The dats shows when this volume was taken. All books not in use for instruction or re- search are limited to all borrowers. V61umes of periodi- cals and of pamphlets comprise so many sub- jects,that they are held in the library as much as possible. For spe- cial purposes they are given out for a limited time. Graduates and sen- iors are allowed five, volumes for twoweeks. Other students may have two vols, from the circulating library for two weeks. Books not needed during recess periods should be returned to the library, or arrange- ments made for their return during borrow- er's absence, if wanted: . Books needed by more than one person are held on the reserve list. Books of special value and^gift books, ~"**£™ .Abe giver wishes " M V< to Cornell University Library arV15524 The growth of church institutions olin.anx 3 1924 031 320 439 The original of this book is in the Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924031320439 THE GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. THE GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. BY THE REV. EDWIN HATCH, M.A. D.D., READER IN ECCLESIASTICAL HISTORY IN THE UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD. NEW YORK : THOMAS WHITTAKER, 2 & 3, BIBLE HOUSE. 1887. H A. 6o33 c n A, ffti^ PREFACE. ' I "HE present work is an endeavour to give "an answer to questions which are fre- quently asked in regard to the apparently wide differences between the primitive and the modern forms of some Christian institutions. It is designed less for scholars than for general readers who are interested in theological sub- jects. Its aim is to be not controversial, but historical. It is a summary of the results at which the writer has arrived from an inde- pendent study of original sources, and the meagreness with which some important sub- jects are treated is due to the fact that it is intended to be supplemented hereafter by a more elaborate work, which the writer has for some time had in preparation. PREFACE. And since the work is thus designed for general readers, and is a summary of results rather than a detailed explanation of the facts upon which they are based, the writer has not thought it desirable to encumber the pages with more than the most necessary references to his authorities. But since the scantiness of the references may convey to some minds an erroneous impression that the evidence also is scanty, the writer thinks it proper to add that he is not aware of having made any state- ment which he is not also ready to support by sufficient proofs. The work has the secondary aim of en- deavouring to stimulate students who have leisure for historical study to give more atten- tion than hitherto to the wide field which lies before them in the ecclesiastical history of the centuries which lie between the fall of the Roman Empire and the political settlement of mediaeval Europe. Oxford, March \tth, 1887. CONTENTS CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTORY. The justification of the fact that Christian institutions have not always been what they are now is to be found in the nature of Christianity, The justification of the particular changes is to be found in Church history. The present work is designed to show in outline the historical circumstances under which some of the more prominent institu- tions of modern Christianity came to exist, and which form the justification of their existence .... pp. I — 8 THE DIOCESE. What is the origin of the modern diocese ? How was it that the majority of Christian Churches in the West came to have an incomplete organization ? The answer is to be found in the circumstances of the original Christian communities of Gaul and Spain. They were Roman, and not native, and in the cities rathef than in the country. The Teutonic conquest at first both preserved and accentuated this state of things. The organization of the Church preserved that of the empire ; the Romans who remained were CONTENTS. reluctant to break through the lines of that organization by multiplying bishoprics ; and the power and prestige of the bishops, which increased as the old Roman party found in them a political as well as an ecclesiastical centre, came in time to render such a multiplication of bishoprics impossible, pp. 9 — 15 In Germany and England the bishops were at first missionary bishops, and Gaul and Spain furnished the model upon which organization proceeded when the missionary character of the Churches had passed awayi .... pp. 15, 16 CHAPTER II. THE DIOCESAN BISHOP. How was it that the officers of one community came to have juris- diction over those of another? The common answer that presbyters were detached from the bishop's Church to take charge of outlying congregations covers only a small proportion of the facts. In the majority of cases in the West communities grew up independently of the bishop's Church, and their officers were appointed by the owners of the church-buildings. The danger to both faith and morals which this system caused led to a reformation, which was the result of the joint action of Church and State. Two principles which had long been recognised in the East, but which had been commonly disregarded in the West, were finally established : 1. That all the clergy within the gan, or county, should be subordinate to the bishop of the county town. 2. That all the bishops within what had been a Roman province should be co-ordinated into a single body, with the bishop of the metropolis at their head . . pp. 17 — 32 The first of these points was secured by a double provision : (i.) that every year the clergy should report themselves to the bishop ; (ii.) that every year the bishop should make a circuit of his district for the purpose of (a) preaching, (i) confirming, and ( c. 33) tells founders of churches that they have no rights in the property of the churches which they have founded, but that the disposal of it belongs to the bishop. The later canon law on the point is based on a letter of Gregory the Great to Felix of Messina, in which he expressly denies to the owner any right in the church, except the right of admission " which is due to all Christians in common." 1 The second claim had a longer history, which must be traced in greater detail. The bishop had been from the earliest times the chief administrator of Church property. Even if it be not true that such administration was in the primitive Church his primary function, it is demonstrably true that when Christianity was recognised by the State, and ' S. Greg., M. Efiist, 2. 5, ad Felic. Messan. (quoted by Gratian, c. 26, Caus. XVI., qu. 7, as from Gelasius). 52 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. the churches were made capable of holding property, it was regarded as an inherent and important part of his office. When country churches began to receive gifts of land, the city bishop was the only person who could legally hold them. In some cases he was not slow to claim them. However strongly a man might desire to specially benefit the church of his own district, and however much the ministers of such a church might need support, the city bishop was legally entitled to claim whatever was offered. The most conclusive evidence of this is that which is afforded by the Council of Carpentras in a.d. 527. "A complaint has reached us,' ' say the Acts of that council, " that the offerings which are bestowed by certain of the faithful on parish churches are so taken possession of by some bishops that little or nothing is left to the churches on which they were bestowed ; it seems to us to be fair and reasonable that if the church of the city over which the bishop presides is so well supplied that, by the favour of Christ, it does not want anything, the offerings to parish churches should reasonably be allotted to the clergy of those FIXED TENURE OF THE PARISH PRIEST. 53 churches, or for their repair ; if, on the other hand, it appears that the bishop has many expenses and but little property, only so much should be reserved for the parish churches as is reasonably sufficient for the clergy, or for their repair, and the bishop should claim the surplus for himself." This canon fully re- cognises the legal right of the bishop, but it marks the transition to the later state of things in its recommendation that the exercise of that right should be limited to cases in which the necessities of his church required it. But the reasonable course which this canon recommends was not always taken. A hundred years later the Fourth Council of Toledo (a.d. 633, c. 33) applies to the action of bishops in the matter the apostolic words, " Avarice is the root of all evils." " Many of the faithful, for the love of Christ and the martyrs, build churches in the dioceses of bishops, and endow them with offer- ings, but the bishops take the offerings away and convert them to their own uses ; the consequence is that the ministers fail, since they lose their means of support, and the ruins of decaying churches are not repaired." Twenty- 54 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. two years later a council of the same province (the Ninth Council of Toledo, c. i.) took the stronger course of empowering the heirs of the founder of a church to watch over the proper appropriation of its funds, and to bring an avari- cious bishop before the metropolitan or the king. But gradually, and before the last-mentioned councils, a rule had been growing up that the bishop should have a third of the revenues of parishes. There are many traces of the rule in subsequent times, but there is not enough evidence to show to what extent it was generally observed. In North Italy at the beginning of the ninth century there was an express enact- ment against giving any part of the tithes of parishes to the bishop ; but the custom is found several years later on the Rhine and in France. At the great ecclesiastical conference of Worms in 829, and also in the Council of Paris in the same year, the right of the bishop to a fourth, not a third, of parish churches is recognised ; but the bishops are urged to remit their share unless they are in special need of it. 1 Like 1 Pertz., M.G.H., i., p. 335, c. 5 ; 6 Cone. Paris., c. 31. FIXED TENURE OF THE PARISH PRIEST. 55 almost all attempts to fix an unvarying rule for constantly varying circumstances, this attempt to give the bishop a definite share in the property of outlying churches became unwork- able. The growing importance and wealth of most city churches made such a share unnecessary as part of a bishop's revenue ; and at the same time the extinction of the remains of paganism, the inclusion of almost all the inhabited parts of the West in the network of the parochial system, and the consequent large increase in the number of the parochial clergy, provided ample channels for the expenditure of the local funds in the localities from which they were derived. The fixed ratio of revenues was replaced by presents in recognition of the bishop's rights. Such presents tended to be rather involuntary than voluntary, and not unfrequently became oppressive exactions. Sometimes they were forbidden by law, and sometimes they were regulated ; for example, in the Parliament which was held by Charles the Bald at Toulouse in 844, it was enacted that a bishop should not require from a parish more than a bushel of barley, a keg of wine, and a pig worth six 56 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. pence, or six pence in lieu of it. 1 In time these payments in kind were all commuted for money fees, and the ancient right of a bishop to a third of all parochial revenues has dwindled in modern times to the payment of small fees to an archdeacon or a bishop on the occasion of his visitation. In this way the detached congregations, after having been brought into the ecclesiastical system, retained or regained no small amount of liberty ; in this way also the ministers of such congregations, after having been brought under the control of the city bishop, obtained, on the one hand, a tenure which was not dependent on the caprice of their patron, and, on the other hand, revenues which were not dependent on the caprice of their bishop. " From the begin- ning it was not so ; " the changed circumstances of Western Europe compelled a change in the relations of ministers to their congregations, and 1 Karoli II., Synodus apud Tolosam, c. 2, Pertz, i., p. 378, "unum modium ordei atque unum modium vim . . . etfrisc- hingam sex valentem denarios aut sex pro ea denarios : " the whole might be commuted for a payment of " duos solidos." FIXED TENURE OF THE PARISH PRIEST, n of congregations to one another. The eccle- siastical system was elastic enough to cover new needs ; and, being elastic, it changed its form. The parochial system grew up underneath the cover of the episcopal system, and as an exten- sion of it. The assignment of separate revenues to the separate parishes prevented an accumula- tion of enormous funds in the hands of the city bishops, which would have been sufficiently dangerous to the State to have brought about their overthrow. The virtual independence of parish ministers, so long as they conformed to general rules, combined the advantages which flow from the multiplication of centres of activity with those which flow from centralised administration. It would be a needless and probably also an untrue optimism to maintain that whatever happened was the ideal best ; but it is none the less clear that the result was not an abnormal outgrowth which needed to be up- rooted, but a legitimate outcome of the action of the ordinary forces of our moral nature within the Christian sphere. THE BENEFICE. IV. THE BENEFICE. T N the sixth and seventh centuries the property of the Church in the West had enormously increased. The number of churches and monasteries was multiplied, and every church and monastery came to have property of its own. With the spread of Christianity in the country districts, and also with the tendency on the part of the survivors of Roman families, in the countries which had been most thickly planted with Roman colonies, to make the Church their heir, there grew up a strong revival of the belief that the gift of money to the Church, and thereby to the clergy and the poor, was a sure means of saving the soul. No small proportion of the deeds of grant which remain, and of the " formulas " or draft forms for such deeds, recite by way of preamble 62 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. that the grant is made by the donor " for the benefit of my soul, and that I may obtain pardon of my sins." The result was that the Church became the richest landowner in Western Europe. The modes in which gifts were made to the Church were of various kinds, and as they all have a bearing upon subsequent times, it is necessary to distinguish them from one another. i. The simplest and most general mode was that of donation in a man's lifetime. This was effected by word of mouth before witnesses ; and a written instrument, though not essential to its validity, yet was a convenient record of the fact. In Teutonic communities it is pro- bable that no other mode of gift was at first recognised by law ; donation to a church by will seems to have no legal effect, and even if it had, the Church naturally preferred an irrevocable gift during a man's life to the uncertainty of a testamentary disposition. i. Where Roman law prevailed, that is to say, among the descendants of the Roman population, even where Teutonic law was the THE BENEFICE. 63 general law of the land, donations by will continued to exist. Such donations were revocable during the lifetime of the donor, and seem to have been not always respected after his death, inasmuch as some extant forms of a will bind both the donor and his heirs by a penalty not to revoke or disregard it. In course of time donations by will came to be recognised in Teutonic communities ; but the fact of their Roman origin is shown by their being- drawn not after Teutonic but after Roman forms of donation ; and the fact of their slow recognition is indicated, among other proofs, by the expressions of doubt which Charles the Great referred to his adviser Alcuin. 1 3. It was probably in consequence of this want of power to prevent revocation during a man's lifetime and of the presumption of Teutonic law in favour of his heirs after his death that a third mode of donation became more frequent than any other, namely, donation with reservation to the donor of the usufruct of the property during his lifetime. It is. Alcuini Epist, 253, ed. JafK (127, ed. Froben.) in the Mon. Carolina, p. 806. 64 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. probable that this mode was in the first instance not recognised by law, inasmuch as the element in the transfer of property to which the Northern races attached most importance, and which underlies the modern " induction " of a clerk to his benefice, was necessarily absent from it. But in the extant forms of deed in which property is thus given to the Church there is an express stipulation that the donation shall hold good in spite of the absence of this corporal surrender of the property; and some- times the donor requires that if his heirs bring a lawsuit for the recovery of the property, they shall pay a heavy fine. Sometimes the legal difficulties of this mode of donation were over.- come by making the donation absolute, and adding a petition, which the new owner, that is the Church, was morally, if not legally, bound to grant, that the original owner should continue to enjoy the use of the property without power to alienate it, and with the obligation to keep it in good order. It was natural that this tendency to endow churches and monasteries with lands on a large scale, and thus to create a power which might THE BENEFICE. 65 be formidable to the State, should meet with checks on the part of the secular authorities. We consequently find that both in the Teutonic codes, and in the adaptations of the civil law which were in force among the Roman element in Teutonic countries, stringent safeguards and limitations were introduced in the interests of a man's family. In some cases the right of donation was limited to those who had no children ; in others no donation was valid unless it had received the sanction of the head of the State ; any person who had a claim upon an estate had to be consulted before it could be alienated, and if his consent were not obtained, he could bring a suit for its restitution. The existence of this tendency to put difficulties in the way of the acquisition of property by the Church is also shown by the frequent enact- ments of councils in reference to it. The penalty of excommunication was constantly imposed upon those who so far " despised their own souls " as to endeavour to retain what their relatives had bequeathed to the " servants of God " and the poor. 1 1 E.g., the Second Council of Lyons, in a.d. 567, c. 1, " de 5 66 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. But in spite of all difficulties and restrictions, the landed property of the Church became enormous. The bishops in a large proportion of cases were the chief landowners in their dioceses. They kept the administration of the property for the most part in their own hands, with the help of a vice-lord, " vicedominus," or " economus," who is frequently mentioned in connection with the archdeacon, the latter being the bishop's deputy in spiritual, as the former was in temporal affairs. The lands were worked by serfs and slaves. Of this there are abounding proofs. The slaves were slaves in the strict sense of the term, " chattels " who passed with the land from one owner to another. It was not until long afterwards that the public opinion of the Church declared itself against slavery in any form ; and it may reasonably be inferred that the condition of church-slaves was easier than that of the slaves of private owners. quibus rebus si quis animtz sua contemptor aliquid alienare prsesumpserit, usque ad emendationis suae vel restitutionis rei ablatse a consortio ecclesiastico vel omnium Christianorum convivio labeatur alienus " : other similar enactments are Cone. Agath., a.d. 504, c. 4 ; 1 Cone. Arvern., a.d. 535, c. 14 ; 4 Cone. Aurel., a.d. 541, c. 14 ; 3 Cone. Paris, a.d. 557, c. I. THE BENEFICE. 67 One reason for this inference is that such slaves could become clerks without the difficulties which impeded the ordination of ordinary slaves. There was probably also a more frequent manumission of such slaves ; and their condition when made free was the better because they were under the special protection of the Church to which they had belonged. It may be interesting to quote one of the extant draft forms of manumission : — " In the name of God, N., though a sinner, yet, by the grace of God, bishop, wishing to obtain the mercy of God, who says, ' Blessed are the merciful, for they shall obtain mercy,' and whose Divine word admonishes us by His prophet, ' Let the oppressed go free and break every burden ' (Isa. lviii. 6), with the consent of our brethren and fellow-citizens, . . . have agreed that we ought to pay a tithe of all the slaves of our church. Therefore we set free from the present day M., a slave of our church, whom we know, as the prophet says, to be 1 oppressed,' so that from henceforth he may live for himself, act for himself, work for him- self, become really free, as if he had been born 68 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. of free parents, and have granted to him all the property which he either has or can acquire. And, moreover, if he uses the defence and pro- tection of our Church, let him know that it is given him not to impose slavery upon him anew, but to defend him." 1 As time went on, and the property became still larger, the personal administration of property by bishops became, to a great extent, impracticable. There grew up a system which has left its mark not only upon the whole Western Church, but also upon the whole economical condition of Europe to the present day. It was the system of lending lands, with or without the payment of a rent, and for a definite or indefinite period, to persons who undertook to cultivate them and enjoyed the usufruct of them, and who came to form an intermediate class between the owner and the actual tillers of the soil. The usufruct of church lands was sometimes thus given to laymen and sometimes to clerks. When given to clerks, it was given without the payment of a rent in 1 Formula Bituricenses, No. 8, in K. Zeumer's Formula Merowingici et Karolini ami, pars prior, p. 171. THE BENEFICE. 69 return : the property was assigned for their maintenance during their lifetime, subject to a power of recall by the bishop in case of their misbehaviour. The clerks were still in theory paid out of the funds of the bishop's church ; but instead of receiving money or food, they received a farm. This was the case also with the canons of a cathedral when the canonical system began ; and hence the later use of " praebenda," which originally meant " rations," and ultimately was applied to the estate which produced the rations. When church lands were lent to a layman they were sometimes, even if infrequently, lent without the payment of a rent, but more com- monly, and, after the middle of the eighth century, invariably, lent on condition of a rent being paid to the Church. The amount of such rent was often very small ; but it was at any rate a recognition of ownership. In some cases the land was thus lent to powerful men to secure their support, or to the relatives of a bishop or abbot as a private favour. The records of the Abbey of Fontenelle, for example, relate that a certain Abbot Teutsind (734 — 738) 70 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. gave almost a third of the estates to his relatives and to courtiers. 1 There are deeds extant which provide for the payment of what was obviously the nominal rent of a few pounds of wax ; and the fact that the system was some- times abused is also indicated by the existence of clauses in deeds of gift providing that the land given shall be used for the benefit of the Church, and shall not be lent by the bishop to secular persons. One of the many survivals of the system in modern times is the payment of rent on saints' days. It was on certain great festivals, and especially the festival of the patron saint, that persons would naturally go from country parts to the central church of the dis- trict, and it was, therefore, convenient that on those occasions they should take their rent with them ; hence it was that " Lady-day," being the festival of one to whom a large proportion of churches came to be dedicated, became a com- mon rent day. Sometimes this lending of church lands was not voluntary, but compulsory. The head of 1 Gesta Abbat. Fontanett., c. 10, in Pertz, M.G.H., Scriptt., ii., p. 282. THE BENEFICE. 71 the State resumed possession of them, and assigned them to his soldiers. In all cases rent was paid for such lands, nor was the proceeding held in the first instance to be objectionable. The most important instance of it was resolved upon at the Council or Parliament of Lestines (" Concilium Liftinense ") in 743, at which Boniface was present. Neither he nor Pope Zachary, who wrote on the subject, seem to have complained of it, or considered that it was otherwise than necessary. But by one of those misunderstandings of history which gather force as they roll on, this compulsory tenancy came to be viewed as a robbery ; the facts that the exigencies of State were imperative, and that rent was paid for the use of the lands, were for- gotten, and the supposed author of the supposed spoliation, Charles Martel, was pictured by the writers of the Middle Ages as undergoing the fiercest of all the tortures of hell. Land thus rented was said to be held " ad precariam," or " ad beneficium." The essence of a " precaria " was that it was revocable ; it was ordinarily renewed on petition every five years, and the ordinary forms of such petition 72 GROWTH OF CHURCH INSTITUTIONS. have been preserved. The custom of so renew- ing it was probably a survival of the Roman custom of renewing the leases of the public land every five years, i.e., with every new " censor," a custom which had continued to exist even after the censorship had ceased to be active, and which seems to have spread also to the lands held by temples or religious societies, e.g., those of the Vestal Virgins. In Roman law there was a distinction between this tenure by " precaria " and tenure by " be- neficium ; " but the two kinds of tenure did not greatly differ, and in the earlier Middle Ages the two terms were used as convertible. For the custom of renewing by petition gradu- ally died out. A form of grant came to be used which specified that it should be deemed to be renewed from time to time without any process of actual renewal, and this was suc- ceeded by the custom of allowing the beneficial use of land to continue during the lifetime of the beneficiary. It was natural that this system should easily lapse into a system of continuing the lease to a man's heirs. A beneficiary came to look upon his land as passing by a kind THE BENEFICE. 73 of right from father to son ; it is clear that in most respects he could do as he pleased with it, the words of the extant deeds " saving the right of the saint " {i.e., the patron saint of the church to which the land belonged) being in- serted as the only saving clause. When, on the contrary, the use of church lands was given to clerks, though they had full legal possession during their lifetime, the lands reverted to the Church at their death. In course of time the word " beneficium " ousted the word " precaria," and became the common expression which ultimately covered all permanent sources from which church officers derived emolument. It was applied not only to canonries and parish cures, but also to bishoprics and the popedom itself. Its main interest for us is in its relation to parishes; and the history of that relation is especially de- serving of study, now that the whole question of the endowments of the Church is coming into the field of active discussion. The history is necessarily complicated, inasmuch as it not only covers a large period of time, but also embraces many various elem^ *" r - f J;