 00 '^ 00 "„ N ^^ "I: 3" to vO -i^ p^ « NO N CO 1-. u-i N -^ ^o IN. in u'.X m t>. N ^ PO ro « N N r^ r^ i^ rn tN, r-» p^ pp) ~~o PO~ m -D m SO •O pp) 'n 'n VO "O 00 rn tT 0_ r; 0^ NO^ ■^ ^ - "**" "". n" 10 N C^ -so T? M ro d 0^ Gro Earn inclui Steam Serv S3 t^ 1-^ rOM N N 00 N Tf P^ o* 0* ro t^ CTN T? "-T iCsO 3 a U \o -"t in ppi 55 i< i-< M •* 'd- « ^ S - f - S (N- r^ r^ !>. fn ro f^ r^ 1-* m^o \i3 vo m fO PO VO NO •a§.l 2 5,^2 = « >,_1 " - = .a a. ■33S-£!og-/3 c 00 N ■*00 PO-O w-i •-^ vD 00 nOnO vo -T Tt i^ -rf r^oo" ON in d d r^ rC o\ 00 ■? c vo -n \o m ■Th r-. ro »n pn 00 10 ON q q ■* ^ On d pn ^°03|-Sx| 00 m — M to pp> th of open the larch, 14. ■* 00 ~ N \0 f^ * 6" «)" M - Th ^ On" «3 - 00 rO'O ■'^ r>» u^ >jn !>* « t-H m ^ . M 00 f1 " '"O^ r4 i- t-^ VO m _S tC» « m" 4.0 4) .S 1« pp> m s ^J P, . 1J ti . ^ s' • ■ • -0 XJ • c . >^ OJ '- 2.5 cfl ■ « >, >> ^ 4 rn Si C/3 ff 1^ J u rt X,X '— U tn .^ i-t t-t « 5 ^ Z 5 2 S-1 -^ . ^<-2 g • c c- CT. ^ OJ ^ C "S „ l> u a> n )-* .T!^ u C C ii -C « u -j; rt '3: w K « .>-5 c3 a "c "o II i 1 c <5 g <;; c "rt "rt ^ *3 *- m S<:p;3 ;3 a u 3 1^ CHAPTER III Some Effects of the past Development of the Means OF Transportation upon the Economic Life OF THE people OF InDIA. The needs of the Indian people for transportation facili- ties have been partially met. It is the intention in this chapter to study some of the effects of this past development of the means of transportation, in order to estimate what might be hoped for in the future when the country is more abundantly supplied with the means of conveyance.' 1 In the field of economics, the use of the word " effect " is considered a dangerous one, because it frequently implies a definite and obvious cause. The student of elementary economics soon learns that while there are economic causes for definite results, yet there is usually not one cause but a diversity of causes w^hich have produced the effect. Besides this, he finds that frequently there is an inter-action between what he has considered cause and effect, so that an effect may be a partial cause, and the cause may be, in part, an effect. In the field of transportation, the difBculty is present in both forms : what may be called an effect of the development of transportation facilities, will have been acted upon and influenced by other forces as well as the means of transportation ; and there is usually a strong reflex action upon the development of the facilities of conveyance from the effects which such means of trans- port may have been the chief cause in producing. For example, one may say that railways have made the industrial development of a cer- tain locality possible, or it may be said that the industrial possibilities of the locality have been responsible for the development of railways. The relation of cause and effect differs with localities and circumstances; sometimes the first statement is more nearly true than the second. In this chapter, when certain effects are attributed to the development of transportation facilities, it is taken for granted that other causes have played their part, and because it is believed that they are minor causes, they are not discussed. In assigning the development of trans- portation as the chief cause, the interaction of forces is not denied. 80 [500 5oi] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT gl The first outstanding effect of the development of better means of transportation is the beginning oif the dissolution of the village as aix economic unit. The evidence that a much wider market is gradually supplanting the old market is cumulative. In the first place, travelers who visit out- lying villages are impresed with the assortment of merchan- dise in the little shops. An increasing amount of the goods kept by the village shop-keeper has not been produced by the village itself but has been imported f romi a neighboring village or city. Much of the entire stock is made up of the essentials for the maintenance of life; vis., flour, ghi,^ spices, rice, gur,^ sugar, oils and cotton goods. Besides these, the village shop contains an increasing amount of miscellaneous goods, much of which has been' imported into India fromi abroad. The most important of such imported goods to be found in the shops of the isolated villages, are mirrors, cutlery, matches, lamps and lanterns, sewing thread, beads, glass bangles, and general hardware. The factor common to all these goods is that they are light in weight, so that the lack of good transportation facilities has not been an* insuperable barrier to importing them into the isolated villages. The importation of such merchandise of light weight is the first evidence of the dissolution of the village as an economic unit. Furthermore, there is a strong presumption that the people of the village have been^ furnishing some part of the increased demand for transportation, as revealed by the increased ton- mileage oif the railways from 1909 to 191 5-16, as well as l>y the increase in distance, a ton of goods was carried. To show that passengers as well as freight have been adding ' ghi is the native clarified butter. 'gur is made in the villages from sugar cane by boiling down the juice and allowing the molasses to remain, so that the product has been called " unclarified sugar." 82 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [502 to the demand for transportation facilities, the unit mile- Freight-ton Mileage of Goods (in thousands) igog 9,340,441 1913-14 15,^3,235 1910 12,092,916 1914-15 15,225,957 1911 13,358,364 1915-16 17,157,841 1912 15,628,595 1916-17 19,825,901 Average Miles a Ton of Goods was Cakried 1909 153.37 1913-14 182.11 1910 184.33 1914-1S 188.04 1911 187.44 1915-16 207.98 1912 19915 1916-17 230.08 Unit Mileage of Passengers (i» thousqnds) 1909 12,364,579 1913-14 16,614,088 1910 13,432,477 1914-1S 16,022,849 191 1 14,372,943 191S-16 16,528,646 1913 15,318,872 1916-X7 17,846,064 age of passMigers for these years is also given.'- The above figures show that the ton-mileage increased in the years from 1909 to 1916-17 by 100 per cent, and that the per- centage of increase in the average distance a ton was hauled was slightly over 50. These high percentages of increase must have had a great influence upon the markets, tending to enlarge them either for production or consumption or both. When the distribution of the population is examined, it becomes evident that the proportion o^f the urban population to the total is only 9.5 per cent.* According to the census of 191 1, the population in towns and villages is distributed! as follows : * ^Iitdian Year Book, 1919, pp. 222-3. 2 Indian Year Book, 1918, p. 396. 'Statistics of British India, Government of India (Calcutta, 1919), vol. iv, pp. 44-45. 503] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 83 Under 500 people 5SI.897 villages 500 to 1000 107,533 " 1000 to 2000 45,841 " 2000 to sooo 14,642 " 5000 to 10,000 1,615 towns 10,000 to 20,000 485 " 20,000 to 50,000 178 " Above 50,000 75 " With such a large part of the total population living in the villages, the strong presumption is raised that the villages! as economic units, have been greatly effected by the increased demand for transportation. This presumption is streng- thened by a reference to the source of the gross eamingsl of 1915-16 from the freight traffic. Eighty-five per cent of these earnings were received for the hauling of general merchandise.^ Another fact in the economic situation in India leads the investigator to believe that the development of transporta- tion is affecting the village as an economic unit ; namely, the great increase in the exports and imports of the country as a whole. No student of Indian economics will deny that the chief cause for this increase has been the development of the means of transport. The following figures, covering almost the entire life of Indian railways, show the increase in the value of the nation's foreign trade (including both exports and imports).^ The first and the last figures are based on averages for three years, and the remaining on averages for five years. ^Statistics of British India, Government of India (Calcutta, 1918), vol. i, p. 197. 'Review of the Trade of India in 1916-17, Parliamentary Papers, 1918, pt. i. The figures are taken from a chart facing page i. Because they have been taken from a chart, they are only approximately correct. 84 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [504 1866-69 Rs. 83 crores 1889-94 Rs. 178 crores 1869-74 90 " 1894-99 183 1874-79 100 " 1^-1904 210 " 1879-84 128 " 1904-09 285 1884-89 ISO " 1909-14 375 " 1914-17 Rs. 356 crores The chief significance of these figures, relating to the village as an economiic unit, lies in the fact that the bulk of India's exports is agricultural produce and raw materials, mainly unmanufactured, which are produced in the villages. The actual figures showing the value of the various articles of export and import for 1916-17 are as follows : ^ Exports Imports 1. Food, drink and tobacco £ 37.SS2,Sii i 18,164,971 2. Raw materials and produce and articles mainly unmanufactured £ 65,866,951 £ 6,678,261 3. Articles wholly or mainly manufactured £50,562,704 £72,974,603 4. Miscellaneous and unclassified £ 1,453,555 £ 1,930,178 It is obvious from the above figures that India, through the development of transportation, has a contact with the outside world, which, with normal growth, will tend to de- stroy the economic independence which the village has had. This foreign trade is affecting both the production and the consumption of the village people. As to consumption, the amazing manner in which articles of light weight find their way into isolated villages, has already been mentioned.* But besides these articles of a miscellaneous character, the staple commodities, upon which the ordinary standard of living depends, are rapidly increasing in those villages which are within reach of the means of transport. Yam and tex- tile fabrics form 40 per cent of the total value oi the im- ports into India, and foreign cotton goods are found on the ^Tables relating to the Trade of British India — 1912-13 to 1916-17, Parliamentary Papers (London, 1919). PP- 7. i3- 2 Cf. supra, p. 81. 505] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 85 shelves of the majority of the dealers in the towns and villages. The quantity of imported sugar accounts for an- other 10 per cent of the total value of imports. The proof that the £10,300,000 spent for foreign sugar is influencing the village consumption lies in the effect of the competition of the foreign sugar with the native gur. Cheap foreign sugar has so influenced the consumption of gwr that students of village life fear that the present taste for gur will die out, and the production of sugar cane in India will be endan- gered.^ That India's foreign trade is affecting the production of the village is brought out sO' clearly in the " Report of the Indian Industrial Commiission-1916-18," that one paragraph will be quoted in full.^ Turning in the first place to the rural areas, we find an increas- ing degree of local specialization in particular crops, especially in those grown for export. Cotton is now no longer planted in small patches in almost every village where conditions are not absolutely prohibitive, but is concentrated in areas which are specially adapted to its various types. The dry plains of cen- tral and western India are admirably suited to a short-stapled but prolific kind ; while the canal-fed zones of the Punjab, the United Provinces and Sind are producing an increasing quan- tity of longer-stapled types, which are also grown in the re- tentive soil and moister climate of Gujarat and in the well- irrigated areas of Madras. The peculiarly favourable climate of Bengal has tempted the ryots to extend their jute cultivation, often at the expense of their foodstuffs, while sugarcane is disappearing from tracts not specially suited for it. A visible sign of this movement may be seen in the abandoned stone cane mills lying near villages in the arid plains of Central India, ' Vide Indian Year Book, 1918, p. 306. ^Report of Indian Industrial Commission, 1916-18, Parliamentary Papers (London, 1919), p. 8. 86 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [506 which now prefer to keep their scanty stores of water for other crops and pay for their sugar by the sale of their cotton. The people have been led to make this change by the cheap railway and steamer transport, and by the construction of roads, which, while facilitating the introduction of foreign imports, also render available to the farmer in his distant and land- locked village a large share of the price offered by far-off nations for articles which once merely supplied the needs of Indian rural life. Markets have sprung up on or near the railway, where the foreign exporters or the larger Indian collecting firms have their agencies ; and the ryot is now not far behindhand in his knowledge of the fluctuations in the world- prices of the principal crops which he grows. It is evident, therefore, that the development of the means of transportation has rendered the Indian village less in- dependent as an economic unit, than it was in past genera- tions.^ This widening of the markets, with the concomitant changes in consumption and production, might be considered the national beginning of an industrial revolution.* The second outstanding effect of the expansion of the means of transportation follows naturally from the breaking- up of the economic self-sufificiency of the village : prices tend to move toward equality, both with reference to different times in the same place, and to different places at the same time. In short, the introduction of the means of transport brings equalization of prices, both locally and temporally. Under ideal conditions, the difference in prices of a com- 1 " The development of the means of communication is perhaps the most important economic event of the nineteenth century, and the multiplication of metalled roads and railways is alone sufficient to ex- plain the break-up of the old industrial organization, in which every village in India was self-sufficing." Morison, Sir Theodore, The In- dustrial Organization of an Indian Province (London, 1906), p. 215. 2 Cf. Cheney, Edward P., An Introduction to the Industrial and Social History of England (Chautauqua Press, 1910) , pp. 153-4. so?] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 87 modity in two places should not be more than the cost of getting the commodity from one place to the other. Re- garded from the social-benefit point of view, both of these forms oif equalization of prices indicate an economic situa- tion which is highly desirable: it benefits man both as a producer and as a consumer. Such a levelling of prices has taken place in India, when two places have been connected with effective means of transportation. Long before railways were introduced into India, the following table was complied, and shows the varia- tion of prices in two places about 500 miles apart : ^ Cost per ton. Difference. Percentage of difference. In Berar. At Coringa. Rice 124 Rs 45 Rs 79 Rs I7S Cotton 186 32s 139 75 Wheat 31 66 35 "3 Salt 105 30 70 200 The effect of the introduction of railways upon the varia- tion in prices in different places at the same time, can be seen very clearly from the following table of prices in Burma : ^ 1 Vide Cotton, Lt.-Col. A., Public Works in India (London, 1854), p. 93 Lieut.-iColonel Cotton quotes the table from a paper read by Mr. Ashburner before the Asiatic Society in 1837. Berar is in Central India and Coringa is on the Eastern coast at the mouth of the Godaveri River. It will be noticed that Mr. Ashburner, in working out his per- centages of the differences has favored round-numbers. ''Prices and Wages in India, Government of India (Calcutta, 1893), pp. lo-il. The attention of the author was called to the list of prices given in the second and third columns, by Mr. A. S. Tostlebe, M. A., Instructor of Economics in the University of Vermont. Mr. Tostlebe happened to be reading the lists of prices in different places in Burma, 88 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [508 (Wheat prices in seers ^ per rupee) Percentage of Year Rangoon Prome Difference Difference 1861 12.95 4-29 8.66 201.8 The average 1862 12.95 452 8.43 186.5 1863 I2.Q2 4.20 7.82 186. 1 percentage of 1864 11.07 4-29 6.78 158.0 1865 11,55 4-03 7-52 186.6 difference 1866 12.08 4.29 7.79 181.5 1867 12.02 6.34 5.68 89.5 until the in- 1868 12.02 6.24 578 926 1869 12.08 6.05 6x)3 99.6 troduction of 1870 11.07 6.43 4.64 72.1 1871 railways in 1872 1873 9.Q4 1877 was 1874 9.46 1875 1786 3454 16.68 93-3 129-2 1876 26.34 27.16 .82 3.1 1877 The year when the two places were connected by railway. 1878 9.01 7.62 1.39 18.2 The 1879 8.39 7.09 1.30 18.3 igSo 9.83 7.12 2.71 38.0 average 1881 I3.gi8 11.26 2.72 24.1 1882 14.13 14.13 0.00 00.0 percentage of 1883 13.33 II.07 2.26 20.4 1884 14.25 13.57 -68 5.0 difference 1885 18.31 17.69 .62 3.5 1886 13.43 12.58 .85 6.7 after railways 1887 10.53 12.06 1.53 14.5 1888 11.08 9.84 1.24 12.6 were built was 1889 10.73 10.85 -12 i-i i8go 7-49 io-8i 3.32 44-3 16.5 1891 8.19 11.46 3.37 41.1 The above table also shows in a general way that the year- to-year prices in Prome fluctuated less after the railway was built than was the case before the line was opened. The and concluded, without any additional knowledge on the subject, that a railway must have been opened between Rangoon and Prome in 1876. The Irrawaddi section of the Burma Railway between the two places was opened in 1877. 1 A seer is the approximate equivalent of two pounds. vO at P vO on 'i V ^ UJ ' i 1 3NIWVJ. 3Nn Nww HUM a3iD3NNO0 -andivawvs AVMiivb >-a Q3i03NNO3 andsviis ON* andivy 3NIWVJ 509] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 89 average of differences from year to year in the eleven years (for which prices are quoted) before the introduction of the railway connection is 3.58 seers per rupee/ For the four- teen years after 1877, the year-to-year variation in pricesi averages only 2.06 seers to the rupee. Because of the in- ability to procure the prices of wheat in Prome from 1871 to 1874, conclusions can not be drawn as positively as would be the case of the list were complete. The figures raise the presumption that the railway connections tended to reduce local and temporal variation in prices. The chart facing this page shows even miore clearly the effect of the introduction of railways upon the equalization of prices. The prices of wheat are shown from 1861 to 1 91 6, as obtained in the three centers, Bilaspur, Raipur and Sambalpur.'* The towns all lie in the Central Provinces. The distance between Bilaspur and Raipur is 68.52 miles. The two places were connected by the main line of the Bengal-Nagpur Railway in 1889. Sambalpur lies off the main line at a distance of 30 miles. A branch was built, connecting this city with the main line in 1893. Sambalpur is 126.8 miles distant from Bilaspur. The tendencies to) temporal and local equalization of wheat prices after the lines of railway were built is e-vident from the chart. As a study of the chart would lead one to believe, the three towns passed through two hard famines.' The indication of an isolated and narrow market in India ' From a statistical point of view, this average is not a fair measure of the stability of prices before the railway was built, because of the great influence exerted on the average by the very large fluctuations of 187S and 1876.- On the other hand it is a fundamental point of this argument that with railway connections with the outside world, such great fluctuations can not occur. ^Prices and Wages in India, 1893, 1918. 2 Cf. infra, p. 95. go INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [510 is the variation between the harvest and market prices. The former is, as the name signifies, the price at which the grain sells at the time when the crops are gathered. The latter is the average price at which the grain has sold throughout the year. If the crop is not composed of perishable goods; if the farmers are free agents and are able to sell their pro- duce to the highest bidder; if they are well informed and alive to their own advantage; and if there is a wide market in which the goods can be sold, then there should not be much divergence between the market and the harvest prices. But in India, this difference between the two prices has been great, especially before the introduction of railways.^ The chief cause has not been the ignorance or indifference of the ryot, but rather the small market which tends to place him at the mercy of the baniya,'' who has, until the advent of co- operative societies and better means of communication, en- joyed double monopoly: that O'f advancing money to the farmers at a very high rate of interest, and that of being the only bidder for the harvest when it was gathered. The past history of the Indian farmiers has shown that an abun- dant harvest could be almost as disastrous as a poor harvest. With reference to this point, Mr. K. L. Datta says : ' Before the advent of railways, in remote areas, whenever pro- duction was plentiful, prices went down very low because of the difficulty and, in many cases, the impossibility of transport- ing it profitably to a place where prices were higher. On the other hand, whenever the crops failed, prices rose exceptionally high owing to the difficulty of importing supplies from the out- 'This point has been splendidly verified by the facts and statistics brought forward by iSir Theodore Morison in his book, The Industrial Organisation of an Indian Province, pp. 215-229, 235-238. ' The baniya is the village shop-keeper as well as the money-lender. ' Datta, K. L., Enquiry into the Rise of Prices in India, Government of India (Calcutta, 1914), vol. i, p. 78. 51 1 ] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 91 side. Railways have now linked up different parts of the coun- try and have constituted it into, as it were, one market. . , . It was most interesting in our local enquiries to observe how a general leveling of prices was taking place throughout the areas intersected by railways and also how local prices are now-a- days greatly affected by prices in distant parts of the country. FAMINE PRICES The effect of the growth of the means of transport upon prices is seen most clearly in famine times.^ If there is a strong tendency toward equality of prices in times of short- age of food supplies, then there is reasonable proof that sup- plies have been able to flow from the places of greatest abun- dance to the localities of greatest need. Such a flow of goods can not occur where the means of transportation are inadequate. A famine occurs where the productive operations of a locality have been interrupted, so that there is a shortage of the means of subsistence. In India, the most common cause of famines in the last century has been the failure of the rain-fall at the monsoon period, so that the cultivation of the soil becomes impossible. Because the country is chiefly dependent upon agriculture, the distress resulting from) droughts is much greater than would be the case if in- dustry were more diversified. The effects of the failure of the monsoons is still furthur intensified because agricul- ture does not yield a flow of goods but a seasonal return. The suffering and mortality which have resulted from past famines have been due in part to the inability of the people ' This discussion of the contribution made by the means of trans- port toward the relief of suffering and death, is not meant to be a treatment of the entire subject of famines in India. Here we are con- cerned with the possibility of a fairly even distribution of the nation's production of the necessities [and a resulting tendency toward equal prices] in famine times. 92 INDIA'S DEMAND FOR TRANSPORTATION [512 to accumulate a surplus of supplies or money, which would tide themi over to a more productive season. The consensus of opinion of different famine commissions and others hag been that the Indian ryots have not stored large quantities of grain when seasons were favorable, and so avoided want in time of scarcity. Theodore Morison draws his con- clusion on this point from statistical studies of the prices of food-grain in the United Provinces. He says : The fluctuations in the price of food-grains before 1861 further prove beyond a doubt that large stores of grain were not kept in those days from one harvest to another. Had large stores of grain been in existence, some portion of them would have been attracted to market by high prices, and so the rise would have been checked. This was clearly not the case ; the most striking characteristics of the prices from 1804 to 1861 is their sudden and violent fluctuations.^ The assistance rendered to famine-stricken areas by im- proved means of transport has been a gradual process. Be- fore eflfective means of transport existed, it sometimes hap- pened that people of wealth died of starvation, not because they did not have money, but because they could not buy food at any price . For example, it is reported that in the famine of 1344-45 in the Deccan, " the emperor Muhammad was unable to obtain the necessities for his household." ' This situation has passed away throughout India. People who have money are able to buy grain. The next stage in the assistance given in famine times by means of transporta- tion is miarked by the presence of grain in limited quanti- ties in places of scarcity, so that the rich are able to buy, but there is little local or temporal equalization of prices. Examples of this stage are still to be found in toiwns and ^ Morison, Sir Theodore, op. cit., p. 296. 'Cyclopaedia of India, op. cit., vol. i, p. 107a. 513] EFFECTS OF THE PAST DEVELOPMENT 93 villages which are isolated, and unconnected with lines of transportation . The final stage is that to be found today in localities which are closely linked up with distant parts of the country, by improved facilities of communication and transport, so that the difference in the prices of the famine- stricken areas and of those where grain has been produced in abundance is not much greater than the cost of transpor- tation and middlemen's profits. The means by which the Government of India has valiantly striven tO' mitigate the suffering and disaster of famines might be summed up under the following heads: (i) The extension of irrigation, so that the people may be independent of the monsoons at least, for a time. Much splendid relief has been rendered by the extension of irriga- tion; i. e. the building of the great canal systems, tanks and wells. It is, however, a generally accepted conclusion that India can never hope for a complete solution of the problem of famines through irrigation.^ Morison says, . . . within certain areas artificial irrigation has been highly successful; the survey shows no less clearly the inevitable limitations of artificial irrigation. The day does not seem to be near at hand, in India or anywhere else, when agriculture can be rendered altogether independent of the weather. While irrigation canals, wells and tanks can never remove the danger of crop failure from the whole of India, yet the localities in which artificial irrigation exists have beent able to furnish a limited amount of food for the people living in the areas