Cornell University Library The original of this bool< is in the Cornell University Library. There are no known copyright restrictions in the United States on the use of the text. http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924074276464 llHlliri «K"5'" LIBRARV 3 1924 074 276 464 Production Note Cornell University Library produced this volume to replace the irreparably deteriorated original. It was scanned at 600 dots per inch resolution and compressed prior to storage using CCITT/ITU Group 4 compression. The digital data were used to create Cornell's replacement volume on paper that meets the ANSI Standard Z39.48-1992. The production of this volume was supported by the United States Department of Education, Higher Education Act, Title II-C. Scanned as part of the A. R. Mann Library project to preserve and enhance access to the Core Historical Literature of the Agricultural Sciences. Titles included in this collection are listed in the volumes published by the Cornell University Press in the series The Literature of the Agricultural Sciences, 1991-1996, Wallace C. Olsen, series editor. ENGLISH FARMING PAST AND PRESENT ENGLISH FARMING PAST AND PRESENT BY ROWLAND E. PROTHERO LATE FELLOW OF ALL SOULS COLLEGE, OXFORD "Writing and plonghing are two different talents ; and he that writes well must have spent in his studj that time which is necessary to be spent in the fields by him who will be master of the art of cultivating them." JlTTHRO TCLL. LONGMANS, GEEEN, AND CO. 39 PATERNOSTER ROW, LONDON NSW YORK, BOMBAY AND CALCUTTA 1912 AU rights reserved PREFACE English Farming Past and Present is based on an article which appeared in the Quarterly Review for 1885. The article was subsequently expanded into a book, published in 1888 by Messrs. Longman under the title of The Pumeers and Progress of English Farming. The book has been out of print for twenty years. Written with the confidence of comparative youth and inexperience, it expressed as certainties many opinions which might now be modified, if not withdrawn. But its motives were two convictions, which time has rather strengthened than weakened. One was, that the small number of persons who owned agricultural land might some day make England the forcing-bed of schemes for land-nationalisation, which countries, where the ownership of the soil rested on a more democratic basis, repudiated as destructive of all forms of private property. The other was, that a considerable increase in the number of peasant ownerships, in suitable hands, on suitable land, and in suitable localities, was socially, economically, and agriculturally advantageous. Since 1888, the whole field of economic history has been so care- fully and skilfully cultivated, that another work on a branch of the subject might appear superfluous. But there still seemed to be room for a consecutive history of English agriculture, written from a practical point of view, and tracing the influence of the progress of the industry on the social conditions of those engaged in its pursuit. Great economic changes have resulted from small alterations in the details of manufacturing processes. Similar changes may often be explained by some little-noticed alterations in farming practice. The introduction of the field-cultivation of turnips, for example, was as truly the parent of a social revolution as the introduction of textile machinery. The main object of The Pioneers and Progress of English Farming, and, in greater vi PREFACE detail, of English Fwrming Past and Present, is to suggest that advances in agricultural skill, the adoption of new methods, the application of new resources, the invention of new implements, have been, under the pressure of national necessities: powerful instruments in breaking up older forms of rural society, and in mould- ing them into their present shape. Students of economic and social questions — and at the present day most people are interested in these subjects — will decide whether the influence of these simple and natural causes hae been greater or less than is suggested. Even those who consider that their importance is exaggerated, may find in the record of their progress a useful commentary on the political explanations which they themselves prefer to adopt. The book may still serve another purpose. It touches rural life at many different points and at many different stages. Dwellers in the country are surrounded by traces of older conditions of society. They may perhaps find, through English Pojrming Past and Present, a new interest in piecing together the fragments of an agricultural past, and in reconstructing, as in one of the fashionable occupations of the day, a picture of the Middle Ages or of the eighteenth century in the midst of their own familiar surroundings. Now that the book is in print and on the eve of publication, I feel more acutely than ever the disadvantages under which it has been prepared. English Farming Past and Present is the by-product of a life occupied in other pursuits than those of Uterature. It has been impossible to work upon it for any continuous period of time. Written in odd half-hours, it has been often laid aside for weeks and even months. My thanks are therefore due, in more abundant measure, to Professor Ashley, Sir Ernest Clarke, and Mr. H. Trus- tram Eve, who have kindly read the proof-sheets and helped me with corrections, and above all to Mr. G. H. Holden, who has also verified the references and prepared the Index. ROWLAND E. PROTHERO. SejOetnber 6, 1912. CONTENTS CHAPTER I. THE MANORIAL SYSTEM OP PABMING. Virgin soils : traces of sites of early villages : " urild field-grass " husbandry ; the permanent division of pasture from tillage ; manors and trcule-guilds ; origin of manors ; the thirteenth century manor and village ; divisions of lemd according to differences of tenure ; villages isolated and self- sufiScing ; importance of labour-rents in the economy of a manor ; the cultivation of the demesne ; the crops grown ; the live-stock ; miscel- laneous produce ; the manorial coinrts : the social grades among the villagers ; the system of open-field farming ; the arable land ; the meadows ; the hams ; the pasture conunons ; the prevalence and permanence of the open-field system ; the domestic industries of the village. Pp. 1-30 CHAPTER II. THE BREAK-UP OP THE MANOR. 1300-1485. Great landlords as farmers : horrors of winter scarcity : gradual decay of the manorial system and the increased struggle for life : aspects of the change : conunon rights over cultivat«d and uncultivated land : tendency towards separate occupation : substitution of labour-rents for money- rents ; the Black Death ; Labour legislation, and its efiect ; Manor of Castle Combe and Berkeley Estates ; new relations of landlords and tenants substituted for old relations of feudal lords and dependents ; tenant-farmers and free laboiu'ers ; leases and larger farms ; increase of separate occupations : William Paston and Hugh Latimer ; wage-earning labourers ; voluntary surrender of holdings ; freedom of movement and of contract. Pp. 31-54 CHAPTER III. PARMING POR PROFIT: PASTURE AND SHEEP- GRAZING. 1485-1558. The passing of the Middle Ages : enclosures in the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries compared ; the commercial impulse and its results ; conversion viii CONTENTS of tillage to pasture : endosurea and depopulation : legislation against enclosures ; literaiy attack on enclosures ; the practical defence of en- closures : larger farms in separate occupation : loss of employment ; enclosures equitably arranged, or enforced by tyranny ; legal powers of landowners ; open-field f Eumers not the chief sufierers by enclosures ; scarcity of employment and rise in prices ; the new problem of poverty : the ranks of vagrants ; the Elizabethan fraternity of vagabonds. Pp. 56-77 CHAPTER IV. THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH. Paternal despotism : restoration of the purity of the coinage ; a definite commercial policy : revival of the wool trade : new era of prosperity among landed gentry and occupiers of land : a time of adversity for small landowners and wage-earning labourers : Statute of Apprentices ; hiring fairs ; growth of agricultural literature : Fitzherbert and Tusser : their picture of Tudor farming : defects of the open-field system : experience of the value of enclosures ; improvement in farming : Bamaby Googe ; Sir Hugh Plat : progress in the art of gardening. Pp. 78-102 CHAPTER V. FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION. 1603-1660. FARMING UNDER THE FIRST STEWARTS AND THE COMMONWEALTH. Promise of agricultural progress checked by the Civil War : agricultural writers and their suggestions : Sir Richard Weston on turnips ajid clover : conservatism of English farmers ; their dislike to book-farming not un- reasonable : unexhausted improvements discussed ; Walter Blith on drainage : attempts to drain the fens in the eastern counties ; the resist- ance of the fenmen : new views on commons : Winstanley's claims : enclosures advocated as a step towards agricultural improvement. Pp. 103-129 CHAPTER VI. THE LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLXJTION. 1660-1700. WorUdge's Syttema Agriciitturae (1669) : improvements suggested by agri- cultural writers ; tyranny of custom ; contempt for book-farming ; slow progress in farming skill ; general standard low ; horses, cattle, sheep, tmd pigs in the seventeenth century ; want of leaders ; growing influence CONTENTS ix of landowners ; the finance of the Restoration, and the abolition of military tenures ; legislation to promote agricultmre ; Gregory King on the State and Condition of England and Wales in 169B : the distribution of population and wealth. Pp. 130-147 CHAPTER VII. JETHRO TULL AND LORD TOWNSHEND. 1700-1760. Agricultural progress in the eighteenth century ; enclosures necessary to advance ; advocates and opponents of the enclosing movement ; area of uncultivated land and of land cultivated in open-fields ; defects of the open-field system as a method of farming ; pasture commons as adjuncts to open-field holdings ; the necessary lead in agricultural progress given by large landowners and large farmers ; procedure in enclosures by Act of Parliament : varying dates at which districts have been enclosed : influence of soil and climate in breaking up or maintaining the open-field system : the East Midland and North Eastern group of counties : improved methods and increased resources of farming ; Jethro Tull the " greatest individual improver " ; Lord Townshend's influence on Norfolk husbandry. Pp. 148-175 CHAPTER VIII. THE STOCK-BREEDER'S ART AND ROBERT BAKEWELL. 1725-1795. Necessity for improving the Uve-stock of the country ; sheep valued for their wool, cattle for power of draught or yield of milk ; beef and mutton the growing need : Robert Bakewell the agricultural opportunist ; his experiments with the Black Horse, the Leicester Longhoms, and the New I«icesteiB ; rapid progress of stock-breeding : sacrifice of wool to mutton. Pp. 176-189 CHAPTER IX. ARTHUR YOUNG AND THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE. 1760-1800. The counties distinguished for the best farming : Hertfordshire, Essex, Suflolk, Norfolk, Leicestershire : the low general standard ; Arthur Young ; his crusade against bad farming, and the hindrances to progress ; waste land ; the " Goths and Vandals " of open-field farmers : want of capital and education ; insecurity of tenure ; prejudices and traditional practices ; impassable roads ; rapid development of manufacture demands a change of agricultural front : Young's advocacy of capitalist landlords and large tenant-farmers. Pp. 190-206 CONTENTS CHAPTER X. LAEGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS. 1780-1813. Agricultural enthusiasm at the close of the eighteenth century ; high prices of agricultural produce ; the causes of the advance ; increased demand and cessation of foreign supplies ; the state of the currency ; rapid advance of agriculture on the new lines of capitalist farming ; impulse given to enclosing movement and the introduction of improved practices ; Davy's liCctures on Agricultural Chemistry ; the work of large landlords : Coke of Norfolk. Pp. 207-223 CHAPTER XI. OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS 1793-1815. Condition of open-field arable land and pasture commons as described by the Reporters to the Board of Agriculture, 1793-1816; (1) The North emd North- Western District ; (2) West MidlEuid and Sonth-Westem District (3) South-Eastem and Midland District ; (4) Eastern and North-Eastem District ; (S) the Fens ; the cumulative effect of the evidence ; procedure under private Enclosure Acts ; its defects and cost ; the General enclosure Act of 1801 ; the Inclosure Commissioners ; the new Board of Agriculture. Pp. 224-252 CHAPTER Xn. THE ENGLISH CORN LAWS. Difficulty in deciding on the good or bad influence of the Com Laws ; restric- tions^on home as well as on foreign trade in com ; gradual abandonment of the attempt to seciue just prices by legislation ; means adopted to steady prices ; prohibition both of exports and of imports : the bounty on home- grown com ; the system established in 1670 and 1689 lasts till 1816 ; its general efiect ; influence of seasons from 1689 to 1764, and from 1766 to 1816 ; difficulty of obtaining foreign supplies during the Napoleonic wars ; practical monopoly in the home market : small margin of home supply owing to growth of population ; exaggerated effect on prices of good or bad harvests ; protection after 1815 ; demand by agriculturists for fair profits ; changed conditions of supply ; repeal of the Com Laws, 1846. Pp. 263-274 CONTENTS xi CHAPTER XIII. HIGHWAYS. Di£Sculties of communicatioii ; influence of natiual waterways on inland trade ; artificial waterways and canal construction ; Roman roads ; mediaevtd road-repair : roads in Tudor times ; introduction of turnpikes at the Restoration ; condition of eighteenth century roads ; failure of statutory labour ; rival theories of Telford and M'Adam ; extinction of turnpike trusts ; highway rates ; main roads. Pp. 275-289 CHAPTEE XIV. THE RURAL POPULATION. 1780-1813. Efiect of enclosures on the rural population ; no necessary reduction in the nnmber of smtill owners, but rather an increase ; consolidation of farms, either by purchase from small owners, or by throwing tenancies together ; the strict letter of the law ; small occupiers become landless labourers ; depoptdation of villages when tillage was abandoned for pasture ; scarcity of employment in open-field villages ; the literary controversy ; the mate- rial injury inflicted upon the rural poor by the loss of the conunons ; no possible equivalent in cash-value : the moral injury ; the simultaneous decay of domestic industries ; the rapid rise after 1790 in the price of provisions ; a substantial advance in agricultural wages. Pp. 290-315 CHAPTER XV. AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND THE POOR LAW. 1813-1837. War taxation : peace and beggary ; slow recovery of agriculture ; the harvest of 1813 ; reality and extent of distress ; the fall of prices ; bankruptcies of tenant-farmers ; period of acute depression, 1814-36 ; ruin of small owners ; misery of agricultural labourers ; reduction in wages and scarcity of employment ; allowances from the rates ; general pauperisation : the new Poor Law, 1834, and its administration. Pp. 316-331 CHAPTER XVI. TITHES. The incidence of tithes under the old law ; the historical origin of tithes ; a free-will offering ; a customary payment ; the appeal to conscience ; »i CONTENTS ecclesiastical penalties for non-payment ; a legal liability : tithes as parochial endowments ; the Reformation ; the collection of tithes in kind unpopular and expensive to tithe-owners ; substituted forms of payment ; the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836 ; its object and meu^hinery. Pp. 332-34S CHAPTER XVII. HIGH FARMING. 1837-1874. Condition of agriculture in 1837 ; current explanation of the distress ; pre- paration for a new start in farming ; legislative changes ; development of a railway system ; Uve-stock in 1837 ; the general level of farming ; foundation of the Koyal Agricultural Society ; notable improvements, 1837-74 ; extension of drainage ; piuchase of feeding stufis ; discovery of artificial fertilisers ; mechanical improvements and inventions ; Repeal of the Com Laws ; the golden age from 1863 to the end of 1862 ; rapid progress in the " Fifties " ; pedigree mania in stock-breeding. Pp. 346-373 CHAPTER XVIII. ADVERSITY. 1874-1912. Industrial crisis; special difficulties of farmers; the weather, and foreign competition; Richmond Commission, 1879-82; second agricultural crisis, 1891-99; Royal Commission of 1893; changes in farming; the day of small things; progress; the aid of science; management of dairy pro- duce ; agricultural education ; effects of present elementary education. Pp. 374-392 CHAPTER XIX. CONCLUSION. 1888 and 1912 : political agitation then and now ; the situation contrasted and compared ; the position of landowners ; of tithe-owners ; of tenemt- farmers ; tenant-right as a defence against sales ; agricultural labourers, their slow progress between 1834 and 1884, and their Unions ; their improved position in 1912. The problem of the future ; the reconstruction of village life : the necessity of an agricultural policy : the prospect of increased burdens on agricultural land. Pp. 393-418 APPENDICES. APPENDIX I. Chronologic^ list of Agricultural Writers down to 1700. Pp. 419-430 CONTENTS xiii APPENDIX II. The Poor Law from 1601 to 1834. Pp. 431-438 APPENDIX in. Pp. 439-462 THE CORN LAWS. A. Prices of Wheat, 1646-1911 (p. 440). B. The Principal Acts relating to the Com Trade (p. 442). C. The Assize of Bread (p. 448). D. Exports and Imports of Com, 1697-1801 (p. 462). E. Bounties paid on Exports of Com, 1697-1766 (p. 462). APPENDIX IV. Tables of Estimates by Gregory TCmg and Charles Davenant. Pp. 463-466 APPENDIX V. Estimates of Acreage and Cropping, 1808, 1827. P. 466 APPENDIX VI. Collection of Tithes. Pp. 467-469 APPENDIX VII. The Agricultural Population according to Census Returns of 1851, 1861, 1871, 1881, 1891, 1901. Pp. 460-461 APPENDIX Vin. Imports of Food, 1866-1911. Pp. 462-463 APPENDIX IX. Agricultural Statistics, 1866-1911. Pp. 464-467 APPENDIX X. Agricultural Wages, 1768-70, 1824, 1837, 1860-1, 1860, 1869-70, 1882, 1892, 1898, 1910. Pp. 468-470 IhDII. ' 'c' r V<^V;". Pp. 471-604. CHAPTER I. THE MANORIAL SYSTEM OF FARMING. Virgin soils : traces of sites of early villages : " wild field-grass" husbandry ; the permanent division of pasture from tillage ; manors and trade-guilds ; origin of manors ; the thirteenth century manor and village ; divisions of land according to differences of tenure; villages isolated and self- suiBcing; importance of labour -rents in the economy of a manor; the cultivation of the demesne ; the crops grown ; the live-stock ; miscel- laneous produce ; the manorial courts : the social grades among the villagers ; the system of open-field farming ; the arable land ; the meadows ; the hams ; the pasture coiomons ; the prevalence and permanence of the open-field system ; the domestic industries of the village. Impbovements in the art and science of English agriculture were in its infancy dependent on the exhaustion of virgin soils. So long as land was abundant, and the people few or migratory, no rotation of crops was needed. Fresh land could be ploughed each year. It was only when numbers had increased and settlements became permanent, that farmers were driven to devise methods of cultivation which restored or maintained the fertihty of their holdings. The progress of farming is recorded in legal documents, in manorial accounts, in agricultural literature. But the story is also often preserved in the external aspect which the land, the villages, or the hedgerows bear in the twentieth century. Dry uplands, where the least labour told the most, were first occupied and cultivated ; rich valleys, damp and filled with forest growth, remained unin- habited and untilled. In spite of difficulties of water-supply, light or sandy soils, or chalky highlands seem to have been the sites of the oldest villages. Patches of the lower slopes of downs were cleared of self-sown beech, and sheltered dips tilled for com ; the high ground behind was grazed by flocks and herds ; the beech woods supplied mast for the swine. SaUsbury Plain, a century ago, bore no sign of human life except the proverbial " thief or 2 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM twain " — ^no contemporary mark of the hand of man but the gallows and their appendages. Yet here are to be found traces of numerous villages. Scored on the sides of the Wiltshire, Dorset, Hampshire, and Sussex downs, " L3niches," " Lynchets," or " Daisses," — grass-grown terraces or benches, — still run horizontally, one above the other, along the slopes. The " elf-furrows " of Soot- land seem to record a similar occupation of hill sites. Local tradition attributes their formation to spade husbandry. Marshall, in 1797, suggested, but only to reject, the operation of the plough. Fifty years later, Poulett Scrope adopted a similar suggestion ; more recently Seebohm revived the same theory. Whatever explanation of the formation of these terraces may be correct, they indeUbly indicate the sites of the earliest settlements, and the nature of the soil first selected for tillage. The most primitive form of agriculture is that known as " wild field-grass " husbandry. Joint occupation and joint tillage were probably its characteristics, as they afterwards were of tribal or village communities. The essential difference Ues in this. In the open fields of the village, pasturage and tillage continue to be separated ; grass-land always remains meadow or pasture ; it is never broken up for tillage. Under the more primitive form of convertible husbandry, fresh tracts of grass were successively taken in, ploughed, and tilled for com. As the soil became ex- hausted, they reverted to pasture. Such a practice may belong to some portions of the Celtic race, or to nomadic stages of civilisa- tion. In 1804 Marshall thought that he could trace the " wild field-grass " system in a custom of the south-western counties. In some districts lords of the manor enjoyed rights of letting portions of the grass commons to be ploughed up, cultivated for com, and after two years thrown back into pasture. Over the whole country, from the Tamar to the eastern border of Dorsetshire, he found that open commons, such as the wide expanse of Yarcombe and the hills above Bridport, which from time immemorial had never known the plough, were distinctly marked with the ridge and furrow. Other features of rural life, which a century ago were more pecuUar to the south-west of England, suggest that arable tillage by village communities, if it ever prevailed in this district, was soon exchanged for a system of convertible husbandry better suited to a damp climate. The cultivated land is divided into little patches by the high Devonshire earthwork, or hedge ; the PERMANENT SEPARATION OF TILLAGE FROM GRASS 3 large open-fielda of the parish can rarely be traced ; fewer of the inhabitants are collected into villages, more are scattered in single houses or tiny hamlets. Cornwall and parts of Devonshire, like Brittany, are a country of hedges, and of a Celtic race. This " wild field-grass " husbandry was displaced in most parts of England by the permanent separation of arable from pasture land. The change indicates an advance towards a more settled state of society, but not necessarily an advance in agricultural practice. The fixed division of tillage and grass may have been introduced into this country by a people accustomed, like the Romans or the Anglo-Saxons, to a drier and less variable climate. If so, it was on this alien system that the agricultural organisation of the mediaeval manor was based. On it also were founded the essential features of those village communities which at one time tilled two-thirds <^ the cultivated soil of England, survived the criticism of Fitzherbert in the sixteenth century, outlived the onslaught of Arthur Young in the eighteenth century, clung to the land in spite of thousands of enclosure acts, were carried to the New World by the Pilgrim Fathers, and linger to this day in, for instance, the Nottinghamshire village of Lexington, where half the land of the parish is tilled by an agricultural association of partners. In the early stages of history, the law itself was powerless to protect individual independence or to safeguard individual rights. Agriculture, like other industries, was therefore organised on prin- ciples of graduated dependence and collective responsibility. Mediaeval manors, in fact, resembled trade guilds, and it would be difficult to frame an organisation which, given the weakness of law and the infancy of agriculture, was better calculated to effect the object of mutual help and protection. Conmiunities grouped together in villages were less liable to attack than detached farm- houses and buildings ; common methods of farming facilitated that continuous cultivation which otherwise might have been interrupted by the frequent absence of the able-bodied men on military expedi- tions ; the observance of conunon rules of management may have hindered improvement, but, if strictly enforeed, it also prevented deterioration. Thus the system was suitable to the times and their conditions. The origin of the legal relation of manors to village communities lies outside the scope of the present enquiry. It concerns tenures 4 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM rather than systems of cultiTatioii. Two theories explain the rights of manorial lords and rights of common exercised over manorial lands. The legal theory, in its crudest form, is that the lord of the manor is the absolute owner of the soil of his manor, and that rights acquired over any part of it by freeholders and tenants are acquired against him, and originate in his grant or sufEerance. The historical theory, stated baldly, is that self-governing, independent com- munities of freemen originally owned the land in common, and were gradually reduced to dependence by one of their members, or by a conqueror, who became the lord of the soil. There seems to be no doubt that individual ownership belongs to on earlier stage of civilisation than communal ownership. But if the second theory is correct, the legal position of the lord of the manor represents a series of encroachments, which transformed the Mark of freemen into the Mark of bondmen, and changed the rights of the villagers over the wastes of the district into customary rights of user over the lord's soil. Questions of the origin and antiquity of manors, and the extent to which they prevailed before the Norman Conquest, have been to a great degree reopened by recent studies. Seebohm, for example, practically supported the legal view by historical argument. He traced the feudal manor to the Roman villa, with the lord's estate as the centre round which clustered cultivators, who tilled the soil under servile or semi-servile conditions. This system, according to his view, was taken over by the Anglo^axon invaders, and the agrarian results of the Teutonic occupation may be summed up in the transfer of the Roman villa, with its servile labourers, to the conquerors. As a complete explanation of social development the legal theory, in spite of this historical support, seems inadequate. But whether the early stages of village com- munities reveal a movement from serfdom or originated in freedom, whether their relations to manors represent encroachments by the lord or advances by the serf, whether the rights of agrarian associa- tions underlay, or were acquired against, the manorial rights of the feudal baron — ^whether, in other words, the land-law of the noble became the land-law of the people, or the reverse — ^is here immaterial. Roughly and generally speaking, the immediate lordship of the land farmed by a village community, including the wastes and commons, was, after the Norman Conquest, vested in the lord of the manor, subject to regulated rights enjoyed by its members. On a manorial estate, at the beginning of the thirteenth century, THE MANORIAL BUILDINGS 5 only the church, the manor-house, and perhaps the mill, rose out conspicuously. There were no detached, isolated farm-houses ; but the remaining buildings of the vUlage, grouped together in a sort of street, were the homes of the peasantry, who occupied and cultivated the greater part of the land. At some Uttle distance from the village stood the manor hall or grange, with its out- buildings, garden, and fishpond, surrounded by clay-built walls with thatched tops. The style and extent of the buildings depended on whether the house was the permanent or occasional residence of the lord ; they also varied with the importance of the manor, and the wealth of its owner. The house itself was built either of timber and clay, or of stone, for brickmaldng was still a forgotten art. It often consisted of a single hall, plastered inside, open to the roof, and earth-floored, which served as court of justice, dining- room, and bedchamber. At one end of the central room was a stable ; at the other a chamber, kitchen, or larder. Below one part of the ground floor was a cellar ; above another part was, perhaps, a " solar," or parlour, approached by an outside staircase. If the manor was sufficiently important, there were probably added a detached building for the farm servants, and a chamber for the bailiff. The outbuildings consisted of bake-house, stables, dairy, cattle and poultry houses, granary, and dove-cote. Some of the oldest specimens of domestic architecture are granaries, like Hazel- ton or Calcot in Gloucestershire, or the dove-cotes which still in country districts mark the former sites of manor-houses. Repairs of the walls and buildings of the manor-house were among the labour services of the tenantry, who dug, tempered, and daubed the clay, cut and carted the timber, and gathered the straw or reeds, for thatching. Where technical skill was needed they were aided by craftsmen, who either held land in reward for their special services, or, on the smaller manors, were hired for the occasion. Tufts of trees, conspicuous ia the hedgeless expanse of arable land by which they were surrounded, marked the sites of villages, as they still do in the high table-land of the Pays de Gaux. Under their shelter clustered the homes of the peasantry, clay-walled,^ open-roofed, earth-floored, chimneyless sheds, covered in with, straw or reeds or heather, and consisting of a single room. Here» divided by a hurdle or wattle partition, lived, not only the human inhabitants, but their cows, pigs, and poultry. Close by were the tofts and crofts of the open-field farmers, each with its miniature 6 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM hay-riok and straw-stack ; and the cottages and curtilages of the cottagers, " fencM al aboute with stikkes." Here were the scanty gardens in which grew the vegetables, few but essential to the health of a population which hved almost entirely on salted meat and fish — often half-cured and half-putrid. These homesteads were in early times the only property held by members of the township in exclusive separate occupation. They were also, at first, the only permanent enclosures on the commonable land. But, as agri- culture advanced, pasture paddocks (" gerstuns " or " garstons ") for rearing stock, calves, or fattening beasts, or for the working oxen, which could not endure his " warke to labour all daye, and then to be put to the commons or before the herdsman," were enclosed in the immediate neighbourhood of the village. In these enclosures, or " happy garstons " as they were called at Aston Boges, were held the village merrymakings, the rush-bearings, the May games, the summerings at St. John's Eve, the pubUc break- fasts, and the distribution of bread and ale in Bogation week. The land comprised in a thirteenth century manor was generally divided into four main portions, and, speaking generally, was cul- tivated on co-operative principles ; the demesne or " board " land, reserved for the lord's personal use, surrounding the manor- house, and forming the smaller portion of the whole ; the free land, occupied by freemen holding by military service, or by some form of fixed rent in money or in kind ; the unfree land, occupied by various classes of bondmen, holding by produce-rents and labour services which varied with the custom of the manor ; the common pastures and untilled wastes on which the tenants of the manor and the occupiers of certain cottages, in virtue of their holdings, fed their Uve stock. This right of pasture must be clearly distinguished from those rights which, at certain seasons of the year, were exercised by the associated partners over the cul- tivated arable and meadow lands of the village farm.^ Thus the lord's demesne, using the word in its narrower sense, might be kept in hand, or let on lease to free or unfree tenants, or thrown 1 By " village faim " is meant the land in the village which was occupied by an association of partners, who were bound by the same rules of cultiva- tion, held inteimized strips of arable land over which at certain seasons the whole body exercised common rights, annually received fdlotted portions of meadow for hay, and enjoyed, in virtue of their arable holdings, the right to turn out stock on the common pasture. This open-field system of farming is described pp. 23-27. LABOUR MORE NEEDED THAN MONEY 7 into the village farm, or dealt with as to portions in each of these three ways. But whether the land was treated as a compact whole, like a modem home-farm, or whether the landlord, as a shareholder in the village association, allowed it to be cut up into strips and intermixed with other holdings, the demesne was mainly cultivated by the labour services of the un£ree peasantry. The rest of the land of the manor, forming the larger portion of the cultivated area, was farmed by village partners, whose rent chiefly consisted in the labour, more or less definite in amount, which they were obliged to perform on the lord's demesne. In this method of cultivating a manorial estate there are many contrasts with the modem system. The three-fold division of the agricultural interests into landlord, tenant farmer, and wage- eaming labourer was practically unknown. Landowner and tenant- labourer owned, occupied, and cultivated the soil, and the gradual relaxation of the labourer's tenure of the land, and the inter- position of the tenant farmer between the two existing classes, simi up the early social history of English farming. Li the thirteenth century, muscles were more essential to the prosperity of the land- lord than money rents. The cultivators of the soil grew their produce, not for sale, but for their own consumption. Each manor or village was isolated and self-sufficing. Only in the neighbour- hood of towns was there any market for the produce of the farm. Few manufactured articles were bought. Salt, tar, iron (bought in four-pound bars), mill-stones, steel for tipping the edges of imple- ments, canvas for the sajls of the wind-mill, cloths for use in the dairy, in the malthouse, or in the grange, together with the dresses of the inhabitants of the hall, and a few vessels of brass, copper, or earthenware, satisfied the simple needs of the rural population. Hands were therefore more required than money on manorial estates. If the manor was well stocked with labour, the land paid ; when the stock of labour shrank, the profits dwindled. It was in order to retain a sufficient supply of labour on the land that bond- men were restrained from leaving the manor to assume the tonsure of the clerk or the flat cap of the apprentice, to become soldiers or to work outside the manor. Even their marriages were carefuUy controlled by licences. It was, again, in order to exact and super- vise the due performance of labour services that the lord of the manor maintained his large official stafi — his seneschal, if he owned several manors, his steward, his bailifl, and the various foremen of 8 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM the laboureis, such as the reeve, the hayward, the head-reaper, and the granger. But with the thirteenth century begins the practice of keeping estate accounts, in which the amount and cash values of the labour services are entered. Thus the uncertainty of villein-tenure was modified, and the means were prepared for commuting obligations to work into their money equivalents. Already the causes were operating which hastened the process, and changed agriculture from a self-sufficing industry into a commercial system of farming for profit. Population was increasing ; trade was growing ; urban classes, divorced from rural pursuits, were forming ; means of communication were improving ; money taxes took the place of personal services ; the standard of living rose ; coin was needed, not only to meet the demands of the government,, but to buy the luxuries of more civilised life. The obligations of the peasantry to cultivate the demesne varied, not only with local customs, but with the seasons. Their most important services were the autumnal, Lenten, and summer plough- ings on the three fields, into which the arable land of the demesne was generally divided. The crops grown were, as winter seeds, wheat and rye, and, as spring seeds, oats, barley, beans, peas, or vetches. In smaller quantities, flax, hemp, and saffron were locally raised in separate plots. Boots, clover and artificial grasses were still unknown. Rotations of crops, as they are now understood, were therefore impossible. The soil was rested by fallowing the one- half, or the one-third, of the arable land required by the two or the three course system. Red rivet, or a lost white variety, was then recommended for wheat-sowing on light land, red or white pollard for heavy soils, " gray " wheat for clays. But on the tenants' land, rye was the chief grain crop. It is the hardiest, grows on the poorest soils, makes the toughest straw. Rye was then the bread-stuff of the English peasantry, as it still is in Northern Europe. The flour of wheat and rye were often mixed together, and bread made in this form was called " maslin." ^ It retained its moisture longer than pure wheaten bread, and, as Fynes Moryson ^ Lat. mixtUio ; " mestilon,"- anon, author of Hoeebonderie (thirteenth century) ; " miscellin," Harrison (sixteenth century) ; " massledine," Henry Best (1641); "mashelson," Yorkshire (1797). In The CmrvpUat Fanmr (1760) it is called " maislen " ; but the writer says that it is " ill husbcmdry to grow wheat and rye together." Fitzherbert (1623) reconunends rye and wheat to be sown together as the surest crop to grow and good for the husband- man's household. But he does not believe in the slowness of rye in ripening. THE THREE PLOUGHINGS 9 says in his Itinerary (1617), was used by labourers because it " abode longer in the stomach and was not so soon digested with their labour." Wheat and rye were sometimes sown together. But as rye was slower to lipen, the better practice was to sow it alone and earlier, lest, as Tusser (1557) writes, " rye tarty wheat, till it sheds as it stands." The mixed cultivation was, however, recommended as a cure for mildew, and for this reason prevailed in Yorkshire in 1797. Barley was ihe drink-corn, as rye was the bread-corn, of the Middle Ages. It was of two kinds. The head with two rows of grain seems to have been used exclusively for brewii^ ; the coarser four-rowed head, known as " drage," was used partly for brewing, partly for feeding pigs and poultry. Barley and oats were often sown together. In the North, oats were extensively cultivated ; but they were grey-awned, tbdn, and poor. In the Midlands and South of England they were comparatively rare on tenants' land. The fallows were three times ploughed in preparation for wheat and rye. The seed began to be sown after Lammas Day (August 12),^ and at latest was completed by Hallowmas (November 1). For oats, beans, and peas, the land was ploughed and the seed sown between the Feast of Purification (February 2) and Easter. Oats were said to be best sown in " the dust of March." " On St. Valentine's Day cast beans in clay. But on St. Chad sowe good or bad." That is to say, the time for sowing beans was between February 14 and March 2. Barley came last. The land was ploughed and sown between Hoke-tide (the third Tuesday after Easter) and Pentecost. The ploughings were performed, and the teams suppUed and driven, partly by the servants of the demesne, partly by the tenants. Sometimes ploughmen seem to have been hired. The harrowings were similarly provided for, and the harrow, often a hawthorn tree, weighted on its upper side with logs, was suppUed from the lord's waste. Here also harrowers seem to have been sometimes specially hired. In this case they possibly provided their own home-constructed implements with sharp points or teeth like the modem type of harrow. When the fallows were first broken up, as was then the practice, in March, or when the land was prepared for barley, the grotmd was often so hard that the clods had to be subsequently broken. For this * The Julian calendar was in force. To make the dates correspond mth those of the present Gregoriem calendar, twelve days have to be added. 10 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM purpose the ploughman, holding the principal hale of the plough in his left hand, carried in his right a " clotting beetle," or " maul," such as that which is depicted in the Cotton MSS. A " Dover-court beetle " was a necessary tool in the days of Tusser ; and Plot, whose Natural History of Oxfordshire appeared in the seventeenth century, reconmiends its use after the land was harrowed. The amount of wheat, rye, beans, and peas usually sown to the acre was only two bushels ; and of oats and, strangely enough, of barley, four bushels. The yield of wheat rarely exceeded five- fold, or ten bushels to the acre ; that of the leguminous crops ranged from three- to six-fold, or from six to twelve bushels to the acre ; that of oats and barley varied from three- to four-fold, or from twelve to sixteen bushels to the acre. Considerable care was exercised in the choice and change of the seed-corn, which was often one of the produce-rents of the tenants. On the Berkeley Estates (1321) the seed was changed every second or third year ; the upland com being sown in the vale, and vice versa. Wheat rarely followed a spring grain crop. If it did, it may be supposed that it received the greater part of the manure mixed with earth, which the tenants carted from the demesne yard, and spread on the manor farm. From the point of view of manuring the land, the right of folding was a valuable privilege. Tenants, unless they purchased a licence to fold their sheep on the land they occupied, were often obliged to feed and fold their flocks on the lord's land for fallow or in his own fold. Sometimes the herbage of the lord's land for fallow was sold to a sheep-master to be depastured on the land. Lime wa:S used on heavy clays, or to destroy moss. The value of marl in improving the texture of sandy soils and some kinds of clays was appreciated. On the Berkeley Estates it was first used in the fortieth year of Henry III. But the cost was excessive. " Marl," says Fitzherbert,^ " is an excellent manure, and . . . exceeding chargeable." Sea sand was used near the coast ; soot and even street refuse were employed on home farms. Drain- age, except in the form of ridging the surface of wet soils, was rarely practised. Sometimes, as Palladius recommends (Book VI. St. 6), shallow trenches filled with gravel, stones, or hollow alder stems, and turfed over, were cut, and, on the manors belonging to 1 Fitzherbert's Book of Husbandry, book i. c. 20 (ed. 1698). For agri- cultural literature, see Chronological List in Appendix I. MEDIAEVAL HARVESTINGS 11 the Collegiate body of St. Paul's Cathedral, it was one of the labour services to clean out the ditches. But the science of deep drainage made little progress before the nineteenth century. Beans were often dibbed ; but all other seed was sown broadcast. The actual labour of sowing was probably performed by the lord's bailiff, or the hayward, with his own hand, as, at the beginning of the last century, all seed was sown by the farmer himself. The hoeing and the weeding of the crops were among the labour services of the tenants. In cleaning land the maxim was ancient : "Who weeda in May - Throws sU away," and the crops were generally weeded in June or the first few days of July. Walter of Henley^ (thirteenth century) gives St. John's Day (June 24) as the earliest date for cleaning the land. " If," he says, " you cut thistles fifteen days or eight before St. John's Day, for each one will come two or three." On a Suffolk manor, in the fourteenth century, sixty " sarclers," or weeders, were employed in one day, armed, if the weather was dry, with a hook or forked stick, and, in wet weather, with nippers. The meadows of the demesne were mown, and the hay made, carted, and put on the manorial ricks, by the labour services of the tenants. They also reaped, bound, gathered, loaded, carted, and stacked the com crops in the lord's grange. They also threshed the com, and winnowed-it, unless, as was sometimes the case, the duty of winnowing fell to the dairjrwoman, or " Daye." If any com was sent for sale to the markets, it was carried there by the labour services of the tenants, in their carts drawn by their teams. Harvestings in the Middle Ages were picturesque scenes of bustle and of merriment among the thousands to whom they meant the return of plenty. On 250 acres at Hawstead in Suffolk, towards the close of the fourteenth century, were grown wheat, oats, barley, peas, and " bolymong," a mixture of tares and oats. The grain crops were cut and housed in two days. On the first day appeared thirty tenants to perform their " bedrepes," and 244 reapers ; on the second day, the thirty tenants and 239 reapers, pitchers, and stackers. Many of this assembly were the smaller peasantry on the manor ; the rest were the lord's farm servants, together with ' Walter of Henley's Buabandry, together teith an anonymous Husbandry, Seneschaucie, and Robert Orosaeteste's Rules, ed. E. Lamond, 1890. For agricultural literature, see Clironological List in Appendix I. 12 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM wandering bands of " cookers " or harvesters, who had already begun to travel the country at harvest time. A cook, brewer, and baker were hired to supply dinner at nine and supper at five. Reapers were organised in bands, or "setts," of five. The anonymous author of Hoaebonderie^ (thirteenth century) calculates that each band could reap and bind two acres a day. Barley and oats, as well as peas and beans, were generally mown ; rye and wheat were reaped. But the reaping, as in Roman times, seems to have consisted of two operations : the first was to cut the ears, the second to remove part of the straw for thatching, or to be used as forage for cattle, as Utter for strewing the sheep-house, folds, and yards, or as bedding for men. Often the value of the straw of thin short com hardly paid for the expense of removal, and the stubble was either grazed or burned on the ground, or ploughed in. The most important crops of the farm were the com crops of wheat, rye, and barley, which were raised for human food and drink. Their consumption, especially if the lord of the manor lived on the estate, was enormous. Domestic households were considerable, and often only the bailifi was paid money wages. Rations were also allowed to tenants when performing many of their services. Though the manual and team work of the tenants provided most of the labour of the farm, the lord also employed a large permanent stafi of agricultural servants, most of whom were occupied in the care of Uve-stock. Such were the horseman or waggoner, oxherd or ploughman, cowherd, shepherd, swineherd, warrener, and keepers of hawks and dogs, whose wages were mostly paid in kind. There were, besides, other servants in husbandry, hired for special occasions, whose food and drink formed a large portion of their payment. The granary was, therefore, rarely so full that any surplus remained for sale. For such ready-money as he needed, the lord looked mainly to the produce of his live-stock. For their consumption were grown the remaining crops — the hay, beans, peas, and oats ; though oats were not only used for human food, but in some districts were brewed into inferior beer. Horse-farms appear in some estate accounts ; but they probably supplied the " great horse " used for military purposes. On an ordinary farm the horses used for farm-work were mostly home- bred, and were divided into cart-horses, and — ^under the names of stotts, " affers," or " avers " — ^plough-horses. Colts, not needed 1 Hoaebonderie in W(Uter of Henley' » Husbandry, ed. E. Lamond, 1890. PLOUGH-OXEN 13 to keep up the supply, were sold. Plough-teams were seldom made up of hoises only ; if hoises were used at all, they were mixed with oxen. But, as a rule, oxen were preferred to horses. Though horses worked more quickly, when the ploughman allowed them to do BO, — ^they pulled less steadily, and sudden strains severely tested the primitive plough-gear. On hard ground they did less work, and only when the land was stony had they any advantage. Economical reasons further explain the preference for oxen. From St. Luke's Day (October 18) to April, both horses and oxen were kept in the stalls. During these twenty-five weeks neither could graze, and Walter of Henley calculates that the winter-keep of a horse cost four times that of an ox. Horses needed more attend- ance ; they required to be rubbed, curried, and dressed. Oxen were less liable to sickness than horses. The harness of the ox, mainly home-made from materials supplied on the estate, was cheaper to provide and repair. Shod only on the forefeet, the shoeing of the ox cost less than that of the horse. When either horse or ox was past work, the profit of the one lay in his hide ; of the other, not only in his hide, but the larder : the ox was " mannes meat when dead, while the hoise is carrion." Great care was taken both of horses and of oxen. Li Seneechaucie^ (thirteenth century) the duties both of the waggoner and oxherd are care- fully defined ; each was expected to sleep every night with his charges. Cattle were seldom fatted even for the tables of the rich ; oxen were valued for their power of draught : cows for their milk. It may, indeed, be said that fresh butcher's meat was rarely eaten, and that, if it was, it was almost universally grass-fed. No winter- keep or feeding stuff was available ; not even carrots or parsnips were known. The commons, generally unstinted, carried as much stock as could keep skin and bone together in the winter, and the lord could not only turn out on them his own sheep and cattle, but license strangers for money payments to do the same. Even if the commons were stinted, the margin was too bare to mean abundance. The best pastures were either in the lord's own hands, and were saved by him at the exx>ense of the commons, or were let out to individuals in separate occupations. Even among these superior feeding-grounds, there were few enclosures which would fatten a bullock. At the wane of the summer, the cattle had the ^ In WaUer of Henley's Huabandry, ed. 1900. 14 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM aftennath of the hay meadows, and the stubble and hauhn of the arable lands. During this season they were at their best. They only survived the winter months in a state of semi-starvation on hay, straw, and tree-loppings. It was, therefore, the practice at the end of June to draft the aged cows, worn-out oxen, and tooth- less sheep, or " ci-ones," prepare them as far as possible for the butcher, slaughter them in the autumn, and either eat them fresh or throw them into the powdering tub to be salted for winter con- sumption. " For Easter at Martilmas (November 11) hange up a biefe " is the advice of Tusser. The dairy produce was a greater source of money revenue, though the home consumption of cheese must have been very large. But the management was necessarily controlled, like the management of the stock, by the winter scarcity. The yield of a cow during the twenty-four weeks from the middle of April to Michaelmas was estimated at four-fifths of her total annual yield. Six to ten ewes gave as much milk as one cow ; but the best practice was to cease milking ewes at Lammas Day (August 12). Cheese-making formed an important part of the dairywoman's duties, and the purchase of the cloths and utensils used in its manufacture are a serious item in estate accounts. Cheese seems generally to have been made of skim-milk, though superior varieties were doubtless foimd on the lord's table. Most of the butter made in the summer months was either sold, or salted and preserved in pots and barrels for winter use.^ The butter-milk was either drunk, made into curds, or more rarely used to fatten pigs. The curds were eaten with wine or ale ; the whey, vmder the name of " whig," made a cool and wholesome summer drink. During the winter months, milk fetched three times its summer price, and was generally sold. For this, among other reasons, calves were timed to fall before autunm. In the scarce months of winter, the price obtained for milk during eight weeks was supposed to be worth more than the calf. Small open-field farmers must usually have sold their calves as soon as possible. The same practice prevailed on the demesne. The total ^ Kogers, noticing that butter was sold by the gallon, seems to have con- cluded that it was melted {Six Centimes of Work and Wages, ed. 1890, pp. 94-6). But it would seem from the thirteenth century writings of Walter of Henley and the anonymous author of Hosebonderie, that two pottles of butter made 1 gallon of 7 lbs., 2 gallons made 1 stone ; and 14 stone 1 wey. What- ever inference may be founded on the use of a liquid measure, it is discounted by the use of the pottle and the stone. SHEEP 15 number of live-stock, including horses but not including sheep, sold from the manor of Fomcett in thirteen years, between 1272 and 1306, waa 152.* Out of this total 99 were calves. The cows of the demesne were under the care of a cowherd, who was required to sleep every night with his charges in the sheds. Sheep were the sheet anchor of farming. But it was not for their mutton, or for their milk, or even for their skins, that they were chiefly valued. Already the mediaeval agriculturist took his seat on the wool-sack. As a marketable commodity, both at home and abroad, English long wool always commanded a price. It was less perishable than com, and more easily transported even on the worst of roads. To the Flemish weavers it was indispensable, for Spanish wool could not be used alone, and the supply from Saxony was not as yet developed. The washing and shearing of sheep were among the labour services of the tenantry. Certain districts, especially Shropshire, Leominster, and the Cotswolds, were from very early times famous for the excellence of their wool. So far as its quaUty depended on breed rather than on soil, some care, as evidenced by the higher prices paid for rams, was taken to improve the flocks. From Martinmas to Easter sheep were kept in houses, or in moveable folds of wooden hurdles, thatched at the sides and tops. During these months they were fed on coarse hay or peas-hauhn, mixed with wheaten or oaten straw. For the rest of the year they browsed on the land for fallows, in woodland pastures, or on the sheep conunons. But in the autumn they were not allowed to go on the ground, till the sun had purified the land from the " gelly or matty rime," which was supposed to engender scab. So also they were driven from the damp, low-lying groimds lest they should eat the white water-snails which our ancestors, suspected of breeding the rot. These two diseases made sheep- farming, in spite of its profits, a risky venture. The scab does not seem to have attacked sheep before the latter end of the thirteenth century ; but, from that time forward, the tar-box was essential to every shepherd. The rot is carefully treated by Walter of Henley, if he is the real author of the passage interpolated in the Bodleian manuscript of his work.^ The writer discusses the ^ The Economic Development of a Norfolk Manor (1086-1566). By Frances Gardiner Davenport, pp. 33-36. * WtiUer of Henley, 1890, ed. E. Lamond. The passage is given on pages 37-8, and its genuineness is disputed in the Introduction, p. zzii. 16 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM symptoms of the disease. White veins under the eyelids, wool that can be easily pulled away from the tibs, a skin that will not redden when rubbed, are signs of unsoundness. Another sign is when the November hoar-frost melts rapidly on the fleece, for the animal is then sufEering from an imnatural heat. The losses of the flockmasters from the " murrain," to use the generic term for diseases employed by mediaeval writers, were so severe as to create another danger. The minute instructions against fraud given to the official staff show that shepherds not infrequently produced the skin, and explained the disappearance of the carcase by death from disease. "Let no sheep," says the author of Seneschaucie, " be flayn before it be seen and known for what fault it died." The value of the flock made the shepherd one of the most important of farm servants. He was required to be a patient man, " not over- hasty," never to be absent without leave at " fairs, markets, wrestling-matches, wakes, or in the tavern," and always to sleep in the fold together with his dog. Later writers insist on the value of lameness in the shepherd, as a lame man was unlikely to over- drive his sheep. Swine were the almost universal hve-stock of rich and poor. As consumers of refuse and scavengers of the village, they would, on sanitary grounds, have repaid their keepers. But mediaeval pigs profited their owners much, and cost them little. It was a Glouces- tershire saying : " A swine doth sooner than a cowe Bring an ox to the plough." In other words, a pig was more profitable than a cow. For the greater part of the year pigs were expected to pick up their own living. When the wastes and woodlands of a manor were extensive, they were, except during three months of the year, self-supporting. They developed the qualities necessary for taking care of themselves. The ordinary pigs of the Middle Ages were long, flat-sided, coarse- boned, lop-eared, omnivorous animals, whose agility was more valuable than their early maturity. Growth and flesh were the work of time : so also were thickened skin, developed muscles, and increased weight of bone. The styes were often built in the woods, whence the pigs were only brought to feed on the arable land after the crops were cleared, or, at times of exceptional frost, to subsist on the leavings of the threshing-floor. During most months of the year they ranged the woods for roots, wild pears, wild phmis, crab PIGS AND POULTRY 17 apples, sloes, haws, beech-mast, and acorns. Only when the sows were farrowing, or when am'TnalH were being prepared for the rich man's table, were they specially fed. Pigs were fatted on inferior com, especially coarse barley, peas, beans, sMm- and bntter-milk, or brewers' grains which were readily obtainable when nearly every household brewed its own barley beer. The amount consumed varied with the purpose intended to be served. The boar was fatted for the feast on ten times the grain bestowed in finishing ordinary animals for conversion into salted pork or smoke-dried bacon. Walter of Henley impUes that some attention was given to breed, as he recommends the use of well-bred boars. But the only quahty on which he insists is that the animal should be able to dig, or, in other words, support itself. Modem ideas of purchasing com for fattening purposes, or of converting into pork or bacon farm-pro- duce for which no ready market was available, scarcely entered into the heads of mediaeval fanners. On the contrary, they tell us that, if pigs were entirely dependent on the crops of the arable land, they could not be kept at a profit, when the wages of the swineherd, the cost of the grain consumed, and the damage done to growing crops had been taken into account. Some trade was, however, carried on in stores. This is proved by the records of Fomcett manor {A Norfolk Manor, 1086-1565), which show that, in years when no pigs were kept, stores were bought and fatted for the larder. The poultry yard was under the care of the dairywoman, who sometimes seems to have had the poultry to farm at so much a head. Ducks are not mentioned in any of the mediaeval treatises on farming, though they appear in the Berkeley accounts in 1321 : gnineafowl and turkeys were unknown. But the number of geese and fowls, and, on important estates, of peacocks and swans, was large, and it was swollen by the produce-rents which were often paid in poultry and eggs. The author of Hosebamderie gives minute instructions as to the produce for which the dairywoman ought to account. " Each goose ought to have five goslings a year : " each hen was to answer for 115 eggs and seven chickens, " three of which aa^t to be made capons, and, if there be too many hen chickens, let them be changed for cocks while they are young, so that each hen may answer for three capons and four hens a year, .^d for five geese you must have one gander, and for five hens one cock." Besides the poultry yard, the dove-cote or pigeon-house was a B 18 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM source of profit to the lord and of loss to the tenant. Prodigious numbers of pigeons were kept ; not only were they eaten, but their dung was prized as the most valuable of all manures. The privilege of keeping a pigeon-house was confined to manorial lords and jealously guarded, and every manor had its dove-cote. The story of the French Revolution shows how bitterly the peasants resented the plunder of their hard-earned crops by the lord's pigeons. Doubtless many a British peasant in mediaeval times was stirred to the same hostility by the same nuisance. To the produce of the crops and the live-stock of the demesne must be added game, rabbits from the " conygarth " or warren, cider from the apples, oil from the nuts, honey and wax from the bee>hives, and sometimes grapes from the vineyards. Bee-keeping was an important feature of agricultural industry. The ancient proverb says : " He that hath sheep, swine, and bees, sleep he, wake he, he may thrive." Honey, besides being the only sugar, was invaluable in the still-room, and in the arts of the apothecary, physician, and " chirui^eon." It was an ingredient in mead and metheglyn. It was used in embalming, in medicines, and in such decoctions as mulse water, oenomel, honey water, rodomel, or quintessence. Wax was not only necessary for the candles of the wealthy, but, like honey, was largely used in mediaeval medicine. Mixed with violets, it was a salve : it was also one of the ingredients of " playsteiB, oyntementes, suppositories, and such like." In some districts of England, vineyards formed part of the equipment of manors ; one was made by Lord Berkeley towards the close of the reign of Edward HE., and his biographer suggests that he learned the " husbandry . . . whilst hee was prisoner in fErance or a Traveller in Spaine." Few great monasteries were without vine- yards, which are mentioned thirty-eight times in Domesday Book. It is not necessary to explain the disappearance of the vine by a change of climate. Wine was then often sweetened with honey and flavoured with blackberries and spices. Unless it came from abroad, it was rarely drunk in its pure state. It would, therefore, be unsafe to found any theory of climatic change upon the pro- duction of a liquid which, in its natural state, may frequently have resembled vinegar. Besides the produce of the live-stock and crops of his demesne, the lord of the manor had other sources of revenue. There were the fixed money or produce rents for their land paid by free tenants MANORIAL COURTS 19 and bondmen, and the money payments which were sometimes accepted in lieu of labour services. Sales of timber and underwood, of turf, of herbage, licences to fold on the tenant's land, or licences to turn pigs into the lord's woods for beechmast or acorns, brought in varying sums of money. The mill at which the tenants ground their com was his property. Whether the miller was his servant, or farmed the receipts, a considerable proportion of the tolls went into the landlord's purse, though the cost of repairs and upkeep diminished the net profits. On some manors the oven in which the bread was baked was abo the property of the lord of the manor. The fees and fines levied and settled by the manorial courts in the course of a year were surprisingly large ; besides their administra- tive work, they were at once the guardians and the interpreters of the customs of the manor. The range of business administered in these courts, to which the tenants, both free and bond, were' summoned as jurors, therefore embraced the domestic and financial afiairs of the manor. Here were paid the fees for peimission to reside outside the manor, to send children to school, to enter minor orders, to apprentice a son to a trade, or to marry a daughter. Here too were imposed the fines for slovenly work at harvest, for sellii^ cattle without the lord's leave, for appropriating commons and wastes, for moving a neighbour's landmark, for neglecting to repair a cottage, for failing to discharge labour dues. Here too were fi^^ed the contributions of the tenantry in money or labour towards the maintenance of the by-roads within the manor, and the fines for neglect of the duty to keep their surfaces in repair, to provide for their proper dramage, and to remove obstructions. Here aJso crime was punished ; offenders against life or property, as well as poachers, were mulcted ; wrangling scolds and tavern-hunters were presented ; idlers were deprived of their holdings, and, as a last resort, expelled from the manor. Here too were fixed and levied the necessary contributions for the repair of the stocks, the pillory, the ducking-stool, and the pound. Here the miller would be fined for itiiTiTig rubbish with his flour, the baker for selling short weight, the brewer who adulterated bis beer, the ale-wife and tavern-keeper who used false measures or mixed the drink they sold with peony seed, salt or garUck, the carrier for failing to deliver goods, the householder who harboured a stranger without a licence. Here also were received and entered the fees of tenants for admission to their holdings, and the payment of fines by sons who succeeded 20 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM their fathers. Here, finally, on the sworn evidence of a body of jurors chosen from the tenants, were drawn up the surveys of the manor which recorded the exact condition of the estate — ^the total acreage of the demesne, and of each of the arable fields, of the meadows, the several pastures and the pasturage, and their annual values ; the state of the woods and the coppices, how much could be out, and what they were worth yearly ; the acreage of the commons and the stock which they woxdd carry ; the number of the live-stock of various kinds ; the holdings of the free tenants, and their rents or services ; the holdings of the villeins, bordars, and cottagers, their services and money equivalents ; the profits of fisheries, mills, and incidental manorial rights ; the number of tenants who had finally commuted their services for fixed payments in cash, of those who, at the discretion of the lord, either rendered labour services or paid the money values, and of those who still discharged their personal obligations by actual work. The remainder of the cultivated land of the manor was occupied by tenants who paid rents in the form of military or labour services, or money, or produce. Their farm practices, crops, and hve-stock were the same as those of the demesne, though their difficulties in combating winter scarcity were greater. Free tenants, whose tenure was military service, or who had commuted the per- sonal obhgations for quit-rents, may sometimes have held land, like modem farmers, in their exclusive occupation for individual cultivation. But the area of free land was comparatively small, and, as often as not, it was thrown into the village farm, occupied and cultivated in common by an agrarian association of co-partners, &ee and unfree. The varieties of tenure were great. So also were the varieties of social condition, and of the obligations by which the grades of those social conditions were governed. The distinctions between freemen and bondmen and between freehold and bond tenure had been, in the eye of the law, broad and deep. But custom had gradually intervened, and, with endless variety of practice, miti- gated the severity of legal theory. At law the bondman's position was subject to the lord's caprice. Unlike the freeman, he was tied to the manor ; he could not leave it without Ucence from the lord, and payment of a fine. His services were uncertain in amount, and could be increased at the lord's pleasure. He paid a fine to many his daughter, to send his son to school, to make him a priest RANKS IN RURAL SOCIETY 21 or an apprentice. His lands and his goods and chattels might be seized by his loid, and when he died, his holding was given to whom the lord willed : his heir bought a licence to inherit even his moveables, and paid a fine when he was admitted to his father's tenancy. In the thirteenth century, some at least of these condi- tions had been modified. The bondman's services had become fixed ; he could buy and seU, hold property, and dispose of his possessions by will. In theory he might still be at the mercy of the lord's will : but custom had so regulated the exercise of that will that it could no longer be capricious. Speaking broadly ,*- the ma^ss of the occupiers of land were, in the eye of the law, unfree — bondmen who rented the shares in the land which they cultivated for themselves by labour services on the lord's demesne. It was the amount and certainty of their services which determined the rank of the unfree. Sometimes the service was for the autumn only, or for autumn and spring work, whether on specified days or at peirticular periods ; sometimes of team work, sometimes of manual labour, sometimes of both ; some- times of week-work throughout the year, and either of one, two, or three days in each week. All their spare time was spent on their own holdings. Of this semi-servile class the villeins formed the aristocracy. The villein was neither a servant in husbandry nor a labourer for wages. He occupied land, and, like Chaucer's ploughman, had " catel " of his own. He was a partner in the village association, holding land of various amounts. In theory the size of his holding was based on the number of oxen which, in discharge of his share of the joint liability, he could contribute to the manorial plough-team.' A " hide " of land, which Professor * Students of Profeasor Maitland's invaluable works mU recognise the danger of broad and general statements, to all of which there are exceptions and modifications. • The hide, or "carucate" of Domesday Book, or "ploughland," which aver- ages 120 acres, is sometimes said to have been as much land as a team of 8 oxen could plough in a year of 44 weeks of working days. But Walter of Henley, who is the authority for this statement, only tries to show that the area should be 160, or even 180, acres; he does not say that it actually was of this larger size. It does not seem likely that a fiscal unit varied with the nature of the soil, the weight of the plough, the condition of the team, the configuration of the land, and the temperament of the ploughman. It seems more probable that the hide or carucate was the definite area of 120 acres. Therefore a quarter of a carucate (30 acres) was the Domesday " virgate," which, imder the name of " broad oz-gang," " husband-land," " farm-hold " or " farm " in the North, " yardland " in the Midlands, " full land " in Cambridgeshire, and " living " or " whole place " in Dorsetshire, formed the typiced arable 22 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM Maitiand considers to have been " the land of a household," was treated as the area which a team of eight oxen could plough in a working year. Its extent may have varied. But, if the size was 120 acres, then each hide consisted of four portions of 30 acres, called " virgates," or 8 portions of 15 acres, called " bovates." Thus the eighth part of the hide, or " bovate," was the land of one ox ; the fourth part of the hide, or " vii^ate," was the land of two oxen ; and the whole hide was the land of the complete team of eight oxen. It was on this basis that the tenemental land, in theory, and sometimes in practice, was divided. The typical holding of the villein was regulated by his capacity to furnish one or two oxen to the team. In other words, it was the " virgate " or " yardland " of 30 acres, though one-ox holdings or " bovates " of 15 acres, and even half-ox holdings, were frequent. Villeins of the higher grade were generally distinguished from inferior orders of the semi-servile classes of the peasantry by the size of their holdings in the village farm, by the certainty of their agricultural services on the demesne, and by the obUgation to do team-work rather than manual labour. The smaller the holding, the vaguer the labour obligations, the more manual the work, — the lower was the grade of the villein. Besides the villeins there were other orders of bondmen — such as the rural handicraftsmen who were specially provided with land, and the bordars and cottars, who rented particular cottages and garden ground, which often carried with them from two to five acres of arable land, together with common rights. The two latter classes, besides their obligatory manual services, probably eked out their subsistence either as hired labourers on the demesne or by supplying the labour for which their wealthier neighbours were responsible. At the bottom of the social ladder were the serfs, to whom strict law assigned no rights, though there were many varieties in their grades and position. Their chief badge of serfdom was the indeterminate character of their services — the obligation to labour in the manner, at the time, and for the wage, if any, which the lord directed. But holding of the common-field farmer. It was m fact as much as two oxen could plough in the working year. There were, however, also " one-oz men," whose holdings of 16 acres were an eighth of a carucate, and were called in Domesday Book " bovates," and at later stages " narrow oxgangs," or " half places." Smaller holdings consisting of half bovates, like the " farthing holds " of Dorsetshire, " fardels " of Somersetshire, or " fairundells " of Gloucestershire, were by no means uncommon, and in practice there was no fixed area for the arable holdings of open-field farmers. THE OPEN ARABLE FIELDS 23 the serf might occupy land, own cattle, and labour for himseU. Thus, out of these various classes, free and unfree, sprang small landowners, tenant farmers, copyholders,* and wage-earning labourers. Bound the village, or " town," in which were gathered the home- steaxls of the inhabitants, lay the open arable fields, which were cultivated in common by the associated partners. Here were grown the crops which Shakespeare enumerates. These were the lands " of Ceres " : " — ^thy rich leas " Of wheat, rye, barley, vetches, oats, and peas." * Here, at harvest time, the yellow of the com crops alternated with the dark and light greens of beans or peas and the brown of the bare fallows. This cultivated area, which included the driest and soundest of the land, was hedgeless, open, and unenclosed, divided by turf-grown balks into fields — two, three, or, rarely, four in number. If the former, one field lay fallow, while the other was under tillage for com, or beans, or peas. This dual system still prevailed near Gloucester in the nineteenth century, and existed at Stogursey in Somersetshire in 1879. But from the Norman Conquest onward the three-field system was the most prevalent. Down to the middle of the reign of George HE. the arable land received the unvarying triennial succession of wheat or rye, of spring crops such as barley, oats, beans, or peas, and of fallow. ' The term " copyholder " belongs to a later date. In the thirteenth century, practically all land held in villeinage, or in bondage, was held " according to the custom of the manor " {aeoundum consiietudinem mcmerii). The title was the sworn testimony of those who knew the custom. Land was said to be held not only " according to the custom of the manor," but " at the will of the lord " (ad volwntatem domini). By the thirteenth century, however, the will of the lord was no longer arbitrary, but could only be exer- cised according to manorial custom. Towards the end of the fourteenth century, another expression was added. Tenants were said to hold land " according to the custom of the manor by a copy of the entry on the court roll " (per copiam rotuU cwrioB). Probably it haid been found that, owing to the increased mobility of the rural popula- tion, oral testimony was not always available. Hence it became the practice to enter the incidents of the tenure of customary land on the rolls of the manorial court, and tenants were called copyholders, because the copy of the entry was the evidence of their title. The words " at the will of the lord " were still retained, and it has been suggested {The End of Villainage in England, by T. W. Page, American Economic Association, May, 1900, pp. 84-6) that the use of the words indicated an increased power on the part of the lord to abolish or alter the custom. » Tempest, Act iv. So. i. 60-1. 24 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM During these seven centuries a more scientific rotation was in some districts adopted. Thus at Aston Boges, in Oxfordshire, a fourth course wa« interposed. But, speaking generally, open-field hus- bandry rather retrograded than advanced, as the discipline of manorial officials relaxed. Each of the three arable fields was subdivided into a number of shots, furlongs, or flats, separated from one another by unploughed bush-grown tinf balks, varying ia width from two to sixteen feet.^ These fiats were in turn cut up into parallel acre, halt-acre, or quarter-acre, strips coinciding with the arrangement of a ploughed field into ridges and furrows. If the strips were acre strips, they were a furlong in length (220 yards) and 4 rods (22 yards) in breadth. Ploughmen still measure the acre in the same way as the open- field strip. Theoretically each flat was square, with sides of 40 poles, containing 10 acres ; in practice every variety of shape and admeasiu'ement was found. But, though the pole from which the acre was raised varied from the 13J feet of Hampshire to the 24 feet of Cheshire, two sides of the flats always ran parallel. Thus each of the three arable fields resembled several sheets of paper, cut into various shapes, stitched together like patch-work, and ruled with margins and lines. The separate sheets are the flats ; the margins are the headlands running down the flats at right angles to, and across the ends of, the parallel strips which are represented by the spaces between the lines. The lines themselves are the " balks " of unploughed turf, by which the strips were divided from each other. The strips appear under different names. For instance, in Scotland and Northumberland they were called " rigs " ; in Lincolnshire " selions " ; in Nottinghamshire " lands " ; in Dorsetshire " lawns " ; in North Wales " loons " ; in Westmor- land " dales," and their occupiers " dalesmen " ; in Cambridgeshire " balks " ; in Somersetshire " raps " ; in Sussex " pauls " ; else- where in southern counties " stitches." When the strips were stunted by encountering some obstacle, such as a road or river, they were called " butts." ^ Stray odd comers which did not fit in with the parallel arrangement of the fiats were " crustae," ' that ^ The balks appear under a variety of names, such as " raines," "reins," " walk," " meres," " lynches," " lantchetts," " landshares," " launchers," or " edges." < As in Kewington Butts. * RegiMry of Worcester Priory (Camden Society), 1865, p. 18a. SCATTERED STRIPS IN OPEN-FIELDS 25 is, pieces broken off, " pightels," " gores," ^ " fothers," ^ and " pykes," because, as Fitzherbert explains, they were " often brode in the one ende and a sharpe pyke in the other ende." The arable fields were fenced against the Uve-stook from seed- time to harvest, and the intermixed strips were cultivated for the separate use of individuals, subject to the compulsory rotation by which each of the three fields was cropped. On Lammas Day separate user ended, and conunon rights recommenced ; hence fields occupied in this manner were, and are, called Lammas Lands or " haJf-year lands." After harvest the hayward removed the fences, and the live-stock of the community wandered over the fields before the common herdsman, shepherd, or swineherd. The herdsman, in the reign of Henry Vlii., received 8d. a year for every head of cattle entrusted to his care, and the swineherd 4d. for every head of swine. When sheep were folded on the cultivated land, each farmer provided, during the winter months, his own fold and fodder for his flock. Richard Hooker, while he held the country Uving of Drayton Beauchamp in Buckinghamshire, was found by two of his former pupils, " like humble and innocent Abel, tending his small allotment of sheep in a common field." That no occupier might find all his land fallow in the same year, every one had strips in each of the three arable fields. If the holding of the open-field farmer consisted of thirty acres, there would thus be ten acres in each field. In other words, he would have ten acres under wheat and rye, ten acres under spring crops, and ten acres fallow. The same care was taken to make the divisions equal in agricultural value, so that each man might have his fair pro- portion of the best and worst land. To divide equally the good and bad, well and iU. situated soil, the bundle of strips allotted in each of the three fields did not he together, but was intermixed and scattered. In the lowest part of the land — ^if possible along a stream — lay the " ings," " carrs," " leazes," or meadows, annually cut up into lots or doles, and put up for hay. These doles were fenced off to be mown for the separate use of individuals either from Candlemas (February 2), or, more usually, from St. Gregory's Day (March 12) 1 As in Kensington Gore. > Ci. Chaucer (Prologue, 630) : "A ploughman was his brother. That hadde y-lad of dong ful many a fother," where the word is generally taken to mean a load. 26 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM to Midsummer Day ; from July to February, or later, they were open, common pasturage. Sometimes the plots, which varied in size from a half-acre downwards, went with the arable holdings, so that the same man annually received the same portion of meadow. Sometimes the plots were balloted for every year. Each lot was distinguished by a name, such as the cross, crane's foot, or peel, i.e. baker's shovel, which will often explain puzzling field-names. Corresponding marks were thrown into a hat or bag and drawn by a boy. This balloting continued up to the last century in Somerset- shire, and stm continues at Yamton in Oxfordshire.^ After the hay had been cut and carried, the meadows reverted to common occupation, and were grazed indiscriminately by the live-stock of the village, till they were again fenced off, allotted, and put up for hay. On the outskirts of the arable fields nearest to the village lay one or more " hams " or stinted pastures, in which a regulated number of live-stock might graze, and therefore supplying superior feed. Brandersham, Smithsham, Wontnersham, Herdsham, Con- stable's Meld, Dog Whipper's Land, Barber's Furlong, Tinker's Field, Sexton's Mead, suggest that sometimes special allotments were made to those who practised trades of such general utility as the stock-brander, the blacksmith, the mole-catcher, the cow- herd, the constable, the barber, the tinker, and the sexton. The dog-whipper's usefulness is less obvious ; but possibly he was employed to prevent the live-stock from beiag harried by dogs. Even the spiritual wants of the village were sometimes supplied in the same way. Parson's Close and Parson's Acre are not uncommon. It is significant that no schoolmasters seem to have been provided for by allotments of land. Besides the open arable fields, the meadows, and the stinted hams, there were the common pastures, fringed by the untilled wastes which were left in their native wildness. These wastes pro- vided fern and heather for litter, bedding, or thatching ; small wood for hurdles ; tree-loppings for winter browse of live-stock ; fuzre and turves for fuel ; larger timber for fencing, implements, and building ; mast, acorns, and other food for the swine. Most of these smaller rights were made the subject of fixed annual pay- ments to the manorial lord ; but the right of cuttlog fuel was generally attached to the occupation, not only of arable land, but 1 As described by B. H. Gretton in The Economic JoumoU tat March, 1912. THE COMMON-PASTURES 27 of cottages. The most important part of these lands were the common pastures, which were often the only grass that arable farmers could command for their live-stock. Thej therefore formed an integral and essential part of the village farm. No rights were exercised upon them by the general public. On the contrary, the commons were most jealously guarded by the privileged commoners against the intrusion or encroachments of strangers. The agistment of strange cattle or sheep was strictly prohibited : commoners who turned out more stock than their proper share were " presented " at the manorial courts and fined ; cottages erected on the commons were condemned to be pulled down ; the area within which swine might feed was carefully limited, and the swine were to be ringed.^ Those who enjoyed the grazing rights were the occupiers of arable land, whose powers of turning out stock were, in theory, proportioned to the size of their arable holdings, and the occupiers of certain cottages, which commanded higher rents in consequence of the privilege. It was on these commons that the cattle and sheep of the village were fed. Every morning the cattle were collected, probably by the sound of a horn, and driven to the commons by the village herdsman along drift ways, which were enclosed on either side by moveable or permanent fences to keep the animals from straying on to the arable land. In the evening they were driven back, each animal returning to its own shelter, as the herd passed up the village street. Similarly, the sheep were driven by the village shepherd to the commons by day, and folded at night on the wheat fallows. Sheep were the manure carriers, and were prized as much for their folding quality as for their fleeces. In some districts they were kept almost entirely for their agricultural value to the arable land. Until the winter they were penned in the common fold on the fallows or the stubbles. After the fallows had been ploughed, and before the crops on the other fields were cleared, they had only the commons. During winter each commoner was obliged to find hay for his sheep and his own fold, the common shepherd penning and folding them so as gradually to cover the whole area. The open-field system, thus briefly sketched with its arable, meadow, and permanent pasture land, prevailed at some time or ^ The Regulations for " Common Bighta at Cottenham and Stretham " are printed by Dr. Cunningham in the Camden MisceUany, vol. zii. (1910), pp. 173-296. 28 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM other throughout England, except perhaps in the south-west. The following description of the crofters' holdings in Skye in 1760 might have been written, with but few alterations, of half the cul- tivated area of England in the eighteenth century : " A certain number of tacksmen formed a copartnery and held a tract of land, or township, for which they paid tribute to the chief, and each member was jointly and severally responsible. The grazing was in common. All the arable land was divided into ridges, assigned annually, by lot among the partners. Each might have a dozen or more of these smaU ridges, and no two contiguous except by accident ; the object being to give each partner a portion of the better and inferior land. The copartner appears to have had cotters under him, for whose work he paid." The prevalence of the system may still be traced with more or less distinctness in rural England. The counties in which it was most firmly established are counties of villages, not of scattered farmsteads and hamlets. Turf balks and lynches record the time when " every rood of ground maintained its man." Irregular and regular fences, narrow lanes and wide highways, crooked and straight roads, respectively sug- gest the piecemeal or the wholesale enclosure of common fields. The waving ridges on thousands of acres of ancient pasture still represent the swerve of the cumbrous village plough with its team of eight oxen. The age of the hedgerow timber sometimes tells the date of the change. The pages appropriated to hedges by agricultural writers of the eighteenth century indicate the era of the abolition of open fields, and the minuteness of their instructions proves that the art of making hedges was still in its infancy. The scattered lands of ordinary farms, compared with the compact " court," " hall," or " manor " farm, recall the fact that the lord's demesne was once the only permanent enclosure. The crowding together of the rural population in villages betrays the agrarian partnership, as detached farmsteads and isolated labourers' dwellings indicate the system by which it has been supplanted. Accurate comparison between the conditions of the rural popula- tion in the thirteenth and twentieth centuries seems impossible. Calculations based on the prices of commodities, involving, as they must, the translation of the purchasing power of mediaeval money into its modem equivalent, are necessarily guess-work. They are- also to a great extent irrelevant, for few of the necessaries of life were ever bought by the cultivators of the soil, and whether the THE SELF-SUPPORTING VILLAGES 29 com that they raised was fetching 3s. or 6s. the quarter in a distant market made little difference to the inhabitants of villages. They grew it for their own consumption. Owing to diflSculties of com- munication, every village raised its own bread-supply. Hence a great extent of land, which from a farming point of view formed an excessive proportion of the total area, was tilled for com, however tmsuited it might be for arable cultivation. As f aciUties of transport increased, this necessity became less and less paramount. Land best adapted to pasture no longer required to be ploughed, but might be put to the use for which it was naturally fitted. Improve- ments in means of communication were thus among the changes which helped to extinguish village farms. But for the time, and so long as the open-field system prevailed, farming continued to be in the main a self-sufficing industry. Except for the payment of rent, little coin was needed or used in rural districts. Parishes till the middle of the eighteenth century remained what they were in the thirteenth century — isolated and self-supporting. The inhabitants had little need of communication even with their neighbours, still less with the outside world. The fields and the hve-stock provided their necessary food and clothing. Whatever wood was required for building, fencing, and fuel was supphed from the wastes. Each village had its mill, and nearly every house had its oven and brewing kettle. Women spun and wove wool into coarse cloth, and hemp or nettles into linen ; men tanned their own leather. The rough tools required for cultivation of the soil, and the rude household utensils needed for the comforts of daily life, were made at home. In the long winter evenings, farmers, their sons, and their servants carved the wooden spoons, the platters, and the beechen bowls. They fitted and riveted the bottoms to the horn mugs, or closed, in coarse fashion, the leaks in the leathern jugs. They plaited the osiers and reeds into baskets and into " weeles " for catching fish ; they fixed handles to the scythes, rakes, and other tools ; cut the fiaUs from holly or thorn, and fastened them with thonp to the staves ; shaped the teeth for rakes and harrows from ash or willow, and hardened them ia the fire ; cut out the wooden shovels for casting the com in the granary ; fashioned ox-yokes and bows, forks, racks, and rack-staves ; twisted willows into scythe-cradles, or into traces and other harness gear. Travelling carpenters, smiths, and tinkers visited detached farmhouses and smaller villages, at rare intervals, to perform 30 THE MANORIAL SYSTEM those parts of the work which needed their professional skili. But every village of any size found employment for such trades as those of the smith and the carpenter, and the frequency with which " Smiths Ham " appears among field names suggests the value which the inhabitants attached to the forge and the anvil. Mean- while the women plaited straw or reeds for neck-collars, stitched and stuffed sheepskin bags for cart-saddles, peeled rushes for wicks and made candles. Thread was often made from nettles. Spinning-wheels, distafEs, and needles were never idle. Home- made cloth and linen supplied all wants. Flaxen linen for board- cloths, sheets, shirts or smocks, and towels, as the napkins were called, on which, before the introduction of forks, the hands were wiped, was only found in wealthy houses and on special occasions. Hemp, in ordinary households, supphed the same necessary articles, and others, such as candle-wicks, in coarser form. Shoe- thread, halters, stirrup-thongs, girths, bridles, and ropes were woven from the " carle " hemp ; the finer kind, or " fimble " hemp, supplied the coarse linen for domestic use, and " hempen home- spun " * passed into a proverb for a countryman. Nettles were also extensively used in the manufacture of linen ; sheets and table- cloths made from nettles were to be found in many homes at the end of the eighteenth century. The formation of words like spin- ster, Webster, lyster, shepster, maltster, brewster, and baxter indicated that the occupations were feminine, and show that women spun, wove, dyed, and cut out the cloth, as well as malted the barley, brewed the ale, and baked the bread for the family. ' MidBwrnmer-NigtU's Dream, Act iii. Sc. 1. FEUDAL BARONS AT CORN-MARKETS 31 CHAPTER II. TIEE BREAK-UP OP THE MANOR. 1300-1485. Great lamdloids as faimeTS : horrors of winter scarcity : gradual decay of the manorial system and the increased struggle for life : aspects of the change : common rights over cultivated and uncultivated land : tendency towards separate occupation : substitution of labour-rents for money- rents; the Black Death; Labour legislation, and its effect; Manor of Castle Combe and Berkeley Estates ; new relations of landlords and tenants substituted for old relations of feudal lords and dependents ; tenant- f anneis and free labourers ; leases and larger fanns ; increase of separate occupations : Wilhcon Paston and Hugh Latimer ; wage-earning labourers ; voliintaiy sturender of holdings ; freedom of movement and of contract. CHAiiraES in farming practices are always slow ; without ocular demonstration of their superiority, and without experience of increased profits, new methods are rarely adopted. In the Middle Ages agriculture was a self-supporting industry rather than a profit-making business. The inmiediate neighbourhood of large towns created markets for the surplus produce that remained after satisfying the needs of the cultivators of the soil. But remoter villages contained neither buyers of produce nor pioneers of improve- ments. Edward I. was a gardener, and Edward n. a farmer, horse-breeder, and thatcher. These royal tastes may have set the fashion. Here and there great lay landowners, as well as great ecclesiastics, actively interested themselves in farming progress. Thomas, first Lord Berkeley, who held the family estates from 1281 to 1321, encouraged his tenants to improve their land by marling, or by taking earth from the green highways of the manors. Another famous farmer was his grandson, the third Lord (1326-61). Feudal barons are rarely represented as fumbling ra the recesses of their armour for samples of com. But " few or noe great fajres or marketts were in those parts, whereat this lord was not himself, as at Wells, Gloucester, Winchcomb, Tetbury, and others ; where also hee new bought or changed the severall grains that sowed his 32 THE BREAK-XJP OF THE MANOR axrable lands." > These mediaeval prototypes of " Farmer George," of " Tumip " Townshend, or of Coke of Norfolk were rare. Few of the baronial aristocracy verified the troth of the maxim that "the master's foot fats the soil." The strenuous idleness or the military ardour of youthful lords was generally absorbed in field sports and martial exercises — in tilting at the ring, in hawking, hunting the buck, or lying out for nights together to net the fox. Grown to man's estate, they congregated for a month at a time at " tylts, tumaments, or other hastiludes," or exchanged the mimicry of war for its realities in France, or on the borders of Scotland and Wales. Most of the lay barons rebelled against the minute and continuous labotu* of farming, and this contempt for bucolic life may be illustrated from heraldry. Its emblems are drawn from sport, war, mythology, or religion. Products and implements of husbandry are despised, unless, like the " garb " or sheaf of the Washboumes, the scythe of the Sneyds, or the hay-wains of the Hays, they had been ennobled by martial use. Few landowners, except the wealthiest, had as yet built per- manent residences on their distant estates. Content with temporary accommodation, they travelled with their households and retinues from manor to manor, and from farmhouse to farmhouse, in order to consume on the spot the produce of their fields and live-stock. It was the practice of the first Lord Berkeley to go " in progress from one of his Manor and f armehouses to an other scarce two miles a sunder, making his stay at each of them . . . and soe backe to his standinge houses where his wife and family remayned . . . sometymes at Berkeley Castle, at Wotton, at Bradley, at Awre, at Portbury, And usually in Lent at Wike by ArUngham, for his better and neerer provision of Pish." His example was followed by his successors. But in the frequent absences of manorial lords on military service at home or abroad, iheir wives played important parts in rural life. Joan, wife of the first Lord Berkeley, " at no tyme of her 42 yeares manage ever travelled ten miles from the mansion houses of her husband in the Countyes of Gloucester and Somersett, much lesse humered herselfe with the vaine delights of London and other Cities." She spent much of her time in super- vising her " dairy affairs," passing from farmhouse to farmhouse, taking accoimt of the smallest details. The fanuly tradition ^ The Livea of the Berkdeye, by John Smyth of Nibley, ed. Maclean (1883), vol. i. p. 300. THE MONKS AS FARMERS 33 lingered long. The same housewifely courses were followed by the widowed Lady Serkeley, who administered the estates during her son's minority in the reigns of Henry Vlil. and Edward VI., and died in 1664. At all her country houses she " would betimes in Winter and Somer mornings make her walkes to visit her stable, bames, dayhousc, pultry, swinetroughs, and the like." Her daughter-in-law's tastes were drSerent. She was a sportswoman, delighting in buck-hunting, skilled with the cross-bow, an expert archer, devoted to hawking, commonly keepiog " a cast or two of merlins, which sometimes she mewed in her own chamber, which falconry cost her husband each yeare one or two gownes and Mrtles spoiled by their mutings." Well might the elder lady " sweare, by God's blessed sacrament, this gay girle wiU begger my son Henry ! " Great ecclesiastics made their progresses from manor to manor like the lay barons, and for the same reason. But in many instances monks were resident landowners, and by them were initiated most of the improvements which were made in the practices of mediaeval farming. They studied agriculture in the light of the writings of Cato, Varro, and Columella : the quaintly rhymed English version of Palladius was probably the work of an inmate of a religious house at Colchester ; the Bides for the management of a landed estate are reputed to be the work of one of the greatest of thirteenth century churchmen, Robert Grosteste, Bishop of Lincoln ; Walter ' of Henley is said to have been a Dominican, and manuscripts of his work, either ia the original Norman French or translated into English or Latin, found a place in many monastic libraries. Throughout the Middle Ages, both in England and France, it was mainly the influence of the monks which built roads and bridges, improved Uve-stock, drained marshes, cleared forests, reclaimed wastes, and brought barren land into cultivation. Large improvements in the mediaeval methods of arable farming were impossible until farmers commanded the increased resources of more modem times. There was littie to mitigate, either for men or beasts, the horrors of winter scarcity. Nothing is more characteristic of the infancy of farming than the violence of its alternations. On land which was inadequately manured, tind on which neither field-turnips nor clovers were known till centuries later, there could be no middle course between the exhaustion of continuous cropping and the rest-cure of barrenness. The fallow was un vSritable Dimanche accords d, la terre. As with the land, so 34 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR with its products. Famine trod hard on the heels of feasting. It was not only that prices rose and fell with extraordinary rapidity ; but both for men and beasts the absolute scarcity of winter always succeeded the relative plenty of autumn. Except in monastic granges no great quantities of grain were stored, and mediaeval legislators eyed corn-dealers with the same hostiUty with which modem engineers of wheat comers are regarded by their victims. The husbandman's golden rule must have been often forgotten — that at Candlemas half the fodder and all the com must be untouched. Even the most prudent housekeepers found it difficult always to remember the proverbial wisdom of eating within the tether, or sparing at the brink instead of the bottom. Many, like Fanurge, eat their com in the blade. Equally violent were the alternations in the employment afforded by mediaeval farming. Weeks of feverish activity passed suddenly into months of com- parative indolence. Winter was in fact a season to be dreaded alike by the husbandman and his cattle, and it is not without good cause that the joyousness of spring is the key-note of early English poetry. Under the conditions which prevailed in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, Uttle advance in farming practices could be expected. During the greater part of the period, therefore, the history of agriculture centres round those economic, social, and political changes which shaped its future progress. Under the pressure of these influences the structure of feudal society was undermined. The social mould, in which the mediaeval world had been cast, crumbled to powder under a series of transformations, which, though they worked without combination or regularity, proved to be, from the latter half of the fourteenth century onwards, collectively and uniformly irresistible. Prom within, as well as from without, the manor as an organisation for regulating rural labour and administering local affairs was breaking up. As money grew more plentiful, it became more and more universally the basis on which services were regulated. Commerce, as it expanded, created new markets for the sale of the produce of the soil. Parlia- ment assumed new duties ; the Royal Courts of Justice extended their jurisdiction ; and, as a consequence, manorial courts lost some of their importance in matters of local self-government. Land was beginning to be regarded as a source of income, not of military X>ower. As landowning became a business and farming a trade. THE NEW STRUGGLE FOR LIFE 35 agricultural progress demanded less personal dependence, a freer hand, a larger scope for individual enterprise. The foundations of feudalisni were thus shaken, though the Hundred Years' War main- tained its superstructure intact. It is this contrast between reality and appearance which gives an air of hollowness and artificiality to the splendour of the reign of Edward HI. The break-up of the manorial system accompanied the transition from an age of graduated mutual dependence towards an age of greater individual independence. It meant the removal of restric- tions to personal freedom, the encouragement of individual enter- prise, the establishment of the principle of competition in determining both money rents and money wages. From another point of view the results were not entirely advantageous. Against the older system it might be urged that it created a lack of opportunity which caused local stagnation. In its favour might be pleaded that it maintained a certain level of equality among the households in village communities, presided over by the lord of the manor. Now, however, the struggle for life becomes intensified ; the strong go to the front, the weak to the wall ; for one man who rises in the social scale, five sink. Here, one prospers, laying field to field, adding herd to herd and flock to flock. Here, others sell their live-stock, yield their strips of land to their more enterprising neighbour, and become dependent upon him for employment and wages. From the fourteenth century onwards the agricultural problem of holding the balance even between the economic gain and social loss of E^ricultural progress has puzzled the wisest of legislators. The manorial organisation of labour suffered no sudden or uni- versal coUapse, due to any improvements in the methods or altera- tion in the aims of farming. It rather underwent a gradual and local decay which originated in economic, social, and political causes, and proceeded most rapidly in the neighbourhood of trading centres or sea-ports. It would be inaccurate to attempt to divide this process into successive stages, because they always overlapped, were generally simultaneous, and were often almost complete on one manor before they had begun on another. But from one point of view, the movement increased the number of holdings which were separately occupied ; in another aspect, it exchanged labour ser- vices for their cash values, and altered the relations between feudal lords and their retainers into those of employer and employed, and of the letter and the hirer of land ; in another, it applied principles 36 TBDE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR of competition to money rents and money wages ; in another, it encouraged enterprising tenants to recognise that the best results of farming could only be obtained on compact holdings, large enough for the employment of money as well as of labour. The tendency towards the separate occupation and individual management of land had already begun, though it was most marked on the new land which was brought into cultivation. On the ancient arable land it was checked by the rights of common which were enjoyed, not only over the waste, but over the open arable fields. In their origin these rights were arable and attached only to arable land. Each occupier of an arable holding was entitled to graze on the common pastures the horses and oxen required for his tillage operations, and to feed the sheep needed for manuring his cultivated land. Without this right the associated partners in the common venture of farming would have had no means of supporting their beasts after the crops were sown. Common rights of pasture were therefore integral portions of, and essential adjuncts to, the ancient tillage system.^ No rights of common of pasture could be claimed by the general public. The only persons by whom they could be acquired and enjoyed were the occupiers of arable holdings. It was as occupiers of portions of the tilled land, which was in fact or in theory attached to their homes, that cottagers claimed and exercised grazing privileges. On most manors three distinct kinds of common rights existed. The first kind is, in this connection, unimportant, though its creation marks an improvement in agricultural practices and a step towards the break-up of the early open-field system. It arose when the partners in a village farm agreed, with the sanction of the lord of the manor, to set aside a portion of their joint arable holdings for pasture, to be used in common in a " stinted " or regulated manner. " There is commonly," says Ktzherbert,* " a common close taken in out of the common fields by tenants of the same towne, in which close every man is stinted and set to a cer- taintie how many beasts he shall have in common." The second class of conmion of pasture consisted of rights enjoyed by the partners of the agrarian association over the whole cvUivated area of the village farm, both over the arable portion that lay fallow in rotation, and over all the other arable lands and meadows, after the crops had been cleared and before the land was again sown or I See chapter i. pp. 23-27. * The Bolce of Surveyeng and Improvementet (1623), ed. 1639, chap. iz. VARIOUS RIGHTS OF COMMON 37 put up for hay. The third kind of conunon of pasture consisted of rights over that part of the manor which was neither arable nor meadow, — ^the outlying portions, which were left in their natural condition, — ^the pastures, moors, wastes, woods, and heaths, which had never been tilled. These rights were attached to the arable holdings of manorial tenants, and to the occupation of particular cottages on the manor, and, when the strictness of the ancient system relaxed, might also be acquired by neighbours and strangers who neither Uved nor held land within the manor. " In these commons," says Pitzherbert,^ " the lord should not be stinted because the whole common is his own." Rights of common of pasture over cultivated or commonable land, under the second heading, were enjoyed by the partners in the village farm, were exercised in virtue of their arable holdings, were limited to the extent of the farm, and could only be extinguished by the agreement of the co-partners. But if the lord of the manor, as a partner in the farm, had allowed portions of his demesne to be intermixed with the strips of his tenants, he could withdraw those portions at will, even though their withdrawal diminished the com- monable area of cultivated land. With this exception, land subject to these rights of common could not be freed by any individual tenant, unless the main body of his farming partners assented. Rights of common of pasture over the imtiUed land, under the third heading, were at first confined to the occupiers of arable holdings on the manor. In process of time, however, they were less narrowly limited. They could not be enjoyed by a landless public ; but they might be exercised by persons living both within and without the manor. In the case of persons living within the manor, the enjoyment of common rights belonged to the occupation of arable holdings or of particular cottages to which arable land had been or was attached. In the case of persons living outside the manor, rights might be acquired by neighbours and strangers, either by direct grant from the lord of the manor, or, through his sufferance, by long usage. As a general rule, the number of live- stock which each manorial tenant or freeholder could pasture on the wastes was fixed, or capable of being fixed, in proportion to his holding. Vaguer rights were acquired by neighbours and strangers, and it was in these cases mainly that the lord's right of enclosure was successfully resisted. At common law it seems that, against ' Surveying, ohsp. iv. 38 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR his own customary tenants, the lord of the manor could always enclose the wastes at pleasure. Whether before 1236 he had the same power at common law against the iree tenants of the manor is disputed. Be this as it may, the Statute of Merton ^ in that year empowered the lord of the manor to enclose against his free tenants, provided enough pasture was left to satisfy his previous grants of rights of common. Fifty years later, the Statute of Westminster ^ (1285) extended the lord's right of enclosure to the case of those neighbours and strangers who had acquired grazing rights, subject to the same condition of sufficiency of pasture. Practically the existence of rights of common of pasture only prevented enclosures when the rights were enjoyed by the associated body of tenants over one another's cultivated and commonable land, or when general rights, vaguely expressed, had been acquired by strangers or neighbours over the untilled wastes of the lord of the manor. Unless a custom to the contrary could be established, an enclosure of untilled waste by the lord of the manor would be upheld in the law courts, provided that the number of live-stock which could be turned out by the commoners was certain or capable of being ascertained, and that enough pasture was left to satisfy the grazing rights. As early as the end of the twelfth century, landlords had begun to withdraw their demesne lands from the village farm, to con- solidate, enclose, and cultivate them in separate ownership. They had also pared the outskirts of their woods and chases, reclaimed and enclosed these " assart " lands, as they were called, and either added them to their demesnes or let them in several occupations. They had also begun to encourage partners in village farms ^ to agree among themselves, to extinguish their mutual rights of common over the cultivated land which they occupied, to con- solidate their holdings by exchange, and to till them as separate farms. The pace at which these enclosures proceeded, and the extent to which they were carried, varied with each county and almost with each manor. But by the end of the fifteenth century, though the great bulk of the village farms remained untouched, the area of land over which manorial tenants enjoyed rights of common was considerably diminished, partly by the action of lords of the manors, partly by that of the tenants themselves. Portions of the 1 20 Hen. m. c. 4. > 13 Ed. I. c. 46. ' See chapter i. p. 6, note 1, and pp. 23-27. MONEY RENTS AND WAGES 39 tintilled waste had been enclosed, reduced to cultivation, and let in separate farms to rent-paj^ing leaseholders, and to copyholders, who were admitted to their tenancies in the Court Baron and entered as tenants on the court roll. " Many of the lordes," says Ktzherbert, " have enclosed a great part of their waste grounds, and straightened their tenants of their commons within." So also, by withdrawing those parts of the cultivated demesne which lay in the village fields, and letting them in small compact holdings, they had reduced the area of cultivated land over which common of pasture was enjoyed. Fitzherbert notes that " the mooste part of the lordes have enclosed their demeyn landes and medows, and kepe them in severaltie, so that theyr tenauntes have no comyn with them therein." Finally, the tenants themselves followed the example of their landlords. Wherever the custom of the manor permitted the practice, tenants and partners in the village farms accepted " Ucenses to enclose part of their arable land, and to take in new intakes or closes out of the commons," or agreed with their fellow-commoners to extinguish, temporarily or permanently, their mutual rights to graze each other's arable and meadow lands after the crops had been cleared. At first the holdings, whether separate or associated, were, as has been previously described, rented by labour services or produce- rents. But from the latter half of the thirteenth century onwards a change had been taking place. Landowners, who were them- selves exchanging their personal services for cash equivalents, needed money not only to make the purchases required by on advancing standard of Uving, but to satisfy the demands of the royal tax-collectors. In their land they found a new source of income. They still kept their demesnes in hand ; but they pre- ferred to cultivate these home farms by the contract services of hired men, whether servants in husbandry or day labourers, instead of relying on the compulsory labour of tenants, which it was difficult and expensive to supervise. They were, therefore, willing to commute for money payments the team dues, and, to a less extent, the manual dues, by which much of the manorial land was rented — whether in the whole or in part, whether temporarily or permanently. Those who owed the personal services were on their side eager to pay the cash equivalents. The money payments freed them from labour obligations which necessarily interfered with their own agri- cultural operations, and enabled them to devote themselves, con- 40 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR tinaously and exclusively, to the cultivation of their own holdings. Their places on the demesne land were taken by wage-earning fann- servants or hired labourers, recruited from the landless sons of tenants, or from cottagers who either had no holding at all or not enough to supply them with the necessaries of life. Thus there were hired farm-servants and day-labourers cultivating the demesne land for money wages ; tenants paying money rents only for their holdings ; others who still paid their whole rent in produce or in labour ; others whose labour services had been partially commuted for money payments, either for a period or permanently. < The local and gradual break-up of the manorial organisation of agricultural labour was accelerated by the Black Death (1348-9). Entering England through the port of Weymouth in August, 1348, the plague spread to the north before it died out in the autumn of the following year. It had been preceded by several years of dearth and pestilence, and it was succeeded by four outbreaks of similar disease before the end of the century. During its ravages it destroyed from one-third to one-half of the population. Lords of manors suffered both as owners of land and as employers of labour. Whole families were swept away, and large quantities of land were thrown on the hands of landlords by the deaths of free- holders and customary tenants without heirs or descendants. Numbers of bondmen took advantage of the general confusion, threw up their holdings, escaped into the towns, or joined the ranks of free labourers. Their dereUct holdings increased the mass of untenanted land, and their flight diminished the amount of resident labour available for the cultivation of the home farm. Those tenants who remained on the manor found in the landlord's diffi- culty their opportunity of demanding increased wages, of commuting labour services for money payments,^ of enlarging the size of their ' Before the Black Death, on 81 manors, the services of tenants supplied the necessary farm labour on the demesnes in the following proportions : on 44, the whole ; on 22, the half ; on 9, an inconsiderable portion ; on 6, all labour services were commuted. After the Black Death (1371-80), on 126 majiors, the proportions were as follows : on 22, the whole ; on 26, the half ; on 39, an inconsiderable portion ; on 40, all labour services were com- muted. The End of Villainage m England, by T. W. Page (Publications of the American Economic Association, May, 1900), pp. 44-46, 69-65. Miss Davenport {The Economic Development of a Norfolk Manor, 1906, pp. 62, 68) says that, out of 3219 services charged on the lands of Fomcett Manor in 1376, only 195 were available in 1406. STATUTES OF LABOUR 41 holdings, of establishing the principle of competitive rents. The " Great Death " in fact produced the natural results. There was a fall in rents and a rise in wages, because the supply of land exceeded the demand, and the demand for labour was greater than the supply. Legislation came to the aid of landowners by endeavouring to maintain the supply of labour and to regulate the rise both of wages and of prices. The statutes clearly illustrate the difficulties of landlords and consumers. The crisis was so abnormal that unusual action seemed justifiable. In the plague years of 1348-9 agricultural labour was so scarce that panic wages were asked and paid. A similar rise in prices took place simultaneously. So exorbitant did the demands both of labourers and producers appear, following as they did on a previous rise in both wages and prices, that a royal proclamation was issued in 1349. It ordered all men and women, " bond or free," — ^unless living on their own resources, tilling their own land, employed in merchandise, or exercising some craft, — to work on the land where they hved at the rate of wages current in 1346. Those who gave or took higher wages were fined treble or double the sums so given or received. The claim of lords of manors to the services of their own men was acknowledged. But their claim was no longer exclusive ; they were not to employ more labour than they absolutely required. The king's proclamation was not universally obeyed. Employers had either to lose their crops or yield to " the proud and covetuous desires " of the men. They were indeed placed in a difficulty. On the one hand, men could not be hired under threepence to perform the same services which had been recently commuted for a half-penny. On the other hand, the strike was well-aimed and well-timed. It hit the most vulnerable points. The classes of agricultural labourers against whom the proclamation was specially directed were ser- vants in husbandry, mowers, reapers, and harvesters. Servants in husbandry, boarding at the home-farm or the houses of the larger tenants, were the ploughmen, carters, cowherds, shepherds, milk- maids, and swineherds, who had the care of the Uve-stock. They, like the harvesters, were indispensable. If the crops were not harvested when ripe, they spoiled ; if the Hve-stock were neglected, they died. To solve the difficulty ParUament itself intervened. The provisions of the proclamation were supplemented by the first Statute of Labourers (1349, 23 Ed. III.), and expanded by a. 42 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR series of Acts extending over the next 150 years.^ The stocks, imprisonment, outlawry, and branding were the punishments of those who refused to work, or absented themselves without hcence from the hundred where they Uved. Every boy or girl, who had served in husbandry up to the age of twelve " at the plough or cart," was bound to " abide at the same labour." Justices, either of the Peace or under a special commission, were sworn to enforce the Acts, and to fix the rates of wages at which labourers could be compelled to serve. How far this legislation attained its immediate ends it is difficult to say ; the repeated re-enactment of labour laws, the petitions of employers, and the preambles to successive statutes may seem to suggest that it failed. On the other hand, there is abundant evidence* that the law was rigorously enforced, and this would naturally be inferred from the fact that its administration was entrusted to officials who were directly interested in compelling obedience to its provisions. The rise both in wages and prices was great. But the statutes undoubtedly prevented either from reaching famine height. Whether they were completely successful or not, they embittered the relations between employers and employed, and so prepared the ground for the Peasants' Rising of 1381. Confronted by a discontented peasantry, burdened with large tracts of land which threatened to pass out of cultivation, hampered by the scarcity and deamess of labour, landlords turned in new directions for relief. Here and there, where the climate favoured the expedient, they reduced their labour-bills by laying down tracts of arable land to pasture. Elsewhere the demesnes were let off in separate farms at money rents. Often, in order to secure tenants, the land was let on the " stock and land " system, similar to that of the rrUtayer, the landlord findmg the stock and implements. Sometimes the entire manor was leased to one or 1 E.g. 1360-1 (34 Ed. m. cc. 10, 11) ; 1368 (42 Ed. IIL o. 6) ; 1377 (1 Rio. n. c. 6) ; 1386 (8 Bic. H. c. 2) ; 1388 (12 Bic. U. cc. 3-9) ; 1402 (4 Hen. IV. c. 14) ; 1405 (7 Hen. IV. c. 17) ; 1423 (2 Hen. VI. c. 18) ; 1427 (6 Hen. VI. c. 3) ; 1429 (8 Hen. VI. c. 8) ; 1444 (23 Hen. VI. c. 12) ; 1496 (11 Hen. Vn. c. 22) ; 1496 (12 Hen. VII. c. 3) ; 1614 (6 Hen. VHI. c. 3) ; 1663 (6 Eliz. c. 4). >MiBS Putnam's Enforcement of the Statutes of Labourers (1908), (Columbia University : Studies in History, Economics and Public Law, vol. zzxii.) is an exhaustive commentary on the administration of the law from 1349 to 1360. THE MANOR OF CASTLE COMBE 43 more tenants, who paid a fixed annual rent for the whole, and then sub-let portions of the land.^ Two examples of this gradual transformation of the manorial system may be quoted. In the first instance— that of Castle Combe * in Wiltshire — ^the neighbourhood of a clothmaking industry may have made the process of change exceptionally rapid, even for the south of England. At the Domesday Surrey the manor contained 1200 acres imder the plough. Of this arable land, 480 acres were in the lord's demesne, cultivated by 13 serfs and the team and manual labour of the manorial tenants. The remainder of the arable area (720 acres) was occupied by 5 villeins, 7 bordars, and 5 cottagers. There was a wood of a mile and half in length by three quarters of a mile in breadth. There were also three water mills. The whole popidation consisted of bondmen : none were, in the eye of the law, free. In 1340 the tenemental land had increased to nearly 1000 acres. There were ten freemen, holding between them 247 acres of arable land. Of these freemen, one of the three millers held an estate of inheritance to himself and his heirs, at a fixed quit-rent, subject to a heriot and attendance at the manorial courts. The nine remaining freemen, among whom were the other two millers, held their land at will at fixed money rents and similar services. The rest of the inhabitants were still bondmen. Fifteen customary tenants occupied for the term of two Uves 540 arable acres, in holdings of from 60 to 30 acres, partly by money rents, partly by labour services. Eleven others held 15 acres each (165 acres) for two lives, paying their rent only by labour on the demesne ; but in addition nine of them also held crofts, for which they paid annual money rents. All these classes, in virtue of their holdings, were protected against caprices of the lord's will by manorial customs. Many of them remained bondmen in status, but the condition of their tenure was raised. Eight " Monday-men " held cottages and crofts or curtilages by labour services only. These thirty-four bondmen, at the will of * Thus the land of the manor of Hawated in Sufiolk was let in 1410 by Sir William Clopton to Walter Bone, Sir William reserving the manor-house and the fines and other legal rights of a manor (History of Hawated, pp. 193-5). ^Hittory of the Manor, etc. of CasUe Combe, by G. Poulett Scrope (1862). The areas are calculated on the assumption that the local " earucate " con- tained 120 acres. Whatever the actual acreage may have been, the pro- portions remain the same. 44 THE BREAK-XJP OF THE MANOR the lord, could buy themselves out of their labour obligations on payment of the cash values which are entered against their services in the steward's book. In this event substitutes were provided in the twelve cottagers, who paid a fixed money rent for their cottages. Immediately after the " Great Death " the final stage is reached. In 1352 the demesne was cut up into separate farms, and let on money rents. Labour services were therefore no longer needed, and were either merged in the copyhold rents or allowed to die out. The second instance, that of the vast estates of the Berkeleys, covers a wider area. The policy adopted by the family in the management of their manors in Gloucestershire, Somersetshire, Essex, and elsewhere, was in one important respect consistent from 1189 to 1417. Throughout the whole period, successive lords aimed at increasing their enclosures. They began to withdraw those portions of the demesne which lay in " common fields, here one acre or ridge, and there an other, one man's intermixt with an other," to consolidate them, free them from common, and enclose. By exchange with free tenants, other lands were thrown together and similarly treated. The skirts of woods and chases were taken in hand, and hundreds of acres of " assart " land were enclosed. Sometimes these enclosures were made by agreement ; sometimes without. Maurice de Berkeley (1243-81) had within his manor of Hame " a wood called whitclive wood, adioinynge whereunto were his Tenants' arrable and pasture grounds and likewise of divers freeholders. This hee fancieth to reduce into a parke ; hee treateth with freeholder and tenant for buyinge or exchanginge of such of their lands lyeing neere the said wood as hee fancied : In which wood, also, many others had comon of pasture for theire cattle all tymes of the yeare, (for noe woods or grounds, in effect, till the Eve of this age, were inclosed or held in severalty :) with theis also hee treatieth for releases of their comon : After some labor spent, and not prevailinge to such effect as hee aymed at : hee remembered (as it seemeth) the Adage, muUa rum laudantur nisi priua peracta : many actions are not praisworthy till they bee done : Hee there- fore on a sodaine resolutely incloseth soe much of each man's land imto his sayd wood as hee desired : maketh it a parke, placeth keepers, and storeth it with Deere, And called it, as to this day it is, Whitclyve parke. They seeing what was done, and this lord offeringe compositions and exchanges as before, most of them THE BERKELEY ESTATES 45 soone agreed, when there was noe remedy. . . . Those few that rema3med obstinate fell after upon his sonne with suites, to theire small confort and less gaines." ^ For the first 140 years of the period (1189-1417) the lords of Berkeley steadily pursued the plan of converting customary tenancies and tenancies of newly enclosed lands into freeholds of inheritance at fixed quit-rents which represented the rack-rents then current. They seem to have feared that in future years the income of their land would fall rather than rise. Robert de Berke- ley began the policy (1189-1220) ; it was continued by his successor, Maurice ; it culminated in the time of Thomas, first Lord Berkeley (1281-1321), who himself created 800 of these freeholds, many of which still remained when John Smyth wrote the history of the family in 1628. This family poKcy was, however, completely reversed by his grandson Thomas, third Lord Berkeley (1326-61). Many himdreds of the freeholds created by his predecessors were repurchased, and let at rack-rents. His example was, for the next half century, actively followed by his successors. But for this reversal of the family policy, Smyth calculates that three-quarters of the Berkeley Estates would have been freeholds of inheritance, paying fixed quit-rents of fourpence or sixpence an acre for land which in 1628 was worth twelve shillings. At no time during the period (1189-1415) was any large proportion of the demesne lands divided and let on lease. The Berkeleys themselves farmed on a gigantic scale through their bailifis and their reeves. Thus the third lord (1326-61) kept in his own hands the demesnes of upwards of 75 manors, stocking them with his own oxen, cows, sheep, and swine. On no manor did the flock of sheep number less than 300 ; on some it reached 1500. At Bever- ston in Gloucestershire, in the seventh year of Edward HI., he sheared 5775 sheep. From these manors his supplies were drawn to feed each day at his " standing-house " 300 persons and 100 horses. Thence came every year geese, ducks, peacocks, capons, hens and chickens, — 200 of each kind, many thousands of eggs and 1000 pigeons, coming from a single manor, — stores of honey, wax, and nuts, an " uncredible " number of oxen, bullocks, calves, sheep and lambs, and vast quantities of wheat, rye, barley, oats, pease, beans, apples, and pears. All was accounted for with minute detail by the stewards, reeves, and baJlifis. Their accounts for * Lives of the Berkeleys, voL i. pp. 140-1. 46 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR the manors and for the household show what amount of com remained in the granary from the previous year ; how much was each year reaped and winnowed, sold at markets, shipped to sea ; how much was consumed in the lord's house, in his stable, in his kennels, in the poultry yard, or in the falcons' mews ; how much was malted ; how much was given to the poor, to friars and other religious orders by way of yearly allowances. The policy of repurchasing freeholds and of increasing enclosures was pursued by the fourth lord (1361-68) and by his son (1368- 1417). But from 1385 onwards the practice of farming the demesne lands through the reeves was abandoned. " Then," says Smyth, " began the times to alter, and hee with them (much occasioned by the insurrection of Wat Tyler and generally of all the Comons in the land,) And then instead of manureing his demesnes in each manor with his own servants, oxen, kine, sheep, swine, poultry and the like, under the oversight of the Reeves of the manors. . . . This lord began to joyst and tack in other mens cattle into his pasture grounds by the week, month, and quarter : And to sell his meadow grounds by the acre ; and so between wind and water (as it were) continued part in tillage, and part let out and joysted as aforesaid for the rest of that kings rajgne. And after, in the time of Henry the fourth, let out by the year stU more and more by the acre as hee found chapmen and price to his likeing." ^ The landlord was ceasing to be a patriarchal farmer and becoming only a rent-receiver. The process went on with increasing rapidity. By the end of the reign of Edward IV. the greater part of the manors and demesnes had been let to tenants, either on rack-rents or at lesser rents with the reservation of a fine. The day-works due from the old customary tenants, in proportion to their holdings of yard-lands and " far- rundeUs," together with their produce rents, were commuted into money equivalents and added to the new rents. The story of the Manor of Castle Combe and of the estates of the Berkeleys holds true, with many variations, of England generally. Everywhere the cultivation of demesnes by the labour services of manorial tenants was gradually abandoned, and the older system replaced by separate farms, let for money rents to individual occupiers. The change proceeded more rapidly in the south and south-west than in the north and east. But as the fifteenth century 1 Livea of the Berkeleyt, vol. ii. pp. 5-6. FREE LABOURERS 47 neared its close the relations between owners, occupiers, and cul- tivators of land had, in many parts of England, assumed a more modem aspect. There was a large iocrease in the number of free- holders, and of leaseholding or copyholding farmers renting land in individual occupation ; there was also an increase in the number of free labourers whose only capital was their labour. The complete aboUtion of villeinage had been demanded by the people in the rising of 1381, and one of the principal objects of the rioters had been the destruction of the rolls of the manor courts, which were the evidence not only of their titles but of their disabilities. Possibly they may have hoped that, if the court roUs were destroyed, they would be left in undisturbed possession of their holdings. Possibly they may have expected to escape the payment of the vexatious fines and licences incidental to the tenure, and there is some suggestion that landlords were endeavouring to recoup themselves for the loss of income, which the commutation of labour services and the decrease of the manorial population had produced, by the stricter exaction of payments. Eighty years later the class of villeins, which once had included the great mass of the rural population, was fast disappearing. The more prosperous members of the class had retained their hold on the land, whether on the demesnes, the assart lands, or the village farms. Some had become freeholders ; others rented their holdings at fixed money rents on leases for a term of years or for Uves ; others, whose rights were derived from ancient customs, were admitted as copyholders for lives and possibly of inheritance on the court roll of the manor. The uncertainty of villein tenure was gone, and its brand of personal servitude could not long continue when the old relation of feudal lord and dependent was exchanged for that of landlord and tenant or of employer and employed, and was expressed in cash instead of personal services. Even landless bondmen had for the most part gained their personal freedom. Some purchased freedom by money payments ; on some the influence of the Church, or the pricking of conscience conferred it by a deathbed emancipation ; the legal presumption of natural hberty and the decisions of the law courts bestowed it on others. Here a bondman escaped from the manor and was lost sight of ; here a man took refuge in a town ; another accepted the tawny livery of the Berkeleys or of some other great lord ; a fourth received the tonsmre, or took service in a monastery, as a lay brother ; a fifth made freedom the condition on which he would 48 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR take up land. In numerous cases the services were lost from neglect, because they ceased to be profitable when landlords aban- doned farming and became only rent-receivers. In all these ways the ranks of freemen and free labourers were recruited. The numbers of villeins dwindled fast. But the tenure survived the Tudor period. Its abolition was demanded ia the eastern counties during Kett's rebeUion (1649), and all men who had not been legally emancipated hved throughout the reign of Elizabeth in peril that its incidents might be revived against them. Even the old personal services still lingered. Till the end of the eighteenth century, labour dues as part of the rent of land were enforced in the north-west of England. Half the county of Cumberland was stiU unenclosed in 1794. " By far the greatest part of this county was held under lords of manors, by that species of vassalage, called customary tenure ; subject to the payment of fines and heriots, on alienation, death of the lord, or death of tenant, and the payment of certain annual rents, and performance of various services, called Boon-days, such as getting and leading the lord's peats, plowing and harrowing his land, reaping his com, hay-making, carrying letters, etc., etc., whenever summoned by the lord." ^ The fifteenth century hes midway between two recognised periods of distress among the rural population. Agriculturally, its history is almost a blank. The silence has been interpreted in different ways. Some writers have considered it as a time of progress ; others have read it as the reverse. There is evidence that the principal sufferers by the dynastic and aristocratic struggle of the Roses were the nobiUty and the soldiers, that country districts were not laid waste, and that villages and their populations were neither destroyed nor harried. If so, rural life may have advanced peacefully, profiting by the absorption of landowners in more exciting pursuits than the administration of their estates. When once the struggle was ended, a new world began to piece itself together. Accepting the spirit of the coming age, agriculture reorganised itself on a money basis, and two classes emerge into prominence — capitalist tenant-farmers and free but landless labourers. Both had been slowly forming during the first three quarters of the century : both were equally essential to the changed conditions of farming. The tenant-farmer had risen in the social * Qenerdl View of the AgnouUwre of the County of OumberUmd, by John Bailey and Oeorge Culley (1794), p. 11. FORMATION OF KEW CLASSES 49 scale ; the labomer, if the possession of land alone measored his position in society, had fallen. Mediaeval oiganisations of trade were undergoing a mTniloT transformation. Guilds, like village farms, had maintained a certain equality of wealth and position among the master craftsmen, and apprentices and journeymen not only looked to become masters themselves, but shared in the advantages of membership of the organised crafte. At the close of the fifteenth century, the wealthier liveried masters began, like capitalist tenant-farmers, to form a higher rank within the guild, and to control and administer its policy. Below them in the scale a new class was coming into existence. Independent journeymen were increasing in number — ^hired artisans who derived no benefits from the guilds, enjoyed no prospect of becoming master-craftsmen, and depended for their livelihood, like the free labourer divorced from the soil, on employment and wages. For the rising classes, the fifteenth century may have been a period of prosperity ; for the classes which were in some respects falling, it was probably a time of adversity. Only thus can the rose-coloured descriptions o{ wnters like Sir John Portescue be reconciled with the darker accounts which might be put together from other sources. It is not in the gay holiday scenes of a Chaucer, but in the grimly realistic pictures of a Langland that the features of rural life are most truly painted. Leaseholders and copyholders in separate occupation of farms had increased rapidly in number as well as in importance. Their ranks were swollen by the tenants of the reclaimed wastes, by those among whom the demesne was now divided, and by holders of the " stock and land " leases who had saved sufficient capital to stand on their own feet ; by men of capacity and enterprise, who realised the superior advantages of a separate holding, however small ; by hundreds of the old customary tenants, who found that the rents for which their personal services had been commuted were higher than the competitive money rents which land could command when the supply was excessive. The terms for which leases ran grew longer. They advanced from a year to five years, then to seven years, then to ten years, then to twenty-one, then to lives, and often to fee farm. The increasingly prolonged term illustrates the greater confidence in the stability of the government. It also indicates, on the part of the farmer, a growing sense of the legal security which leases afforded ; on the part of landowners, the wish to retain D 50 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR as long as possible their responsible tenants ; and, among the more far-sighted of the tenantry, a desire to rid themselves of the imper- fect ownership which cnstomary tenure implied. Finally, farms were increasing in size. The word " farm " was itself changing its mean- ing from the stipulated rent to the area of land out of which the payment issued. In this transition another meaning of the word was lost. In many parts of England at that time, and in the north of England down to the last century, a farm meant that definite area of land which afforded a living to the occupier and his family.^ By the end of the fifteenth century it had acquired its modem sense of an indefinite area of land occupied by one tenant at one rent. Complaints of the practice of throwing together a number of men's " livings " into one holding in one man's occupation begin to be frequent, and are directed against the absorption of the small arable holdings of from ten to thirty acres. They occur in sermons, in Petitions to the King, in doggerel verae. The letter of the Vicar of Quinton in Gloucestershire, written to the President of Magdalen College, Oxford,^ at the close of the fifteenth century, breathes the spirit of the twentieth century. Magdalen College owned an estate in the parish of Quinton, and the president hesitated whether the College should let the land as one farm, or, as we should now say, let it in small holdings. The vicar appeals on behalf of his parish- ioners. " Aftur my sympull reson," he writes, " it is mor meritory to support and succur a comynte [community] then one mane, yowre tenan[ts] rathere then a stronge man, the pore and the innocent for [instead of] a gentylman or a gentylman's man." Whatever may have resulted from the vicar's appeal, circum- stances generally favoured the multipUcation of separate holdings and their increase to a size which rendered the employment of money as well as of labour remunerative. Practical agriculturists, like Fitzherbert, urge every man to " change fields with his neigh- bour, so that he may lay his lands together," keep more hve-stook, improve the soil by their " compostynge," and rest his com land when it becomes impoverished. The long wars with France were over ; the civil strife between York and Lancaster was ended ; the central government under Henry VII. was firmly established ; trade was beginning to expand ; population, arrested in its increase since the death of Edward I., was once more growing. On the 1 The Anoient Farms of Northumberland, by F. W. Dendy (1893), pp. 11-19. ' England in the Fifteenth Century, by the Rev. W. Denton (1888), p. 318. PASTON AND LATIMER 51 other hand, land had depreciated in value ; rents had declined ; farming had deteriorated ; useful practices had been discontinued ; cattle were dwindling in size and weight ; the conunon pastures had become infected with " murrain " ; the arable area of open- fields had grown less productive, and without manure its fertility could not be restored. Land was cheap to buy and cheap to rent. Enterprising purchasers and farmers could make it pay, if they realised the advantages of separate occupation, of employing money on the land, of reviving obsolete practices like marling, and, in certain climates, of adopting a convertible husbandry that adapted itself to fluctuating needs better than the open-field system, which rigidly regulated the cultivation of the soil and permanently separ- ated arable land from pasture. The one obstacle to the success of the new tenant-farmer was the scarcity and deamess of labour. But sheep-grazing cut down labour bills, while legislation checked the natural rise of wages, and barred the outlet into towns against agricultural labourers and their sons. Even a high rate of wages often proved nominal rather than real, for, under the Statutes of Labourers, farmers had the option of paying their men in com at the statutory price of 6s. 8d. a quarter when com fell below that price, or in money when the price of com approached or exceeded the statutory figure. Two contemporary pictures have been painted of the lives of tenant-farmers, who were fathers of famous sons — one at the opening, the other at the close, of the fifteenth century. Each picture seems to be more or less typical of the farming class at the periods to which they belong. Clement Paston, at the beginnii^ of the century, lived at the village of Paston, near Mundesley in Norfolk.^ " He was," says an anon3mious writer who was no friend to the family, " a good plain husband(nian), and lived upon his land that he had in Paston, and kept thereon a plough all times in the year, and sometimes in barlysell two ploughs. The saide Clement yede (went) at one plough both winter and summer, and he rode to mill on the bare horseback with his com under him, and brought home meal again under him, and also drove his cart with divers corns to Wynterton to sell as a good husband(man) ought to do." He had at the most 100 or 120 acres of land, some of it copyhold, and a " little poor water-mill." He married a bond- woman. Their son William, who was kept at school, often on 1 Paston Letters, ed. Gaiidner, Introduction, voL i. pp. 28-30. 52 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR borrowed money, became a distmgaished lawyer, a sergeant-at-law, in 1429 a Judge of the Common Pleas, and the founder of the Paston family. At the close of the same century, Hugh Latimer the father of the Bishop of Worcester, was a farmer in Leicester- shire. Preaching before Edward VI.,' the son describes his father's circumstances. The elder Latimer rented some 200 acres of arable land with rights of common of pasture, employed half a dozen men on his farm besides women servants, ran 100 sheep, milked 30 cows, owned oxen for ploughing, and a horse for riding or for the king's service. He portioned his daughters with £50 or £60 apiece ; and, besides teaching his son to " lay his body in the bow," sent him to school and college. He was hospitable to his neighbours and charitable to the needy. And this he did out of the profits of his farm. For wage-earning landless labourers, the last 130 years of the period from 1200 to 1485 were probably, in some respects, unpros- perous. They now were exposed to the fluctuations, not only of the price of necessaries, but of the labour market. Yet agricultural change had not affected them wholly for the worse. The bright side was the bondman's passage towards personal freedom ; the darkest feature was his divorce from the soil. To some extent his severance from the land was the means and the price of his personal emancipation. The surrender of the hold on the land was, at this period, mainly due to voluntary action by the villeins themselves ; it was not caused by clearances for sheep fanning. A landlord had no desire to lose them either as tenants or as labourers. Their flight threw more land on his hands, and at the same time increased the scarcity of labour for its cultivation. But villeins, whose holdings were small, had little inducement to retain them, and much to gain by escape. The sentimental objection to the tenure had been deepenied and embittered by the teaching of wandering friars and " poor preachers." Freedom meant the rise out of a condition, the degra- dation of which Hiey had begun to feel with a new acuteness. It meant also new possibilities. Beyond the limits of their own manor, they might, as freemen, acquire other holdings, or join the ranks of free labourers, or settle behind a city wall and practise some handicraft. After the " Black Death " the prospect of employ- ment in towns was good. Hands were at a premium. The great 1 Sermon* (Parker Society), p. 101. THE LABOURERS' GAIN AND LOSS 53 scarcity of labour is proved by the fact that the severity of the Labour Statutes was relaxed in the case of immigrants into London, and, temporarily, into Norwich. That the chances of town life were in themselves sufficient inducements for flight from the manor is shown by the willingness of villeins to surrender their holdings, and purchase licences to Uve within the walls of cities. But very often another cause must have made the voluntary severance from the land a Hobson's choice. The yield of arable land on open- field farms was so small that farming scarcely provided necessaries. Throughout the closing years of the fifteenth century, successive outbreaks of murrain had killed numbers of cattle and sheep, swept off geese and poultry, and even destroyed the bees. If the results of similar outbreaks in the sixteenth century justify the conclusion, it may be supposed that it was the live-stock of open-field farmers which suffered most. Without stock small holders or cottagers found common rights valueless, and their few acres of arable land rather a burden than a profit. To such men the voluntary surrender of holdings, with or without flight, might well seem the choice of a lesser evil. For a time they may have prospered as labourers for hire. But when the conversion of tillage to pasture had begun, their daily employment and their harvest earnings were in peril. In such conditions it must have been useless, if not impossible, to enforce residence within the limits of the manor. The possibility that the manor itself might not provide work for its inhabitants was recognised in the labour legislation of the period. Indirectly the Labour Statutes, though manifestly not passed in the interest of labourers, aided their progress towards freedom of movement and of contract. They broke down the exclusive right which lords of the manor claimed over the personal services of their manorial dependents. Hitherto no one could employ a villein from another manor without the risk that this superior claim might be asserted. Under the king's proclamation of 1349, the lord's right is recognised, preferentially, but not exclusively. He has the first claim, not the only claim, to the services. He may not employ more labour than he absolutely needs. When his requirements are satisfied, his villein may, and on demand must, work for other employers. In the statutes them- selves the same principle is carried further. Servants in husbandry are bound to appear, tools in hand, in market towns to be publicly hired, as, five centuries later in many parts of England, they 54 THE BREAK-UP OF THE MANOR frequented the local statute fairs, or mops— cowmen with the hair of cows twisted in their button-holes, or carters and ploughmen with whip-cord in their hats. Thus the very legislation which was designed to maintain the supply of rural labour and check migra- tion into towns, introduces that principle of freedom of movement which is essential to the modem relations of employer and employed. In another respect, also, the Labour Statutes loosened the depend- ence of bondmen on their manorial lords. The jurisdiction of the king's law courts was extended till it invaded the sacred precincts of the manor court, and settled disputes between the lord and his villeins. Wages even were no longer to be fixed as between a bond- man and his feudal lord ; they were to be controlled by Justices of the Peace acting as the king's agents. It is not suggested that the fifteenth century labourer beinefited by a change which virtually transferred the light of fixing wages to an association of employers. But the transfer of authority was a not unimportant step towards the complete collapse of the manorial organisation, and towards free competition as the true basis of money wages. THE PASSING OF THE MIDDLE AGES 56 CHAPTER III. FARMING FOR PROFIT: PASTURE AND SHEEP- GRAZING. 1485-1558. The passmg of the Middle Ages : enclosures in the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries compared ; the commercial impxiJse and its results ; conversion of tillckge to pasture : enclosures and depopulation : legislation against enclosures ; literary attack on enclosures ; the practical defence of en- closures : larger farms in separate occupation : loss of employment ; enclosures equitably arranged, or enforced by tyranny ; legal powers of landowners ; open-field farmers not the chief sufierers by enclosures ; scarcity of emplo3rment and rise in prices ; the new problem of poverty : the ranks of vagrants ; the Elizabethan fraternity of vagabonds. OvT of wars at home and abroad, and pestilences destractive both to man and beast, emerged one great agricultural change which by 1485 was practically completed. Feudal landowners, instead of pursuing the patriarchal system of farming their own demesnes by the labour services of their dependents, had become receivers of rent. Home-farms and " assart " or reclaimed lands were culti- vated, not by lords of the manor through bajlifis and labour-rents, but by freeholders, leaseholders, copyholders, and hired labourers. Further changes were close at hand. With the dawn of the Tudor period began the general movement which gradually transformed England into a mercantile country. The amount of money in actual use was increasing ; men possessed more capital, could borrow it more easily, and lay it out to greater advantage. Commerce permeated national life. Feudalism was dead or dying, and trade was climbing to its throne. The Middle Ages were passing into modem times. On the agricultural side, the spirit of trading competition gave fresh impulse to an old movement which, in spite of a storm of protest, continued in activity throughout the Tudor period, and, after a century and a half of silent progress, became once more the centre of literary controversy before it triumphed at the close of 56 FARMING FOR PROFIT the reign of George lU. That movement is described as enclosure, and it is generally treated as necessarily destructive to the old village farms. But the word includes various processes, some of which rather strengthened than weakened the open-field system. Some enclosures, such as closes for stock-feeding, intakes from the common for arable purposes, even the not uncommon practice of fencing portions of the open-fields for several occupation, whether temporarily or permanently, were really efforts to adapt village farms to changing needs. Another form of enclosure was the culti- vation of new land obtained by clearing forests, approving portions of wastes, or draioing fens. Here also village farms were not directly affected. Indirectly, indeed, these new enclosures pro- duced a considerable effect. Much of the reclaimed land was tilled for com ; thus the ancient arable soil was relieved from the former necessity of bearing grain crops, and might not improbably be put to the use for which it was best adapted. A third process was the direct enclosure of open-fields and pasture commons. This form generally appeared in the neighbourhood of towns, where the demand for animal food and dairy produce was greatest and labour found a ready market, or in counties where some manufacturing industry prevailed and small grass holdings made a less exacting claim on the time of the handicraftsmen than tillage. But what- ever form the enclosure took, the general drift of the movement was towards individual occupation of land. It was therefore always, and particularly in the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries, directly opposed to the open-field system of fanning in common. At both periods that special form of enclosure was prominent which meant the break-up of the mediaeval agrarian partnerships and the substitution of private enterprise for the collective efforts of village associations. But in details the earlier and the later movements were strongly contrasted. In the sixteenth century, the change was opposed and partially arrested by legislation ; in the eighteenth century, it received from Parliament encouragement and support. Under Henry VIII., it was mainly inspired by com- mercial advantage ; under George III., it was alleged to be enforced by necessity. In the sixteenth century some of the grass-land was undoubtedly used for grazing beasts. But it was maioljr to supply the growing wool trade that Tudor husbandmen substituted pasture for tillage, sheep for com. They took their seats on the wool- sack, and maidens of all degrees were spinsters. Hanoverian TUDOR AND HANOVERIAN ENCLOSURES 57 fanners reveised the process ; they valued sheep for their mutton instead of their fleeces, and concentrated their energies on the production of bread and meat for the teeming populations of manufacturing cities. Dearth of bread was in Tudor times the most efEective cry against enclosures ; under Gleorge m. it was the unanswerable plea for their extension. At the opening of the sixteenth century, enclosure did not always mean improved farm- ing ; the conversion of arable land into inferior sheep-waJk was rather retrogression than progress. At the close of the eighteenth century, it at least meant the opportunity for advance and for the introduction of better practices. To some extent, indeed, the different developments of the two movements measure the improve- ments in the methods and the increase in the resources of Hanoveriiin farmers. The Tudor husbandman might devote himself exclusively to the one or the other of the two branches of farming ; but he had not mastered the secret of their union. If he changed from tillage to pasture, he did so completely. He could not, like his successor, combine the two, and by the introduction of new crops, at once grow more com and carry more stock. Agriculturally, the period which opens with the Battle of Bos- worth and ends with the early years of Elizabeth is one of transition towards the modem spirit and forms of land cultivation. Like all transition periods, it is full of suffering for those who were least able to adapt themselves to altered conditions. The ruin of noble families by the Wars of the Roses, the lavish expenditure which Henry VUJL. made fashionable, the rise in prices, and the difficulty of raising rents, compelled many " unthrifty gentlemen " to sell their estates. The break-up of landed properties and their passage into new hands favoured the introduction of the commercial impulse. The landholders whose " unreasonable covetousness " is most loudly condemned «rere mainly speculators in land, men who had made money in business, had capital to invest, could afford the exx>ense of enclosures, and were determined to make their estates pay. Such were " the Merchant Adventurers, Clothmakers, Gold- smiths, Butchers, Tanners, and other Artificers," ' — " the merchants of London" who "bie fermes out of the handes of worshypfull gentle- men, honeste yeomen, and pore laborynge husbandes."^ Translated ^ Petition to Hemy Vm. (1514), quoted by F. J. Fumivall in BaU/odt from MSS., p. 101 (Pablications of the Ballad Society, voL L). > Thomas Lever's Sermone (1550) ; Arber's Reprints, p. 29. 68 FARMING FOR PROFIT into the language of to-day, the old landlords had been satisfied to draw from their estates certain advantages and a low percentage of profit ; the new men required at the least a four per cent, return in money on their investments. Feudal barons had partly valued their land for the number of men-at-arms it furnished to their banners ; Tudor landowners appraised its worth by the amount of rent it paid into their coffers. Mediaeval husbandmen had been content to extract from the soil the food which they needed for themselves and their families. Tudor farmers despised self- sufficing agriculture ; they aspired to be sellers and not consumers only, to raise from their land profits as well as food. As trade expanded, and towns grew, and English wool made its way into continental cities, or was woven into cloth by English weavers, new markets were created for agricultural produce. Fresh in- centives stimulated individual enterprise, and both landlords and tenants learned to look on the land they respectively owned or cultivated as a commercial asset. Among the results of this conquest of agriculture by the new spirit of commercial competition three may be noticed — ^firstly, the clearer recognition of the advantages of farms held in individual occupation, large enough to make the employment of capital remunerative ; secondly, the substitution of pasture for tillage, of sheep for com, of wool for meat ; thirdly, the attack upon the old agrarian partnerships in which lords of the manor, parsons, freeholders, leaseholding farmers, copyholders, and cottagers had hitherto associated to supply the wants of each village. Legisla- tion failed to prevent a movement which harmonised and syn- chronised with the progressive development of the nation on commercial lines. But in its earUer stages, the consequences to the rural population were serious. Many tenants lost their hold- ings, many wage-earning labourers their employment, when land- lords " turned graziers," and farmers cut down their labour-bills by converting tillage into pasture. It is impossible to doubt the reality of the distress. From 1487 onwards, literature, pamphlets, doggerel ballads, sermons, liturgies, petitions, preambles to statutes. Commissions of Enquiry, Acts of Parliament, bear witness to a considerable depopulation of country districts. In the numerous insurrections, which marked the sixteenth century and the early years of the reign of James I., rural distress undoubtedly con- tributed its share. But zealous advocates of Roman Catholicism SHEEP-FARMING 69 found it useful to ally agrarian discontent with religions leaction, and men like Protector Somerset thoaght it politic to attribute anti-Protestant risings entirely to agricultural causes. There was no novelty in the withdrawal of demesne lands from the open-field farm and their partition into individual occupations ; or in fencing o£E portions of tiie home-farm and of the reclaimed " assart " lands as separate plots ; or in the appropriation of parts of the commonable waste for private use ; or in the encouragement given to partners in the village association to throw their scattered strips together into one compact holding. Each of these processes had been for many years in progress ; each had necessitated enclosures ; none had required the decay of farm-houses and cottages, loss of employment, eviction of tenants, or rural depopula- tion. But from the Tudor enclosing movement these consequences did necessarily result, because its objects were the promotion of sheep-farming, the conversion of tillage into pasture, the con- solidation and enlargement of grass holdings. If farmers had not yet at their disposal the means of realising the full Iruth of the maxim that " the foot of the sheep turns sand into gold," the new commercial aristocracy were quick to see that money was to be made, or at least to be saved, by the growth of wool. It is true that down to 1540 the prices of wool remained low ; but some at least of the grass was taken up by the graziers, and the saving in labour effected by pasture farming was great. Sheep could not be herded with success on open commons, still less on the arable lands of village farms, and small holdings were incompatible with large flocks. It was these new elements which upset the calculations of agriculturists like Eitzherbert (1523), or Cardinal Pole ^ in Starkey's Dialogue (1536), or Tusser (1557), or Standish (1611), who hoped that the economic advantages of enclosure might be secured without the social loss which the conversion of large tracts of arable land into wide pasture farms inflicted on the rural population. If evidence which is rarely impartial may be impUcitly trusted, considerable tracts of cultivated land were converted into wilder- nesses, traversed only by shepherds and their dogs ; roofless granges and half -ruined churches alone marked the sites of former hamlets ; the " deserted village " was a reality of the sixteenth ' In the Dialogue between Cardinal Pole and Thomas Lupaet, Pole defends enclosures for pasture on the plea that cattle, as well as com, were necessary for human food {England in the Beign of Henry VIII., ed. J. M. Cowper, E.E.T.S., extra series xxxii. 1878). 60 FARMING FOR PROFIT century. Already anxious for the maintenance of the national supply of com, men began to be alarmed at another result of the movement which became increasingly prominent. John Rous ^ (1411-91), chantry priest of Guy's CliSe and Warwickshire antiquary, was the first to protest agaiost the decay of population caused in the midland counties by enclosures for pasture farming. To this rural exodus the attention of Parliament had been called by the Lord Chancellor in the first year of Richard m. (1484). Francis Bacon, writing of the opening years of the reign of Henry VII., says : ^ " Inclosures at that time began to be more frequent, whereby arable land, which could not be manured without people and families, was turned into pasture which was easily rid by a few herdsmen ; and tenances for years, lives, and at will, whereupon much of the yeomanry lived, were turned into demesnes. This bred a decay of people." So formidable did the danger begin to appear, that in 1489 two Acts of Parhament were passed for its prevention. The first Act was local, dealing with the effects of enclosures in the Isle of Wight from the point of view of national defence ; the second is general, directed " against the pulling down of tounes " (i.e. townships or villages). These Acts were the pre- cursors of many others throughout the sixteenth century ,3 for- bidding the conversion of arable land into pasture, ordering newly laid pasture to be restored to tillage, directing enclosures to be thrown down, requiring decayed hotises to be rebuilt, limiting the number of sheep and of farms which could legally be held by one man, and imposing severe penalties for disobedience to the new provisions. No favour was shown by Parliament to enclosers, except perhaps in the case of deer-parks. On the contrary, strenuous efforts were repeatedly made to stop the process of enclosure. Nor wafi the Grovemment satisfied with passing laws and imposing penalties. Wolsey personally interested himself in enforcing obedience to the laws against the decay of houses and farm-buildings and against '■ BUtoria Begvm Angliae, ed. 1746, pp. 116-24. But Thomas Eeame was not always a reliable editor. 'Hittory of King Benry the Seventh {Worka, ed. Spedding, voL vi. pp. 93-4). * E.g. 1489 (4 Hen. Vn. oc. 16, 19) ; 1514 (6 Hen. Vin. o. 6) ; 1616 (7 Hen. Vni. o. 1) ; 1633-4 (26 Hen. Vm. o. 13) ; 1536-6 (27 Hen. Vm. c. 22) ; 1661-2 (6 and 6 Ed. VI. c. 6) ; 1666 (2 and 3 Phil, and Maiy, c. 2) ; 1662-3 (6 Eliz. 0. 2) ; 1593 (36 Eliz. c. 7, repealing part of 6 Eliz. c. 2) ; 1697-8 (39 Eliz. c. 1) ; 1601 (43 Eliz. c. 9) ; in 1624 the enclosure laws were repealed. LEGISLATION AGAINST SHEEP-WALKS 61 the conversion of arable land to pasture. Active steps were taken to see that buildings were restored and enclosures and ditches levelled. In default, heavy penalties were exacted. A Com- mission was appointed in 1517,^ which enquired into all cases where farm-houses had been destroyed since 1485, or where ploughs had been put down by the increase of pasture farming. Similar enquiries were held in 1548, 1566, and 1607. No doubt these strenuous efforts checked the movement. But they failed to stop it altogether. In this respect they succeeded no better in encourag- ing tillage than the quaint pedantry of the law, which gave arable land precedence over other land, or conferred on beasts of the plough privileges that were denied to other animals. The new legislation seems to have been satisfied, or evaded, without serious difficulty; partly, because compositions for breaches of its provisions might be paid or exemptions purchased; partly, no doubt, because the administration of the law was often entrusted to those who were interested in making it a dead letter. The destruction of farm buildings was forbidden ; but it was easy to keep within the statute by retaining a single room for the shepherd or the milk- maid ; a solitary furrow driven across newly laid pasture satisfied the law that it should be restored to tillage ; the number of sheep to be owned by one man was limited, but the ownership of flocks might be fathered en sons or servants. Down to the middle of the reign of Elizabeth the enclosing and grazing movement con- tinued. At subsequent intervals it renewed its special activity throughout the seventeenth century, when dairying began to claim a larger share of the attention of farmers. It was restrained or encouraged rather by natural causes than by legislation. Fluctua- tions in the prices of wool or com, the increased profits of improved methods of arable farming, and the restoration of the fertility of the ancient tilled land, which was brought back to the plough after an enforced rest from excessive cropping, gradually restored the preponderance of tillage over pasture. The grievances of the rural population are to be gathered not only from legislation, proclamations, petitions, articles of complaint, the Returns of Commissioners, or the records of the law courts. They are also written large in More's Utopia, and in much of the ephemeral literature of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. The cry of the people is heard, often in exaggerated tones, in the sermons of 1 The Dometdajf of Indoturea (1617-8), by L S. Leadom, 2 vols. 1897. 62 FARMING FOR PROFIT popular preachers like Tyndale, Becon, and Latimer, in the pam- phlets of such writers as Simon Fish, Henry Brinklow, or Philip Stubbes, or in the rhymes of versifiers like " Sir " William Forrest, Robert Crowley, and Thomas Bastard, or in such anonymous ballads as " Nowe-a-dayes " : ^ " The townes go down, the land decayea ; OS comefeyldes, playne layea (grass-land) ; Gret men makithe now a dayes A shepecott in the church. Commons to close and kepe ; Poor folk for bred to cry and wepe ; Towns pulled downe to pastur shepe ; This ys the new gyse !" Throughout the burden is the same — enclosure of commons, con- version of plough-land into pasture, sheep-farming, excessive rents, exorbitant fines, consolidation of small holdings into large farms, decay of houses and farm-buildings, formation of deer-parks, and, more rarely, enclosure of open-field arable farms. Here are to be found fierce denunciations of the " caterpillars of the common- weal," * who " join lordship to lordship, manor to manor, farm to farm, land to land, pasture to pasture," and gather many thousands of acres of ground " together within one pale or hedge " ; or of the unchristian landlords, who " rack and stretch out the rents of their larids," taking " unreasonable fines," " setting their pore tenants so straitely uppon the tenter hookes as no man can Ijrve on them " ; * or of the insatiable " cormorants " who " let two or three tenantries unto one man," " take in their commons " till not so much as a garden ground is safe, and make " parks or pastures of whole parishes " ; * or of the " unreasonable covitous persones whiche doth encroche daily many ffermes more than they can be able to occupye or mainteyne with tilth for come as hath been used in tymes past, forasmoche as divers of them hath obteyned and encrochfed into their handes, X, XII, XIV, or XVI fermes in oon mannes hand attons " ;S or of the " ambicious suttletie " of those 1 " Nowe-»-dayes," Ballads from MSS., ed. P. J. FumivaU (Publications of the Ballad Society, vol. L p. 97, 1868). * Thomas Becon, Jewel of Joy (Parker Society, Beeon's Workt, p. 432). * Philip Stubbes, Anatomy of Ahusea (1683), (New Shakespeare Society, p. 116). < William Tyndale, Dodrmal Treatites (Parker Society, p. 201). ' Petition to Henry VIII., quoted in BaUadafrom MSS., vol. i. p. 101. CONDEMNATION OF ENCLOSURES 63 who make " one fearme of two or three," and even sometimes " bringe VI to one " ; or of the greed of " step-lords," like the " rich franklings," ^ who " Occupyinge a dosen men's lyvyngis Take all in their owne hondee alone." Nor do the innocent causes of much of the trouble escape attack ; sheep " that were wont to be so mjke and tame, and so smal eaters, now, as I heare sade, be become so greate devowerers, and so wylde, that they eate up and swallow down the very men themselfes," * drive " husbandry " out of the country, and thrust " Christian labourers " off the land. " Sheepe have eate up our medovs and our downes. Our come, our wood, whole villages and townes ; Tea, they have eate up many wealthy men. Besides widowes and orphEme childeren ; Besides our statutes and our Iron Lawes, Which they have swallowed down into their maws : — Till now I thought the proverbe did but jest. Which said a blacke sheepe was a biting beast." ^ Enclosers were condemned by preachers as " guilty before God of the sin in the text — ' they have sold the righteous for silver and the poor for a pair of shoes.' " A playwright like Massinger did not draw entirely on his imagination, but expressed the feeling of the day when he painted his portrait of a Sir Giles Overreach, insensible to pity for his victims and justly called : "Extortioner, Tyrant, Cormorant, or Intruder On my poor neighbour's right, or grand Incloser Of what was common to my private use." * In the passion for sheep and hedges, which changed " merrie England " into " sighing or sorrowful England," men saw the fulfilment of the prophecy " Home and Thome shall make England forlome." ^ Superstitions enforced the popular judgment, and legend doomed " emparkers," like Sir John Townley, to haunt the solitudes they had created, uttering bitter cries of unavailing remorse. >"Bede me and be nott Wrothe." By William Boy (1627), Arber's Reprints, 28. * More's Utopia, bk. L (Ralph Robynson's Translation), ed. Lupton, p. 61. 3 Bastard's Chrestoleros (1698), bk. iv. Epigram 20. * A New Way to pay Old Debts, Act. iv. Sc. 1. » Francis Trigge, Humble Petition of Two Sisters : the Church and the Com- numweaUh (1604). 64 FAEMING FOR PROFIT It was eaay for popiilor preachers and pamphleteers to excite popular passion against the " greedy gulls " and " insatiable cormorants," who advocated and practised enclosures, and to denounce the agricultural tendencies of Tudor times as solely guided by selfish greed. But there are practical and broader sides to the question. When once land was regarded as an important asset in the wealth of the nation, national interests demanded that it should be utilised to the greatest possible advantage. Without enclosures, the soil could not be used for the piu^oses to which it was best adapted, or its resources fully developed. If money was to be made out of land, or if its full productive ■pawei was to be realised, it was individual enterprise alone that could make or realise either. Under the open-field system one man's idleness might cripple the industry of twenty : only on enclosed farms, separately occupied, could men secure the full fruit of their enter- prise. This fact had slowly revealed itself during the last two centuries. To exchange intermixed lands, to consolidate compact holdings, and fence them off in separate occupation, had long been the aim both of landlords and tenant-farmers. Few practical men would have disputed the truth of Fuller's statement : " The poor man who is monarch of but one enclosed acre will receive more profit from it than from his share of many acres in common with others." Tudor agriculturists went further in their zeal for farming pro- gress. They saw that a small enclosed plot of 15 acres could be used with less advantage than a large enclosure of 150 acres which enabled the tenant to invest money in the land, carry more stock, provide his cattle with more winter food, and, if the climate per- mitted, adopt convertible husbandry. This was recognised both by landowners and farmers of the progressive school, and the increased size even of arable farms continues to be a feature in sixteenth century changes. For successful sheep-farming, a large stretch of land, held in individual occupation, was stiU more essential. From this point of view the untilled common wastes were unprofitable. Whether land was enclosed for tillage or as sheep runs, its productiveness was increased by enclosure. Finally, the natural fertility of arable land on open unenclosed farms was becoming exhausted. The system was one of taking much from the land and putting little back. The soil, lightly ploughed, seldom manured, often foul, was in some districts worn-out. From 1349 DRAWBACKS TO OPEN-FIELD FARMING 66 to 1485, that is, from the Black Death to the Battle of Bosworth, its yield had declined ; its farming had deteriorated. Fitzherbert, writing in the fiist quarter of the sixteenth century, notes that useful agricultural practices had in many parts become obsolete, that crops were smaller, and methods of husbandry more slovenly. The fall in rentals had been general. But it was on demesne lands, or on enclosed farms, that the fall in rents had been least. These were the lands which were in the best condition, because on them most manure had been expended. Open-field farmers commanded httle or no manure for their arable land, and were practically dependent on sheep for fertilising the soil. Yet in winter, animals, reduced to the lowest possible number, barely sur- vived on straw and tree-loppings. The miserable condition of live-stock on open-field farms and commons exposed the sheep to the scab and the rot, and the cattle to the murrain. It was no uncommon spectacle to see the head of an ox impaled on a stake by the highway, as a warning that the township was infected. Agriculturists might with good reason plead that the changes which they advocated were justified, if not necessitated, by the progress of farming. They hoped that even open-field farmers might themselves recognise the advantages of enclosure, and would agree to consolidate their intermixed holdings and extinguish their reciprocal rights of common. Fitzherbert in his Book of Husbandry argues strongly in favour of enclosures, and especially insists on their advantages in keeping live-stock, which, he saj^, thrive best and cost least on enclosed land. If a farmer has only a twenty years' lease of his land, it will pay ^lim to go to the expense of fraicing ofi his land in separate parcels with hedges and ditches. C!ommon-field farmers have to pay 2d. a quarter for each head of cattle, and Id. a quarter for each head of swine, under the care of the common herdsman and swineherd. If they wish to thrive, each must keep a shepherd of his own. The hire of the herdsman and the swiaeherd, together with the wages and board of the shepherd, and the cost of hurdles and stakes put together, double the rent. If a farmer encloses, he may have to pay three times this annual cost in one year ; but he has no further expense. " Than hathe he euery fyelde in seueraltie : and by the assente of the lordes and the tenauntes euery neyghbour may exchaunge landes with other. And than shall his farme be twyse so good in proflite to the tenaunte as it was before, and as muche lande kepte E 66 FARMING FOR PROFIT in tyllage, and than shall not the ryche man ouer-eate the poore man with his cattell, and the fourth parte of haye and strawe shall seme his cattell better in a pasture than foure tymes so muche will dooe in a house, and less attendaunce, and better the cattell shall lyke, and it is the chiefest sauegarde for come bothe daye and nyght that may be." To the same effect wrote Tusser in the comparison between " champion " (or open-field) " and severall " (or enclosed) in his Five Hundreth Good Pointea of Good Hvsbandrie (1573). "More profit is quieter found, (Where pastures in severall bee); Of one seelie aker of ground Than champion maketh of three. The t'one is commended for groin, Yet bread made of beanes they doo eate ; The t'other for one loafe have twaine Of mastlin, of tie, or of wheate." But the agriculturists did not anticipate that one shepherd, with his dog, his crook, shears, and tar-box, might take the place of many ploughmen. They had not reckoned on the strength of the new commercial spirit, and of the impulse which it gave to large grazing farms. The area of land actually returned as enclosed and converted to pasture was relatively small. It has been calculated that, durii^ a period of nearly two centuries, — that is, from 1455 to 1637, — the total acreage enclosed and converted did not exceed 750,000 acres, and that the total number of persons thrown out of work was not greater than 35,000.^ At the present day, four million acres of arable land may in fifteen years be converted into pasture without calling the serious attention of a single statesman ' Mr. Gay's estimate of the total area afiected between the years 1466 and 1607 is 616,673 acres (" Inclosures in England " in Qitairterly JowmcA of Economics, voL zvii. pp. 676-97). He admits that this is probably an under- estimate. The figure given in the test is the calculation made by the Bev. A. H. Johnson in The DUappearance of the 8mM Landoumer (1909), pp. 48, 68. On the other hand, a contemporary writer {Oertayne causes gathered together. Four Supplications, E.E.T.S. extra series ziii.,pp. 101-2) estimates that at that time (1661) 60,000 ploughs had been put down, and that each plough not only mainteuned six persons, but provided food in addition for 7^ persons. In other words, upwards of 660,000 persons lost their means of support. This is an obvious exaggeration. More than two-thirds of the oxbb. affected lay in the Midland counties (" in umbehco regni," as Kous writes), and especially in Northamptonshire, Oxfordshire, Bucks, Warwick, Berkshire, Leicestershire, Bedfordi^bire, and Huntingdonshire. The northern and southern counties were almost untouched. In the west, Gloucestershire, and in the east, Korfolk, were the only districts seriously a£Eected. RURAL DEPOPULATION 67 to the consequent loss of employment and rural depopulation. Bat small though the acreage may have been, it was considerable in proportion to the cultivated area, and the suffering was undeniably great. The distress was aggravated by the disbanding of the great retinues which had been maintained in feudal households, and by the consequent disturbance of the labour market. It was still more intensified by the suppression of the monasteries (1536-42). Not only were a very large number of dependents deprived of their livelihood, but enclosures on the old ecclesiastical estates were carried out with peculiar harshness. The new owners among whom the monastic lands were distributed, bound by no sentimental tie to the existing tenants, claimed that the royal grant EumuUed all titles derived from the previous owners, entered on their possessions as though they were vacant of leaseholders or copyholders, and enclosed the land for sheep-runs. The doggerel ballad, " Vox Populi, Vox Dei " (1549),^ laments the consequences of the change of ownership : " We have shut away aU doisteis. But still we keep eztortioiieTS : We have taken their lands for their abuse, But we have converted them to a worse use." Voluntary agreements for the valuation and commutation of rights of common were often entered into between tenants and landowners, and bargains were struck on equitable terms. Instances like that given in the following extract from Rennet's Parochial AntiguUiea ^ might be indefinitely multipUed : " The said Edmund Rede, Esquire granted and confirmed to Thomas Billyngdon one close in Adyngrave, in consideration whereof the said Thomas Billyngdon quitted and resigned his right to the free pasturage of four oxen to feed with the cattle of the said Edmund Rede and all right to any common in the said pasture or inlandys of the said Edmund." Here in 1437 was the principle of commutation of rights of common accepted and enforced by private contract. In other cases a semblance of agreement may have been secured by threats. But justice was not always perverted in the interests of landlords. Attempted acts of oppression were frequently checked by the courts of law. As an instance may be quoted the proposed en- closure of the common-fields at Welcombe, near Stratford-on- 1 Ballade from M88. 11. 638-41. The spelling is modernized. (Publication of the Ballad Society, vol. i. p. 139.) « VoL u. 324. 68 FARMING FOR PROFIT Avon.^ The example ia the more interesting because it leveaJs one of the rare appearances of William Shakespeare in pubUc life. In 1614 William Combe, of Stratford-on-Avon, the Cro\ni tenant of the " College," wished to withdraw his arable land from the open- field farm of Welcombe, enclose it, and lay it down to pasture. He aJso wished to enclose so much of the ancient greensward or pasture as his rights of pasturage represented. To his scheme he had obtained the consent of Lord Chancellor Ellesmere, as representative of the Crown, and the active co-operation of the Chancellor's steward. Shakespeare, however, was in a position to be a formidable opponent, for he not only owned land adjoining, but also held the unexpired term of a lease of half the tithes of the open-fields. But a deed, dated October 28, 1614, secured him from any loss of tithe through the conversion of tillage into pasture, and his consent to the enclosure was obtained. Combe had now only to deal with the Corporation of Stratford, who offered a strenuous resistance. Strong language did not move them ; in the Corporation MS. the witnesses are duly noted who heard him call them " Purtan knaves," " doggs and curres." Tempting offers were refused, though Combe proposed to compensate them in more than the value of the tithe, to undertake the perpetual repair of the highways passing over the land, and to increase the value of the rights of freeholders and tenants by waiving part of his claim to turn out sheep and cattle on the commons. Then Combe took matters into his own hands, and prepared to enclose his land by surrounding it with a ditch. This brought the dispute to a crisis. Not apparently without the knowledge of the Town Clerk, the townspeople filled in the ditch. A breach of the peace seemed imminent. The matter was, there- fore, referred to the law-coiuis, and at Warwick Assizes, on March 27, 1616, Lord Chief Justice Coke made an order that " noe inclosure shalbe made within the parish of Stratforde." The Dingles, which formed part of the common-fields of Welcombe, remain uninclosed to this day. Instances of the tyrannical use of power could also be quoted. The Tudor age was rough, and might was sometimes right. Sir Thomas More in his Utopia (1616) paints this side to the picture, when he speaks of " husbandmen . . . thrust owte of their owne, or els by coveyne and fraude or by vyolent oppression they be put > Shakespeare and the Endoavre of Common Fields at Weloombe, edited by C. M. Ingleby (1886). METHODS OF CONSOLIDATING ESTATES 69 besydes it, or by wronges and injuries they be so weried that they be compelled to sell all." If a small freeholder or copyholder proved obstinate, the proceedings of Sir Giles Overreach, in A New Way to Pay Old Debts (Act ii. Sc. 1), may illustrate the methods by which a Naboth's vineyard, even when it belonged to a manorial lord, might be appropriated by a wealthy capitalist : " I'll therefore buy some cottage near his manor, Which done, I'll make my men breckk ope his fences. Ride o'er his standing com, and in the night Set fire on his bams, or break his cattle's legs. These trespasses draw on siiits, and suits expenses Which I can spare, but will soon beggar him. When I have harried him thus two or three year. Though he sue in fonnd pauperis, in spite Of all his thrift and care he'U grow behindhand. Then, with the favour of my mem at law, I will pretend some title : want will force him To put it to arbitrement. Then if he sell For half the value he shall have ready money. And I possess his land." Considerations of mutual advantage, equitable bargains, fair pur- chase, superior force, legal chicanery, threats and bullyrag, were all at work to hasten the change to the individual occupation of land, and the consoUdation of separate holdings. If copyholders or commoners appealed to the law-courts, matters, no doubt, some- times ended as they were friended. " Handy-dandy " was in the Middle Ages a proverbial expression for the covert bribe offered by a suitor, and the occasional perversion of justice is enshrined in the Latin jingle : Jus sine jure datur, si nummus in aure loqtuUur. Illegal evictions are not included among the grievances alleged by the leaders in any of the risings of the peasantry which marked the Tudor period. Their absence from these lists justify the con- clusion that open illegaUty was at least rare. But the law itself gave landowners abundant opportunities of regaining possession of the land. Leaseholders for a term of years or for lives had no legal claim to a renewal of their leases, when the term of years had expired or the last life had dropped. Bents might then be raised to aji exorbitant sum or extravagant fines exacted, and, unless the tenant was prepared to pay the increased charge, he must surrender his holding. Cottagers or squatters on the waste could rarely show any legal claim to the occupation of land, and the tenancy of a cottage to which rights of common attached could be practically determined by enhancing the rent. Copyholders were, in all 70 FARMING FOR PROFIT probability, almost equally insecure in their holdings. So long as they were in possession, the court roll was evidence of the incidents of their tenure. But the law was still vague as to rights of suc- cession to copyholds. It may be doubted whether copyholds of inheritance were yet known, and it is reasonably certain that. the normal copyhold was for a term of years or for lives. At the expiration of the term of years or of the last life, normal copy- holders were at the mercy of the lord. Even if copyholds of inheri- tance were recognised by lawyers in the sixteenth century, they were still insecure. Their titles must often have been incapable of legal proof ; they might be forfeited by some real or technical breach of custom ; their renewal was subject to the payment of fines on admittance, which might, where no manorial custom fixed the sum, be arbitrary in amount. It was not till the close of the eighteenth century that the law fixed the limits of a reasonable fine, and, if the fines were arbitrary, the landlord had a weapon with which even copyholds of inheritance, as vmderstood by modem lawyers, might be determined. It is impossible to doubt that exorbitant rents and excessive fines, of which the peasant leaders, preachers, and pamphleteers so bitterly complain, were sometimes used to dispossess leaseholders and copyholders. The powers were legal ; but their exercise often worked injustice. Yet it should be remembered, on the other side, that the raising of rents or the enhancing of fines, whenever the opportunity occurred, were the only means of adjusting the landlord's income to the great rise in the prices of agricultural produce. In the Compendious or Briefe Examination ^ the Knight puts the landlord's case. " In all my life time," he says, "I looke not that the thirde part of my lande shall come to my dispocition that I may enhaunce the rent of the same, but it shalbe in mens holdinges either by lease or by copie graunted before my time. . . . We cannot rayse all our wares as youe maye yours." Rents, based on the commutation of labour services at a fixed annual sum in the fourteenth century did not represent the annual value of the land in 1560. Nor were fines for renewal or on * The CompenMouB or brief e Exa/rmnation of certayne ordinary complairUs of divers of our countrymen in these our dayes was printed in 1681, and the authoiship is attributed to " W. S. Gentleman." But Miss Lamond dis- covered, edited, and published (1893) an edition from a MS. probably written in 1649. She gives reasons for assigning its authorship to Jolm Hales. " W. S." may have been William Stafford (1664-1612) ; but that he was not the writer appears to have been conclusively proved. STRONG POSITION OF OPEN-FIELD FARMERS 71 admittance always excessive. Roger Wilbraham,^ of Delamere in Cheshire, about the middle of the seventeenth century, left behiad him instructions for his heir : " It will be expected of my heir that he deale no worse with tenants than I have done. And for his directions I have set down ye yearly values according to which I deale and wold have him to deale with the tenants. My rule in leasing is to take for a fine from ancient tenants : 8 years' value for 3 lives, 6 years' value to add 2 lives to 1, 2 years' value to add 1 life to 2, 1 year's value to change a life, or more if there is any great disparity in years betwixt the lives." When, therefore, rents were raised or fines enhanced, the landlord was not always trying to dis- possess his tenant. As often as not, he was claiming his proper share of the tenant's " unearned increment." Against these weapons of the law the cultivators of the old home-farms and of the assart lands were practically defenceless. It is therefore natural to suppose that they were the principal sufferers by the enclosing movement. In their case enclosures did not of necessity involve any breach of the old or new law. Even the provisions of the Tudor legislation were not infringed, unless the land, thus cleared of its cultivators, was so used as to throw any number of holdings together into the hands of one man, to " decay " farm-buildings or houses, to convert tillage into pasture, and so put down ploughs, or to carry an illegal number of sheep. But open-field farmers were in a stronger position. The common rights, which each partner in the association enjoyed over the whole cultivated area of the village-farm, could only be ex- tinguished by agreement, real or 'enforced, among the commoners. Nor was this consent the only obstacle to enclosure which the system presented. The intermixture of the strips is recognised as a protection against enclosure by the ablest of the sixteenth century writers on the subject. In the Compendious or Briefe Examination both the Doctor and the Husbandman agree as to the dif&culties which these two features of the open-field system threw in the way of any general enclosure. The same points are insisted upon by eighteenth century writers. It is not, of course, asserted that the difficulties of enclosing open-field farms were insuperable. Ever since the thirteenth century, village farms had been broken up, both by large landowners and comparatively small freeholders. ' Quoted from the Wilbraham MSS. at Delcuneie by F. K. Twemlow in The Twemlowa : their Wives, and their Homes (1910), p. 17. 72 FARMING FOR PROFIT But, before the enclosure acts of the eighteenth century, it was a slow and piecemeal process, by which the principal landlord, or some freeholder who was a partner in the farm, gradually con- solidated in his own hands the whole or a part of the commonable cultivated land, enclosed it, and freed it from common rights. No doubt the Enclosure of uncultivated wastes injured the tenants of village farms, because it restricted the area of rough pasture grazed by their hve-stock. Enclosures of this kind, carried out without leaving a sufGiciency of common pasture, were the chief grievance of the peasantry in Kett's rebellion in Norfolk. In this connection the re-enactment by Edward VI. of the statutes of Merton and Westminster,^ is significant. But the meaning is obscure. It may have been intended to increase the amount of tillage by bringing new land under the plough in exchange for that which had been laid down to grass. Except through the attack upon their pasture commons, it is reasonable to conclude that open- field farmers escaped the storm of sixteenth century enclosures more hghtly than the less protected cultivators of demesnes and " assart " lands. This seems to have been the case. Bitter com- plaints were made against the enclosure of open-fields. But the outcry was practically confined to the corn-growing counties of the Midlands, which throughout the whole period were seething with discontent and insurrection. Yet even here, with the exception of Leicestershire, the enclosing movement cannot have, to any great extent, succeeded, since these are the very counties which, in the eighteenth century, still contained the largest proportion of " cham- pion " or open land. Advanced free-traders might agree with Raleigh that England, like Holland, could be wholly suppUed with grain from abroad without troubling the people with tillage. Others of a less theo- retical turn of mind looked no further than the immediate distress which the abandonment of tillage produced. If the enclosing movement had been accompanied by a large extension of arable farming, the market for agricultural labour might have been so enlarged as substantially to relieve agrarian distress. But the extension of pasture and the substitution of a shepherd and his dog for the ploughmen and their teams only increased the scarcity of employment. Tenant-farmers lost their leaseholds ; copy- holders were dispossessed of their holdings ; squatters and cottagers, 1 3 and 4 Edward VI. c. 3. (See p. 38.) DISTRESS m RURAL DISTRICTS 73 who had eked out their harvest earnings by the produce of the live-stock which they maintained on the commons, were ruined ; servants in husbandry and labourers for weekly wages were thrown out of work. The high prices of necessaries, combined with the loss of commons, the ravages of the murrain, and a succession of dry summers, had driven many small cultivators over the narrow border-line which separated them from starvation. Rents rose exorbitantly till, for farmers at rack-rent, existence became a misery. There was an ominous growth of middlemen, " lease- mongers, who take groundes by lease to the entente to lette them againe for double and tripple the rente," '- and battened on the land-hunger of the people. Legislators were bewildered by currency questions, and violent changes in the standard purity of the gold and silver coinage aggravated the distress by raising or lowering prices. As gold and silver poured into the Old World from America, prices rose throughout Europe. The rise was in England attributed to every cause other than the cheapening of the precious metals. While from one or the other of these causes the purchasing power of wages rapidly diminished, their nominal value remained station- ary, and labourers were forced to accept the statutory rates. It was on those agriculturists who were unwilling or unable to adapt themselves to the times that the blow fell with the greatest severity. The Husbandman in the Compenndwms Examination knew several of his neighbours who had " turned ether part or all theire arable grounde into pasture, and therby have wezed verie Rich men." These were the men of whom Harrison and Sir Thomas Smith speak as " coming to such wealth that they are able and do daily buy lands of unthrifty gentlemen and make . . . their sons gentlemen." But the Husbandman himself, having " enclosed litle or nothinge of my grownd, could never be able to make up my lorde's rent, weare it not for a Htle brede of neate, shepe, swine, gese and hens." Hence it is that, while Latimer laments the d^radation of small yeomen who, like his father, had farms of " three to four pounds a year at the uttermost," Harrison describes the rise of substantial farmers and of the middle classes, and their improved standard of living. The distribution of wealth was becoming more and moie unequal ; the problem of poverty was acquiring a new significance. In the growing struggle for existence 1 Robert Crowley's Way to Wealth (1660). See also his Epigrams "of LeasemongoTS " and " of Bent rayseis." 74 FAEMING FOR PROFIT it was possible for men, who were neither infirm nor idle, to lose their footing. Voluntary almsgiving was tried and proved inade- quate. QraduaUy and cautiously the legislators of the reign of Elizabeth were forced to apply the principle of compulsory pro- vision for the relief of the necessitous .^ Previous legislation, in dealing with the impotent poor, had outlined the systems of local liability and of settlement which were adopted in the later poor- laws ; but it had been mainly concerned with the suppression of those persons who were styled idle rogues and vagabonds. The object explains, though to modem ideas it cannot justify, the harshness of the law. Able-bodied men and women, who were willing to work but had lost their livelihood, were unknown to the legislators who had sketched the first poor-laws for the reUef of the impotent poor and the punishment of sturdy beggars {vaiidi mendicantes). Our ancestors did not discriminate closely between the different sources of poverty. To them, as is stated in the preamble to the statute of Henry Vlll.,* " ydlenes " was the " mother and rote of all vyces." The " great and excessive nombres " of idle rogues and vagabonds were a crying evil. To this class belonged the men who committed " contynuaU theftes, murders, and other haynous offences, which displeased God, damaged the King's subjects, and disturbed the common weal of the realm." Apart from the committal of serious crime, the mass of idle vagrants was in country districts a nuisance and a danger. The kidnapping of children was not uncommon. Housewives were robbed of their linen, and their pots and pans, or terrified by threats of violence into parting with their money. Horses were stolen from their paddocks, or, stiU more easily, from the open-field balks on which they were tethered ; pigs were taken from their styes, chickens and eggs from the henroosts. Men and women, as they returned from markets, were waylaid by sturdy ruffians. Shops, booths, and stalls were pilfered of their contents. Tippling-houses were converted into receivers' dens for stolen goods. The com- parative leniency of the laws of Henry VII. had failed ; therefore the evil must be stamped out with a severity which was not only unsentimental but ferocious. Here the interesting point is whether the ranks of idle rogues > See Appendix 11., The Poor Lama, 1601-1834. » 1530-1 (22 Henry Vm. o. 12) supplemented in 1636 by 27 Heniy VHI. c. 26. UNEMPLOYED LABOUR 76 were to any large extent swollen by agriculturists, driven to want and desperation by the loss of their holdings. The sturdy beggars, against whom Richard II. had legislated, had not the excuse of want of employment. They consisted, partly of disbanded soldiers who had so long followed the trade of war that they knew no other ; partly of men who had suffered that general moral deteriora- tion which often resulted from great catastrophes like the successive visitations of the " Black Death." In the fifteenth century, the close of the French war and of the Wars of the Roses again recruited the ranks of idle poverty and crime. To them were added, at a later date, the disbanded retinues of great nobles, " the great flock or train," to quote More's Utopia, " of idle and loitering serving-men, which never learned any craft whereby to get their living." Finally, the suppression of the monasteries displaced and threw upon the world a large number of dependents, many of whom, from inclination or necessity, joined the army of sturdy beggars. Disbanded soldiers, discharged serving-men, and dismissed depend- ents of monastic institutions account for a formidable total of unemployed labour, without the addition of clothiers out of work or displaced agriculturists. But the evidence of More's Utopia cannot be ignored. The passage is famihar ^ in which he speaks of the husbandmen " thrust owte of their owne " by enclosures ; compelled to " trudge out of their knouen and accustomed howses " ; driven to a forced sale of their " housholde stuffe " and " con- strayned to sell it for a thyng of nought." " And when they have, wanderynge about, sone spent that, what can they els do but Steele, and then justelye, God wote, be hanged, or els go about a beggyng ? And yet then also they be cast in prison as vagaboundes, because they go about and worke not ; whom no man will set a worke, though they never so willingly ofEer them selfes therto." More's eloquent appeal may have produced effect. In the year after the publication of Utopia, the first and most important Com- mission was issued (1517-19) to enquire into the progress and results of enclosures in the twenty-four counties principally affected. The Returns of the Commissioners in Chancery are admittedly imperfect. But they justify the conclusion* that More's picture, though true * Utopia, bk. i., ed- Lupton, pp. 53-4. ' Hypothetical tables based on these retvims have been constructed by Mr. Gay, showing that the total number of persons displaced by enclosures during the period 1485-1617 did not much exceed 6931. See Johnson's IHawppearanee of the SmaU LancUntmer, p. 58. 76 FARMING FOR PROFIT in particular instances, is as a general description of rural conditions too highly coloured. Dispossessed agriculturists undoubtedly con- tributed some proportion of the class which the Government grouped under the heading of idle rogues. Contemporary writers imply that the proportion was large : modem research, based on con- temporary enquiries and returns, suggests that it was relatively small. The evidence seems insufficient for a decision. In coping with a real evil, the Government attempted no classification. The innocent suffered with the guilty, and men and women, whether many or few, who had lost their means of livelihood and were willing to work, were the victims of severe punishment designed for the class of professional vagabonds. Something is known of the degrees, practices, and jargon of the Elizabethan fraternity of vagabonds. Awdelay and Harman^ describe the " Abraham man," or " poor Tom," bare-legged and bare-armed, pretending madness; the "Upright man" with his staff, and the " Ruffler " with his weapon ; the " Fraters," Pedlars, and Tinkards ; the " priggars of Frauncers," or horse-stealers, in their leather jerkins ; the " Counteriet Cranke," feigning the falling sick- ness, with a piece of white soap in his mouth which made him foam like a boar : the " Palliards," with their patched cloaks, and self- infficted sores or wounds ; and many others of the twenty-three varieties, male and female, of the professional beggar. But even Harman seldom enquired into their previous life. Some, like the " Ruffler," had either " serued in the warres or bene a seruinge man " ; others, like the " Uprights," have been " serueing men, artificers, and laboryng men traded up to husbandry." The " wild Roge " was a " begger by enheritance — his Grandfather was a begger, his father was one, and he must nedes be one by good reason." Few allusions can be gleaned from Shakespeare's writings to the agricultural changes which were taking place around him. But when we pass from the movement itself to some of the results which it helped to produce, his references are many and clear. The mass of " vagrom men " was a real social danger which exercised the wits of wiser men than Dogberry.* ' The Fraternity of Vacabondea, by John Awdeley (1561) and A Caveat or Warening for Commen Ctirsetera, by Thomas Harmon (1667-8). 'Many of the types of beggars appear in Shakespeare's pages. There is Harman's " BufiBer," " the worthiest of this unruly rablement " : " . . . fit to bandy with thy lawleu Bons To raffle in the commonwealth of Borne." {Tit. Andr. Act i. So. 1, U. 312-3.) SHAKESPEARE'S " VAGROM MEN " 77 There is the "pedlar," the aristocracy of the profession, a clever plausible rascal like Autolyous. " The droncken tyncker " is represented by Christopher Sly — " by birth a pedlar ... by present profession a tinker " — drunk on the heath, and in debt for ale to Marian Hacket {Tam. Sh. Ind. ii. 11. 19-22). There is the " prygger " or " prygman," who " haunts wakes, fairs, and bear-baitings " (WitU. TcOe, Act iv. Sc. 2, 1. 109). There is Awdeley's " chop- logyke," who gives " XX w6rdes for one," to whom Capulet likens his daughter Juliet {Rom. and JtU. Act iii. Sc. 6, 1. 160). There is Harman's " Bogue," or " Wild Rogue," in the " rogue forlorn," who sheires the hovel and the straw with King Lear and the swine {Lear, Act iv. Sc. 7, 1. 39). Edgar, disguised as a madman and calling himself ' poor Tom " {Lear, Act iii. Sc. 4, L 57), is Awdeley's " Abraham man," who " nameth himselfe ' poore Tom.'. . Whipped from tithing to tithing," he had only received the punishment to which an Elizabethan statute (39 Eliz. c. 4) sentenced " all fencers, bearwards, common players, and minstrels ; all jugglers, tinkers and petty chapmen," and other vagrants who were adjudged to be rogues, vagabonds, and sturdy beggars. CHAPTER IV. THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH. Patemcd despotism : restoTatioii of the purity of the coinage ; a definite commeTcial policy : revival of the wool txade : new era of prosperity among landed gentry and occupiers of land : a time of adversity for small landowners and wage-earning labourers : Statute of Apprentices ; hiring fairs ; growth of agricultural literature : Fitzherbert and Tusser : their picture of Tudor farming : defects of the open-field system : experience of the value of enclosures ; improvement in farming : Bamaby Googe ; Sir Hugh Flat : progress in the art of gardening. The reign of Elizabeth marks a definite stage in English history. The mediaeval organisation of society, together vrith its trade guilds and manorial system of farming, had broken down. Out of the confusion order might be evolved by a paternal despotism. The Queen's advisers, with strong practical sagacity, set themselves to the task. They sate loosely to theories and rode no principles to death. But so firmly did they lay their foundations, that parts of their structure lasted until the nineteenth century. National con- trol displaced local control. The central power gathered strength: it directed the economic interests of the nation ; it regulated industrial relations ; through its legislation and administration it fostered the development of national resources. The restoration of the standard purity and weight of the coinage was resolutely taken in hand. Its debasement had been the cause of much of the economic distress in previous reigns ; credit was ruined, and the treasury bankrupt. The debased, sweated, and clipped silver coinage was called in, and new coins were issued. As silver flowed into the country from the New World, the amount of money in circulation increased. More capital was available in a handy form, and, when legitimate interest ceased to be confused with usury, more people could borrow it on reasonable terms. The way was thus paved for a new era of commercial prosperity. In mediaeval times the whole external trade of the country had DEFINITE COMMERCIAL POLICY 79 been in the hands of foreigners. Elizabeth followed and developed the commercial policy of England, which first assumed a dehberate continuous shape under Henry Vii. Foreign traders were dis- couraged, and English merchants favoured. The Hanseatic League lost the last of its privileges ; the Venetian fleet came to England less and less frequently, and at last ceased altogether to fly its flag in the Channel. The import of manufactured goods was checked. The export of raw material and of English sheep was narrowly restricted, though long wool, as the staple of a great trade, was still sent abroad freely. The Government realised to the full all the abuses of patents and monopoUes ; but they did not hesitate to grant both privileges in order to stimulate native enterprise. Companies were formed with exclusive rights of trading in par- ticular countries. The oldest and most powerful of these Companies, the Merchant Adventurers, obtained a royal charter in 1564. The Muscovite, Levant or Turkey, Eastland or Baltic, and Guinea or African Companies were formed to push English trade in foreign parts. In 1600 the East India Company was chartered. The mercantile marine was encouraged by fishery laws, which gave English fishermen a monopoly in the sale of fish. Men who argued that abstinence from meat at certain seasons was good for the soul's health risked the stake or the rack ; but, for the sake of multiplying seamen, the Government did not hesitate to ordain fast-days on which only fish was to be eaten.*^ To foster the home manufacture of cloth, it was made a penal offence for any person over the age of six not to wear on Sundays and holy days a cap made of English cloth. Stimulated by such methods, trade throve apace, and English goods were carried in English-built ships, owned by Englishmen, and manned by English seamen. While foreign merchants were discouraged, foreign craftsmen, especially religious refugees from France or Flanders, were welcomed as settlers, bringing with them their skill in manufacturing paper, lace, silk, parchments, light woollens, hosiery, fustians, satins, thread, needles, and in other arts and industries. The English wool trade was restored to more than its former ^ The rule of eating fish twice a week was continued from Catholic times ; but a, third day was added by Elizabeth from motives of " civile policy." " Accounting the Lent Season, and all fasting dales in the yeare, together with Wednesday and Friday and Saturday, you shall see that the one halfe of the yeare is ordeined to eate fish in " (Cogan, Haven of HeUhe, ed. 1612, p. 138). 80 THE REK3N OF ELIZABETH prosperity. On it had long depended the commercial prosperity of the comitry. John Cole, " the rich clothier of Reading " at the end of the thirteenth century, was as famous as his fellow-craftsman, John Winchcomb, the warlike " Jack of Newbury," became in the days of Henry VUI. Wool was the chief source of the wealth of traders and of the revenues of the Crown. It controlled the foreign policy of England, supplied the sinews of our wars, built and adorned our churches and private houses. The foreign trade con- sisted partly in raw material, partly in semi-manufactured exports such as worsted yams, partly in wholly manufactured broad-cloth. As the manufacture of worsted and cloth goods developed in this country, the demand and consumption rapidly increased at home. According to the purpose for which it was to be used, wool was divided into long and short. In England, long wool was employed mainly for worsted fabrics, but also to give strength and firmness to cloth. Abroad, it was eagerly bought in its raw state for both purposes. In long wool, or combing-wool, England had pracr tically a monopoly of the markets, and to it the export trade of raw material was almost exclusively confined. Short wool, on the other hand, was used for broad-cloth. In its raw state it had a formidable rival abroad in the fleeces of the Spanish merino. Only in the manufactured state did it compete with Flemish and French fabrics on the Continent, and often found itself unable, owing to the excellence of merino wool and the skill of foreign weavers, to maintain its hold on the home market. Wool-staplers were the middlemen. They bought the wool from the breeder, sorted it according to its quaJity, and sold it to the manufacturer. Dyer,^ two centuries later, describes their work : " Nimbly, \Tith habitual speed. They Bever lock from lock, and long and short. And soft, and rigid, pUe in several heaps. This the dusk hatter asks ; another shines. Tempting the clothier ; that the hosier seeks ; The long bright lock is apt for aiiy stufEs : If any wool, peculiar to our isle. Is given by nature, 'tis the comber's lock. The soft, the snow-white, and the long-grown flake." In the long-wooled class Cotswold wool held the supremacy, with Cirencester as its centre, though the " lustres " of lincolnshice always commanded their price. Among short-wools, Byeland had 1 The Fleece (1767), bk. u ; U. 83-88 and 446-47. CHANGE m THE QUALITY OF WOOL 81 the pre-eminence, with Leominster as the centre of its trade. " Lemster ore " was the equivalent of the " golden fleece " of the ancients, and poets compared the wool for its fineness to the web of the silk- worm, and for its softness to the cheek of a maiden. During the Tudor period, a change was passing over the wool trade, which may have influenced the labour troubles of the period as weU as the policy of land-holders. As enclosiu-es multipUed, sheep were better fed, and the fleece increased in weight and length, though it lost something of the fineness of its quality. Li other words, the wool was less adapted for the manufacture of broad- cloth. The old pastures were also wearing out. During long and cold winters, if the sheep is half-starved, the fleece may retain its fineness, but it loses in strength. There also was a deterioration in the quahty of short wool. How far these considerations may have influenced pasture-farming is necessarily uncertain. But it is at least a coincidence that, in spite of the increase in the number of sheep, there was, in the early years of the Tudor period, con- siderable distress in the clothing trade. As the reign of Elizabeth advanced, the great development of home manufactures provided a remedy. The newly established Merchant Companies opened up fresh markets abroad for English cloth. At the same time Prance and the Low Countries, distracted by civil or religious wars, ceased for the moment to be our rivals in the trade. English broad- cloths were exported abroad in increasing quantities. The suspen- sion of continental manufactures checked the exportation of Enghsh long wool. But again the religious troubles of the Continent relieved the situation. Foreign refugees settled in England, bring- ing with them secrets in the manufacture of worsted, light woollen stnfis, and hosiery, for all of which English wool was specially adapted. Thus England was once more growing prosperous, and farming shared in the general prosperity. As the reign advanced, agri- cultural produce rose rapidly in price. The rise no longer depended on those fluctuations in the purity of the coinage, which had been so frequent that no man knew the real value of the coin in which he was paid. For a time the influx of silver had cheapened the precious metals, diminished their purchasing power, and so created deamess. But the great expansion of trade gradually absorbed the new supply of silver. The later rise in agricultural prices was due to F 82 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH the relative scarcity of produce, which was caused by the increased consumption consequent on revived prosperity, by a higher standard of living, and by a growing population. The necessary spur of profit was thus appUed to farming energies. Leaseholders for a long term or for lives, and copyholders at fixed quit-rents had their golden opportunity, and many of them used it to become wealthy. Of the general prosperity of the landowning and land-renting portion of the rural community, there is sufficient evidence. Every man, says Harrison,^ turned builder, " pulled downe the old house and set up a new after his owne devise." In ten years more oak was used for building than had been used in the previous hundred. Country manor-houses were buUt not of timber, but of brick or stone, and they were furnished with " great provision of tapistrie, Turkie work, pewter, brasse, fine linen and . . . costUe cupbords of plate." Ordinary diet had become less simple. " White-meats," — ^milk, butter, eggs, and cheese, — ^were despised by the wealthy, who preferred butcher 's-meat, fish, and a " diversitie of wild and tame foules." The usual fare of the country gentleman was abundant, if not profuse. The dinner which Justice Shallow ordered for Falstafi might be quoted as an illustration. But more direct evidence may be produced. Harrison says that the everyday dinner of a coimtry gentleman was " foure, five, or six dishes, when they have but smaU resort." Gervase Markham in his English Housewife gives directions for a " great feast," and for " a more humble feast, or an ordinary proportion which any good man may keep in his family, for the entertainment of his true and worthy friend." The " humble feast " includes " sixteen dishes of meat that are of substance and not emptie, or for shew." To these " sixteen full dishes," he adds " sallets, fricases, quelque choses, and devised paste, as many dishes more, which make the full service no lesse then two-and-thirtie dishes." In dress, also, the country gentry were growing more expensive, imitating the " diversities of jagges and changes of colours " of the Frenchman. Already, too, as Bishop Hall has described in his Satires, they were in the habit of deserting their country-houses for the gaiety of towns, and the " unthankful swallow " " built her circled nest " in " The towered chimnies which shovild be The windpipes of good hospitalitie." Of the yeomen, who included not only farming owners, but ^ Harrison, Detcription of England (1577), bk. ii. oc. vi. zii. zxii. PROSPERITY OF YEOMEN 83 lessees for lives and copyholders, Harrison says that they " com- monlie live wealthilie, keepe good houses, and travell to get riches." ^ Their houses were furnished Mdth " costlie furniture," and they had " learned also to garnish their cupbords with plate, their joined beds with tapistrie and silke hangings, and their tables with carpets and fire naperie." Though rents had risen and were still rising, " yet will the farmer thinke his gaines verie small toward the end of his terme if he have not six or seven yeares rent lieing by him, therewith to purchase a new lease, beside a faire garnish of pewter on his cupbord, three or foure featherbeds, so manie coverlids and carpets of tapistrie, a silver salt, a bowle for wine, and a dozzen of spoones to furnish up the sute." Old men noted these changes in luxurious habits — " the multitude of chitnnies lateUe erected," " the great amendment of lodging," and " the exchange of vessel as of treene platters into pewter and wodden spoones into silver or tin." Writing of the Cheshire yeomen in 1621, William Webb says : ^ " In building and furniture of their houses, till of late years, they used the old manner of the Saxons ; for they had their fire in the midst of the house against a hob of clay, and their oxen also under the same roof ; but within these forty years it is altogether altered, so that they have built chimnies, and furnished other parts of their houses accordingly. . . . Touching their housekeeping it is bountiful and comparable with any shire in the realm. And that is to be seen at their weddings and burials, but chiefly at their wakes, which they yearly hold ... for this is to be understood that they lay out seldom any money for any provision but have it of their own, as beef, mutton, veal, pork, capons, hens, wild fowl, and fish. They bake their own bread and brew their own drink. To conclude, I know divers men, who are but farmers, that in their housekeeping may compare with a lord or a baron in some countries beyond the seas. Yea, although I named a higher degree, I were able to justify it." In the Isle of Wight, Sir John Oglander ' com- pares the state of the country at the close of Elizabeth's reign with that at the outbreak of the Civil War. At the former period he says that " Money wase as plentiful in yeomens purses as nowe in ye beste of ye genterye, and all ye genterye full of monyes and owt of debt." * Description, bk. ii. ch. v. > Quoted in King's Vale Royal (1778), vol. i. pp. 30, 31. • Oglander Uemovra (1596-1648), p. 66. 84 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH The small copyholder's house is described by Bishop Hall as being : " Of one bay's breadth, Ood wot, a eilly cote Whose thatched spars are furred with sluttish soote A whole inch thick, shining like blackmoor's brows Through smoke that downe the headlesse barrel blows, At his bed's feete feeden his stalled teame. His swine beneath, his pullen o'er the beame." The outside walls were made of timber uprights and cross-beams, forming raftered panels which were thickly daubed with clay. But the fare which the small copyholder enjoyed was at least as plentiful as that of landless labourers in modem times. In one of the Elizabethan pastoral poems a noble huntsman finds shelter under a shepherd's roof. The food, even if something is allowed for Arcadian licence, was good, though, in the language of the day, it consisted mainly of " white meat." The guest was supplied with the best his host could provide : " Browne bread, whig, bacon, curds, and milke. Were set him on the borde." Fresh butcher's meat was rarely seen on the table. Of the " Martyl- mas beef," hung from the rafters and smoked, Andrew Borde ^ thought httle. If, he says, a man have a piece hanging by his side and another in his belly, the piece which hangs by his side does him more good, especially if it is rainy weather. Bacon, souse, and brawn were the peasant's meat. " Potage," Borde elsewhere writes, " is not so moch used in all Crystendom as it is used in England." It was part of the staple diet of the peasant, whether made of the liquor in which meat had been boiled, thickened with oatmeal, and flavoured with chopped herbs and salt, or made from beans or pease. Oatmeal porridge, and " fyrmente," made of millr and wheat, were largely used. His bread was generally made of wheat and rye, often mixed, as Best states,' with pease — a peck of pease to a bushel of rye, or two pecks of pease to the same quantity of rye and wheat. Even " horse-bread," as Borde calls it,^ made of pease and beans, was better than the mixture of acorns which Harrison says * was eaten in times of dearth. Yet the husbandman had his feastings, such as "bridales, purifications of women and such od meetings, where it is incredible to tell what meat is consimied and spent." 1 Andrew Borde's Dyetary (1642), oh. xvi. ' Farming Book, p. 104. » Borde's Dyetary, ch. si. • Detcription, ch. vi. NEW BUYERS OF LAND 85 The prosperity of the rural community was not imiversal. For many of the smaller gentiy, and for day-labourers for hire, times were hard. Landowners, whose income was more or less stationary, suffered from the rise in prices, accompanied, as it was, by a higher standard of luxury. When leases fell in, or Uves were renewed, or copyholders were admitted, rents might be increased or fines enhanced. But in an extravagant age, when country gentlemen b^an to be attracted to London, such opportunities, if the tenants belonged to a healthy stock, might come too rarely or too late. Many owners were compelled to sell their estates. Land was often in the market. Thus two opposing tendencies characterised the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. The division of church lands among grantees who already owned estates strengthened the landed aristocracy, while continual sales democratised the ownership of land. It is said that only 330 families can trace their titles to land * beyond the dissolution of the monasteries. Li the two centiuies that followed, few of the gentry retained their hold on their estates, unless they were enriched by wealthy marriages, by trade, or by the practice of the law. The buyers generally belonged to the rising middle classes. Harrison, in his Description of England} says that yeomen, " for the most part farmers to gentlemen," by attention to their business " do come to great welth in somuch that manie of them are able and doo buie the lands of unthriftie gentle- men." Fynes Moiyson, in his Itinerary * (1617) notes that the Eng- lish " doe . . daily sell their patrimonies, and the buyers (except- ing Lawyers) are for the most part Citizens and vulgar Men." Sir Simon Degge* (1669), a learned lawyer, declares that in Stafford- shire, during the past sixty years, half the land had passed into the possession of new men. He attributes this change of ownership, partly to divine punishment for the sacrilege of those who were grantees of ecclesiastical property, partly to the extravagance of the country gentry who now took pleasure in spending their estates in London. He makes these comments on Erdeswick's Survey of Staffordshire, drawn up between 1693 and 1603, and goes on to say that there were then in the county only " three citizen owners " ' Bk. ii. ch. V. The DeacripHon vas published in 1677. The same passage occurs in Sir Thomas Smith's De RepvbUca Anglorum, bk. i. ch. xsiii. published in 1583. ■ Part m. bk. iii. ch. iii. * Degge's Letter is printed as a supplement to Eideswick's Survey of Staffordshire in the edition of 1717. 86 THE REIGN OP ELIZABETH of land, and that now, in 1669, there were three Barons, four Baronets, and twenty calling themselves Esquires who had bought estates with money made in trade. Similar is the evidence of the compiler of Angliae Notitia ^ (1669). " The English," he says, " especially the Oentry are so much given to Prodigality and Sloth- fulness that Estates are oftner spent and sold than in any other Countrey . . . whereby it comes to passe that Cooks, Vintners, Innkeepers, and such mean Fellows, enrich themselves and begger and insult over the Gentry . . . not only those but Taylors, Dancing Masters and such Trifling Fellows arrive to that Riches and Pride, as to ride in their Coaches, keep their Summer Houses, to be served in Plate, etc. an insolence insupportable in other well-govem'd Nations." Another class, that of labourers, suffered from the deamess of agricultural produce, because their wages were fixed by law, and only by slow degrees followed the upward tendency of prices. In some respects the worst evils of the period 1485-1558 were passing away, or were modified by the expansion of trade. Enclosures still continued. Acts of Parliament* were still passed against the decaying of towns and against the substitution of pasture for tillage, and one of the most vehement of protests against enclosures, was made by Francis Trigge,' in 1604. But land was now more frequently enclosed for arable farming, and there was consequently less displacement of labour. The great extension of gardens attached to country houses provided new occupations. Industries like spinning, weaving, and rope-making, which were previously confined to particular towns by the craft-organisations of guilds, spread into rural districts, and employed villagers in supplying not merely their domestic wants but the needs of manufacturers. Agriculturally, a change was taking place in the labourer's condi- tion. For the cultivation of the soil, farmers, except in the North and East, looked less to servants in husbandry and more to the day- labourers, whose wages assumed a new importance in the assess- ments of the Justices of the Peace. As the prices of agricultural produce rose, and as, here and there, the improvement of roads brought new markets within the reach of farmers, it was cheaper ^In the 1692 edition of AngUeie Notitia the words "Prodigality, Sports, and Pastimes " are substituted for " Prodigality and Slothfulness." * 1662-3, 6 Eliz. c. 2 ; 1697-8, 39 Eliz. cc. 1 and 2 ; 1601, 43 Eliz. c. 9. ' The Humble Petition of Two Siatera : the Chwreh and Oormtum-wecMi. LABOURERS AKD THEIR WAGES 87 to pay wages to hired labourers than to board agricoltural servants, especially if, as Tusser says, they required roast meat on Sundays and Thursdays. Free labour, sometimes, but not invariably, stUl associated with the occupation of land, was becoming in the southern and midland counties the chief agent in cultivating the soil. Where enclosures were fewest, the largest number of labourers supplemented their wages by the profits of their land, their rights of common, and their goose-runs. Where enclosures were most extensive, those labourers were most numerous who were dependent only on their labour-power. Apparently there was difficulty in lodging this increasing class of landless labourers, and an attempt was made to use existing cottages as tenement houses. The Govern- ment endeavoured to check these tendencies by legislation.^ Not more than one family was allowed to occupy each cottage, and to every cottage four acres of land were to be attached. But the most important attempt to regulate the labour-market was the Statute of Apprentices (1563).^ This industrial code " touching divers orders for artificers, labourers, servants of husbandry, and apprentices " deals with labour in the towns as weU as in the country. It was framed, partly as a consolidating Act, partly because, as the Preamble states, the allowances limited in previous legislation had, owing to the advance in prices, become too small. It was passed in the hope that its administration would " banish idleness, advance husbandry, and yield unto the hired person both in the time of scarcity and in the time of plenty a convenient proportion of wages." It pro- ceeds on the old lines that men could be compelled to work. But it contemplates a minimum wage at the rates current in the district, establishes a working day for summer and winter, and endeavours to provide for technical instruction by a system of apprenticeship. Any person between the age of twelve and sixty, not excepted by the Statute, could be compelled to labour in husbandry. AU engagements, except those for piecework, were to be for one year. Masters unduly dismissing servants were fined. Servants unduly leaving masters were imprisoned. No servant could leave the locaUty where he was last employed without a certificate of lawful departure. Hours of labour were twelve hours in the summer and during daylight in winter. Wages were to be annually fixed by the Justices of the Peace, after considering the < 1589, 31 Eliz. c. 7. • 1662-3, 6 Eliz. c. i. 88 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH circumstances, in consultation with " such grave and discreet persons as they shall think meet." No higher wages than those settled under the assessment were to be given, or received, under severe penalties. At harvest time, artificers and persons " meet to labour " might be compelled to serve at the mowing or " iTiniTig " of hay and com. Persons over twelve and under eighteen might be taken as apprentices in husbandry and compelled to serve till the age of twenty-one. By agreement the age might be extended to twenty-four. Under the provisions of this Statute agricultural labourers and servants were engaged annually. Shortly before Martinmas, the chief constable of the division sent out notices that he would sit at a certain town or village on a given day, and required the petty constables to attend with lists of the masters and servants in their districts. At the appointed place and time the chief constable met his subordinates and the masters : the servants also assembled, all " cladde," as Henry Best describes them,^ " in their best apparrell," in the market square, the churchyard, or some other public place. The chief constable took the lists, called each master in turn accord- ing to the entries, and asked him whether he was willing to set such and such a servant at liberty. If the master replied in the negative, the constable stated what were the wages fixed by the Justices, received a penny fee from the master, and bound the servant for a second term of a year. If the answer was in the affirmative, the constable received from the servant a fee of twopence, and gave him his certificate of lawful departure. Meanwhile masters who wished to hire labourers, whether men or women, walked about among the assembled crowd in order to choose Ukely-looking servants. When a master had made his choice, his first enquiry was whether the man was at liberty. If the servant had his ticket, the master took him aside, and asked where he was bom, where he was last employed, and what he could do. Best once heard the answer : " I can sowe, I can mowe, And I can stacke, And I can doe My master too. When my master tumes his backe." If the last employer was present at the sitting, he was sought out, * Bural Economy in Yorkshire in 1641, being the Farming and account Book» of Henry Best (Surtees Society, vol. zxxiii. 1867), pp. 132-6. BIRTH OF AGRICULTURAL LITERATURE 89 and asked whether the man-servant was " true and trustie . . . gentle and quiett . . . addicted to company-keepinge or noe," or whether the woman-servant was a good milker, not " of a sluggish and sleepie disposition for dainger of fire." Then followed the bargaining for wages. Sometimes the servant asked for a " gods- penny " on striking the bargain, " or an old suite, a payre of breeches, an olde hatte, or a payre of shoes ; and mayde servants to have an apron, smocke, or both." Sometimes it was a condition to have so many sheep wintered and summered with the master's flock, and to have the twopence which was paid for the certificate refunded before handing over the ticket to the new master. Once hired, the servant could not leave the master, nor the master dismiss the servant, without a quarter's warning. In Yorkshire a servant liked to come to a new place on Tuesday or Thursday. Monday was counted an unlucky day, and the proverb ran : " Monday flitte Never sitte." Farming annals are comparatively silent as to the conditions in which day-labourers for hire lived in the reign of Elizabeth. But in one respect, as has been said, they undoubtedly shared the general prosperity. Though their wages remained low, and only fitfully rose as the purchasing power of money declined, they were more secure of employment. In the increased demand for labour resulting from improved methods of agriculture lay their best hopes for the future. It is probable that the decay and ultimate dissolution of the monasteries had for the time inflicted a heavy blow on the development of agriculture as an art. To English farming in the early centuries the monks were what capitalist land- lords became in the eighteenth century. They were the most scientific farmers of the day : they had access to the practical learning of the ancients ; their intercourse with their brethren abroad gave them opportunities of benefiting by foreign experience which were denied to their lay contemporaries. Already, however, there were signs that their places as pioneers would be occupied. Throughout Europe agricultural Uterature was commencing, and writers were at work urging upon farmers the improved methods which enclosure revealed to them. In Italy Tarello and the translators of Crescentius, in the Low Countries Heresbach, in France Charles Estienne and Bernard Palissy, in England Fitzherbert and Tusser, wrote upon farming. It was not long before the gentry 90 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH began to pay attention to agriculture. As Michel de I'HSpital solaced his exile with a farm at fitampes, so Sir Richard Weston in the reign of Charles I., and Townshend in that of George 11., occupied their leisure in farming, and in their retirement conferred greater benefits on the weU-being of England than they had ever done by their poUtical activities. Up to the sixteenth century Walter of Henley's farming treatise had held the field. Now it was superseded. In 1523 appeared the Boke of Husbandrye, " compyled," as Berthelet says in his edition of 1534, "sometyme by mayster FitzHerbarde, of Charytie and good zele that he bare to the weale of this moost noble realme, whiche he dydde not in his youthe, but after he had exercysed husbandry with greate experyence XL yeres." In the same year was also printed, by the same author, the Boke of Surveyinge and Improvements. The Book of Husbandry is a minutely practical work on farming, written by a man familiar with the Peak of Derbyshire and by a horsebreeder on a large scale who possessed " 60 mares or more." The Book of Surveying is a treatise on the relations of landlord and tenant and on the best methods of developing an estate. Only an experienced farmer could have written the first ; the second required no greater acquaintance with law than might be acquired by a shrewd landowner in the administration of an estate. The authorship of the two books has been claimed for Anthony Fitz- herbert, who was knighted in 1521-2 on becoming a Justice of the Common Pleas, and also for his elder brother John Fitzherbert.^ It is difficult to credit the Judge — ^immersed in judicial and political duties, and absorbed in the composition of legal works — ^with the practical knowledge of farming displayed in the Book of Husbandry. 1 The dispute as to the authorship of the Books of Husbandry and Surveying is ancient. Professor Skeat {JntrodtuiHon to the Book of Huabandry, English Dialect Society, 1882), and Mr. Rigg {Dictionary of National Biography) champion Sir Anthony : the Bev. Reginald Fitzherbert {EngUah Historical Review, April, 1897), Sir Ernest Clarke, whose knowledge of agricultural bibliography is unrivalled (Transactions of Bibliog. Soe. 1896, p. 160), and Mr. Gay {Quarterly Journal of EcorumUes, 1904) support the elder brother, John. The Catalogue of the British Museum now attributes the authorship of both books to John Fitzherbert. Berthelet, who printed the edition of 1634, speaks of the author, in the passage quoted in the text, as though he were dead. This would be true of John Fitzherbert, who died in 1631, but not of Sir Anthony, who hved till 1638. The " XL yeres " experience, from which the author wrote, could not be claimed by Sir Anthony in 1623 ; it might well have belonged to John, who was bis elder brother. It is known that John Fitzherbert was for four years a student at the Inns of Court, where he might have laid the foundation of his legal knowledge. FITZHERBERT AND TUSSER 91 It is much less difficult to imagine that John Fitzherbert should combine minute experience of agricultural details mth a sufficient knowledge of law to write the Book of Surveying. At any rate, the Book of Husbandry became, and for more than half a century remained, a standard work on English farming. Thirty-four years later appeared Thomas Tusser's Hundreih Good Pointes of Husbandrie (1557). The work was afterwards expanded into Five Hundreih Pointes of Good Husbandrie, united to as many Good Pointes of Huswifery (1673). Like Fitzherbert, Tusser was a champion of enclosures, and his evidence is the more valuable because he was not only an Essex man, a Suffolk and a Norfolk farmer, but began to write when the agitation against enclosures in the eastern counties was at its height. His own life proved the diffi- culty of combining practice with science, or farming with poetry. " He spread his bread," says FuUer, " with all sorts of butter, yet none would ever stick thereon." He was successively " a musician, schoolmaster, serving-man, husbandman, grazier, poet — ^more skilful in all than thriving in his vocation." To the present generation he is Uttle more than a name. But his doggerel poems are a rich storehouse of proverbial wisdom, and of information respecting the rural life, domestic economy, and agricultural practices of ovu: Elizabethan ancestors. His work was repeatedly reprinted. It is also often quoted by subsequent writers, as, for example, by Henry Best in his Farming Book (1641), by Walter BUth in his English Improver Improved (1649), and by Worhdge in the Systema Agri- cvUurae (1668-9). The practical parts of the poem were edited in 1710 by David Hillman under the title of Tusser Redivivus, with a conmientary which continually contrasts Elizabethan practices with those of farmers in the reign of Queen Anne. When Lord Molesworth in 1723 proposed the foundation of agricultural schools, he advised that Tusser's " Five hundred points of good husbandry " should be " taught to the boys to read, to copy and get by heart." From the pages of Fitzherbert and Tusser may be gathered a picture of Tudor agriculture at the time when Elizabeth came to the throne. But even in this Uterature, which probably represents the most progressive theory and practice of farming, it is difficult to trace any important change, still less any distinct advance on thirteenth century methods. Here and there, on the contrary, there are signs that fanners had gone backwards instead of forwards. Agricultural implements remaiaed unaltered. Ploughs were still 92 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH the same heavy, cumbrous instruments, though several varieties are mentioned as adapted to the difEerent soils of the country. But Fitzherbert was famiUar with the same device for regulating the depth and breadth of furrows, which was one of the most notable improvements in the eighteenth century ploughs. Oxen were still preferred to horses for ploughing purposes by both Fitzherbert and Tusser. Iron was more used in the construction of ploughs ; both share and coulter were more generally of iron, and the latter was well steeled. Iron also entered more largely into the building of waggons. Instead of the broad wheels made entirely of wood, Fitzherbert recommends narrower wheels, boimd with iron, as more lasting and lighter in the draught. So long as artificial grasses and roots were unknown, the farmer's year necessarily remained the same — its calendar of seasonable operations regulated by the recurrence of saints' days and festivals, and controlled by a behef in planetary influences as unscientific as that of Old Moore or ZadMel. Since the Middle Ages, the only addition to agricultural resources had been hops, introduced into the eastern coimties from Flanders at the end of the fifteenth century. The date 1524, which is usually given for their introduction, is too late ; so also is the rhyme, of which there are several variations : " Hops, reformation, bays, and beer, Came into England all in one year." Hops were apparently unknown in 1523 to Fitzherbert in Derby- shire ; but in 1552 they were sufficiently important to be made the subject of special legislation by Edward VI. In Tusser 's day they were extensively cultivated in Suffolk. On enclosed land their cultivation rapidly increased. Harrison (1577) questions whether any better are to be found than those grown in England. Reginald Scot, himself a man of Kent, published his Per/ite PUUforme of a Hoppe Garden in 1574, with minute instructions for the growing, picking, drying and packing of hops. The book was reprinted in 1575, and again in 1576. It was still the standard work in 1651. In Hartlib's Legacie it is called " an excellent Treatise, to the which Uttle or nothing hath been added, though the best part of an hundred years are since past." Fitzherbert starts his Book of Hvsbandry with the month of January. But Tusser begins his farmer's year at Michaelmas as the usual date of entry. Both writers note that an open-field farmer entered by custom on his fallows on the preceding Lady-Day, in CORN CROPS ON TUDOR FARMS 93 order that he might get or keep them in good heart for his autumn sowing. As the Julian Calendar was still in force, the dates are twelve days earlier than they would be under the present Gregorian Calendar. Even with this difference, few farmers of to-day would accept Tusser's advice to sow oats and barley in January ; they would be more likely to agree with Fitzherbert that the beginning of March is soon enough. All wheat and rye were sown in the autumn, — ^from August onwards, — and the heaviest grain was selected for seed by means of the casting shovel. Neither of the writers speak of spring wheat, possibly because the preparation for it woidd not fit in with the rigid rules of open-field farming ; but both mention other varieties in the three com crops. Fitzherbert thinks that red wheat, sprot barley, and red oats are the best, and peck wheat, here barley, and rough oats the worst varieties. Mixed crops were popular, such as dredge, or barley and oats ; bolymong, or oats, pease, and vetches ; and wheat and rye. As to the mixed sowing of wheat and rye, the authors differ. Probably their respective experiences in Derbyshire and Suffolk diverged. Fitz- herbert advises that wheat and rye should be sown together, as the blend makes the safest crop and the best for the husbandman's household ; but he recommends that white wheat be chosen because it is the quickest to arrive at maturity.-' He was therefore no behever in the slowness of rye to ripen. Tusser, on the other hand, condemns the practice of sowing the two corns together because of the slow maturity of rye as compared with the relative rapidity of wheat. If they are to be blended, he says, let it be done by the miller. The seed was to be covered in as soon as possible. On the time-honoured question whether rooks are greater malefactors than benefactors, — ^whether they prefer grubs and worms to grain, — neither writer has any doubt. Both give their verdict against the bird, in the spirit of the legislation of their day.^ As soon as the com is in, says Fitzherbert, it should be harrowed, or " croues, doues, and other Byrdes wyll eate and beare away the comes." Tusser advises that girls should be armed with slings, and boys with bows, " to scare away pigeon, the rook, and the crow." Both writers urge the preparation of a fine tilth for barley, — ^in rural 'Heniy Best, writing a century later (1641), preferred "Kentish wheate ... or that which (hereabouts) is called Dodde-reade " {Farming Book, p. 46). • E.g. 24 Hen. Vm. o. 10; 8 Eliz. c. 16. 94 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH phrase " as fine as an ant-hill," — and advise that it should be rolled. Tusser recommends that wheat should also be roUed, if the land is sufficiently dry. For seeding, Fitzherbert adopts the mediaeval rule of two bushels of wheat and rye to the acre. All seeds were scattered broadcast by the hand from the hopper. Neither writer mentions the dibbing of beans, though that useful practice had been introduced by thirteenth century farmers. For barley, oats, and " cod ware," Fitzherbert recommends a thicker seeding than was practised in mediaeval farming. The best yield per acre is obtained from moderate or thin sowing. But it has been suggested that Elizabethan farmers more often allowed their land to become foul, and that crops were more thickly sown in the hope of saving them from being smothered. The suggestion is perhaps confirmed by the space which Fitzherbert devotes to weeds, and by his careful description of the most noxious plants. At harvest, wheat and rye were generally cut with the sickle, and barley and oats were mown with the scythe. Fitzherbert advises that com ricks should be built on scaffolds and not on the ground. In the eighteenth century the advice was still given and still imheeded. In their treatment of drainage and manure, neither author makes any advance on mediaeval practice. To prevent excessive wetness, both advise a water-furrow to be drawn across the ridges on the lowest part of the land ; but neither describes the shallow drains, filled with stones, and covered in with turf, which were familiar to farmers in the Middle Ages. Mole-heaps, if carefully spread, are not an unmixed evil. But when Tusser champions the mole as a useful drainer of wet pastures, it is evident that the science of draining was yet unborn. In choice of manure, neither writer appears to command the resources of his ancestors. The want of fertilising agencies was then, and may even now prove to be, one of the obstacles to small holdings. At the present day the small cultivator can, if he has money enough, buy chemical manures, and, unlike his Elizabethan ancestor, he no longer uses his straw or the dung of his cattle as fuel. But when chemical manures were unknown, it was imperatively necessary to employ all natural fertilisers. Fitzherbert does indeed deplore the disappearance of the practice of marling. ^ But Tusser does not mention the value 'Arthur Standish, writing in 1611, says that straw and dung were used as fuel {The Commons Complaint, p. 2), and Markham {Enrichment of the Weald of Kent) shows the antiquity of the practice of mturling by saying that trees of 200 or 300 years old may be seen in " innumerable " spent marl-pits. SHEEP ON OPEN-FIELD FARMS 95 of marl, lime, chaJk, soot, or town refuse, all of which were used in the Middle Ages, and it is doubtful whether mediaeval farmers followed his practice of rotting straw in pits filled with water, or of carting manure on to the land and leaving it in heaps for a month before it was spread or ploughed in. One new practice, and that a miserable one, is recommended. It is suggested that buck-wheat should be sown and ploughed in, in order to enrich the soil. Both Tusser and Fitzherbert advise that on open-field land the sheep should be folded from May to early in September. But Fitzherbert believed that folding fostered the scab. Among the practical advantages of enclosures which he urges is the opportunity that they afforded to farmers of dispensing with the common fold, saving the fees to the common shepherd and the cost of hurdles and stakes, and keeping their flocks in better health. June was the month for shearing. Fitzherbert recommends that sheep should be carefully washed before they were shorn, " the which shall be to the owner greate profyte " in the sale of his wool. Probably the modem farmer has found that his unwashed wool at a greater weight but a lower price is worth as much as his washed wool at less weight and a higher price. Fitzherbert considers sheep to be " the most profitable cattle that any man can have." But, until the introduction of turnips, the true value of sheep on arable land could not be realised. Hence the two branches of farming, which are now combined with advantage to both the sheep farmer and the corn-grower, were entirely dissevered. Until clover, artificial grasses, turnips, swedes, mangolds took their place among the ordinary crops for which arable land was cultivated, no farmer experienced the full truth of the saying that the foot of the sheep turns sand into gold. The practice of milking ewes still continued. Fitzherbert condemns it ; but Tusser, though he notices the injuri- ous results, weakens the effect of his warning by promising that five ewes will give as much milk as one cow. Neither Fitzherbert nor Tusser has anything to say on the improvement of breeds of cattle for the special purposes that they serve. The " general utility " animal was still their ideal. Yet the root of the matter is in Fitzherbert, when he says that a man cannot thrive by com unless he have live-stock, and that the man who tries to keep live- stock without com is either " a buyer, a borrower, or a beggar." If once the difficulty of winter keep could be solved, here was the secret of mixed husbandry realised, and the truth of the maxim 96 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH verified that a full buUock yard makes a full stack-yard. On horses and horse-dealing Fitzherbert is fuU of shrewdness. He defines the horse-master, the " corser " and the " horse leche." " And whan these three be mette," he dryly observes, " if yeh adde a poty-carye to make the fourthe, ye myghte have suche foure, that it were harde to truste the best of them." The times at which Fitzherbert and Tusser respectively wrote give special interest to their championship of enclosures. As has been already noticed, both wrote when the agitation against the progress of the movement was at its height, and Tusser was familiar with the eastern counties at the moment of Kett's insurrection in Norfolk. As practical farmers both writers insist on the evils of the open- field system ; but it fell within the province of neither to criticise the tyrannical proceedings by which those evils were often remedied. They rather dwell on the superior yield of enclosed lands,i and on the obstacles to successful farming presented by open-fields — the perpetual disputes, the damage to crops, the waste of land by the multitude of drift-ways, the cost of swineherds, cowherds, and shepherds who were employed as human fences to the com and meadows. Incidentally also they reveal many practical difficulties of the open-field farmer in ploughing and draining. During the winter months, he was obhged to bring his hve-stock in sooner, keep them longer, and feed them at greater cost, than his neighbour on enclosed land. For winter keep, when his hay and straw were running out, he had nothing to rely on but " browse " or tree- loppings. In rearing live-stock he was heavily handicapped. Unless he had pasture of his own, he was forced to time his lambs to fall towards the middle of March. Hence the proverb : " At St. Luke's day (Oct. 18, Greg. Cal.) Let tup have play." Thus he risked losing lambs because the common shepherd had too much on his hands at once ; his lambs lost a month on the meadow before it was put up for hay ; and the owner missed the profits of an early sale at Helenmas (May 21), and had to sell, if he sold at all, at the same time as all other open-field farmers. The same restrictions hampered him in rearing calves. He could not afford to keep the cow and calf in the winter ; therefore he was obliged to time the calf to come after Candlemas. These and other disadvantages convinced practical agriculturists 1 See ch. iii. pp. 65-66. AGRICULTUEAL ADVANTAGES OF ENCLOSURES 97 of the inferiority of the open-field system. Experience waa in favour of enclosures. Fitzherbert points to the prosperity of Essex as an example of the advantage of enclosures. The author of the Compendious or Briefe Examination says that " the countries where most enclosures be are most wealthie, as Essex, Kent, Deven- shire." So also Tusser compares " champion " (open) counties, like Norfolk and Cambridgeshire, with " enclosed " counties, like Essex and Suffolk and says that the latter have " More plenty of mutton and biefe. Come, butter, and cheese of the best. More wealth anywhere, to be briefe. More people, more handsome and prest. ..." The proverbial expression " Suffolk stiles " seems to point to the early extinction of open-fields. Norden in his Essex Described^ (1594) calls the county the " Englishe Goshen, the fattest of the Lande ; comparable to Palestina, that flowed with milke and hunnye." So " manie and sweete " were the " commodeties " of Essex, that they compensated for the "moste oruell quarteme fever " which he caught among its low-lying lands. Every practical argu- ment that could be pleaded against open-field farms in the days of Henry VLLl. or Elizabeth might be urged against the system with treble force from the end of the eighteenth century onwards, when farming had grown more scientific, when new crops had been introduced, when drainage had been reduced to a science, and when, under the pressure of a rapidly increasing population, farms were becoming factories of bread and meat. Enclosures undoubtedly assisted farming progress. Before the end of the reign the effect of the movement, combined with increased facilities of communication, is distinctly visible. Under the spur which individual occupation and better markets gave to enter- prise, " the soil," as Harrison says, " had growne to be more fruitful, and the countryman more painful, more careful, and more skilful for recompense of gain." Increased attention was paid to manuring. In Cornwall, farmers rode many miles for sand and brought it home on horseback ; sea-weed was extensively used in South Wales ; in Sussex, lime was fetched from a distance at heavy expense ; in Hertfordshire, the sweepings of the streets were bought up for use on the land. The yield of com per acre was rising. On the well-tilled and dressed acre, we are told that wheat now averaged 1 Camden Society (1840), p. 7. G 98 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH twenty bushels, and that barley sometimes rose to thirty-two bushels, and oats and beans to forty bushels. The improvement of pastures is shown in the increased size and weight of Uve-stock. The average dead weight of sheep and cattle in 1500 probably did not exceed 28 lbs. and 320 lbs. respectively. At the beginning of the seventeenth century the dead weight of the oxen and sheep supplied to the Prince of Wales's household was no doubt excep- tional ; but the difference is considerable. " An ox should weigh 600 lbs. the four quarters ... a mutton should weigh 46 lbs. or 44 lbs." A new incentive to improvement in arable farming and stock- rearing was supplied by the lower price of wool, consequent partly on over-production, partly on deterioration in quality. This deterioration was in some cases the result of enclosures. The wool was sacrificed to the mutton, and the demand for butcher's meat was not yet sufficient to make the sacrifice profitable. When English wool first came into the Flemish market, it was distinguished for its fineness, and sold at a higher rate than its Spanish rival. It was indispensable for the foreign weaver. The best fleeces were those of the Ryeland or Herefordshire sheep, for which Leominster was the principal market. In the days of Skelton, El3^our Bum- mynge, ale-wife of Leatherhead, had no enviable reputation ; but when her customers made a payment in kind, she was a shrewd judge of its value : " Some fill their pot full Of good Lemster Wool." Drayton's Dowsabel had a " skin as soft as Lemster wool." Rabe- lais makes Panurge cheapen the flock of Ding-dong ; and when the latter descants upon the fineness of their wool, the English translator (Motteux, 1717) compares them to the quality of " Lemynster wool." From the preamble to a statute of the reign of James I. (4 Jac. I. c. 2.) it would seem that Ryeland flocks were cotted all the year. The second price was fetched by Cotswold wool. The sheep that are kept on downs, heaths and commons produce the finest, though not the heaviest, fleeces. It was the experience of Virgil : " Si tibi lanicium curae, . . . fuge pabula laeta." In the same sense wrote Dyer : " On spacious airy downs, and gentle hills, With grass and thyme o'erspread, and clover wild, The faiiest flocks rejoice ! " BARNABY GOOGE 99 As the commons and wastes of England began to be extensively enclosed, the quality of the fleece deteriorated. Heavier animals — better suited to fat enclosed pastures, and producing coarser wool — were introduced. English wool lost its pre-eminence abroad ; and, though still commanding high prices, was no longer indispensable for foreign weavers. The loss was to a great extent counterbalanced by increased consumption at home. But, at the time, the decrease in value was at least as influential in checking the conversion of arable land to pasture as were Acts of Parliament. Open-field farms were not as yet such obstacles to agricultural progress as they became after the discovery of new resources and new rotations of crops which could only be utilised to fuU advantage on enclosed lands. But already these new sources of wealth were in sight. The great difficulties in the way of mediaeval and Tudor farmers were want of winter keep and lack of means to maintain or restore the fertility of exhausted soils. In the agricultural literature of Elizabeth the remedy for both is dimly suggested. In 1577 appeared Foure Bookea of Hvsbandry^ to which Bamaby Googe, a better poet than Tusser, gave his name. The work was a translation of Heresbach, with 16 additional pages by the translator. Googe mentions Fitzherbert or Tusser as writers worthy to be ranked with " Yarro, Columella, and PaUadius of Home " ; advises agriculturists to read " Maister Bicynolde Scot's booke of Hoppe Gardens " ; and quotes an imposing list of " Aucthors and Hus- bandes whose aucthorities and observations are used in this book." By this reference he does not necessarily mean that all the men whose names he mentions had written books on farming, but rather that he had consulted those who were reputed to be most skilful in its practice. In other words, there were already agriculturists, like "Capt. Byngham," "John Somer," "Richard Deeryng." " Henry Denys," or " WiUiam Pratte," whose methods were an object lesson to their less advanced neighbours. Googe's book has been despised because it was " made in Germany." But in this fact Hes its chief value. The farming of the Low Countries was better than the farming of England, and Googe gives English agri- culturists the benefit of foreign experience. He is the first writer to mention a reaping machine—" a lowe kinde of carre with a couple of wheeles and the frunt armed with sharpe syckles, whiche, ^ Foure Bookea of Htubandry, collected by M. Conradus Hereabcushius Newely Englished and increased by Bamabe Googe Esquire, London, 1677. 100 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH forced by the beaste through the come, did cut down al before it." He iosists on the extreme importance of manure, and the value of marl, chalk, and ashes. But he does not consider that farmers can thrive by manure alone. On the contrary, he thioks that " the best doung for ground is the Maister's foot, and the best provender for the house the Maister's eye." He also gives a caution against the persistent use of chalk, because, ia the end, it " brings the grounde to be Starke nought, whereby the common people have a speache, that grounde enriched with chalke makes a riche father and a b^gerly sonne." He mentions the use of rape in the Principality of Qeves, a valuable suggestion whether for green-manuring, for the oil in its seeds, or for use as fodder for sheep. He commends " Trefoil or Burgundian grass," which he believes to be of Moorish origin and Spanish introduction, for " there can be no better fodder devised for cattell." He says that turnips have been found in the Low Countries to be good for live-stock, and that, if sown at Mid- summer, they win be ready for winter food. In English gardens turnips were already known. They appear under the name of " tnmepez " among " Rotys for a gardyn " in a fifteenth century book of cookery recipes ; Andrew Borde ^ (1542) recommends them " boyled and eaten with fiesshe " ; William Turner, the herbalist, mentions that " the great round rape called a tumepe groweth in very great plenty in all Germany and more about London then in any other place of England " : Tusser classes them among " roots to boil and to butter " ; but Googe, though only as a translator, was the first writer to suggest that field cultivation of turnips which revolutionised English farming. Another Elizabethan writer makes the first attempt to combine science with practice. Sir Hugh Plat was an ingenious inventor, and, as Sir Richard Weston calls him, " the most curious man of his time." He devotes the second part of his Jewell House of Art and Nature (1694) to the scientific manuring of arable and pasture land. ManTU« presents itself to his poetic mind as a Goddess with a Cornucopia in her hand. If land, he says, is perpetually cropped, the earth is robbed of her vegetative salt, and ceases to bear. The object, therefore, of the wise husbandman must be to restore this essential element of fertility. His list of manurial substances is long. He recommends not only farm-yard dung, but marl, lime, street refuse, the subsoil of ponds and " watrie bottomes," salt, 1 Dyetary, oh. xix. Sm HUGH PLAT 101 ashes from the boming of stubble, weeds, and bracken ; the hair of beasts, malt dust, soap-ashes, putrified pilchards, garbage of fish, blood offal and the entrails of animals. He warns farmers of the difficulty in discovBring the right proportion of marl to lay on different sorts of soil. He condemns the waste of the richest properties of farm-yard manure, and recommends the use of covers to all pits used for its accumulation. He himself used a bam roof at his farm at St. Albans, which moved up and down on upright supports, so that the muck-heap could be raised, yet always remain under cover. In his Arte of setting of Come (1600) he advocates dibbing as superior to broadcast sowing. He traces the origin of the practice to the accident of a silly wench, who deposited some seeds of wheat in holes intended for carrots. He goes so far as to say that, by dibbing, the average yield of wheat per acre would be raised from 4 quarters to 15 quarters ! The growth of an agricultural literature, as well as Googe's list of notable authorities, suggest that landowners were beginning to interest themselves in com and cattle. Probably their taste for farming was encouraged by the fashionable love for horticulture. In the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries both had declined : in the Tudor age both revived. The garden was the precursor of the home-farm. In the reign of Elizabeth, gardening became one of the pursuits and pleasures of English country life. The art was loved by Bacon ; it was patronised by Burghley and Walsingham ; it gathered round it a rich Uterature ; it claimed the services of explorers and builders of Empire like Sir Walter Baleigh. Tudor architects used pleasure gardens to carry on and support the lines of their main buildings, and even repeated the patterns of their mural decorations in the geometrical " Knots " of their flower borders ; but they banished kitchen gardens out of sight. The cultivation of vegetables made less progress than that of flowers and fruits. This useful side of horticulture, like farming, was as yet comparatively neglected by the Tudor gentry. But an advance was made. The first step was to recover lost ground. In order to flatter Elizabeth, Harrison probably exaggerated the disuse of vegetables before the accession of her father. He over-states his case when he says that garden-produce, which before was treated as fit for hogs and savage beasts, now supplied not only food for the " poore commons " but " daintie dishes at the tables of delicate merchants, gentlemen, and the nobiUtie." It was doubtless true 102 THE REIGN OF ELIZABETH that the art of gardening, like that of farming, had declined during the period which preceded Tudor times. Yet in the decadent fifteenth century, rape, carrots, parsnips, turnips, cabbages, leeks, onions, garlic, as well as numerous " Herbes for Potage," and " Herbes for a salade " appeared in a book on gardens,^ or in the recipes of cookery books. On the other hajid, it is said that, in the reign of Henry Vlll., Queen Catherine was provided with salads from Flanders, because none could be furnished at home, and that onions and cabbages, known in the reign of Henry IH. and praised by Piers Plowman, were in the first part of the fifteenth century imported from the Low Cbuntiies. Now, however, in the reign of Henry Vlil. and onwards, gardening, as Fuller says, began to creep out of Holland into England. In Shakespeare's day, it may be remembered that potatoes ^ as yet only " rained from the sky " and that Anne Page would rather " be set quick i' the earth. And bowled to death with turnips," than marry the wrong man. Sandwich became famous for its carrots, and in the neighbourhood of Fulham, and along the Suffolk coast, gardens were laid out in which vegetables were extensively cultivated. In rich men's gardens potatoes found a place after 1585, though for some years to come, they were regarded, and sold, as luxuries. Here then were accumulating new sources of future advance in farming. Yet progress must have been slow. Robert ChUd, writing anonymously on the " Deficiencies " of agriculture in 1651,' says : " Some old men in Surrey, where it (the Art of Gardenivg) flourisheth very much at present, report, That they knew the first Gardinera that came into those parts, to plant Cab- ages, CcXUfiowers, and to sowe Tumepa, Garrets, and Parsnvpa, and to sowe Baith [early] Pease, all of which at that time were great rarities, we having few, or none in England, but what came from Holland and Flaunders." He goes on to say that he could name '' places, both in the North and West of England, where the name of Gardening and Hawing is scarcely knowne, in which places a few Gardiners might have saved the lives of many poor people, who have starved these dear years." •■ The Feate of Gardenimge, by Mayster Ion Gardener, printed in Archaeologia, vol. liv., with a glossary by 'iSia. Evelyn Cecil. ' Merry Wivea of Windsor, Act. v. So. 6 and Act iii. So. 4. ^Hartlib's i^octe (1661), pp. 11-12. PROMISE OF PROGRESS 103 CHAPTER V. FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION (1603-1660). FARMING UNDER THE FIRST STEWARTS AND THE COMMONWEALTH. Promise of agricultural progress checked by the Civil War : agricultural writers and their suggestions : Sir Richard Weston on turnips and clover : conservatism of English farmers ; their dislike to book-fanning not un- reasonable : unexhausted improvements discussed ; Walter Blith on drainage : attempts to drain the fens in the eastern counties ; the resist- ance of the femnen : new views on commons : Winstanley's claims : enclosures advocated as a step towards agricultural improvement. The beginning of the seventeenth centuiy promised to usher in a new era of agricultural prosperity. During the first four decades of the period prospects steadily brightened. No general improve- ment in farming practices had been possible until a considerable area of land had been enclosed in one or other of the various forms which enclosures might assume. Under the Tudor sovereigns — ^in the midst of much agrarian suffering and discontent — this indispensable work had been begun, and it continued throughout the seventeenth century. Estates were consoUdated ; small farms were thrown together ; open village farms in considerable numbers gave place to compact and separate freeholds or tenancies ; agrarian partner- ships, in which it was no man's interest to be energetic, made way, here and there, for that individual occupation which offered the strongest incentive to enterprise. Thus opportunities were afforded for the introduction of new crops, the application of land to its best use, and the adoption of improved methods. Dairying was extended in the vales of the West and South West ; com and meat found better and dearer markets ; under the spur of increased profits arable farming again prospered, and the conversion of tillage to pasture was arrested. New materials for agricultural wealth were accumulating ; turnips, already grown in English gardens, were 104 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION lecommended for field cultivation ; twenty years later, potatoes were suggested as a farming crop ; the value of clover and other artificial grasses had been recognised, and urged upon English farmers. Methods became less barbarous. An Act of Parliament was passed " agaynst plowynge by the ta,ile," and the custom of " pulling off the wool yearly from living sheep " was declared illegal. Drainage was discussed with a sense and sagacity which were not rivalled till the nineteenth century. Increased care was given to manuring ; new fertilising agencies were suggested ; the merits of Peruvian guano were explained by G. de la Vega at Lisbon in 1602 ; the use of valuable substances, known to our ancestors but discou; tinned, was revived. Attention was paid to the improvement of agricultural implements. Patents were taken out for draining machines (Burrell, 1628) ; for new manures (1636) ; for improved courses of husbandry (Chiver, 1637 and 1640) ; for ploughs (Hamil- ton, 1623 ; Brouncker, 1627 ; Parham, 1634) ; for instruments for mechanical sowing (Ramsey, 1634, and Plattes, 1639). On all sides new energies seemed to be aroused. Much of the land had changed hands during the preceding cen- tury, and the infusion of new blood into the ownership of the soil introduced a more enterprising and business-like spiirit into f armiog. The increased wealth of landowners showed itself in the erection of Jacobean mansions ; farmer owners, tenant-farmers for Uves or long terms of years, copyholders at fixed 4uit-rents, made money. Only the agricultiu-al labourer still suffered. His wages rose more slowly than the prices of the necessaries of life ; his hold on the land was relaxing ; his dependence upon his labour-power became more complete. He was more secure of employment ; but in this respect alone was his lot altered for the better. The promise of improvement was checked by the outbreak of the Civil War. Excepting those who were directly engaged in the struggle, men seemed to follow their ordinary business and their accustomed pursuits. The story that a crowd of country gentle- men followed the hounds across Marston Moor between the two armies drawn up in hostile array, may not be true ; but it illustrates the temper of a large proportion of the inhabitants. It was the prevailing sense of insecurity, rather than the actual absorption of the whole population in the war, that caused the promise of agri- cultural progress to perish in the bud. In more settled times under the Commonwealth, fanning prospects again brightened. But POUnCS SUSPEND PROGRESS 105 practical progress was once more suspended by the social changes and political uncertainties of the last half of the seventeenth century. Agriculture languished, if it did not actually decline. It is a significant fact that between 1640 and 1670 not more than six patents were taken out for agricultural improvements. Country gentlemen ceased to interest themselves in farming pursuits. " Our gentry," notes Pepys, " are grown ignorant in everything of good husbandry." Without their initiative progress was almost im- possible. Open-field farmers could not change their fifild-customs without the consent of the whole body of partners. Farmers in individual occupation of their holdings had not, as a general rule, the enterprise, the education, the capital, or the security of tenure, to conduct experiments or adopt improvements. But the period was one of active preparation. A crowd of agricultural writers followed in the train of Fitzherbert, Tusser, and Googe. Leonard Mascall in his Booke of CatteU (1591) had instructed husbandmen in the more skilful " government " of horses, oxen, cattle, and sheep. Gervase Markham wrote on every variety of agricultural subjects, multiplying his treatises under different titles with a rapidity which gained for him the distinction of being the " first English hackwriter," and proved that books on farming found a' sale.^ Horses were made the subject of special treatment. Blundeville's Power chiefyat offices belonging to Horae- manahippe (1565-6) was followed by such books as Markham's Diacourae on Horaemanahippe (1593) and How to Ghuae, Bide, Trayne, ^ As an agricultural writer, Markham's reputation was doubtful, in spite of the many editions which were published of his works. In Hartlib's Ltgade (1661) B. Child in his " Large Letter " had spoken of the want of a complete book on English husbandry. On this a critic had remarked " England hath a perfect systeme of Husbandry, viz. Markham." The author replies (Legcusie, 3rd edition, 1655) : " He speaketh more of Markham than ever I heard before, or as yet have seen. In general he is accounted Uttle more than a Translator, unless about Cattle, and yet I cannot but in that question his skill. . . . The works which I have seen of his are, first, the great book translated out of French " (The Cowntry Farm, 1616, a revision of Surflet's translation of the Maiaon Ruatigue, with additions from foreign writers), " which whether well or ill done, I will not declare ; but I am sure our Hus- bcmdmen in England profit little by it. Secondly I have seen five several bookes bound up together, two or three of which he acknowledgeth to be anothers, as The Improvement of the Wild of Kent, also his Houawifery he acknowledgeth to have had from a Countess, also part of his Farewell is borrowed, and what he owneth, if I have seen all, are very short in many particulars. . . . Yea, if I understand any thing, he setteth down many gross untruths, which every Countryman will contradict." He quotes instances, cmd concludes " he hath done well in divers things, and is to be commended for his industry." 106 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION and Dyet both Hunting and Sunning Horses (1599), by Grymes's Honest and Plaine Dealing Farrier (1636), and by John Crawshey's Cowatryman's Instructor (1636). Then, as now, horsedealing was a trial of the sharpest wits, blunted by the fewest scruples. Crawshey, who describes himself as a " plaine Yorkshire man," warns his readers against being deceived when buying horses in the market, " for many men will protest and swear e that they are sound when they know the contrary, onely for their private gaine." Where so much is strange in farming matters, it is refreshing to find familiar features. The proper treatment of woodlands was discussed by Staudish (1611). Rowland Vaughan (1610), struck by the sight of a streamlet issuing from a mole-heap in a bank, discussed new methods of irrigation, or " the summer and winter drowning " of meadows and pasture. Even the smaller profits of farming received attention. Numerous books were published on orchards, and on gardens, in which were now accumulating such future stores of agricultural riches as turnips, carrots, and potatoes. Mascall in 1581 had written on the " husbandlye Ordring of Poultry " ; Sir Hugh Plat had instructed housewives in the art of fattening fowls for the table ; and John Partridge published a treatise on the same subjects, in which he gives recipes for keeping their natural foes at bay. The following may be recommended to Hunt Secretaries, who are impoverished by demands on their poultry fimds. " Rub your poultry," says Partridge, " with the juice of Rue or Herbe grasse and the wesels shall do them no hurt ; if they eate the lungs or lights of a Foxe, the Foxes shall not eate them." Nor were bees neglected. Thomas Hill (1568), and Edmund Southeme (1593) had written on the " right ordering " of bees. But Charles Butler's Feminine Monarchie (1609), and John Levett's Orderinge of Bees (1634) became the standard authorities on the subject. Both books were known to Robert Child, author of the Large Letter on the deficiencies of English husbandry, published by Hartlib in 1651 .^ He says that Butler " hath written so exactly, and upon his owne experience " that little remained to be added. Henry Best (1641),* however, preferred Levett to any other writer on bee-keeping. " Hee is the best," he thinks, " that ever writte of this subjeckt." During the same period men like Gabriel Plattes or Sir Richard 1 HartUb's Z/egaeie, p. 64. Bobert Child in the 1651 edition speaks of Levett as " Leveret." * Farming Book, p. 68. SIR RICaaARD WESTON 107 Weston were suggesting new agricultural methods, or introducing new crops which were destined to change the face of English farm- ing. Plattes (1638), who seems to have been of Flemish origin, urged that com should be steeped before sowing, and not sown broadcast but set in regular rows. To those who adopted the sug- gestion of the " com setter," he promised a yield of a hundred-fold, and he invented a drill to facilitate and cheapen the process. Plattes was on the verge of a great improvement. But men who looked for no larger return than six-fold or eight-fold on the grain sown, regarded his promise as the dream of a visionary who had not travelled beyond the sound of Bow Bells. Unfortunately, the career of Plattes confirmed the contempt with which practical farmers were ready to regard the theories of agricultural writers. Like Tusser, he failed in farming. As Tusser died (1580) in the debtor's prison of the Poultry Compter, so Plattes is said to have died starving and shirtless in the streets of London.^ Sir Richard Weston could at least lay claim to thirty years experience in the successful improvement of his estates at Sutton in Surrey " by Fire and Water." He had enriched his heathy land by the process of paring and burning, " which wee call Devon- shiring " ; he had also adopted Vaughan's suggestion of irrigation, and proved its value on his own meadows. But the important change with which Weston's name wiU always be associated is the introduction of a new rotation of crops, founded on the field cultiva- tion of roots and clover. As Brillat-Savarin valued a new dish above a new star, so Arthur Young regards Weston as " a greater ben^actor than Newton." He did indeed offer bread and meat to millions. Whether Weston had visited Flanders before 1644 is uncertain. His attempt to make the Wey navigable by means of locks suggests that he was acquainted with the foreign system of canals. On the other hand, his treatise on agriculture implies that he paid his first visit to the country in that year as a refugee. A Royalist and a Catholic, Weston, at the outbreak of the Civil War, was driven into exile, and his estates were sequestrated. He took refuge in Flanders. There he studied the Flemish methods of agriculture, especially their use of flax, clover, and turnips. For the field cultivation of clover he advises that heathy ground should be pared, burned, limed, and well ploughed and harrowed ; that the seed should be sown in April, or the end of March, at the rate 1 Hortlib's Legacie (Srd edition, 1656), p. 183. 108 PROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION of ten pounds of seed to the acre ; that, once sown, the crop should be left for five years. The results of his observations, embodied in his Discours of the Husbandrie used in Brabant and Flanders, were written in 1645 and left to his sons as a " Legacie." The subse- quent history of the " Legacie " is curious. Circulated in manu- script, an imperfect copy fell into the hands of Samuel Hartlib, who piratically published it in 1650, with an unctuous dedication " to the Right Honorable the Council of State." In the following year HartUb seems to have learned the name of the author and to have obtained possession of a more perfect copy. He therefore wrote two letters to Weston, asking him to correct and enlarge his " Discourse." Receiving no answer, he republished the treatise in 1651. Eighteen years later, the Discours was again appropriated — this time by Gabriel Reeve, who, in 1670, reprinted it under the title of Directions left by a OenUeman to his Sons for the Improve- ment of Barren and Heathy Land in England and Wales. Roots, clover, and artificial grasses subsequently revolutionised English farming ; but it was more than a centiuy before their use became at all general. Other crops were pressed by agricultural writers upon the attention of farmers — such as flax, hemp, hops, woad and madder for dyes, saffron, liquorice, rape, and coleseed. A more important suggestion was the field cultivation of potatoes, which hitherto had been treated as exotics, rarely found except in the gardens of the rich. In 1664 John Forster ^ urged farmers to grow them in their fields. He distinguishes " Irish Potatoes " from Spanish, Canadian, or Virginian varieties, points to their success in Ireland, notices their introduction into Wales and the North of England, and recommends their trial in other parts of the country. It was not till the Napoleonic wars that the advice was taken to any general extent. None of these crops, it may be observed, could be introduced on an open-field farm, imless the whole body of agrarian partners agreed to alter their field customs. Another noteworthy book is the Legacie (1651), which passes under the name of Samuel HartUb, who has gained undeserved credit by his piracy of Weston's work. By birth a Pole, Hartlib had come to England in 1628. By his Beformation of Schooles (1642), trans- lated from Comenius, he forced himself on the notice of Milton, who in 1644 curtly addressed to biTn his Tract Of Education. From. Weston's Discours, Hartlib stole the title of the Legacie (1651), com- 1 Englcmd'e Happinets Increaeed, etc., by John Forster Gent. 1664. FARMING DEFICIENCIES 109 posed of letters from various writers on the defects of English agriculture, and their remedies. Five-sixths of the Legacie are taken up with " A Large Letter . . . written to M. Samuel HartUb," signed (1655), by B. Child. It throws a clear Ught on some of the conditions of English farming in the middle of the seventeenth century. In the " Large Letter " the cumbrousness of the English ploughs, carts, and waggons is noticed. Clumsy implements and bad prac- tices were said to exist side by side with obvious improvements, which yet foimd no imitators. Some Kentish farmers used " 4, 6, yea 12 horses and oxen " in their ploughs, and in Ireland farmers fastened their horses by the tails. Yet in Norfolk the practice was to plough with two horses only, while in Kent itself, a certain Colonel Blunt of Gravesend ploughed with one horse, and an ingeni- ous yeoman had invented a double-furrow plough. Men who perplexed their brains about perpetual motion would, says the writer, have used their ingenuity to more effect it they had tried to improve the implements of agriculture. Cattle-breeding, except " in Lancashire and some few Northern Counties " was not studisd ; no attempt was made to improve the best breeds for milking or for fattening. Dairying needed attention ; butter might be " better sented and tasted " ; our cheeses were inferior to those of Italy, France, or Holland.^ Various remedies against the prevalence of smut and mildew in wheat are suggested, including hme, change of seed, early sowing, and the use of bearded wheat. Flax and hemp were unduly neglected, though both might be grown, it is sug- gested, with profit to agriculturists, and to the great increase of employment ; as a remedy against this persistent neglect, the author advocates compulsory legislation, to force farmers, " even like brutes, to understand their own good." Twenty-one natural substances are recommended as manures, the value of which had been proved by experience. Among them are chalk, marl, lime, farm-yard dung, if it is not too much exposed to the sun and rain ; " snaggreet," or soil full of small sheUs taken out of rivers, and much used in Surrey ; owse, from marshy ditches or foreshores ; seaweed ; sea-sand, as used in Cornwall ; " folding of sheepe after 1 This also had been the opinion of Googe, who places the Parmesan cheese of Italy fiist. Then follow, in order of merit, the cheeses of Holland, Nor- mandy, and lastly, of England. Among English cheeses the best came from Cheshire, Shropshire, Banbury, Suffolk, and Essex. " The very worste " is " the Kentish cheese." 110 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION the Maunders maimer, (viz.) mider a covert, in which earth is strawed about 6 inches thick " ; ashes, soot, pigeons' dung, msElt-dust, blood, shavings of horn, woollen rags as used in Hertfordshire, Oxfordshire, and Kent. It need scarcely be pointed out that for none of these fertilisers was the agriculturist indebted to chemistry, and that no attempt was as yet made to restore to the soil the special properties of which it is impoverished by par- ticular crops. To meadows and pasture no attention was paid ; mole-heaps and ant-hills were not spread and levelled ; in laying down land to graze, little care was taken to sow the best and sweetest grasses. Clover, sainfoin, and lucerne were generally ignored. The practice of " aoiling," that is, of cutting clover green as fodder for cattle, is, however, commended. Large tracts of land were allowed to lie waste, so " that there are more waste lands in England than in all Europe besides, considering the quantity of land." Among the waste lands he includes " dry heathy commons." " I know," he adds, " that poore people wiU cry out against me because I call these waste lands : but it's no matter." The destruction of woods for fuel is condemned. For this con- sumption the glass furnaces of the South, the salt " wiches " of Cheshire, and, above aU, the iron-works of Surrey, Sussex, and other counties, were responsible. The writer probably alludes to " Dud " Dudley's experiments, when he expresses the hope that the difficulties of using " sea-coal " for the smelting of iron might be overcome so as to save our timber. Experiments were not sufficiently tried, and a " Colledge of Experiments," already recom- mended by Gabriel Plattes, is once more suggested. Men do not know where to go if they want advice, or to obtain reliable seeds and plants. Some means was needed of bringing home to other husbandmen a knowledge of the improvements made by their more skilful brethren. Another deficiency in English husbandry was its insular repugnance to foreign methods and new-fangled crops. Men objected that the new seeds " will not grow here with us, for our forefathers never used them. To these I reply and ask them, how they know ? have they tryed ? Idlenesse never wants an excuse ; and why might not our forefathers upon the same ground have held their hands in their pockets, and have said, that Wheat, and Barley, would not have grown amongst us ? " The same com- plaint, it may be added, is made by Walter Blith in The English Improver Improved : " The fourth and last abuse is a calumniating EXAGGERATED PROMISES OF " RUSTICK AUTHORS " 111 and depraving every new Invention ; of this most culpable are your mouldy old leavened husbandmen, who themselves and their fore- fathers have been accustomed to such a course of husbandry as they will practise, and no other ; their resolution is so fixed, no issues or events whatsoever shall change them. If their neighbour hath as much com of one Acre as they of two upon the same land, or if another plow the same land for strength and nature with two horses and one man as well as he, and have as good com, as he hath been used with four horses and two men yet so he will continue. Or if an Improvement be discovered to him and all his neighbours, hee'l oppose it and degrade it. What forsooth saith he, who taught you more wit than your forefathers ? " Seventeenth century farmers did not lack descendants in later generations. It took a heavy hammer and many blows to drive a nail through heart of oak. It would be unjust to lay on agriculturists the whole blame for neglect of improvements. Much deserves to rest on the agri- cultural writers themselves. Their promises were often exaggerated beyond the bounds of beUef ; mixed with some useful suggestions were others which were either ridiculous or of doubtful value. Men actually and practically engaged in cultivating the soil were, there- fore, justified in some distrust of book-farmers. Turnips were undoubtedly an invaluable addition to agricultural resources. But it was an exaggeration to say with Adolphus Speed ^ that they were the only food for cattle, swine, and poultry, sovereign for con- ditioning " Hunting dogs," an admirable ingredient for bread, affording " two very good crops " each year, supplying " very good Syder " and " exceeding good Oyl." Nor was confidence in Speed's advice on other topics likely to be inspired by his promise that land, rented at £200 a year, might be made to realise a net annual profit of £2000 by keeping rabbits. Similarly the remedy which is sug- gested in Hartlib's Legacie (3rd edition, 1655) " against the Rot, and other diseases in Sheep and Horses " is enough to cast suspicion on the whole book : " Take Serpents or (which is better) Vipers," advises the writer, " cut their heads and tayls off and dry the rest to powder. Mingle this powder with salt, and give a few grains of it so mingled now and then to your Horses and Sheep." Other suggested remedies are, at least, more easy of appUcation. " The colicke or pain in the belly (in oxen) is put away in the beholding of geese in the water, specially duckes." If a horse sickens from * Adam out of Eden (1659). 112 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION some mysterious ailment, " a piece of fern-root placed under his tongue will make hini immediately voyde, upward and downward, whatsoever is in his body, and presently amende." Again, neither silkworms nor vineyards, though both are favourites with the Stewart theorists, commend themselves strongly as a safe livelihood to practical men whiT farmed under an English climate. Nor was it possible to take seriously the proposed introduction of " Black Foxes, Miiske-cats, Sables, Marlines," etc., suggested by Robert Child, the author of the principal tract in the Legaeie, as an addition to the agricultural wealth of the country. He adds to his list " the Elephant, the greatest, wisest, and longest-Uved of all beasts . . . very serviceable for carriage (15 men usually riding on his backe together)." It would have added variety to English rural life to see the partners in a village farm conveyed to their holdings on the back of a co-operative elephant, and dropping oS as they arrived at their respective strips. But it is doubtful whether they would have found their four-footed omnibus " not chargeable to keepe." Literary and experimental agricultiu:istB naturally gained a reputation similar to that of quack medicine vendors. In practice they often failed. Like ancient alchemists, they starved in the midst of their golden dreams. Tusser, teaching thrift, never throve. Gabriel Plattes, the corn setter, died for want of bread. Donald- son, the author of the first Scottish agricultural treatise, admits that he took to writing books because he could not succeed on the land. Even Arthur Young failed twice in farm management before he began his invaluable tours. In the " Large Letter " on the defects of English farming, and their remedies, from which quotations have been already made, Child also notices the amount of land that lay waste from want of drainage. This was one of the crying needs of agriculture. Without extensive drainage, the introduction of new crops and improved practices was impossible. With the hour comes the man. The necessity and methods of drainage were ably discussed by Walter Blith. Writing as " a lover of Ingenuity," he published his English Improver in 1649. His treatise, interlarded with biblical quotations, was the first which dealt with draining. As the Puritans of the day sought Scriptural authority for their political constitu- tion, so the Puritan farmer justifies his advocacy of drainage by references to the Bible. " Oan the rush," he asks with Bildad, " grow without mire or the flagg without water ? " In other ways WALTER BLITH 113 also Blith's work is significant of the era of the Civil War. He himself beat his ploughshare into a sword, became a captain in the Bomidhead army, dedicated his second edition mider the title of The English Improver Impraoed (1652) " to the Right Honourable the Lord Generall Cromwell," adorns it with a portrait of himseK arrayed in fuU mihtary costume, and adds the legend ' Vive La Re Pvblick: Among the remedies which Bhth suggests for the defects of English farming, he urges the employment of more capital ; enclosures, with due regard to cottiers and labourers ; the aboUtion of " slavish customs " ; the removal of water-mills ; the extinction of " vermine " ; the recognition of tenant-right. It is an indica- tion of agricultural progress that the question of tenants' improve- ments should be thus forcing itself to the front. Sir Richard Weston in his Discours called attention to the Flemish custom, unknown to HiTn in England, of " taking a Farm upon Improvement." In Flanders leases for twenty-one years were taken on condition that " whatsoever four indifEerent persons (whereof two to bee chosen by the one, and two by the other) should judg the Farm to bee improved at the end of his Leas, the Oivner was to paie so much in value to the Tenant for his improving it." In the Preface to his Legacie, Hartlib had imitated Weston in urging the adoption of this custom in England. BUth, who also quotes the Flemish lease with approval, points out the injustice of the English law and the hindrance to all improvements which it created. " If," he sajra, " a Tenant be at never so great paines or cost for the improvement of his Land, he doth thereby but occasion a greater Rack upon him- self, or else invests his Land-Lord into his cost and labour gratia, or at best lies at his Land-Lord's mercy for requitall ; which occasions a neglect of all good Husbandry. . . . Now this I humble conceive may be removed, if there were a Law Inacted, by which every Land-Lord should be obliged, either to give biin reasonable allowance for his clear Improvement, or else sufier him or his to enjoy it so much longer as till he hath had a proportionable requitall." The question had not yet become acute ; but, with the insecurity of tenure which then prevailed, it was not surprising that tenant-f aimers were averse to improvements. Their experi- ence was embodied in the proverbial saying current in Berkshire : " He that havocs may sit He that improves must flit." H 114 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION The same experience inspired the popular saying prevalent in the Lowlands of Scotland. Donaldscm, in his Husbandry Anatomised (1697) says that, when a tenant improves his land, " the Land- lord obUgeth him either to augment his Rent, or remove, insomuch that it's become a Proverb (and I think none more true), Bowih and Sit, Improve and Flit." In treating of drainage, BUth deals not only with surface water but the constant action of springs and stagnant bottom water. He urges that no man should attempt to lay out his drains by the eye alone, but by the aid of " a true exact Water Levell," an instrument which he carefully describes and depicts. No drain, he said, could touch the " cold spewing moyst water that feeds the flagg and rush," unless it was " a yard or four feet deep," provided with proper outfalls. The drains were to be filled with elder boughs or with stones, and turfed over. He insists that they should be cut straight, not, as open-field farmers were compelled to cut them — for want of space or from the opposition of their neighbours — ^with turns and angles. His views are sound and advanced on general schemes of drainage, which, for " the commonwealth's advantage " should, he suggests, be enforced by compulsory powers upon land- owners. When BUth wrote, the condition of the fens had become a matter of national importance. It was now that the great work of draining and reclaiming the drowned district had been for the first time seriously undertaken on a scale commensurate with the magnitude of the task. It is singular that foreigners should have taught the English how to deal, not only with land, but with water. As farmers, the Low Countries were far in advance of England, and from them came the most valuable improvements in agricultural methods, as well as the most useful additions to agricultural resources. Dutchmen drained our fens ; irrigation, warping, canals were all foreign importations. The irrigation of meadows, which M. de Girardin described as a sound insurance against drought, is said to have been first practised in England in modem times by the notorious " Horatio Pallavazene," of Babraham ..." who robbed the Pope to lend the Queen." Warping was brought from Italy to the Isle of Axholme in the e^hteenth century, and by its means the deposits at the estuary of the Humber were converted into " polders." The Dutch and Flemings had mastered the secret of locks and canals long before any attempt was made to render THE DRAINING OF THE FENS 115 English rivers navigable, or available for water-carriage in inland districts. The great French " Canal du Midi " was completed in 1681, nearly a centuiy before the example was followed in England. In this connection it may be also noticed that a colony of Walloon emigrants, settled at Thomey towards the middle of the seventeenth century, introduced into the district the practice of paring and burning the coarse tussocks of grass, and the paring plough was long known as the French plough. Robert Child in his " Large Letter " on the most notable deficiencies of English agriculture, printed in HartUb's Legacie (1651), suggests that the drainage of marshes was not begun till the reign of Elizabeth. " In Qu. Elizabeth's dayes," he writes, " Ingenuities, Curiosities, and Oood Husbandry began to take place, and then Salt Marshes began to be fenced from the Seas." In this he is mistaken. Some progress had been made at an earher date. A number of Acts were passed in the reign of Henry VlH. for the reclamation of marshes and fens by undertakers, who were usually rewarded with half the reclaimed land. Thus Wapping Marsh was reclaimed by Cornelius Vanderdelf in 1544, and the embankment of Plumstead and Greenwich Marshes was begun in the same reign. Isolated marshes had been drained in the eastern counties during the reign of Elizabeth. Norden (Surveyor's Diaiogue, 1607) says : " much of the Fennes is made lately firme ground, by the skill of one Captaine Lovell, and by M. WiUiam Englebert, an excellent Ingenor." But it was not till the reign of Charles I. that any serious attempt was made to deal with the Great Level of the Fens, which extended into the six counties of Cambridge, Lincoln, Hunting- don, Northampton, Suffolk, and Norfolk. Seventy miles in length, and varying in breadth from ten to thirty miles, the fens comprised an area of nearly 700,000 acres. Now a richly fertile, highly cultivated district, it was, in the seven- teenth century, a wUdemess of bogs, pools, and reed-shoak — ^a vast morass, from which, here and there, emerged a few islands of soUd earth. Here dwelt an amphibious population, travelling in punts, walking on stilts, and living mainly by fishing, cutting willows, keeping geese, and wild-fowling. " H. C." who, in 1629, urged upon the Government the Drayning of Fennes, paints an unattractive picture of the country : " The Aer Nebulous, Grosse, and full of rotten Harres ; the Water putred and muddy, yea, full of loath- some Vermine ; the Earth spuing, unfast, and boggie ; the Fire 116 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION noysome turfe and hassocks ; such are the inconveniences of the Drownings." Eight great principal rivers — the Great Ouse, the Cam, the Nene, the Welland, the Glen, the Milden-hall or Lark, the Brandon or Lesser Ouse, and the Stoke or Wissey' — carry the upland waters through this wide stretch of flat country towards the sea. Whenever the rains fell, the rivers rose above their banks, and, especially if the wind was blowing from the east or south, flooded the cotmtry for miles around. It was only in the map that they reached the ocean at all. Two causes principally contributed to make the country a brackish swamp. The outfalls of the rivers had become silted up so that their mouths were choked by many feet of alluvial deposit.* Twice every day the tides rushed up the channels for a considerable distance, forcing back the fresh water, and converting the whole country into one vast shallow bay. Efforts had been made by the Romans to reclaim these flat levels, and their " causey " is still in existence. In the palmy days of the great monasteries of Crowland, Thomey, Ely, and Ramsey, isolated districts were occupied, and highly cultivated. WiUiam of Malmes- bnry, writing in the reign of Henry 11. (1143), describes the district round Thomey as " a very Paradise in pleasure and delight ; it resembles heaven itself — ^it abounds in lofty trees, neither is any waste place in it ; for in some parts there are apple trees, in other vines which either spread upon the ground or run along poles." Such a description applies only to the islands on which the great monasteries were situated. The rest of the country had become, at some unknown period of history, an unproductive bog, affording little benefit to the realm other than fish and fowl, and "overmuch harbour to a rude and almost barbarous sort of lazy and beggarly people." No important effort was made to reclaim the district till the time of John Morton, Bishop of Ely, afterwards a Cardinal and Arch- bishop of Canterbmy, in the reign of Henry VII. As a grower of strawberries he is enshrined in literature ; but in the history of * Sir Jonas Moore, History of the Great Level of the Fennea (168S), p. 9 ; Wells, Hietory of the Bedford Level (1830), vol. i. p. 6 ; Vermuyden, Discourse touching the Drayning of the Qreat Fennes (1642), p. 4. • Andrewes Burrell, in his Brief e Relation Discovering Plamely the True Ca/uses why the Qreat Levell of Fetiea . . . have been drowned (1642), says that, when working for the Earl of Bedford in 1636 in deepening " Wisbeach Biver," he " discovered a stony bottome upon which there was found lying at several! distances seven boates, which for many yeores had laine buried eight foot under the bottome of the river." COMPLETION OF THE FEN DRAINAGE 117 farming his principal achievement was probably suggested by his residence in Flanders from 1483 to 1485 as a poUtical refugee. A cut, forty feet wide and four feet deep, running from Peterborough to Wisbech, still bears the name of " Morton's Learn " and still plays an important part in the drainage of the country. Other local efforts were made, which proved for the most part ineffective. In spite of individual enterprise, the general condition of the district was so deplorable that it attracted the attention of the Government. The fens were surveyed, Ck>mmissioners and Courts of Sewers appointed, and an Act (1601) was passed for the drainage of the Great Level. In 1606, under a local Act, a portion of the Isle of Ely was reclaimed, the undertakers receiving two-thirds of the land thus recovered from the water. In 1626 the drainage of Hatfield Chase, Ditchmarsh, and all the lands through which crept the Idle, the Aire, and the Don, was commenced by ComeUus Vermuyden. Three years later, the greater task was attempted of draining that portion of the fens which was afterwards known as the Bedford Level. In 1630 the local gentry who formed the Commoissioners of Sewers, contracted with Vermuyden (now Sir Cornelius) to execute the work, and the fourth Earl of Bedford headed the undertaking. The work began vigorously enough. In 1637 the Commissioners of Sewers certified its completion ; but the winter rains flooded the country ; the Earl of Bedford was at the end of his resources ; he had spent £100,000, and was in danger of losing it all. The certificate of completion was reversed. Charles I. intervened ; fresh arrangements were made for the allotment of the recovered land ; a new Company of Adventurers was formed ; Vermuyden still directed the operations, although his skill was attacked by Andrewes Burrell in his Briefe Relation (1642). Vermuyden in his defence {Discourse, 1642) pleaded that the only purpose of the first Agreement was to make the land " summer groimd." The new venture was more ambitious. Though the work was partially suspended during the Civil War, it proceeded under the Common- wealth. In 1649 the fifth Earl of Bedford joined the imdertaking, and, four years later, the drainage was finished. New channels and drains were made to carry off the surface water ; existing drains were scoured and straightened ; banks were raised to restrain the rivers within their beds ; new outfalls into the sea, provided with sluices, were made, and old ones deepened and widened ; numerous dams were erected to keep out the sea. In 1652 Sir C. 118 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION Vermuyden reported the completion of the work to the CouncU, saying that " wheat and other grains, besides unnmnerable quantities of sheep, cattle, and other stock were raised, where never had been any before." The Bedford Level was the largest work imdertaken. It was also the most complete, iihougheven here for a time there were failures. Other marshes were attacked by improvers, with more or less success. From various causes, however, the water often regained its hold on the coimtiy. In some cases the work was only partially finished ; in others, it was so inadequately executed by persons whom BUth calls " mountebank engineers, idle practitioners, and slothful impatient slubberers," that it broke down under the rainfall of the first wet season ; in others, the wind- mills, which were used to raise the water of the interior districts to the levels of the main rivers, could not cope with a flood ; in others, the works were destroyed by the fenmen, and were not really restored till the beginning of the nineteenth century. The marshes were to fenmen what wastes and commons were to dwellers on their verge. Catching pike and plucking geese were more attractive than feeding bullocks or shearing sheep. Any change from desultory industries to the settled labour of agriculture was in itself distasteful to the commoners, and Uttle, if any, com- pensation was made for their rights or claims to pasture, turf- cutting, fishing, or fowling. All over the fen districts there were, on the one side, outbursts of popular indignation, and, on the other, complaints of the " riotous letts and disturbances of lewd persons." The commoners were called to arms by some Tyrtaeus of the fens, whose doggerel verses have been preserved by Dugdale in his History of Imbanking and Draining : Come, brethren of the water, and let us all assemble. To treat upon this matter which makes us quake and tremble. For we shall rue it, if' t be true, the Fens be undertaken. And where we feed in fen and reed; they'll feed both beef and bacon. Behold the great design, which they do now determine. Will make our bodies pine, a prey to crows and vermin ; For they do mean all fens to drain and waters overmaster ; AH will be dry and we must die, 'cause Essex calves want pasture. The feathered fowls have wings to fly to other'nations, But we have no such things to help ova transportations ; We must give place (oh grievous case 1) to homM beasts and cattle. Except that we can all agree to drive them out by battle. DESTRUCTION OF THE DRAINAGE WORKS 119 Wherefore let us entreat our ancient water nurses To show their power so great as t'help to drain their purses. And send us good old Captain Flood to lead us out to battle, Then Twopenny Jack with skales on's ba«k will drive out all the cattle. The CSvil Waxs gave the fenmen their opportunity. Vermuyden seems to have been personally unpopular : he was a ZealandCT ; most of his workmen were foreigners ; the adventurers who settled on the lands which they had reclaimed were French or Dutch Protestants. The commoners, moving swiftly and silently in their boats, broke down the embankments, fired the mills, filled up the drains, levelled the enclosures, turned their cattle into the standing com. They attacked the workmen, threw some of them into the river, held them under the water with poles, and burnt their tools. The perpetrators of the outrages worked so secretly that they could rarely be identified. Sometimes their action was bold and open. In the neighbourhood of Hatfield Chase, near the Isle of Axholme, every day for seven weeks, gangs of commoners, armed with mus- kets, drew up the flood-gates so as to let in the flowing tide, and at every ebb shut the sluices, threatening that they " would stay till the whole level was weU drowned, and ,the inhabitants forced to swim away like ducks." Even the rehgion of the French and Dutch Protestants was not respected. From Epworth in 1656 comes their petition that the fenmen had made their church a slaughter-house and a burying-place for carrion. Major-General Whalley was entrusted by Parliament with the task of protecting the adventurers. But agitators like Ijlbume and Noddel were at work among his soldiers, and the commoners showed no respect for the authority of Parhament. " They could make as good a Parliament themselves ; it was a Parliament of clouts." In some cases the resistance of the fenmen secured them further concessions ; in others they succeeded in destroying the works of the under- takers. It was not till after 1714 that the riots caused by the reclamation ceased to disturb the peace of the country. By that time the object was partially achieved, and many of the swamps and marshes of the fen districts were restored to the ague-shivering, fever-stricken inhabitants in their primitive unproductiveness. The struggle for the reclamation of the waste-lands of the water- drowned fens is another aspect of the older land-battle between enclosers and commoners. Men like Robert Child in his Large Letter in Hartlib's Legacie, or Walter BUth, championed reclamation 120 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION for the same reasons that they advocated enclosures. The former, writing in 1650 before the drainage was complete, speaks of " that great Wen of lincolneshire, Cambridge, Hungtingdon, consisting, as I am Informed, of 380,000 Acres, which is now almost recovered." " Very great, therefore," he continues, " is the improvement of draining of lands, and our negligence very great, that they have been waste so long, and as yet so continue in divers places : for the improving of a Kingdome is better than the conquering a new one." Blith, writing three years later {English Improver Improved, 1652), speaks of the work as finished. " As to the Drayning, or laying dry the Fenns," he says, " those profitable works, the Com- mon-wealths glory, let not Curs Snarl, nor dogs bark thereat, the unparralleld advantages of the World." But when these and other writers of the period dealt with enclosures, they treated the subject from a new point of view. As a matter of farming, their arguments were sound. But economic gain might involve social and moral loss, and the Stewart writers on agriculture tried to recon- cile the two aspects of the question. In the interests of agricultural progress, they are practically unanimous in their advocacy of indi- vidual as opposed to common occupation of arable land. But in the case of commons of pasture, they vigorously defended the claims of the commoners, both tenant-farmers and cottagers. More advanced members of the Repubhcan party went beyond the recognition of pasture rights, and claimed the common, not for the open-field farmers to whose arable holdings it was historically attached, but for the general public — irrespective of claims arising from neighbour- hood or from the tillage of adjacent land. On the practical assertion of such claims a curious side-light is thrown by the proceedings of Jerrard Winstanley in 1649. Winstanley and his friends sought to establish a society having all things in common. With this object they settled on the common lands of St. George's Hill, near Walton-on-Thames, and began to plough, cultivate, and enclose the land. Lord Fairfax's soldiers burned their huts, and turned them o£E. Winstanley, in the jargon' of the day, identified the struggle, in which his personal profits were staked, with the prophetic Armageddon " between the Lamb of Righteousness . . . and the Dragon of Unrighteousness." Need- less to say, he found himself a champion of the former. He sets forth his claims in a pamphlet addressed to the General as A Letter to the Lord Fairfax and hie Council of War : . . . Proving it an A COMMUNISTIC SOCIETY 121 undeniable Equity That the Common People ought to dig, plow, plant, and duxU upon the Commons, without hiring them or paying Rent to any. He was, he says, opposed by none save " one or two covetous freeholders that would have all the commons to themselves, and that would uphold the Norman tyranny over us, which by the victory that you have got over the Norman successor is plucked up by the roots and therefore ought to be cast away." In other words, the effect of the Civil War and of the defeat of Charles I., as interpreted by his school of thought, was to establish the rights of the people to " have the land freed from the entanglement of lords, lords of manors, and landlords, which are our taskmasters," " to enter on their inheritance," and "dig, plow, plant and dwell upon the Commons " without rent, and improve them " for a public treasiuy and livelihood." Instead of the existing law, the rule was to be established of " First come, first served." For this appropriation and improvement of the commons the inspiration of the " Lamb of Righteousness " was claimed, so long as the new possessors were Winstanley and his communistic society ; but the same processes were the direct suggestion of the " Dragon of Unrighteousness," if the work was carried out by the adjacent owners and cultivators of the soil. In either case, whoever was the encloser, the general public gained no advantage ; the pasture commons were ploughed, enclosed, and appropriated to individuals. The episode is significant. Probably Winstanley had, and has, sympathisers. But the views of those practical agriculturists, who were interested in the enclosure and tillage of open-fields and commons in order to accelerate farming progress, were less revolu- tionary. Had they been carried into efiect, much social loss might have been averted. From the purely commercial side, their argu- ments in favour of converting open-field land into separate holdings and of enclosiog the commons and wastes were overwhelming. There need be no depopulation, for tillage would be increased. If the rights of commoners were respected, the social drawbacks to the change might be removed. The whole question was assuming a new form. The improvements in arable farming suggested by Stewart and Commonwealth writers minimised the social loss caused by enclosures, at the same time that they magnified the economic waste of the open-field system. Tudor farmers had treated arable and pasture farming as two distinct branches, which could not be combined. On open-field 122 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION land, though some live-stock was maintained by means of commons, the energies of farmers were almost exclusively concentrated on com. On enclosed land, com might be comparatively relegated to the background, and the farmer's mainstays were meat, dairy produce, and, if a flock-master, wool. So long as this rigid dis- tinction was maintained, enclosures often meant depopulation and a dwindling wheat-area. Experience was crystallised into the proverb " No balks, no com." It is true that, towards the end of Elizabeth's reign, the advantages which enclosures gave to the enterprise of the arable farmer were reaUsed, and land began to be fenced off, not for pasture only, but also for tillage. But the economic case for enclosures was enormously strengthened, when the real pivots of mixed husbandry were discovered, and when Stewart agriculturists found that neither turnips, nor clover, nor artificial grasses, nor potatoes, nor drainage, were possible on open-fields which were held in common for half the year. Yet the experience of the previous two himdred years had created a mass of well- founded prejudice, which fought stubbornly against any extension of the practice of enclosing land. It is for this reason, probably, that the best writers of the Stewart and Commonwealth period labour hard to prove that enclosures of open-fields and commons, whatever their past history had been, necessitated neither depopula- tion nor decay of tillage, and might even promote not only economic but social gain. In his Book of Surveying (1523) Fitzherbert had written on the way " to make a township that is worth 20 marks a year worth £20 a year." His plan was to discover, first, how many acres of arable land each man occupied in the open-fields, how much meadow, and what proportion of common pasture were attached to his hold- ing ; and secondly, by means of exchange, to consolidate these lands, lay them together, and enclose them in several occupation. Every man should have " one little croft or close next to his house." In the Briefe Examination (1549) the Doctor, who represents the author's views, only condemns those enclosures of land which were made for the conversion of tillage into pasture, or " without recompence of them that have right to comen therein." It was on this principle that in 1545 the Royal wastes of Hounslow Heath were enclosed under the award of Commissioners, who set out a portion of the heath to each inhabitant ; either as copyholds, or on leases for terms of years. "THEEE ACRES AND A COW" 123 Sentiments like these became the commonplaces of Stewart and Commonwealth writers. The demand for " three acres and a cow " can show an origin of respectable antiquity. Gabriel Plattes (1639) ^ pleads that all parties would gain by enclosures, landowners by increased rents, clergymen by improved tithes, the poor by increased employment. " I could wish," he adds, " that in every Parish where Commons are inclosed, a comer might be laid to the poore mens houses, that every one might keep a Cow or for the maintenance of his familie two." The wish of the Stewart writer had been expressed by a Tudor predecessor a century earUer. Thomas Becon^ in 1540 had suggested that landlords should attach to every cottage enough " land to keep a cow or two." Walter Bhth* argues vigorously in favour of enclosures, and quotes with approval the whole of Tusser's poem comparing " champion " (open) and " severall " land. Of open-field farmers he says " Uve they do indeed, very many in a mean, low condition, with hunger and care. Better do those in Bridewell. And for the best of them, they live as uncomfortably, moyling and toyling and drudg- ing. What they get they spend." But in all enclosures he expressly makes the condition that all interests should be provided for — ^not only those of the landlord, but those also of the " Minister to the People," the " Freeholder Farmer or Tenant," and the " Poor Labourer or Cottier." All these, he says, would gain by the process. He takes the last first : " Look what right or Interest he hath in Common, I'U first allot out his proportion into severall with the better rather than with the worse, a Proportion out of everyman's inheritance." At the same time he condemns " depopulating Inclosure . . . such as former oppressive times by the will and power of some cruell Lord either through his greatness or purchased favour at Court, or in the Common Courts of England, by his purse and power could do anything, inclose, depopulate, destroy, mine aU Tillage, and convert all to pasture without any other Improvement at aU . . . which hath brought men to conceive, that because men did depopulate by Enclosure, therefore it is now impossible to enclose without Depopulation." To the same effect as Bhth writes Robert Child in the " Large ^ A Discovery of Infinite Treasure, Hidden since the World's Beginning, by O(abTiel) P(lattes), 1639. ' The Jewel of Joy, 1540. ' English Invprover Invproved, ed. 1653. 124 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION Letter " in Hartlib's Legacie (1651). He regards wastes and commons as defects in English husbandry, and in defence of his position asks eight questions, which he does not attempt to answer, preferring to leave " the determination for wiser heads." 1. " Whether or no these lands might not be improved very much by the Hriabandry of Flounders (viz.) by sowing Flax, Tumeps, great Clover-Orasse, if that Manure be made by folding Sheepe after the Flaundera way, to keepe it in heart ? 2. " Whether the Bottennesse and Scabbinesae of Sheepe, Murrein of Cattel, Diseases of horses, and in general all diseases of Cattel do not especially proceed from Commons ? 3. "If the rich men, who are able to keepe great stockes are not great gainers by them ? 4. " Whether Commons do not rather make poore, by causing idlenesse than maintaine them : and such poor, who are trained up rather for the Gallowes or beggery, than for the Commonwealths service ? 5. " How it cometh to passe, that there are fewest poore, where there are fewest Commons, as in Kent, where there is scarce 6 Comr- mons in the County of a considerable greatnesse ? ^ 6. " How many do they see enriched by the Commons : and if their Cattel be not usually swept away by the Bat, or starved in some hard winters ? 7. " If that poore men might not imploy 2 Acres enclosed to more advantage, than twice as much in a Common ? " And lastly, if that all Commons were enclosed, and part given to the Inhabitants, and part rented out, for a stock to set the poore on worke in every County." Blith not only quoted Tusser in support of Ids opinion, but adds that " all that ever I yet saw or read " held the same opinion. " Tis true I have met with one or two small Pieces, as M. Spriggs, and another whose name I remember not, that write against depopu- lating Inclosure, with whom I freely joyn and approve." It is probable that he alludes to Henty Halhead's Inclosure Thrown Open etc. (1650), to which Joshua Sprigge of Banbury contributed a ' Tusser held the some opinion that poverty and conunons go together. In his comparison between " Champion Country and Several! " he writes : " T'one barefoot and ragged doth go And ready in winter to starve ; When t'other you see not do so. But hath that is needful to serve." THE CASE AGAINST ENCLOSURES 125 Preface. The tract is an appeal against enclosures, mainly based on past history. It probably belongs to a group of pamphlets dealing with the Midland counties, where the enclosing movement seems to have been active. Halhead describes how would-be enclosers begin by upsetting the field customs by which the cultiva- tion of the land was regulated ; how they tell the people that they will be three times as well off, that enclosure stops strife and con- tention, " nourisheth Wood in hedges," and keeps sheep from rotting. If they cannot prevail by these promises, they begin a suit at law, and make the resisters dance attendance at the law- courts for months and even years. Then they pull out their purses, and offer to buy them out. If this fails, on goes the suit till a decree against the open-field partners is granted in Chancery. The description bears the stamp of accuracy. But, logically, neither the old methods of enclosing nor the results of the conversion of tUlage into pasture really met the case put forward by the new advocates of enclosure as an instrument both of social and agricultural progress. The case for enclosures of open-field farms and commons is vigorously stated in three tracts ; one by S. Taylor (1652) ; ^ another by Adam Moore (1653) ; " the third by Joseph Lee (1656).* Their arguments are mainly based on the wretched conditions of the commons, the poor farming of open-field land, and the social and agricultural gain which, as Lee's practical experience had shown, resulted from individual occupation. None of the three authors alludes to the recent discoveries of roots, clover, and grasses, or to the improved methods of drainage, on which BUth and others so strongly reUed. Of Taylor nothing is known, except that his tract shows him to have been a vehement assailant of ale-houses. Moore tells us that he was a Somersetshire man. The Rev. Joseph Lee was a Leicestershire " Minister of the Gospel " at Cotesbaoh, who had been violently attacked by his professional brethren for the * Common Oood : or the Improvement of Commons, Forests, and Chases by Indoaure, by S. T(aylor), 1652. * Bread for the Poor . . . Promised by Enclosure of the Wastes and Common Orounds of England, by Adam Moore, Gent. 1653. 'Ei>To|(a ToS 'Aypov; or a Vindication of a Regulated Enclosure, etc., by Joseph Lee, Minister of the Gospel, 1656. The contrary view to that taken by Lee was stated by John Moore, Minister of Knaptoft in Leicestershire, whose tract The Crying Sin of England of not Caring for the Poor, etc., was published in 1653. Moore's Scripture Word against Incloswre (1656) was an answer to Lee. 126 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION share he had himself taken in. the enclosure of Catthorp Common. In his Epistle to the Reader he explains why he preferred to reply to these attacks by a tract and not by a sermon : "I am very sensible that if our pulpits had sounded more of the things of Christ, and lesse of the things of the world, it had been better with us then it is this day." Part of the tract consists of hard text- fighting ; but its value lies in the facts which he quotes from his own experience. Enclosures, in the opinion of the three writers, are not only " lawfull " but " laudable." They injure none, but profit aU. Lee considers that five classes ought to be considered, landlords, ministers, the poor, cottagers, and tenant-farmers. Moore omits the ministers, but asserts the claims of the remaining four classes. All three writers agree that a certain portion of the Commons ought to be set aside for the poor, and the rest proportionately divided. This, says Lee, was the principle adopted at Catthorp. If this were done, there need be no depopulation. In proof Lee mentions a number of parishes in Leicestershire, where the land had been enclosed without any decay of population, houses, or tillage. Neither would it lead to any diminution of useful employment. The same number of maid-servants would be employed ; and though there might be fewer lads, they would be more useful citizens if set to some trade. On the industrial gain thus derived from enclosures the three authors are also agreed. They in effect answer the fourth question asked by Robert Child in the " Large Letter " in HartUb's Legacie with an unhesitating aflSrmative. At the beginning of the century, Norden (1607) had drawn attention to the character of the squatters who settled on the edges of wastes and commons. He describes them as " people given to Uttle or no labour, hving very hardly with oaten bread and sour whey and goat's milk, dwelling far from any church or chapel, . . . as ignorant of Grod or of any civil course of life as the very savages among the infidels, in a manner which is lamentable and fit to be reformed by the lord of the manor." Fifty years later, according to the three authors, commons were blots on the social life of the nation. Children, says Taylor, are " brought up Lazying upon a Common to attend one Cow and a few sheep," and " being nursed up in idleness in their youth they become indisposed for labor, and then begging is their portion or Theevery their Trade. . . . The two great Nurseries of Idlenesse and Beggery etc. are Ale-houses and THE CASE FOR ENCLOSURES 127 Commons." Taylor says that " people are nowhere more penurious than such as border on commons." " This poverty," he explains, " is due to Grod's displeasure at the idleness of the Borderers," or commoners. They have no settled industry. They look to the profits of a horse or cow. if they can keep one ; if not, they can at least " compass a goose or a swine." If they have no live-stock at all, they are " sure of furze, fern, bushes, or cowdung, for fuel to keep them warm in winter." They can beguile, writes Moore, the " silly Woodcock and his feathered fellows by tricks and traps of their own painful framing," and so gain money enough to keep them till they have to work again. Sometimes they earn a few shillings by guarding the flocks aad herds of others. But, if a sheep or a cow is missing, the " chuck-fists " will not pay them their wage, but suspect them of theft, and proceed against them by law. The Commons are, in fact, " Nurseries of Thieves and Horse-stealers." Lee is of the same opinion that commons fostered idleness. Perhaps, he admits, "3 or 4 shepherd boyes " by enclosures " wiU be necessitated to lay aside that idle emplojonent ; . . . destructive to the soules of those Lads, in that, poor creatures, they are brought up by this means without either civill or reHgious education." When they should have been at school or at church, they were " playing at nine-holes under a bush," while their cattle make a prey on their neighbour's com, and " they themselves are made a prey to Satan." Other moral gains are alleged that by enclosure an end is put to occa/Sions for litigation and strife between common-field farmers, or for quarrels between herdsmen, and that there are fewer opportunities for pilferings of land and of com, or for the destruction of a neighbour's crops by turning in hors^ and cattle under pretence that they have broken loose from their tethers. It is not true, in the opinion of the three writers, that enclosures necessarily destroy tillage. On the contrary, the cheapness and abundance of com are due to the opportunities that enclosures afford for breaking up worn-out pastures which yield double the quantities produced on common fields. Nor is it true that enclosers are under a curse so that the land passes out of their, famiUes. Instances to the contrary are adduced from Leicestershire, and that cannot be a sx>ecial curse on enclosures which is a fate common to all other landholders. Enclosure may diminish the number of horses ; but one horse well kept is worth three so " jaded and tyred 128 FROM JAMES I. TO THE RESTORATION as aie the horses of common-field farmers." Nor is it any tyranny for the majority to enforce enclosure where the whole body of partners are not unanimous. At Gatthorp one man with common for seven sheep stood out. The rest overruled Viim ; but he lost nothing. All that the other commoners did was to enclose their portions of the common away from him. That the agricultural gain is great, scarcely admits of a doubt. On open-fields the corn- land is worn out. It can only be induced to bear at all by constant ploughings and Uberal manurings, which absorb all profits in labour and charges. Even then there is often Uttle more than a bare return of seed, poor in quaUty — " small humble-Bee-Ears with little grains." The pease land is no better ; it may provide enough for seed and keep of the horses ; but it yields no clear profit. The live-stock that are reared on the commons are dwarfed and under- sized ; they are driven long distances to and fro, so that they have neither rest nor quiet. Colts, raised on the commons, by cold and famine come to no good. " Cattle, nurtured there, grow to such brockish and starved stature " that, Uving, they grieve the owner's eye, and, dead, deceive the Commonwealth. Sheep do better ; but they even are so pinched that they make little profit. One sheep in an enclosiu-e is worth two on a common. There are five rots in the open-fields to one rot in enclosed land. The commons are over-stocked. They are, says Moore, " Pest-houses of disease for cattle. Hither come the Poor, the Blinde, Lame, Tired, Scabbed, Mangie, Rotten, Murrainous." No order is kept ; but milch cows, young beasts, sheep, horses, swine — often uuringed — and geese are turned out together. Furze and heath are encouraged by com- moners, because they keep cattle and sheep alive in hard winter when fodder is scarce ; but the same space covered with grass would be more useful. That which is every man's is no man's, and no one tries to better the commons. When it is everybody's interest to improve the pasture, it is nobody's business to do the work. The whole subject of enclosures had yet to be fought out. From the point of view of production, the change was desirable ; no pressure of population as yet made it necessary. Commons were essential to the existence of those open-field farms, which advocates of agricultural improvement recognised as an obstacle to pro- gress ; but new methods and new resources had as yet hardly advanced beyond theories. Neither the argument from increased ALTERED TONE RESPECTING ENCLOSURES 129 productiveness, nor the appeal for progress, had gained their full force. Yet the altered tone of agricultural writers is significant. It was almost as incontestably in favour of enclosure as the tone of Elizabethan writers had been opposed to the process. Generalisa- tion from handfuls of particular instances is always easy. A large tract of country might have been improved and enclosed with the approval of all parties. But there were the widest differences between commons, or between commons and moors, wastes, and bogs. Moore himself reserves his bitterest condemnation for what he calls " marish," as opposed to " uplandish," commons. Stress might be laid on the moral influences of common land either way, and self-interest or bias is always prone to conceal itself under the mask of moral motives. The same rights might encourage industry and thrift, or idleness and crime. It was doubtless illogical to argue that enclosures must always depopulate, whether the change was effected with or without regard to the claims of cottagers and small commoners, or for the purpose of incres/Sing the area either of tillage or of pasture. Yet those who had suffered from enclosures were not unjustified in the conclusion that history would repeat itself. Whichever way the question was ultimately decided, it could not fail to affect the condition of the rural population for better or for worse, and to affect it profoundly. Unfortunately the decision was made, in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, under an economic pressure which completely overrode the social considerations that should have controlled and modified the process of enclosure. CHAPTEE VI. THE LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION. 1660-1700. WarUdge'a Syatema Agrieultwrae (1669) : improvements suggested by agri- cultural writers ; tyranny of custom ; contempt for book-farming ; slow progress in fanning skill ; general standard low ; horses, cattle, sheep, and pigs in the seventeenth century ; want of leaders ; growing influence of landowners ; the finance of the Restoration, and the abolition of military tenures ; legislation to promote agriculture ; Gregory King on the State and Gondition of England and Wales ia 1696 : the distribution of population and wealth. The practical improvements, which had been suggested by " Rustick Authors " in the first sixty years of the seventeenth century, were collected by John Worlidge in his Syatema AgrieuUurae (1669). Five editions of this " first systematic treatise on farming " show that it was for some time regarded as a standard authority. Free from the extravagant promises of his predecessors, Worlidge sum- marises their most useful recommendations. Inordinate space is still allotted to such topics as trees, orchards, "garden tyllage," bees, and silkworms, which occupy 106 pages out of a total nimiber of 217. On the side of stock-breeding and stock-rearing his book remains especially defective. For information on this subject he merely refers readers in a general way to other writers. Three pages only are devoted to the section " Of Beaats," in which the special qualities required for the difierent uses of horses, cattle, and sheep are wholly ignored ; only in the case of dogs does Wor- lidge appear to recognise the variety of purposes for which animals are bred. Even the most practical work on farming which was published in the seventeenth century is ill-balanced and defective. Yet it is remarkable how many of the triumphs of nineteenth century farming were anticipated by these early writers, a century and a PREPARATIONS FOR AGRICULTURAL ADVANCE 131 half before the improvements were generally adopted. Already the germs of a proper rotation of crops had been implanted, and a few advanced husbandmen, familiar with the methods of the Low Countries, had realised that, in roots and clovers, they commanded the means, not only of keeping more stock, but of increasing the yield of com. Already some of the drawbacks of broad-cast sowing had been pointed out, and the advantages of setting in regular rows suggested. Already the foreign use of oU-cake for cattle had been observed and recommended to English farmers. But, as Mortimer ^ notices, Lincolnshire farmers, after pressing out the " oyl " from their coleseed, preferred to " bum the cakes to heat their Ovens." Already also the field-cultivation of potatoes had been suggested, and it is a coincidence that the suggestion was made only a few years after the drainage of those fens, on the clover- sick soil of which, two centuries and a half later, the adoption of the crop worked a revolution. Already the use of silos and of ensilage, the storage of water in tanks for dry districts, the value of coverings to rick-stands, even the utility of the incubator for rearing poultry — a box heated by a candle or a lamp — ^had been urged on Stewart agriculturists. In a tentative fashion the " Rus- tick Authors " were feeling after improved agricultural machinery. Googe's reaping car, the double-furrow plough of the " ingenious yeoman of Kent," Plattes' com-setter, the com drill depicted by Worhdge, which made the furrow, sowed the seed, and deposited the manure, were the ancestors of many useful inventions. Still more vaguely Stewart writers were looking for the aid of science. Its future benefits could not, of course, be foreseen. But the demand for an Agricultural College, the recognition of the work of the Royal Society, the study of such books as Willis' Defermmtor tione or Glauber's Miracidum Mundi, in which an attempt was made to analyse the elements that contribute to vegetation, show that expectations had been aroused. Already a Land Registry, by which land could be made to pass as freely as money, had been suggested by Andrew Yarranton. Already also the aboUtion of " slavish customs," and of " lU Tenures as Copyhold, Knight- Service etc," which " much discourage Improvements and are (as I suppose) Badges of our Norman Slavery " was demanded. The Hares and Rabbits legislation had been foreshadowed in the out- I The whole Art of Hiubcmdry ; or the Way of Managing and Improving of Land (1707). 132 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION cry against the destraction of growing crops by " coneys," and hares which in 1696, according to Gregory King's minute calcula- tion, numbered 24,000. The necessity for General Highway and Enclosure Acts had been ui^ed on the country. The prelude to the long struggle for compensation for unexhausted improvements had been sounded. Even the twentieth century agitation for piue bread had been anticipated in the protest that " the corruption of the best aliments, as bread, and which are in most use with us, causeth the worst Epidemical! Diseases." Here and there some changes in farming practices had been made for the better. But such progress was purely local, and rarely survived the individual by whom it was effected. Traditional methods were jealously guarded as agricultural heirlooms. Even ocular proof of the superior advantages derived from improvements failed to drive the John Trot geniuses of farmiag from the beaten track in which their ancestors had plodded. Circumstances com- bined to render the force of custom tyrannical. The agrarian partnerships on village farms opposed a natural obstacle to change. On open-fields, where the rotations of crops were fixed by imme- morial usage, based on the common rights of the whole body of associated farmers, no individual could move hand or foot to effect improvements. Unless a large number of joint occupiers, often ignorant, suspicious, and prejudiced, agreed to forgo common rights and adopt turnips and clover, it was impossible to introduce their cultivation. The enterprise of twenty farmers might be checked by the apathy or caution of one. It was for this reason mainly that Worlidge addresses his treatise to the " gentry and yeomanry," and that he thinks the moment opportune for improve- ment, because so many farmers had been obliged to give up their holdings owing to " the great Plenty and Smallness of Value of the Orivnary Prodiu^ions of the Earth," which left no profit to those who " exercised onely the Vulgar Methods of Agricviture." Even if the new materials for agricultural wealth were successfully intro- duced by some energetic landlord or tenant on an enclosed farm, the result of the experiment was rarely known beyond the im- mediate neighbourhood. Each village was at once isolated and self-sufficing. Communication was difficult ; frequented roads were often impassable except for a well-mounted horseman or a coach drawn by eight horses. Education had not spread to the class to which farmers generally belonged. Letters were rarely ISOLATION OF VILLAGES 133 interchanged. Visits were seldom paid. The only form in which information could be disseminated was in books or pamphlets, and in remote villages buyers were few or none. Newspapers had hardly begun to exist. The first attempt to found a scientific agricultural paper was made by John Houghton, whose Collection of Letters for ihe Imprvoement of Husbandry and Trade appeared in a weekly series from 1681 to 1683, and again from 1692 to 1703. It is improbable that the circulation could have been extensive even among the wealthiest of the country gentry. Rumours of the progress of the outside world scarcely penetrated to distant villages. Farmers of one district knew Httle more of the practices of the next than they did of those of Kamchatka. Beyond the limited range of their horizon, their neighbours were only " Anthropophagi, and mea whose heads Do grow beneath their shoulders." In this extreme isolation must be sought a fruitful cause for the slow diffusion of agricultural improvements. Another cause lay in the absence of any strong incentive to raise more produce from the soil than was requisite for the immediate wants of the producers. Markets were, in many parts of England, not only difficult of access but few in number. From vast and crowded haunts of labour and trade the cry of the artisan had not yet arisen for bread and meat. As soon as the farmer had satisfied the needs of himself, his family, and his rent, his work was done. TiU a wider demand for agricultural produce had been created by the rapid growth of population which resulted from the development of manufacturing industries, and till the new markets had been brought to the farmer's door by improved means of communication, the supply was mainly regulated by the wants of the producer himself. Another cause for the neglect of improvements has been already mentioned. A contempt for book-farmers, which was not wholly unjustifiable, partially explains the slow adoption of new methods and new crops. Of this class of agricultural writers, Thomas Tryon affords an interesting example. Like most men of his kind, he was a " Jack of aU trades:" He was a voluminous writer on a miscellaneous variety of subjects — against drinking brandy and " smoaking tobacco," upon brewing ale and beer, upon medical topics, upon dreams and visions, on the benefit of clean beds, on the generation of bugs, on the pain in the teeth. He also com- 134 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION posed a " short discourse " of a Pythagorean and a mystic. His agricultural book, The Cowalryman'a Companion (1681), is chiefly noticeable for its account of that " Monsterous, Mortifying Dis- temper, the Rot," and for the strange remedies which he suggests for the preservation of sheep from that disorder. Thomas Tryon is an admirable representative of the class of writers who brought the book-farmer into disrepute. But abeady true science was coming to the aid of agriculture. The Sylva (1664) and Terra (1676) of John Evelyn are known to all well-read agriculturists, and John Ray's Catalogvs Phmtarum Anglian (1670) marks an epoch in the history of botanical science. All these conditions combined to raise formidable obstacles to the diffusion of improvements in farming. Agricultural writers scarcely expected that the changes they suggested would be adopted. Donaldson, for instance, says that people will probably answer him with " Away with your fool Notions ; there are too many Bees in your Bonet-case. We will satisfie ourselves with such Measures as our Fathers have followed hitherto." Farmers, says HartUb's Legacie, did not venture to attempt innovations lest they should be called " projectors." Bradley, Professor of Botany at Cambridge, complains in his Complete Body of Husbandry (1727), that if he were to advise farmers " about improvements, they will ask me whether I can hold a plough, for in that they think the whole mystery of husbandry consists." It was long before clover emerged " from the fields of gentlemen into common use " ; it did not penetrate into Suffolk villages till the eighteenth century. In Worcestershire and adjoining districts the personal efforts of Andrew Yarranton m 1653-77 had for the time established its use. But " farmers," says Jethro Tull, writing in the reign of George 11., " if advised to sow clover would certainly reply, ' Gentlemen might sow it if they pleased, but they (the farmers) must take care to pay their rents.' " Even more obstinate was the resistance to turnips. It was of little use^that WorUdge in his Systema (1669) urged upon farmers the cultivation of roots ; or that Reeve (1670) reprinted Weston's advice to use turnips as the best methods of improving " barren and heathy land " ; or that Houghton (1684) described the benefits which had resulted in Norfolk and Essex from growing them as winter food for sheep. Even their advocates had not yet appreciated the full value of roots. Worlidge ^ in 1683 had observed that " sheep fatten 1 Houghton's CoUectione on Butbcmdry and Trade (ed. 1728), vol. iv. p. 142. SLOW ACCEPTANCE OF NEW CROPS 135 very well on turnips, which prove an excellent nourishment for them in hard winters, when fodder is scarce ; for they will not only eat the greens, but feed on the roots in the ground, and scoop them hollow even to the very skin." Houghton ^ in 1694 writes that " Some in Essex have their fallow after tumeps, which feed their sheep in winter, by which means their tumeps are scooped, and so made capable to hold dews and rain water which, by corrupting, imbibes the nitre of the air, and when the shell breaks, it runs about and fertilizes. By feeding the sheep, the land is dung'd as if it had been folded ; and these tumeps, tho' few or none be carried ofE for human use, are a very excellent improvement ; nay, some reckon it so, tho' they only plough the tumeps in, without feeding." They made but slow progress. Sir John Cullum, in his History of the Manor o/ Hawsted, preserves the name of Michael Houghton as the first man in that Suffolk parish, who about 1700 raised a crop of turnips on two acres of his laud. " I introduced turnips into the field," says Tull, " in King William's reign ; but the practice did not travel beyond the hedges of my estate till after the Peace of Utrecht " (1713). Potatoes were even less successful. John Forster (1664) had, as has been already noticed, urged their adoption as a field crop. Houghton notices that they had been brought from Ireland " to Lancashire, where they are very numerous, and now they begin to spread all the Kingdom over. They are a pleasant food boiled or roasted, and eaten with butter and sugar." ^ But Mortimer (Whole Art of Husbandry, etc., 1707) despised them even in the garden as " very near the Nature of- the Jerusalem ArUchoak, which is not so good or wholesome. These are planted either of the Boots or Seeds, and may probably be propagated in great Quantities, and prove a good food for Swine." Neither clover nor turnips became general in England before the latter half of the eighteenth century, and potatoes were not extensively grown till fifty years later, when their value was urged on the country by the Board of Agriculture. The widest differences existed between the fanning of various districts. The general level was extremely low. But in individual cases a high standard was attained, and the best possible use made of such resources as agriculturists could command. In natural fertility the Vale of Taunton, which Norden calls the " Paradise of England," was pre-eminent. The best pastures, according to the ' Ibid. vol. i. p. 213. * Oolleciions, etc. vol. ii. p. 469. 136 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION same authority, were at Crediton and Welshpool. In arable farming, says Mascall, or his editor, Ruscam, the seasons for the operations of agriculture, as well as the choice of implements must depend on the character of the soil. Thus on the " stifEe clayes of Huntingdonshire, Bedfordshire, Cambridgeshvre," on " mist soils that are good and fruitful, as Northamptonshire, Ha/rtfordshire, most parts of Kent, Essex, Barkshire," on " light and dry grounds which have also a certain natural fruitfulness in them as in Norfolk, Suffolk, most parts of Lincolnshire, Hampshire and Surrey " — farmers will adapt themselves to circumstances. On " the barren and unfruitful earths, as in Devonshire, Cornwall, many parts of Wales, Darbyshire, Lancashire, Cheshire, Yorkshire," they must profit by experience. " The best com land in Europe," in the opinion of Gabriel Plattes, was the Vale of Belvoir. The best cheeses were made at Banbury, in Cheshire, or in the Ghedder district. But the latter, says Hartlib's Legacie, were " seldom seen but at Noblemans tables or rich Vintners Sellars." In some places the new crops recommended by the Stewart writers had been tried. Liquorice was grown with success at Pontefract in Yorkshire and at " Godliman " in Surrey ; saffron was established in Essex and Cambridgeshire ; canary seed and caraways were tried in Kent and Oxfordshire ; hops were not confined to Kent, but had spread into Suffolk, Essex, Surrey, and other counties ; sainfoin had been tested at Cobham in Kent ; weld, used for dyeing of " bright Yellows and limon-colours," flourished near Canter- bury ; madder and woad had been proved to be profitable crops ; the best flax and hemp ^ were grown near Maidstone, where a thread factory had been recently established, at Bow and Stratford in Essex, and in Nottinghamshire. At a later date the district round Beccles in Suffolk was famous for its hemp ; rape and cole- seed were established in Kent, Lincolnshire, and elsewhere. Kent, Worcestershire, Herefordshire, Gloucestershire, and the neighbour- hood of London were famous for their apples, and as many as 200 varieties were collected in a single orchard. The cherries of Kent and the quinces of Essex were in chief repute. " There are now," writes William Hughes,* " in Kent and other places of this Nation, ^England's Invprovemeta, and "Seasonable Advice, etc. (London, 1691) is an anonymous treatise on the growth of hemp and flax. « Tfie Oompleat Vineyard, by William Hughes, 1666. A second and enlarged edition appeared in 1670, and The Flower Garden and Compleat Vineyard in 1683. HORSES AND CATTLE 137 such Vineyards and Wall-vines as produce great store of excellent good wine." Increased attention was also being paid to live-stock, and the values of distinctive breeds of horses, cattle, sheep, and pigs were discussed. If Gervase Markham's Chea/pe and good Husbandry (edition of 1631) is compared with Mortimer's Whole Art of Hvsbandry (1707), some idea may be formed of the views of the seventeenth century on stock-breeding. On horses, Markham, in spite of the criticism of Child already quoted, was reputed an authority. " Now for the choyse of the best Horse," he writes, " it is divers according to the use for which you will imploy him." Of " Horses for the Warre," he says, " the courser of Naples is accounted the best, the Almaine, the Sardinian, or the French." " For a Prince's Seat, any supreame Magistrate, or for any great Lady of state," he recommends a " milkewhite " or " faire dapple gray " steed of English breed : failing that, a " Hungarian, SwetMand, Poland, or Irish " horse. The best hunter he finds in " the English horse, bastardized with any of the former Races first spoake of." The finest race-horses are " the Arabian, Barbary, or his bastard-Jennets, but the Turkes are better." " For travaUe or burthen " the best is the Ei^lish horse, and " the best for ease is the Irish-hobby." " For portage, that is for the Packe or Hampers," and " for the Cart or Plough," he makes no selection. For coach horses, he chooses the large English gelding, or the Flemish mare, or the Flemish or Frisian horse. There were doubtless already distinctive breeds in England, such as the York- shire saddle-horses of the Cleveland district, the heavy Black Horse of the Midlands, the Suffolk Punch, or the West-coimtry pack- horse ; but they are not mentioned by Markham. Nor does Mor- timer refer to any English breeds. He tells us, however, that Leicestershire was in his day one of the great horse-breeding counties, and that Hertfordshire farmers bought the colts as two-year-olds, and sold them " at about six Years old to Gentlemen at London for their Coaches." Among cattle, the best breeds " for meat " were the long-homed cattle of Yorkshire, Derbjrshire, Lancashire, and Staffordshire. The tall long-l^ged Lincolns, generally " pide," with more white than any other colour, were reckoned the best for " labour and draught." " Those in Somersetshire and Gloucestershire are generally of a blood-red colour, in all shapes like unto those in Lincolne-shire> 138 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION and fittest for their uses." So fax Markham. Mortimer adds other breeds. "A good hardy Sort for fatting on barren or middling Sort of Land are your Angleaeya and Welch. The hardiest are the Scotch." The best breed for milking, in his opinion, was " the longlegged short-hom'd Cow of the Dutch breed," chiefly found in Lincolnshire and Kent. Both Markham and Mortimer have much to say about sheep, which were reckoned as the most profitable of Hve-stock. Their manifold uses inspired Leonard Mascall ''■ to rhyme in " praise of sheep " : " These cattle (sheep) among the rest, Is counted for man one of the best, No harmful beast, nor hurt at all ; His fleece of wool doth doath us all. Which keeps us all from eztream cold ; His flesh doth feed both young and old : His tallow makes the candles white, To bum cmd serve us day and night : His skin doth pleasure divers ways. To write, to wear, at all assaies ; His guts, thereof we make wheel-strings ; They use his bones for other things ; His horns some shepherds will not lose. Because therewith they patch their shooes ; His dung is chief, I understand. To help and dung the Plowman's land ; Therefore the Sheep among the rest. He is for man a worthy beast." But Mascall makes no attempt to distinguish varieties of breed. Like many of the Stewart writers, he would probably have answered as the Cumberland shepherd replied to the question — ^where he got his rough-legged, ill-formed sheep—" Lor', sir, they are sik as God set upon the land ; we never change any." Markham, how- ever, distinguishes the various breeds by the quality of their wool. The finest short wool came from the small black-faced Hereford- shire sheep in the neighbourhood of Leominster, and in parts of Worcestershire and Shropshire. The Cotswold breed was heavier, but the wool was longer and straighter in the staple, and the fleece coarser. Parts of Warwickshire and Worcestershire, " all Leicester- shire, Buckinghamshire, and part of Northamptonshire, and that part of Nottinghamshire which is exempt from Shenoood Forest " produced " a large-boned Sheep, of the best shape and deepest 1 Mascedl's book on the Oovemment of CatteU, originally published in 1691, was still in circulation nearly a century later, under the title of The Oounlrey- man's Jewel. The edition of 1680 is said to be " Gathered at first by Leonard Mascal, but much Inlarged by Richard Ruseam, Gent." SHEEP AND PIGS 139 staple." These were pasture sheep, and th«r wool was coarse in qnaJity. The Yorkshire breed was " of reasonable bigge bone, but of a staple rough and hairie." Welsh sheep were to be " praised only in the dish, for they are the sweetest mutton." The Lincohi- shire salt marshes bore the largest animals ; but " their legges and beUies axe long and naked, and their staple is coarser than any other." Mortimer practically repeats Markham's list. But he adds one significant remark. Speaking of Lincolns and the coarseness of their wool, he says : " they are lately much amended in their Breed." Some local pioneer of Bakewell and his Leicesters was already attempting the improvement of Lincolns. Both Markham and Mortimer condemn homed sheep, and advise buyers to choose animals with plenty of bone. Both also repeat the warning of Eitz- herbert and Tusser that on open-field farms lambs must be timed to fall in January. Pigs naturally take a prominent place in the books of " Bustick Authors." They are, says Markham, " troublesome, noysome, unruly, and great ravenours," yet they are " the Hushandmans Best Scavenger, and the Huswifea most wholesome sinke," and, " in the dish, so lovely and so wholesome, that all other faults may be borne with." MascaU quotes as a proverb the common saying : " The hog is never good but when he is in the dish." The natural cleanliness of the animal is strongly urged by all the seventeenth century writers. As to breed, no English county could be said to have a better sort than any other. But Markham thinks the best pigs are raised in Leicestershire, some parts of Northamptonshire, and the clay countries borderii^ on Leicestershire. As to colour, he recommends white or " sanded," or black. But these last are said to be rare. Pied pigs he considers to be more subject to measles. Both he and Mortimer attribute the superiority of Leicestershire and the surrounding districts to the great quantities of beans and pulse which were raised in those counties, and Mortimer Euids that the pigs from those parts of the country were mostly sold in London for use at sea. At the Bicstoration, the greatest need of English farming was the leadership of practical men, possessed of the leisure, the educa- tion, and the capital, to test by experiments the value of a mass of theoretical advice, to adopt new crops, introduce new methods, improve the live-stock of the country. Such pioneers were found, at a later date, among the large landowners. In 1660 they were 140 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION not forthcoming from that or from any other class, and this want of leadership to a great extent explains the reluctance of farmers to put in practice many of the improvements which not only book- farmers but practical agriculturists were recommending. The state of society was stiU too unsettled, the title to land too insecure, to tempt expenditure. The number of men who could afford the necessary outlay was relatively few. Landed property in 1660 was distributed in smaller quantities among more numerous owners than it was a century later. The events of the Commonwealth period had further increased this wide distribution of ownership. Large quantities of land, confiscated by the Parliament, had been thrown on the market. Many estates had also been forfeited to the Government and sold, often in small parcels, because the royalist owners either refused or neglected to compound for their " delinquencies." Portions of other properties had been sold by their owners to pay the composition or the Decimation Tax. In all these cases, numbers of the purchasers were small men. At the Restoration, the estates of the Crown and of the Church, and the confiscated lands of eminent royalists were restored to their original owners, without compensation to purchasers who had bought under the authority of the Commonwealth Government. But no attempt was made to cancel the purchase of lands which had been sold under forfeitures to the ParUament, or under the pressure of the taxation imposed by the victorious Puritans on the vanquished royalists. All claims of this nature were barred by an Act, which disappointed Cavaliers condemned as an act of indemnity to the King's enemies and of obhvion to his friends. But whether the RepubUcans were deprived of their purchases, or confirmed in their possession, the example was not lost on their contemporaries. The nature of the compromise effected at the Restoration necessarily impaired th6 sense of security. When titles were precarious, outlay of capital seemed too speculative a risk. Moreover, many of the royalists who were fortunate enou^ to retaia or regain possession of their estates, found themselves too impoverished to spend money on their improvement, or too formed in their habits to endure the tediousness of directing them. The generations which knew the Civil War, the Commonwealth, the Restoration, the rebellion of Monmouth, and the Revolution bad passed away, before landowners, in widely different circumstances, assumed the lead in agricultural progress. INCREASED INFLUENCE OP LANDED GENTRY 141 Changes were already at work which, within the next half centviry, not only restored the position of the landed gentry, but gave them an influence which they had never before possessed. ParUament gained control over the Government, and the House of Commons over Parliament. At the same time the jurisdiction of magistrates was greatly extended. ControUing the House of Commons through the county elections, administering local justice, allied with the Church as the bulwark of Protestantism, recruiting from its wealthiest members the order of the peerage, absorbing into its own ranks their younger sons, the landed gentry became the pre- dominant class in the country. How great was the increase in their power may be illustrated by the difference in the attitude which Elizabethan and Hanoverian Parliaments assumed towards enclosures. Many of the seeds of this growth in the poUtical and social ascendancy of the landed aristocracy were sown during the period under notice. One of the first questions which came before the Restoration Parliament was that of finance. Some permanent provision had to be made for the ordinary charges of Government. A Committee was appointed which reported that the average yearly income of Charles I. for the period 1637-41 had been £900,000, but that of this sum £200,000 were derived from sources no longer available. Parliament decided to raise the annual income of the Crown to £1,200,000. In providing this sum the lines laid down by the Republican financiers were in the main followed. The cost of the Civil War and the subsequent expenses of the Commonwealth Government had been met by the old device of customs duties, and by the new expedients of monthly assessments on lands and goods, and of excise duties, borrowed from the Dutch financiers, on a large range of products which at one time included meat and salt. The old feudal dues, exacted by the Crown on all lands held by military tenure, had dwindled in importance and value, in spite of the attempts made by Henry Vlll. and Charles I. to enforce them with greater rigour. To a large extent their place had been taken by parliamentary grants of subsidies on lands and goods. Those which remained in operation were comparatively unproductive ; they were besides uneconomical, imcertain, and inconvenient. They were also not granted by Parhament, and thus provided the Crown with funds which were not under national control. Their abolition had been recommended in the reign of James I. ; it had been 142 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION carried by a resolution of both Houses of Parliament in 1645 ; it was one of the terms of the Treaty of Newport in 1648, when Charles I. agreed to surrender the dues for the payment of £100,000 a year ; it had been demanded by Puritan agriculturists like HartUb and Blith ; finally, in 1656 the abolition had been passed into law with the consent of Cromwell. Technically speaking, the legislation of the Commonwealth was annulled by the Restoration ; practically, however, the question was not whether the abolished dues should be continued, but whether they should be revived. Against this revival it was argued in 1660 that much land had changed hands in the previous fifteen years without any provision for the possible revival of the liability. The income voted for Charles 11. had to be provided, the problem of ways and means to be solved. The Restoration ParUament might have abandoned the excise duty, or revived the feudal dues, or substituted for them a land tax. They retained the excise introduced by Republican financierSj but reduced it by a half ; they confirmed Cromwell's aboUtion of the emolu- ments which the Crown had derived from lands held in chivalry ; * they declined by a majority of two votes to impose a land tax. At the same time the Crown smrendered its oppressive prerogatives of purveyance and pre-emption. No doubt the immediate result of these fiscal changes was that the landed aristocracy continued to be relieved from a burden, and that, from motives of self-interest, they refused to revive, either in its original or in a substituted form, a system of taxation which, before the Commonwealth, had once attached to land held in chivalry. The abolition of military tenures reduced to some extent the necessary outgoings of many of the landed gentry. At the same time the commercial policy adopted by the Restoration Grovemment maintained, if it did not swell, their incomes. The steady rise in the price of wool during the past century had begun to hamper the clothing trade. In order to lower prices for home manufacturers, an Act passed in 1647, oad re-eoaoted in 1660, prohibited ita exportation. Still further to stimulate the clothing industry, a series of Acts,* from 1666 onwards, ordered the burial of the dead in woollen fabrics. Partly for revenue, partly in compensation for these concessions to manufacturing industries, partly to meet the claims of impoverished adherents, partly to maintain the balance between pasture and tillage, partly, no doubt, to make England 1 12 Cor. n. c. 24. > 18 and 19 Cor. n. c. 4. REGULATION OF THE CORN TRADE 143 self-supporting in its food supplies, important changes were made in the laws which regulated the trade in com.'^ In the reign of Philip and Mary, home-grown com could not be exported if home- prices for wheat rose above 6s. 8d. per quarter, and for cheaper grains in proportion. This limit was raised by subsequent legisla- tion. Thus the home price for wheat, at which exportation was prohibited, was raised in 1593 to 20s., in 1604 to 26s. 8d., in 1623 to 32s., in 1660 to ^Oa.,^ in 1663 to 483.^ In 1660 duties were also imposed on the importation of foreign wheat. These duties were at first nominal. Thus they started at 2s. per quarter on imported wheat, when home-prices exceeded 44s. In 1663 they were raised to 58. 4d. per quarter, when home-grown wheat rose above 48s. In 1670 * the com laws became more frankly protective. No limit of price was fixed above which the exportation of home-grown com was prohibited, and a heavy duty of 16s. a quarter was imposed on foreign wheat when home prices did not exceed 53s. 4d. per quarter. Similar duties were imposed on the importation of other foreign grain at proportionate prices. A further change was made in 1688.^ The Act of that year offered a bounty on the export of home-grown com of 5s. per quarter of wheat, whenever the home-price fell below 48s. per quarter, and on other grain in pro- portion. On these two principles, namely a duty on the importation of foreign com and a bounty on the exportation of home-grown com, combined with frequent prohibitions of exports, the com trade was regulated Hiroughout the eighteenth century. Similar measures were adopted to encourage the raising of cattle, and importations from Ireland were prohibited. Legislation did not, however, raise prices ; it only succeeded in maintaining them. Increased production at home counteretcted the efEect which the restriction of imports might otherwise have produced. England, says Sir William Petty,* " doeth so abound in Victuals as that it maketh Laws against the Importation of Cattle, Flesh and Fish from abroad ; and that the draining of Fens, im- proving of Forests, inclosing of Commons, Sowing of St. Foyne and Glover-grass be grumbled against by Landlords, as the Way to depress the price of Victuals." Elsewhere he adds : I See Appendix m. The Com Laws. ' 12 Car. II. c. 4. » 15 Car. n. o. 7. « 22 Car. U. o. 13. e 1 William and Mary, c. 12. *5ei;era2 Easaya in PoUMccU Arithmetic, ed. 175S, pp. 150-169. 144 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION " it is manifest that the land in its present Condition is able to bear more Provision and Commodities, than it was forty years ago." Throughout the period from the Restoration to the Revolution, except for one disa^strous year of plague, fire, and war, the country prospered. The receipts from customs steadily advanced. Trade was expanding. As Amsterdam decayed, and Portuguese and Spanish Jews fled to England to escape the Liquisition, money flowed into the country. Other religious refugees brought with them useful arts and manufactures. The development of banking stimulated commercial undertakings. Between 1661 and 1687 the receipts from the customs duties more than doubled. Fortunes, made in the city were often invested in land, which now was begin- ning to confer on its possessors a new poUtical and social influence. The landed gentry shared in the growing prosperity, either through its general effects on the country, or by wealthy marriages, or by sending their sons — as Rashleigh Osbaldistone was sent by Sir Hildebrand — ^into business. Between 1675 and 1700, said Sir WiUiam Temple " the first noble famihes married into the City." ^ Latimer had preached against landlords becoming " graziers," and aldermen turning " colliers," and disquietude at this commercial tendency had influenced the legislation of Edward VI. But times had changed. Though Heralds still distinguished between " foreign Merchants " and retail shopkeepers, on the ground apparently that " Navigation was the only laudable part of all buying and selling," yet they ^ had solemnly decided that " if a Gentleman be bound an Apprentice to a Merchant, or other Trade, he hath not thereby lost his Degree of Gentility." Closely united with the nobility, the Church, and the merchant princes, sharing in the general prosperity, and, in virtue of their property, exercising new political and social powers, the landed gentry were beginning to acquire that predominant influence which was so marked a feature in the eighteenth century. The change necessarily added an artificial value to the ownership of land : it not only arrested the tendency towards its wider distribution, but encouraged its accumulation in fewer hands. Once acquired, estates were held together by the introduction of family settle- ' Quoted by Toynbee, Indu»trM Revolution, ed. 1887, p. 63. ' Logan's Treatise of Honor at the end of Gwillim's Display of Heraldry (ed. 1679), p. 155. AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS IN 1696 146 ments. On the eve of this change, it may be of interest to note a contemporary estimate of the agricultural population and wealth of the country at the close of the eighteenth cen- tury. -_ Gregory King, whose training and experience specially qualified him for the task, drew up a statistical accoimt of the " State and Condition " of England and Wales in 1696. His estimates of the actual numbers of the population are the result of an investigation by a competent and careful observer, who made the fuUest use of the information supplied by such figures as those contained in the Hearth-office, the assessments on Births, Marriages, and Burials, the Parish Registers, and Public Accounts. The substantial accuracy of this part of his work has stood the test of subsequent criticism, in spite of his prophecy that in 1900 the population would have risen to 7,350,000. For the rest of his estimates he mainly depended on guess-work. Confidence is scarcely created by his laborious calculation of the numbers of hares, rabbits, and wild fowl in the country. King's figures were largely used by Davenant,'^ but his actual maxiuscript remained unpublished tall 1801 .« King estimated the total acreage of England and Wales at 39 million ^ acres ; of which 11 million acres were arable, averaging a yearly rent per acre of 5s. lOd. ; and 10 million were meadow or pasture, averaging 9s. an acre. Of the 11 million arable acres, ten million were imder the plough for com, pease, beans, and vetches ; one million acres were allotted to flax, hemp, safiron, woad and other dyeing weeds, etc. He goes on to calculate the live-stock of the country thus : " horses (and asses)," 600,000 ; cattle, 4| million ; sheep, 11 million ; pigs, 2 million. The total population in 1696 is estimated at 5,500,000 persons, distributed into 1,400,000 urban, and 4,100,000 rural, inhabitants. The total yearly income of the nation in 1688 is calculated at £43,500,000. Of this total, con- ' An Essay upon the Probable Methods of making a People Oainers in the BaUance of Trade, by Caiarles Davenant, 1698 (Section I. "Of the People of England," and Section II. " Of the Land of England and its Product "). * Published in An Estimate of the Convparative Strength of Oreat Britain, by George Chalmers (1802), under the title of " Natural and Political ObsOTva- tions and Conclusions upon the State and Condition of England, 1696 ; by Gregory King, Esq., Lancaster Herald." > The actual figure is 37,319,221 acres. K 146 LATER STEWARTS AND THE REVOLUTION siderably more than half (£24,480,000) belonged to the followii^ families : Yearly Income. 40,000 Freeholders 1 of the better sort £84 140,000 Freeholders of the lesser sort - - 50 150,000 Fanners - - - 44 364,000 Labouring People and Out-servants - 16 400,000 Cottagers and Paupers - 6 10 0^ King's estimates bring into strong relief the vast revolution which the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries produced in the dis- tribution of population and of wealth. The same point is illustrated from a difierent point of view by a comparison of the wealth of the different counties in 1696 and at the present day. Material for such a comparison is found in the frequent assessments which were made of the counties during the seventeenth century for various fiscal purposes. The central counties are the richest ; then follow in order of wealth the south, the east, the west. Poorest of all is the north. Throughout the whole period, Middlesex is the richest and Cumberland the poorest county. The most conspicuous change was that of Surrey, which rose from the eighteenth place in 1636 to the second in 1693. Excluding Middlesex, and excepting Surrey, the wealthiest district throughout the whole period was formed by a block of six agricultural counties north of the Thames — ^namely Hertfordshire, Bedfordshire, Buckinghamshire, Berkshire, Oxford- shire, and Northamptonshire. Their position illustrates the im- portance of London as a market for agricultural produce. Already its rapid growth was exciting alarm, lest " the Head " should become " too big for the Body." According to Gregory King, its popula- tion was 530,000 souls out of an urban population of 1,400,000, and a total population, urban and rural, of 6| millions. Throughout the whole period, again, the seven poorest counties, though their order in the list varies, were Cheshire, Derbyshire, Yorkshire, Lancashire, Northumberland, Durham, and Cumberland. The assessment of the whole district north of the Humber, comprising one-fifth of the total area of England, was not greater than that of ' It should be noted that freeholders included not only owners emd occupy- ing owners, but tenants for life and lives, ae well as copyholders. * For tables of estimates drawn up by King and Davenant, see Appendix IV. POVERTY OF THE NORTH OF ENGLAND 147 Wiltshire. In the latter half of the following century not only wealth bnt popnlation migrated northwards, and the inhabitants of rural districts began to flow into the centres of trade and manu- facture which crowded round the coal and iron fields and water- power of the northern counties. CHAPTER VII. JETHRO TULL AND LORD TOWNSHEND. 1700-1760. Agricultural piogiess in the eighteenth century ; enclosures necessary to advance ; advocates and opponents of the enclosing movement ; area of uncultivated land and of land cultivated in open-fields ; defects of the open-field system as a method of farming ; pasture commons as adjuncts to open-field holdings ; the necessary lead in agricultural progress given by large landoimers and large formers ; procedure in enclosures by Act of Parliament : varying dates at which districts have been enclosed : influence of soil and climate in breaking up or maintaining the open-field system : the East Midland and North Eastern group of counties : improved methods and increased resources of farming ; Jethro Tull the " greatest individual improver " ; Lord Townshend's influence on Norfolk husbandry. The gigantic advance of agriculture in the nineteenth century dwarfs into insignificance any previous rate of progress. Yet the change between 1700 and 1800 was astonishing. England not only produced food for a population that had doubled itself, as well as grain for treble the number of horses, but dining the first part of the period became, as M. de Lavergne has said, the granary of Europe. Population before 1760 grew so slowly that the soil, without any great increase in farming skill or in cultivated area, produced a surplus. Under the spur of the bounty, land which had been converted to pasture was again ploughed for com, and proved by its yield that it had profited by the prolonged rest. The price of wheat, between the years 1713 and 1764, in spite of large exports, averaged 34s. lid. per quarter ; poor-rates fell below the level of the precediog century ; real wages were higher than they had been since the reign of Henry VI. In England, at least, there was little civil war or tumult, no glut of the labour market, no sudden growth of an artisan class. The standard of living improved. Instead of the salted carcases of half-starved and aged oxen, fresh meat began to be eaten by the peasantry. Wheaten bread ceased to be a luxury of the wealthy, and, at the accession of George III. had become the THE PEASANTS' GOLDEN AGE 149 bread-stnff of half the population. Politically and morally, the period was coirapt and coarse ; materially, it was one of the Golden Ages of the peasant. The only drawbacks to the general prosperity of agriculture during the first half of the century were the visita- tions of the rot, and of the cattle plague. Ellis ^ speaks of the rot in 1735 aa " the most general one that has happened in the memory of man . . . the dead bodies of rotten sheep were so numerous in roads, lanes, and fields, that their carrion stench and smell proved extremely offensive to the neighbouring parts and the passant travellers." A newer and more mysterious scourge was the cattle plague. Starting in Bohemia, it travelled westward, devastated the north of France, and three times visited England. The only remedy was to slaughter infected animals ; in a single year the Government, paying one-third of the value, expended £135,000 in compensation. The great changes which English agriculture witnessed as the eighteenth century advanced, and particularly after the accession of George m. (1760), are, broadly speaking, identified with Jethro Tull, Lord Townshend, Bakewell of Dishley, Arthur Young, and Coke of Norfolk. With their names are associated the chief characteristics in the farming progress of the period, which may be summed up in the adoption of improved methods of cultivation, the introduction of new crops, the reduction of stock-breeding to a science, the provision of increased facUities of communication and of transport, and the enterprise and outlay of capitalist landlords and tenant-farmers. The improvements which these pioneers initiated, taught, or exemplified, enabled England to meet the strain of the Napoleonic wars, to bear the burden of additional taxation, and to feed the vast centres of commercial industry which sprang up, as if by magic, at a time when food supphes could not have been provided from another country. Without the substitu- tion of separate occupation for the ancient system of common cul- tivation, this agricultural progress was impossible. But in carrying out the necessary changes, rural society was convulsed, and its general conditions revolutionised. The divorce of the peasantry from the soil, and the extinction of commoners, open-field farmers, and eventually of small freeholders, were the heavy price which the natiop ultimately paid for the supply of bread and meat to its manufacturing population. 1 Bhepherd'a Sure Chude, 1749. 160 JETHRO TULL AND LORD TOWNSHEND Neither the reclamation of wastes, nor the break-up of open- field farms, nor the appropriation of commons, were novelties. For the last three centuries the three processes, which are generally spoken of as enclosures, had all been proceeding at varying rates of progress. Sut in the period from 1760 to 1815 each received an immense impetus, partly from the rise in the price of com, partly from the consequent increase in rental values, partly from the pressure of a growing population, partly from the improved standard of agriciilture. The literary struggle in advocacy or condemnation of enclosures still continued. But the advocates were gaining the upper hand. In the first half of the eighteenth century, there are at least two notable contributions to the literature of the subject by champions of enclosures, and only one of any importance by an opponent. By the new writers, the unprofitable nature of the use of land under common tillage or common pasture is insisted upon. Thus Timothy Nourse, Oent., in his Campania Fodix ; or Discourse of the Benefits and Im^ovemerUs of Husbandry (1700), vigorously attacks commons as " Seminaries of a lazy Thieving sort of People." In his opinion their live-stock were as unprofitable to the community as the commoners themselves. Their sheep are described as " poor, tatter'd, and poyson'd with the Rot," their cattle " as starv'd. Tod- bellied Runts, neither fit for the Dairy nor the Yoke." So, also, an anonymous author in a short and pithy tract. An Old Almanack {vnth some considerations for improving commons) printed in 1710. With a Postscript (1734-5), suggests that, if the landowner and two- thirds, in number and value, of those interested in an open-field farm and common agreed to an enclosure, their consent should override the opposition of the minority. " Will the Oommumers cornplmn," he asks, " for want of their Commonage ? This they can't do, for few of them have any Cattle, and whether they have or not, there is Recompence out of the Inclosures will more than treble their Loss ? Will the Incumbents complain ? What ! for converting the dry Commons into Com, and the Fenns into Hemp and Flax. WiU the Ingrossers of Commons complain, who eat wp their own Share and others too ? This they dare not. But won't (hose honest Men complain who now live upon the Thefts of Common ? And not with the least Reason, but then there will be Work for them." But the two important advocates of enclosures 'were the brothers John and Edward Laurence. In A New System of Agriculture (1726) a note JOHN AND EDWARD LAURENCE 151 is struck which sounded more loudly as toMois grew, as, with their growth, the demand increased for meat, milk, and butter, as agri- culture improved, as communication was facilitated. The author, the Rev. John Laurence, Rector of Bishops Wearmouth, treats open-field farms as obstacles to agricultural progress. He insists on enclosures and separate occupation as the best means of increas- ing produce and of raising rents. He dwells on the rapid progress which enclosures were then making, points out the great rise in rental value consequent on increased produce, and argues that so far from injuring the poor, enclosures will rather create a new demand for labour by the introduction of improved tillage and pasture- farming, wiU give employment in fencing and ditching, and remove the attractions of wastes and open spaces, which " draw to them the poor and necessitous only for the advantage of pilfering and stealing." In The Duty of a Steward to his Lord (1727) Edward Laurence, himself a land-surveyor, and apparently agent to the Duke of Buckingham, argues the case from the point of view of better and more economical management. A new skilled pro- fession was growing up. It is prophetic of future changes that Laurence points out the evils of employing " country- Attomejrs 2 Ben. VI. Act iv. So. 7, L 62. > Ric. III. Act iii. Sc. 4, 1. 83. IHen. V. Act iii. Sc. 7, 1. 17. Comp. also Fen. amd Ad. st. 60, where Blondevill is closely copied. • Cymh. Act iii. Sc. 2, 11. 72-4. * Bom. and Jul. Act ii. Sc. 4, 1. 75. ' Much Ado, Act i. Sc. 1, 1. 149. ' Mid. N. D. Act iv. So. 1, 1. 129. • Macb. Act ii. Sc. 4, 1. 12. >• 2 Hen. VI. Act iii. So. 1, 1. 261. HORSES FOR " COURSE, CHASE, WAR, OR TRAVEL " 183 the fox was no foe to crops ; hedgerows only added zest to his pursuit ; the new sport satisfied the new conditions, and demanded the prodaction of the modem hunter. The seventeenth century saw some of the conditions created which have developed the various types in horses of to-day. James I. reduced racing to rules ; Charles I. estabUshed races at New- market ; Oliver Cromwell kept his stud ; Charles 11. introduced the "Royal Mares." Changes in the art of war demanded a lighter and more active cavalry. Pox-himting had become a passion with the country gentry. Coaches travelled more rapidly. Oxen were less used on the farm. During the same century, foreign breeds were extensively imported. Arabs were favourites of James I. But the authority of the Duke of Newcastle, who disliked the breed, was paramount ia matters of horse-flesh.^ Barbs, or Turks were preferred till the Grodolphin and Darley Arabians proved worthy rivals to the Byerly Turk. Other breeds were largely imported from Naples, Sardinia, Spain, Poland, Germany, Hungary, Flanders, and Libya. So great was the admixture of blood, that Bradley, writing in 1727, thinks the true-bred English horse hardly exists, " unless we may account the Horses to be such that are bred wild in some of our Forests and among the Mountains." * Horses intended for " the Course, the Chase, War or Travel " were already carefully studied. But horses for faria use were as yet despised. De Grey ^ speaks with contempt of horses for the cart, the plough, the pack-saddle, and Bradley ignores them altogether. It was with the heavy Black-horse of the Midland counties that Bakewell conducted his experiments. The breed had long been known, and had doubtless helped to supply mounts to mediaeval knights. Early in the eighteenth century the breed had been improved by the importation of six Zealand mares. But the long back and long thick hairy legs were still characteristic. Defoe speaks of the Leicestershire horse as the " largest in England, being generally the great black Coach-Horses and Dray-Horses, of which so great a Number are continually brought up to London." Bake- well's object was to correct the type to that which was best suited > Me(hode et Invention NouveUe de dresser les Chevaux (1668). Kew- castle's experiments were made -with Barbs. The Duke also published in 1667 A New Method and Extraordinary Invention to Dress Horses, etc. * OenUeman and Partners Quids, p. 249. * The CompUat Horseman and Expert Ferrier, by Thomas de Orey (6th ed. 1684), p. 8. 184 STOCKBREEDER'S ART AND ROBERT BAKEWELL for draft. Strength and activity rather than height and weight were his aim. In his hands the Black Horse developed a thick short carcase on clean short legs. Marshall, who visited Dishley in 1784, grows enthusiastic over " the grandeur and symmetry of form " displayed in the stallion named K. " He was, in reality, the fancied war-horse of the German painters ; who, in the luxuri- ance of imagination, never perhaps excelled the grandeur of this horse." The Midland horses were generally sold as two-year-olds to the farmers of Buckinghamshire, Hertfordshire, Berkshire, and Wiltshire, who broke them into harness, worked them lightly on the land, and sold them at five or six to London dealers. The practice may account for some of the extravagant plough-teams, which agricultural writers of the eighteenth century often notice and condemn. Bom in 1725, Bakewell was barely twenty when he began his experiments in stock-breeding. He succeeded to the sole manage- ment of his father's farm in 1760. Ten years later, when Arthur Young, armed with an introduction from the Marquis of Rockingham, visited Dishley, Bakewell must have somewhat resembled the typical English yeoman who figures on jugs of Staffordshire pottery : "a tall, broad-shouldered, stout man of brown-red com- plexion, clad in a loose brown coat, scarlet waistcoat, leather breeches, and top-boots." Visitors from all parts of the world assembled to see his farm — his water-canals, his plough-team of cows, his irrigated meadows on which mowers were busy from May to Christmas, and, above all, his Uve-stock — his famous black stallion, his buU " Two-penny," and his ram " Two-pounder." All who came were astonished at the results which they saw, at the docility of the animals, at the kindness with which they were treated. But, if they hoped to learn from Bakewell's Ups the principles which are now the axioms of stock-breeding, they went away disappointed. He was a keen man of business. The secrets of his success were jealously guarded, except from the old shepherd to whom they were confided. So careful was he to keep the lead in his own hands that he adopted the practice of only letting his staJlions, bulls, and rams by the season, and, when his best bred sheep were past service and fatted and sold to the butcher, he is said to have infected them with the rot ia order to prevent their use for breeding purposes. So reports Artiiur Young.^ Round ^ Farmere Tow thrpugh the East of England (1771), vol. i. p. 118. "SMALL IN SIZE, GREAT IN VALUE" 185 the hall of his house were arranged skeletons of his most celebrated animals ; from the walls hung joints, preserved in pickle, which illustrated such points as smaUness of bone or thickness of fat. As there was no inn in the vUlage, he seems to have kept open house for his visitors. He was never married. In his kitchen he enter- tained Russian princes, French and Grerman royal dukes, British peers, and sightseers of every degree. Yet he never altered the routine of his daily life. " Breakfast at eight ; dinner at one ; supper at nine ; bed at eleven o'clock ; at half-past ten, let who would be there, he knocked out his last pipe." Very large sums of money passed through his hands. Yet, if the entry in the GenUe- man'e Magazine ^ refers to him, he was bankrupt in 1776, and so lavish was his hospitaUty that he is said to have died in poverty.^ In the treatment of live-stock for the butcher BakeweU's object was to breed animals which weighed heaviest ia the best joints and most quickly repaid the cost of the food they consumed. He sought to discover the animal which was the best machine for turning food into money. " Small in size and great in value," or the Holkham toast of " Symmetry well covered," was the motto of his experiments. In his view the essentials were the valuable joints, and he swept away as non-essentials all the points on which fashion or prejudice had hitherto concentrated, such as head, neck, horn, leg, or colour. The points which he wished to develop and perpetuate were beauty combined with utility of form, quality of flesh, and propensity to fatness. To attain these objects he struck out a new line for himself. Crossing was then understood to mean the mixture of two aUen breeds, one of which was relatively inferior. Bakewell adopted a different principle, because he regarded this form of crossing as an adulteration rather than as an improvement. He bred in-and-in, using not merely animals of the same native breed and line of descent, but of the same family. He thus secured the union of the finest specimens of the breed which he had chosen as the best, selected for the possession of the points which he wished to reproduce or strengthen. ^ In the Oent. Mag. for Nov. 1776, appears the following entry in the list of bankrupts : " B. Bakewell, Dishley, Leicestersh. dealer." (p. 531). * Other contemporary references to Bakewell, besides those quoted, will be found in the Oent. Mag. vols. bdii. pt. ii. p. 792, and Ixv. pt. ii. pp. 969-70 ; Marshall's Midland Counties, voL i. pp. 292-493 etc. ; Annah of Agrioulture, voL vi. (1786), pp. 466-98 ; Arthur Young's Huabandry of Three Famout Farmers (1811) ; George Culley's Observations on Live Stock (1786). 186 STOCKBREEDER'S ART AND ROBERT BAKEWELL It was with sheep that Bakewell achieved his greatest success. When he began his stock-breeding experiments, he selected his fiheep from the best animals in the neighbourhood, and a guinea, or even half a guinea, secured HiTn his choice from the fold. The breed from which they were chosen were the Leicestershire or Warwickshire long wools. The " true old Warwickshire ram " is thus described by Marshall in 1789 : " His frame large, and remark- ably loose. His bone, throughout, heavy. His legs long and thick, terminating in large splaw feet. His chine, as well as his romp, as sharp as a hatchet. His skin might be said to rattle upon his ribs . . . like a skeleton wrapped in parchment." Even this animal -was handsomer than a ram of the " true old Leicestershire sort," which Marshall saw in 1784. " A naturalist," he says, " would have found some difficulty in classing him ; and, seeing him on a mountain, might have deemed him a nondescript ; a something between a sheep and a goat." Out of these unpromising materials Bakewell succeeded in creating a new variety. His " new Leicesters " became the most profitable sheep for arable farmers. As by degrees the compactness of form, smaUness of bone, fattening propensities, and early maturity were perpetuated, the breed was established, and for a time swept all competitors before them. While other breeds required three or four years to fit them for market, the New Leicesters were prepared in two. Those who tried the Dishley sheep found that they throve where others pined, that while aUve they were the hardiest, and when dead the heaviest. In 1750 Bakewell let rams for the season at 16s. or 17s. 6d. apiece. In 1789 he let none under 20 guineas, and received 3000 guineas for the total of that season's letting. The New Leicesters were the first breed of sheep which were scientifically treated in England, and though they were less adapted for the southern, eastern, and northern counties, their supremacy on enclosed land in their own Midland districts was undisputed. Bakewell raised the New Leicesters to the highest })erfection. But this was not all. His breed in weight of fleece could not com- pete with Idncolns, and was less suited to hills or mountains than for enclosed arable land. He had, however, shown the way in which other breeds might be improved ; imitation was easy. In a less immediate sense he was the creator, not only of the New Leicesters, but of the improved Lincolns, South Downs and Cheviots. Before these breeds, fitted for the most fertile grasslands and plains LEICESTER SHEEP AND CATTLE 187 as well as suited to hills and mountains, native races died away, like Red TTiflin.Tm before the civilised intruders. But gradually supporters raUied round other varieties. Bakewell's weapons were turned against himself. Native sheep of other districts, improved on his principles, began to hold their own, and, though on historical grounds precedence wOI always be given to the New Leicesters and the South Downs (improved by John Ellman of Glynde, 1753-1832), it may be questioned whether they have not been rivalled and sur- passed by other breeds in the qualities for which they were once pre-eminent. Li cattle-breeding BakeweU was less successful. It was his material not his system which failed. He endeavoured to found his typical race on the Lancashires or Craven Longhoms, which were the favourite cattle in Leicestershire, and, in his opinion, the best breed in England. He based his improvements on the labours of two of his predecessors. Sir Thomas Gresley of Drakelow, near Burton-on-Trent, began about 1720 the formation of a herd of Longhoms. On this Drakelow blood Webster of Canley, near Coventry, worked, and to his breed aU the improved Longhoms traced their descent. BakeweU founded his experiments on a Westmoreland bull and two heifers from the Canley herd. To them he applied the same principles which he followed in sheep- breeding, and with great success. As graziers' stock, the breed was greatly improved. But as milkers, the new Longhoms were deteriorated by their increased propensity to fatness. In a county like Leicestershire, which depended not only on feeding stock but on dairy produce,^ this poverty of milking quality was a fatal objec- tion. Even in his Longhoms BakeweU did not long retain the lead. It soon passed away from him to Fowler of BoUright, in Oxfordshire. But the breed itself was beaten by one which possessed superior natural quaUties. Almost throughout England the Durham Shorthorns, founded on the Holdemess and Tees- water cattle, jumped into the first place, as the best rent-payers, both as milkers and meat-producers. The Ketton herd of Charles Colling became to cattle-breeders what BakeweU's Dishley flock of ' Mrs. Paulet of Wymondham, in the Melton district of Leicestershiie, is said to have been the first maker of Stilton cheeses. She supplied them to Cooper Thomhill, who kept the Bell Inn at Stilton (Hunts) on the great norih road from London to Edinburgh, and they became famous among his customers, and throughout England. The manufacture of Stilton cheeses became an industry of the district. Mrs. Paulet vras still living in 1780. 188 STOCKBREEDER'S ART AND ROBERT BAKEWELL New Leicesters were to sheep-masters. It was as necessary for a superior Shorthorn to claim descent from Colhng's bull " Hubback " as for a race-horse to boast the blood of the Godolphin Arabian. From " Hubback " was descended the famous Durham ox, which travelled through England in a specially constructed carriage from 1801 to 1810, exhibiting to the eyes of thousands of farmers a truer standard of shape than any their ancestors had conceived, and con- vincing them by personal interviews of the excellence of the improved breed. The example was followed in many parts of the country. Other breeds, notably the Herefords and North Devons, were similarly improved. The formation of herds became a favourite pursuit of wealthy landlords. Flora Maclvor herself might have lived to see the day, when coimtry gentlemen could become breeders of cattle, without being " boorish two-legged steers like Killan- cureit." Bakewell's success and the rapidly increasing demand for butcher's meat raised up a host of imitators. Breeders everywhere followed his example ; his standard of excellence was gradually recognised. The foundation of the Smithfield Club in 1798 did much to promote the improvement of Uve-stock. Some idea of the effect produced may be gathered from the average weights of sheep and cattle sold at Smithfield Market in 1710 and in 1795. In 1710 the average weights for beeves was 370 lbs., for calves 50 lbs., for sheep 28 lbs., for lambs 18 lbs. In 1795 beeves had risen in average weight to 800 lbs., calves to 148 lbs., sheep to 80 lbs., lambs to 50 Ibs.^ This enormous addition to the meat supply of the country, was due partly to the efforts of agriculturists like Tull, Townshend, Bake- well, and others, partly to the enclosure of open-fields and com- mons which their improvements encouraged. On open-fields and commons, owing mainly to the scarcity of winter keep, the live- stock was dwarfed in size and weight. Even if the number of animals which might be grazed on the commons was regulated by custom, the stint was often so large that the pasture could only cany the smallest animals. Where the grazing rights were unlimited, as seems to have been not unusually the case in the eighteenth century, the herbage was necessarily still more im- poverished, and the size of the Uve-stock more stunted. On * Sir John Sinclair's note for the use of the Select Parliamentary Committee appointed in 179S to consider " the Waste, UninoloBed and unproductive Lands of the Kingdom." Appendix B, section 1, pp. 17, note. Sir John is ^ not, however, always a reliable witness. MUTTON VERSUS WOOL 189 enclosed land, on the other hand, the introduction of turnip and clover husbandry doubled the number and weight of the stock which the land would carry, and the early maturity of the improved breeds enabled farmers to fatten them more expeditiously. But one of the consequences of this change in sheep-farming was not at first foreseen. The wool was sacrificed to the mutton. A large sheep paid better than a small. But as the size of the animal increased, its fleece grew heavier, and the staple longer. The supply of fine fleeces from the Ught, poorly-fed, short-wooled sheep of the com- mons diminished so rapidly that, before the end of the century, a new classification of sheep was introduced. Instead of being divided into long wools and short wools, they were now classified as long wools and middle wools. Improvements in machinery and the introduction of new fabrics utilised the produce of the heavier breeds of sheep ; but, for the better kinds of cloth, home manufac- turers became increasingly dependent on foreign suppUes of short wool, brought from Spain, Saxony, and New South Wales. A change of fashion intensified the need of wool for a finer quaUty of cloth than could be obtained in this country. The coarser fabrics of manufacture from English material, which had contented our ancestors, could not retain their hold on the home or foreign markets. During the Napoleonic wars, the fuU effect of this change in the raw material of woollen manufactures was concealed by the suspension of continental rivalry. When peace was finally pro- claimed, it was at once felt. A pitched battle began between the manufacturer and the agriculturist ; the one demanded the free import of foreign short wool, the other the free export of English long wools, which made better prices abroad. Each resisted the demand of the other. Home manufacturers opposed the free export of British long-wools, because they feared the competition of foreign cloth. British farmers opposed the free import of foreign short wool, because they dreaded lest its introduction would force down the price of their home produce. Finally, in 1826, Lord Liver- pool's government took off the duties both on the import and the export of the raw material. To advocates of enclosiures, the last agricultural defence of the open-field farmer and commoner seemed to be destroyed, when the removal of the import duty deprived the fleeces of their halt-starved sheep of all artificial advantages over the finer and cheaper wools of foreign countries. CHAPTER IX. ARTHUR YOUNG AND THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE. 1760-1800. The counties distingviished for the best fanning : Hertfordshire, Essex, Sufiolk, Norfolk, Leicestershire : the low general standard ; Arthur Young ; his crusade against bad farming, and the hindrances to progress ; waste land ; the " Goths and Vandals " of open-field farmers : want of capital and education ; insecurity of tenure ; prejudices and traditional practices ; impassable roads ; rapid development of manufacture demands a change of agricultural front : Young's advocacy of capitalist landlords and large tenant-farmers. DuEiNG the first three quarters of the eighteenth century many advances had been made in the theory, and some in the practice, of agriculture. Alternations of crops and the management of live- stock were better understood. But progress was still confined to localities, if not to individuals. Only in such counties as Hertford- shire, Essex, Sufiolk, Norfolk, and Leicestershire was a fair standard of farming generally established. The superior enterprise of these favoured districts was due to various causes, and was displayed in different directions. Without any special fertility of soil, Hertfordshire had for the last hundred years enjoyed the reputation of being the best com county in England. To some extent it owed its superiority to the neighbourhood of London. But Middlesex, which shared the same advantage, was relatively backward. In Hertfordshire roads were above the average. In Middlesex turnpike roads, in spite of a large revenue from tolls, are described as " very bad." On the main road from Tyburn to Uxbridge, in the winter of 1797-8, there was but " one passable track, and that was less than six feet wide, and was eight inches deep in fluid mud. All the rest of the road was from a foot to eighteen inches deep in adhesive mud." Hert- fordshire, which had been to a great extent covered with forest. HERTFORDSHIRE FARMING 191 contained, at the close of the eighteenth century, few open-field farms and an inconsiderable area of commons, which were practi- cally confined to the chalk districts in the north of the county. In Middlesex, on the other hand, 17,000 a«res, or one-tenth of the county, were commons, and, out of 23,000 arable acres, 20,000 were cultivated in open-field farms. The neighbourhood of London probably accounts for the predominance of pasture. Hertford- shire had been, for many years, an enclosed county, divided into small estates, and small farms conveniently varied in size. Unlike Middlesex, it was almost entirely arable. Its farmers had at once appreciated the value of turnips and clover, for which the soil was well adapted. Both crops must have been adopted within a few years after their first introduction into the country, if there is any truth in the tradition that Ohver Cromwell paid £100 a year to a Hertfordshire farmer named Howe for their successful cultivation.* Other useful practices were established at an early date. William Ellis of Gaddesden* (died 1758), a Hertfordshire farmer whose writings enjoyed a short-lived popularity, attributed the reputa- tion of " this our celebrated county " to four principal means of improvement : " good ploughings, mixing earths, dunging and dressing, resting the ground with sown grasses." The Hertford- shire men were clean farmers. Their ploughmen were so celebrated that the county was " accounted a Nursery for skill in that Pro- fession." Chalk was largely used on heavy clays, and red clay on sandy or gravelly soUs. Nor were the advantages gained by neigh- bourhood to a great city neglected. London refuse was HberaUy bought and freely employed. Large quantities " of soot, coney- cHppings, Horn-shavings, Rags, Hoofs-hajr, ashes " were purchased from " Mr. Atkins in Tummill-Street near Clerkenwd." To these were added, when Walker * wrote his report on the county, bones — boiled or burned — sheep-trotters, and malt-dust. Great numbers of sheep were also folded, mostly bought at Tring Fair from West- country drovers. But the peculiar practice of Hertfordshire farmers, in which EUis took the greatest pride, was the sowing of tares on the turnip fallows as green fodder for horses in May. '■ Oeneral View of the Agriculture of Hertfordshire, by Arthur Young (1804), p. 65. * E.g. ChiUem and Vale Farming explained (1733) ; The Modem Huaband- man, 8 vols. (1760). • OeriercU View of the AgrieuUwre of the County of Hertford, by D. Walker (1796). 192 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE Young (1770) states that, while in other counties the land lay idle, these crops fed five horses to the acre for a month, at 2s. 6d. each a week. It was on these crops that Hertfordshire farmers reared the horses which they bought as two-year-olds in Leicestershire. Yet at the begiiming of the nineteenth century the example had been rarely followed in other counties. Suffolk and Essex also afforded good examples of the best EngUsh farming as it was practised at the close of the eighteenth century. Both counties had, as a whole, been enclosed for many years. Only on the poor and chalky soil of the north-western district had open- fields held their own. As early as 1618,^ East Suffolk and Mid Suffolk were enclosed, and only " the westeme parts ether wholly champion or neer." In both counties yeomanry abounded, and in Essex the class was in 1807 stiH increasing. " For twenty or thirty years past scarcely an estate is sold, if divided into lots of forty or fifty to two or three hundred a year but is purchased by farmers."* Both counties were centres of manufacturing industries, and in addition enjoyed the advantage of access to a great market. Suffolk suppHed London with butter, Essex with calves, for which it had been famous in the seventeenth century. In both counties large quantities of manure were now used on the land. Farmers were not always so energetic. Under a lease of 1753 a tenant of the Suffolk manor of Hawsted was allowed two shillings for every load of manure which he brought from Bury and laid on the land. In a tenancy of twenty-one years only one load was charged to the landlord. Sixty years later, agriculturists had become more energetic. On the Ught sands of East Suffolk, marl and a calcareous shelly mixture of phosphates called " crag " were freely employed as fertilisers. Chalk from the Kentish quarries for use on the cla;^, as well as London refuse, were purchased by Essex farmers, conveyed by sea up the estuaries, and thence dis- tributed in the county. Probably this trafl&c partly explains the condition of the Essex roads, which were as bad as the Suffolk highways were good. In both counties hollow drainage was practised earlier than elsewhere. The drains were wedge-shaped, filled with branches, twisted straw, or stone, and covered in with earth. Bradley * speaks of the " Essex practice " of making drains 1 Breviary of Suffolk, by Robert Reyce, 1618, edited by Lord F. Hervey, 1902. " North-East Eaaex, by Arthur Young (1807), vol. i. p. 40. > Complete Body of Httsbandry (1727), p. 133-4. ESSEX AKD SUFFOLK 193 two feet deep, at close and regular intervak throughout a whole field, filled with rubble or bushes, and he derives the term " thorough- drainage " from an Essex word " thorow," meaning a trench to cany ofE the water. Ploughing was in both counties economically conducted. The Suffolk swing-plough, drawn by two horses, was the common implement. Oxen were seldom used : "no groaning ox is doomed to labour there " is the evidence of Bloomfield. Turnips and clover were firmly established as arable crops. Suffolk had been for two centuries famous for its field cultivation of carrots. Cabbages were a later introduction, but extensively grown. Hemp was cultivated in the neighbourhood of Beccles, and hops flourished round Saxmundham. In Essex a peculiar crop, grown, generally together, on the same land for three years in succession, consisted of caraway, coriander, and teazels. The teazels were bought by woollen manufacturers, and fixed in a revolving cylinder to catch the surface of bays, says, etc., and so raise the nap of cloth to the required length. Suffolk was also famous for its live-stock. The Suffolk Punch was a short compact horse of about fifteen hands high, properly of a sorrel colour, unrivalled in its power of draught, though, as Cullum wrote in 1790, " not made to indulge the rapid impatience of this posting generation." In the dairy the " milch kine " of Suffolk are said by Beyce (1618) to be as good as in any other county, and he notes the beauty of their horns. In later times the Suffolk Dun was renowned for the quantity of her milk. Suffolk cheese, however, had an evil reputation. It was " so hard that pigs grunt at it, dogs bark at it, but none dare bite it." The mystery of its interior inspired Bloomfield to sing of the substance, which " Mocks the 'weitk efiort of the bending blade, Or in the hog-trough rests in perfect spite. Too big to swallow and too hard to bite." As the eighteenth century drew to a close, it was to Norfolk and to Leicestershire that men had begun to look for the best examples of arable and pasture farming. In both counties progress had been largely due to the character of the farmers, and in Norfolk to the alertness and industry of the labourers. In Norfolk, Marshall (1787) says that farmers were " strongly marked by a liberality of thinking," that they were men who had " mixed with what is called the World, of which their leases render them independent . . . occupying the same position in society as the clergy and smaller N 194 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE squires." Many of them had prospered enough to buy their holdings, and to add to them " numerous small estates of the yeomanry." Nor is this surprising in view of the productiveness of their land under the Norfolk system of husbandry. At the end of the eighteenth century the average annual number of live-stock sent from the county to Smithfield was 20,000 cattle and 30,000 sheep. It was also stated in 1795, that as much com was exported from the four Norfolk ports of Yarmouth, Lynn, Wells, and Blake- ney, as was sent abroad from the whole of the rest of England. In Leicestershire, again, " yeomanry of the higher class " abounded. " Men cultivating their own estates of two, three, four or five hundreds a year are thickly scattered over almost every part of the country " ; they had " travelled much and mixed constantly with one another." In both Leicestershire and Norfolk the special branches of farming which were generally followed brought agri- culturists into contact with their rivals, compelled them to be wide-awake, and sharpened their intelligence. Both were occupied in fattening stock for town markets, the Leicestershire men on pasture breeding their own stock, the Norfolk farmers on arable land buying their cattle from Scottish drovers. In one important respect there was a vtide difference in their development. In Nor- folk, great landowners, Uke Lord Townshend and, later, Coke of Norfolk, took the lead in improvement, tested for the benefit of their tenants the value of the new arable methods, encouraged them by long leases to follow their example, and by high rents made imitation compulsory. In Leicestershire, on the other hand, large landlords were few and had given no lead ; the example was set by large tenant-farmers or substantial yeomen. Other coimties had adopted other useful practices which had scarcely spread beyond their borders. Thus Lancashire excelled in the cultivation of potatoes ; Middlesex was celebrated for the art and practice of haymaking ; Wiltshire for the irrigation and treatment of water-meadows ; Cheshire for its management of dairy produce ; Yorkshire farmers round ShefiGleld had tested the value of bone-dust, many years before the value of the manure was known in other districts. But there is some evidence that other counties had rather fallen back than advanced. This is especially true of Cambridgeshire, which enjoyed the reputation of being the worst cultivated county in England. It will probably be true to say that the country as a whole had made no general advance ARTHUR YOUNG 195 on the agriculture of the thirteenth century. The stagnation was mainly due to the prevalence of wastes, the system of open-field fanning, the risk of loss of capital in improvements made under tenancies-at-wiU, the poverty and ignorance of hand-to-mouth farmers, the obstinacy of traditionary practices, the want of mar- kets, and difficulties of communication. Till these obstacles were to some extent overcome, agricultural progress could not become general. It is with the removal of these hindrances that the name of Arthur Young is inseparably connected. Bom in London in 1741, Arthur Young was the younger son of the Rev. Arthur Young, who owned a small estate of 200 acres at Bradfield in Suffolk. From his father he inherited his literary tastes, a habit of negligence in money matters, and ultimately a landed property. Out of Lavenham School he passed, at the age of seventeen, into a wine merchant's office at Ljmn. A youthful fop and gallant, he there began his hterary career in order to pay for books and clothes. Before he was nineteen, he had published four novels and two poUtical pamphlets. On his father's death in 1759, he abandoned trade for literature, and Lynn for London, where he launched a monthly magazine called The Universal Museum, which only ran for six months. The venture was unpro- fitable. Without profession or employment, he drifted back, in 1763, to his mother's home at Bradfield, married, and settled down to farming as a business. As a practical farmer he failed, and the impression left by his writings is that he always would have done so. On three farms, which he took in rapid succession, he lost money. Meanwhile he was succeeding better as a writer. Books and pamphlets flowed from his pen with prodigious rapidity, and his income was considerable. In 1767 he began those farming tours, in the course of which he drew his graphic sketches of rural England, Ireland, and France.* His careless ease of style, his racy forcible English, his gift of happy phrases, his quick observation, his wealth of miscellaneous detail, make him the first of English agricultural writers. Apart from the value of the facts which they ' A Six Weeks' Tour through the Southern Counties of England and Wales (1768) ; A Six Months' Tour through the North of England (1770), 4 vols. ; The Farmer's Tour through the East of England (1771), 4 vols. ; Tour in Ireland, 1776-7-8 (1780), 2 vols. ; Travela dtiring the Tears 1787, '88, '89 and 1790, undertaken more Particularly with a view of ascertaining the Cultivation, WetUth, Resources, and National Prosperity of the Kingdom of France (1792-4), 2 vols. 196 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE contain, his tours, with their fresh woid-pictures, their gossip, their personal incidents, and even their irrelevancies, have the charm of private diaries. His Ireland was described by Maria Edgeworth as " the first faithful portrait of the inhabitants," and his Frcmce was recognised by Tocqueville as a first-hand authority on the rural conditions of the country on the eve of the Revolution. In 1784 he began his Annals of Agriculture, a monthly publication to which George m., under the name of his shepherd at Windsor, " Ralph Robinson," occasionally contributed. The magazine was con- tinued till 1809, when, owing to failing eyesight, Yoimg discon- tinued its publication. He had written more than a quarter of the forty-six volumes himself. Toung had now succeeded, on the death of his mother in 1785, to the Bradfield estate, his elder brother having broken his neck in the hunting-field. TTia Travels in France show that he sym- pathised with the peasants in their early efforts to free themselves from the ancien rigime. But the subsequent course of the Revolu- tion filled him with horror. In 1793, he wrote an effective pamphlet on The Example of France a Warning to Great BrUain, urged the formation of a " militia of property," and himself joined the Suffolk yeomanry. In the same year Pitt established the Board of Agriculture, with Sir John Sinclair as President. Arthur Young was appointed Secretary with a salary of £400 a year and, later, an official residence in Sackville Street, London. One of the first objects of the Board was to collect information respecting the agricultural conditions of each county. For this purpose Com- missioners were appointed. They were not always wisely selected ; but for this choice, against which Young protested, the President was responsible. Their Reports were severely criticised by William Marshall ^ (1745-1818), an embittered, disappointed man, who had > Maisball's General Survey ...ofthe Rwral Economy of England haa been frequently quoted. His valuable records fill twelve volumes published between 1787 and 1798, two volumes being allotted to each of the six depart- ments into which he divides the coimtry : (1) the Eastern : Norfolk, 2 vols. (1787) ; (2) the Northern : Yorkshire, 2 vols. (1788) ; (3) the West Central : OUnuietterahire, North WiUa, and Herefordehire, 2 vols. (1789) ; (4) the Mid- land : LeieeitartMre, etc., 2 vols. (1790) ; (6) the Western : Devonahire and parts of Somersetshire, Dorsetshire, and Cornwall, 2 vols. (1796) ; (6) the Southern : Kera, Surrey, Stusex and Hampshire, 2 vols. (1798). Of the first ten volumes a second edition was published in 1796. A second edition of the Southern volumes was published in 1799, with the prefix of a sketch of the V(Ue of London. Marshall has none of the charm of Young. He is a heavy, didtustic writer. THE INSPIRATION OF THE MOVEMENT 197 himself originally suggested the establishment of the Board and the compilation of the surveys. But, with all their faults, the reporters coUected a mass of valuable information on the state of fanning from 1793 to 1813. Six of the surveys were by Young himself,* and his Report on Oxfordshire was almost his last literary work. Young was a man of strong prejudices. He was also wanting in power of generalisation. But he worked untiringly for what he believed to be the progress of good farming. On this object were concentrated the chief labours of his Ufe — his enquiries, experi- ments, researches, his collections of statistics, his notes of useful practices, his observations on new methods. His eager face, with its keen eyes and aquiline features, expressed the vivacity of his temperament, just as his tall slender figure indicated the restless activity of his body. A gay and charming companion, his enthusi- asms were infectious. He was the soul and inspiration of the progressive movement. To him, more than to any other individual, were due the dissemination of new ideas on farming, the diffusion of the latest results of observation and experiment, the creation of new agencies for the interchange of experiences, the establish- ment of farmers' clubs, ploughing matches, and agricultural societies and shows. His married life was not happy ; but Ids wife was not entirely to blame. An affectionate father, his whole heart was given to his youngest daughter (Martha Ann, bom 1783, died 1797) nicknamed " Bobbin." Versailles did not afford him so much pleasure as giving to the child a French doll. Her death broke down his health and spirits. Grief deepened into religious melan- choly. His gloom was intensified by failing eyesight. In 1811 he became totally blind. Nine years later (1820), he died in London. When Young began to write on a^culture, vast districts, which might have been profitably cultivated, still lay waste. Of the area already under tillage, a large proportion lay in open-fields. Bat his system is better ; his generalisations are more conclusive, and less contradictory ; his facts are better arranged ; he was, also, a better farmer. A zealous collector of " provincialisms " of speech, he gives lists of the local words which he found in use in the Northern, Midland, and West Central departments, and appends them, with a glossary, to the volumes to which they relate. Besides the Sural Boonomy, he published numerous other works, chiefly on agriculture. 1 Young wrote the Oeneral View of the AgrieiUture of the County of Suffolk (1797), County of Lincoln (1799), of Hertfordshire (1804), of Norfolk (1804), of Etaex, 2 vols. (1807) ; of Oxfordshire (1809). 198 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE Under this system, whatever might be the differences or capacities of the soil, the whole of the land, with rare exceptions, was placed under the same unvarying rotation. It was this inability to put land to its best use which especially roused Young's indignation. When he made his Eastern Tour in 1770, he found nearly all the Vale of Aylesbury cultivated in arable open-fields, lying in broad, high, crooked ridges. The course of cropping was (1) Fallow, (2) Wheat or Barley, (3) Beans. The land was ploughed from two to four inches deep, and five horses were used to each plough. Beans were sown broadcast, and never hoed. Drainage was badly needed, for the ridge system had failed. But the lands were so intermixed that any other system was difficult, if not impossible. Even in June, only the tops of the ridges were dry, and, in the winter, most of the land, crops and all, were soaked with water. As a result, the products were as bad as the land was good. The Vale of Aylesbury farmers, whom Ellis (1733) describes as " one of the most obstinate bigotted sort," " reap bushels where they should reap quarters." Both in Buckinghamshire and in Northamp- tonshire, the cow-dung was collected from the fields, mixed with short straw, kneaded into lumps, daubed on the walls of buildings, and, when dry, used as fuel. " There cannot," says Young, " be such an application of manure anywhere but among the Hotten- tots." 1 Naseby Field in 1770 consisted of 6000 acres, all cultivated on the open-field system, on the same course of cropping which Young found established on village farms from the Vale of Ayles- bury to the north of Derbyshire. Bound the mud-built village lay a few pasture enclosures. The three arable fields were crossed and re-(»rossed by paths to the different holdings, filled with a cavernous depth of mire ; the pastures were in a state of nature, overrun with nettles, furze, and rushes. The farm-houses and buildings, sJi collected in the village, were two miles distant from a great part of the fields. When Young visited the village again in 1785, he found that the land in tillage for spring com was " perfectly matted with couch." Marshall, a less prejudiced observer than Young, visited the Vale of Gloucester in 1789. There he found half the arable land unenclosed. Near Gloucester, and in other parts of the district, there were extensive tracts of land, called " Every 'It was no uncommon practice. Edward Laurence suggests (1727) that " Cow-dung not to be burnt for fuel " should be inserted as a restrictive covenant in all leasee. He mentions Yorkshire and Lincohishire as counties where dung was frequently used as fuel. THE GOTHS AND VANDALS 199 Year's Land," which were cropped year after year without any fallows. Only the cleanest farming could have made such a system productive. But here Marshall found beans hidden among mustard growing wild as a weed ; peas choked by poppies and com mari- golds ; every stem of barley fettered with convolvulus ; wheat pining in thickets of couch and thistle. It is not surprising that the yield of wheat was anything from 18 bushels an acre down to 12 or 8 bushels. Other instances might be quoted to show the general condition of open-field farms. But the system had its champions, even among practical agriculturists, especially if they were flock-masters. It cannot, therefore, always have been characterised by the worst farming. No doubt lower depths might be reached. If severalty made a good farmer better, it also made a bad farmer worse. Nor was the system altogether incapable of improvement. Here and there Young or Marshall alludes to some useful practice adopted on village farms. For instance. Young speaks of the drainage of common pastures by very large ploughs belonging to the parish, cutting 16 inches in depth and the same in width, drawn by 12 horses ; of the introduction of clover by common consent into the rotation of crops, or of the adoption of a fourth course insteeid of the old two- or three-shift system. So also Marshall notes the open-field practice of dibbing and hoeing beans in Gloucestershire, where beans commanded a ready market among the Guinea traders of Bristol as food for negro slaves on the voyage from the African coaat to the West Indies. But, speaking generally, any rotation of crops in which roots formed an element was with difficulty introduced on arable land which was pastured in common during the autimm and winter months ; drainage was impracticable on the intermixed lands of village farms ; among the.-underfed, under- sized, and imderbred flocks and herds of the commons the principles of Bakewell could not be followed. That open-field farmers were impervious to new methods is certain. " You might," says Young, " as well recommend to them an Orrery as a hand-hoe." That they had not the capital to carry out costly improvements is also obvious. They could not bring into cultivation the sands of Norfolk, the wolds of Lincolnshire, or the ling-covered Peak of Derbyshire. From a purely agricultural point of view Young's intemperate crusade against village farms was justified, and he had reason on his side when he said that " the Goths and Vandals of open-field 200 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE fanners must die out before any complete change takes place." To some extent the same arguments applied to small farmers occupying their holdings in severalty. " Poverty and ignorance," says Marshall, speaking of the Vale of Pickering in 1787, " are the ordinary inhabitants of small farms ; even the smaller estates of the yeomanry are notorious for bad management." It was on the larger farms that he found the spirit of improvement and the best practice. In Gloucestershire (1789) he looked to the " few men of superior intelligence " to raise the standard of the profession. Nor did enclosures necessarily mean an improvement of methods. In Derbyshire, at the time of Young's tour in 1770, many farmers on new enclosures pursued the same course of cropping to which they had been restricted by the " field constraint " of village farms. Sometimes the landlord, and not the tenant, was the Vandal or the Goth. Thus in Cambridgeshire fanners on freshly enclosed land were bound by their leases to continue the old course of fallow, com, and beans. Even when a tenant-farmer possessed both enterprise and capital, the method of land-tenure discouraged improvement. Without some security for his outlay, no tenant could venture to spend money on his land. At the same time he was often expected to make improvements which now are considered the duty of a land- lord and parts of the necessary equipment of a farm. Yet the commonest forms of tenure were lettings from year to year, voidable on either side, as they then were, at six months' notice. In the eafitem counties leases for terms of years, with covenants for management, were in the last half of the century becoming a usual form of letting. But elsewhere long leases were regarded with justifiable suspicion by both parties. Tenants objected to them, because they bound them to take land for a long period before they knew what the land would do, and to make fixed annual payments based on current prices which might not be maintained. Land- lords also objected to them, because they deprived owners of the advantages of a rise in prices, and " told the farmer when he might begin systematically to exhaust the land." Where a good under- standing existed between landlords and tenants, leases were not indispensable. Land was often farmed on verbal agreements. Ordinary tenancies-at-will secured Berkshire and Nottinghamshire farmers in their holdings from generation to generation. Under the same tenancy, on the Duke of Devonshire's estates in Derbyshire, INSECURITY OF LAND-TENURE 201 tenants even carried out costly and permanent improvements. Often, however, the uncertainty of this form of tenure checked enterprise ; because of it, also, tenants fell into the routine of the district and plodded along in the beaten track trodden by their ancestors. Sometimes the uncertainty was a real insecurity. Thus, in Yorkshire, in 1787, Marshall notices that confidence between landlord and tenant had been destroyed by successive rises in rents. " Good farming ceased, for fear the fields should look green and the rent be raised." Local rhymes expressed the popular beUef that he " that havocs may sit," while the improving tenant must either pay increased rent or " flit." Leases for Uves were common, especially in the south-western counties. They gave a fixity of tenure ; but they were necessarily, both for tenant and landlord, somewhat of a gambling speculation. Fourteen years' purchase of the rental value was the usual price for a lease of three Uves. The initial outlay crippled the first tenant, and,, only if the lives proved good, was the purchase remunerative. On the other hand, the landlord was often obliged, as the third life drew towards its close, to put himself in as sub-tenant to save his land from exhaustion and his buildings from ruin. Leases for very short terms were not infrequent. On open-field farms in Bedford- shire and Huntingdon the term was three years, in Durham six years, corresponding to the completion of one or two courses of the ordinary three-shift routine. But in the last twenty years of the eighteenth century, leases for 7, 14, and 21 years became more common. Even longer terms were often granted, as the enthusi- asm for improvement extended. Tenants under long leases throve on rents fixed before the high prices during the Napoleonic war ; but after 1813 the position was disastrously reversed. Prudent men had taken their money out. The sufferers were new men, who had enjoyed none of the advantages of the system ; they were its victims, never its beneficiaries. Two of the difficulties by which the tenure is embarrassed were already becoming important, if not burning, questions — ^the compensation for unexhausted improve- ments, and the covenants imposed by landlords. Some of the restrictions imposed by leases were a bar to progress. Leicester- shire graziers, for example, were crippled by the absolute prohibi- tion of arable farming ; they were forced either to sell ofE their stock at Michaelmas when it was cheapest, or to buy winter-keep from Hertfordshire. On the other hand, covenants of a reasonable 202 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE nature proved invaluable in lifting the standard of a stationary agriculture, and raising farming to a higher level. Other formidable obstacles to progress lay in the mass of local prejudices and the obstinate adherence to antiquated methods. All over the country there were men like the " round-frocked " farmers of Surrey, who prided themselves on preserving the prac- tices and dress of their forefathers, men of " inflexible honesty," enemies equally to " improvements in agriculture " and to the commercial moraUty of a new generation. Reforming agriculturists no doubt were too ready to ignore the soUd basis of sound sense and experience which often underlay practices that in theory were objectionable. In their excuse it may be urged that their patience was sorely tried. Traditional methods were treasured with jealous care as agricultural heirlooms ; even ocular proof of the superiority of other systems failed to wean farmers from the routine of their ancestors. In 1768 turnips and clover were still unknown in many parts of the country ; and their full use only appreciated in the eastern counties. In some districts, as in Essex (1808), clover had been adopted with such zeal that the land was already turning sick ; in others it was scarcely tried. In Westmoreland, for instance, in 1794, " the prejudice that exists almost universally against clover and rye-grass " was said to be " a great obstacle to the improvement of the husbandry of the county." In Cumber- land, where clover had been introduced in 1752, it was still rare in 1797. Turnips remained, at the close of the eighteenth century, an " alien crop " in many counties, such as Wiltshire, Dorsetshire, Hampshire, Staffordshire, Herefordshire, Shropshire, Glamorgan- shire, and Worcestershire. Even where they were grown, they were generally sown broadcast, and seldom hoed. In 1780 a Norfolk fanner settled in Devonshire, where he drilled and hoed his roots. His crops were far superior to those of other farmers in the district ; yet, at the close of the century, no neighbour had followed his example. In 1794 many Northumberland sheep-masters still milked their ewes, though the more intelligent had discontinued the practice. Another illustration of the tyranny of custom may be taken from ploughing. In many districts the Norfolk, Bother- ham, or Small's ploughs had been introduced at a great economy of cost. But elsewhere farmers still clung to some ancestral imple- ment. In Kent, at the time of Cromwell, it was not unusual to see six, eight, or twelve oxen attached to a single plough. On the AGRICULTURAL HEIRLOOMS 203 diy land of East Kent, on stony land, on rongh hill-sides, the implement undoubtedly had, and has, its uses. But on all soils alike, a century and a half later, the same huge machine, looking at a distance more like a cart than a plough, with a beam the size of a gate-post, remained the idol of the men of Kent. In Middlesex, in 1796, it was no imcommon sight to see ploughs drawn by six horses, with three men in attendance. In Berkshire (1794), four horses and two men ploughed one acre a day. In Northampton- shire Donaldson (1794) found in general use a clumsy implement, with a long massive beam, drawn by four to six horses at length, with a boy to lead and a man to hold. By immemorial custom in Gloucestershire two men, a boy, and a team of six horses were usually employed in ploughing. Ck)ke of Norfolk sent into the county a Norfolk plough, and ploughman, who, with a pair of horses, did the same work in the same time. But though the annual cost of the operation was thus diminished by a half, it was twenty years before the neighbours profited by the lesson. The backwardness of many agricultural counties was to some extent due to difficulties of communication. By the creation of Turnpike Trusts (1663 and onwards) portions of the great high- ways were placed in repair.^ Yet in the eighteen miles of turnpike road between Preston and Wigan, Young in 1770 measiu^ ruts " four feet deep and floating with mud only from a wet summer," and passed three broken-down carts. " I know not in the whole range of language," he says, " terms sufficiently expressive to describe this infernal road. Let me most seriously caution all travellers who may accidentally propose to travel this terrible country to avoid it as they would the devil, for a thousand to one they break their necks or their limbs, by overthrows or breakings down." The turnpike road to Newcastle from the south seems to have been equally dangerous. " A more dreadful road," he says, " cannot be imagined. I was obliged to hire two men at one place to support my chaise from overturning. Let me persuade all travellers to avoid this terrible country, which must either dislocate their bones with broken pavements, or bury them in muddy sand." The turnpike rojid from Chepstow to Newport was a rocky lane, " full of hugeous stones, as big as one's horse, and abominable holes." Marshall says that the Leicestershire roads, till about 1770, had been " in a state of almost total neglect since the days > For farther details as to roads, see chap, viii , 204 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE of the Mercians." The principal road from Tamworth to Ashby lay, in 1789, " in a state almost impassable several months in the year." Waggons were taken off their wheels and dragged on their bellies. Essex, in the time of Fitzherbert, was famous for the badness of its roads. In the eighteenth century it worthily main- tained its reputation. " A mouse could barely pass a carriage in its narrow lanes," which were filled with bottomless ruts, and often choked by a string of chalk waggons, buried so deeply in the mire that they could only be extricated by thirty or forty horses. " Of all the cursed roads that ever disgraced this kingdom in the very age of barbarism none ever equalled that from Billericay to the ' King's Head ' at Tilbury " was the suffering cry of Young in 1769. The roads of Herefordshire, says Marshall, twenty years later, were " such as you might expect to find in the marshes of Holland or the mountains of Switzerland." In Devonshire, which Marshall con- sidered to be agriculturally the most benighted district of England, there was not in 1760 one single wheeled carriage ; everything was carried in sledges or on pack-horses. The latter were still in uni- versal use in 1796. Crops were piled between willow " crooks," to which the load was bound ; manure was carried in strong panniers, or " potts," the bottom of which was a sort of falling door ; sand was slung in bags across the wooden pack-saddle. Even where efforts were made to improve the highways, the attempt was often rendered useless by ignorance of the science of road-making. Some roads were convex and barrel-shaped. But the faU from the centre of the road to the sides was so rapid that carts could only travel in the centre with safety. Many roads were concave, constructed in the form of a trough, filled in with sand. In wet weather this deposit became porridge. On a road of this formation between Woodstock and Oxford, Marshall, in 1789, encountered labourers employed in " scooping out the batter." Yet in spite of the diffi- culty of communication, distant counties carried on a considerable trade in agricultural produce. Thus calves, bred in Northampton- shire, were sent to Essex to be reared. The animals travelled in carts with their legs tied together, were eight days on the road, and during the journey were fed with " gin-balls," i.e. flour and gin mixed together. Off the main lines of communication, highways were unmetalled tracks, which spread in width as vehicles deviated to avoid the ruts of their predecessors. By-roads were often zig- zag lanes, engineered on the principle that one good or bad turn NEEDS OF A MANTJFACTURING POPULATION 205 deserved another. In narrow ways the bells on the teams were not merely ornaments ; they were warnings that the passage was barred by the entry of another vehicle. When mral districts were thus cat off from one another, their isolation was not only a formidable obstacle to agricTdtnral progress, but made a uniform system of growing com on every kind of land a practical necessity. Yet the dajm when Gloucester seemed " in the Orcades," and York a " Pindarick flight " from London had their advantages. In 1800 it required fifty-four horns, and favourable ciicumstances, for " a philosopher, sis shirts, his genius, and his hat upon it," to reach London from Dublin. Shut off from neighbours by impassable roads, impeded in their access to markets, not ambitious of raising from the soil anything beyond their own needs and the satisfaction of the local demand for bread, farmers felt no spur to improvement. Hitherto the slow increase of a rural population was the only effective incentive to increased production. But as the eighteenth century drew to its close. Watt, Hargreaves, Crompton, Arkwright, and other me- chanical geniuses were b^;inning to change the face of society with the swiftness of a revolution. Population was shifting from the South to the North, and advancing by leaps and bounds in crowded manufacturing towns. Huge markets were springing up for agricultural produce. Hitherto there had been few divisions of employment because only the simplest implements of production were used ; spinners, weavers, and cloth-workers, iron-workers, handicraftsmen, bad combined much of their special industries with the tillage of the soil. But the rapid development of manufacture caused its complete separation from agriculture, and the application of machinery to manual industries completed the revolution in social arrangements. A division of labour became an economic necessity. Farmers and manufacturers grew mutually dependent. Self- sufficing farming was thrown out of date. Like manufacture, agri- culture was ceasing to be a domestic industry. Both had to be organised on a commercial footing. The problem was, how could the inevitable changes be met best and most promptly ? How could a country at war with Europe raise the most home-grown food for a rapidly growing population, concentrated in the coal and iron fields ? How could agriculture supply the demand for artisan labour, and yet increase its own productiveness ? Arthur Young was, at this period of his career, ready with an unhesitating answer 206 THE DIFFUSION OF KNOWLEDGE — large farms, large capital, long leases, and the most improved methods of cultivation and stock-breeding. His object was to develop to the utmost the resources of the soil. To this end all social considerations must be subordinated. Every obstacle to good farming must be swept away — wastes reclaimed, commons divided, open-fields converted into individual occupations, antiquated methods abandoned, obsolete implements scrapped, improved practices uniformly adopted. " Where," he asks, with perfect truth, " is the little farmer to be found who will cover his whole farm with marl at the rate of 100 or 150 tons per acre ? who will drain all his land at the expense of £2 or £3 an acre ? who will pay a heavy price for the manure of towns, and convey it thirty miles by land carriage ? who will float his meadows at the expense of £5 an acre ? who, to improve the breed of his sheep, will give 1000 guineas for the use of a single ram for a single season ? who will send across the Kingdom to distant provinces for new implements, and for men to use them 1 who will employ and pay men for residing in provinces where practices are found which they want to intro- duce into their farms ? " Young's spirited crusade against bad or poor farming would probably have fallen on deaf ears, if it had not been supported by the prospect of financial gain and by the impulse of industrial necessities. As he put the case, more produce from the land meant higher rents for the landlord, larger incomes for farmers, better wages for labourers, more home-grown food for the nation. Under the pressure of war-prices and of the gigantic growth of a manufacturing population, the system which he advocated made rapid progress. Years after his death, it was established with such completeness that men forgot not only the existence of any different conditions, but even the very name of the most active pioneer of the change. In the agricultural Uterature of the early and middle Victorian era, he is almost ignored. The article on English agri- culture in the Encyclopaedia BrUannica, for example, devotes only a few lines to his career. Recently his memory has been revived in England by the renewal under different circumstances of the struggle between large and small farmers. In France, on the other hand, where the contest between capitalist farmers and peasant pro- prietors was never decisively terminated, the discussion has always centred round his name. In the words of Lesage, his latest editor and translator, France has made an adopted child of Arthur Young. "FARMER GEORGE" 207 CHAPTER X. LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS. 1780-1813. Agricultural enthusiasm at the close of the eighteenth centuiy ; high prices of agricultural produce ; the causes of the advance ; increased demand and cessation of foreign supplies ; the state of the currency ; rapid advance of agriculture on the new lines of capitalist farming ; impulse given to enclosing movement and the introduction of improved practices ; Davy's Lectures on Agricultural Chemistry ; the work of large landlords : Coke of Norfolk. The enthiisia.sm for farming progress, which Arthur Young zeal- ously promoted, spread with rapidity. A fashion was created which was more lasting, because less artificial and more practical, than it had been in the days of Pope. Great landlords took the lead iu agricultaral improvements. Their farming zeal did not escape criticism. Dr. Edwards ^ iu 1783 expressed a feeling which was prevalent two centuries before : " Gentlemen have no right to be farmers ; and their entering upon agriculture to foUow it as a busiaess is perhaps a breach of their moral duty." But it was now that young men, heirs to landed estates as well as younger sons, began to go as pupils to farmers. George HE. rejoiced in the title of " Farmer George," considered himself more indebted to Arthur Young than to any man in his dominions, carried the last volume of the Annals with him in his travelling carriage, kept his model farm at Windsor,* formed his flock of merino sheep, and experimented in stock-breeding. The Duke of Bedford at Wobum, Lord Rockingham at Wentworth, Lord Egremont at Petworth, Coke at Holkham, and numerous other landlords, headed the 1 Plan of an Vndertdking for the Improvement of Husbandry etc., by Dr. Edwoids of Barnard Castle (1783). iThe King's Windsor Form is described by Nathaniel Kent in Hunter's ChorgietU Etsays (1803), voL iv. Elssay vii. 208 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS reforming movement. Pox, even in the Louvre, was lost in con- sideration whether the weather was favourable to his turnips at St. Anne's Hill. Burke experimented ia carrots as a field crop on his fann at Beaconsfield, though he pointed his sarcasms against the Duke of Bedford for his devotion to agriculture. Lord Althorp, in the nineteenth century, maintained the traditions of his official predecessors. During a serious crisis of afEairs, when he was Chancellor of the Exchequer, John Grey of Dilston called upon him in Downing Street on political business. Lord Althorp's first question, eagerly asked, was " Have you been at Wiseton on your way up ? Have you seen the cows ? " The enthusiasm for farm- ing began to be scientific as well as practical. No new book escaped the vigilance of agriculturists. Miss Edgeworth's Essay on Irish BvMs (1802) had scarcely been published a week before it was ordered by the secretary of an agricultural society. Nor were the clergy less zealous. An archdeacon, finding a churchyard culti- vated for turnips, rebuked the rector with the remark, " This must not occur again." The reply, " Oh no, Mr. Archdeacon, it will be barley next year," shows that, whatever were the shortcomings of the Church, the eighteenth century clergy were at least devoted to the rotation of crops. Every department of agriculture was permeated by a new spirit of energy and enterprise. Rents rose, but profits outstripped the rise. New crops were cultivated ; swedes, mangel-wmael, kohl rabi, prickly comfrey were readily adopted by a new race of agri- culturists. Breeders spent capital freely in improving live-stock. New implements were introduced. The economy and handiness of ploughs like the Norfolk, or the Rotherham ploughs as improved by James Small of Blackadder Moimt, were gradually recognised, and the cumbrous mediaeval instruments with their extravagant teams superseded. Meikle's threshing machine (1784) began to drive out the flail by its economy of human labour. Numerous patents were taken out between 1788 and 1816 for drills, reaping, mowing, haymaking, and winnowing machines, as well as for horse-rakes, scarifiers, chaff-cutters, tumip-sUcers, and other mechanical aids to agriculture. In the northern counties iron gates and fences began to be used. The uniformity of weights and meaaures ^ was eagerly * Under the Act of Union with Scotland (clause 17) it had been provided that the same weights and measures which were established in England should be used throughout the United Kingdom. But the clause remained LOCAL AGRICULTURAL SOCIETIES 209 discussed and recommended. Cattle-shows, wool-fairs, plooghing- matches were held in various parts of the country. Counties, like Durham, Northumberland, Cheshire, and Leicestershire, started exi)erimental farms. The short-lived Society of " Improvers in the Knowledge of Agriculture " had been formed in 1723. The Society for the " Encouragement of Arts, Manufactures and Com- merce " was instituted in London in 1754. Other associations, more exclusively agricultural, speedily followed. The Bath and West of England Society was founded in 1777, the Highland Society in 1784, the Smithfield Qub in 1798. The creation of the Board of Agriculture in 1793 has been already mentioned. The Farmers' Club was established in 1793. The first number of the Farmer's Magazine, which appeared in January, 1800, rapidly passed through five editions. Provincial societies multipUed. At Lewes, in 1772, Lord Sheffield had established a Society for the " Encouragement of Agriculture, Manufacture and Industry " ; but it does not seem to have survived the war with France and the United States. Few counties were without their organisations for the promotion of agricultural improvement. One of the first was established at Odiham in Hampshire. Kent had its agricultural society at Canterbury (1793) and the Kentish Society at Maidstone. In Cornwall (1793), Berkshire (1794), Shropshire (1790), at Shifnal and at Drayton in Leicestershire (1794), in Herefordshire (1797), pro- vincial societies were founded. The West Riding of Yorkshire had its society at Sheffield, Lancashire at Manchester, Worcestershire at Evesham (1792), Huntingdonshire at Kimbolton. In Northamp- tonshire similar associations were formed at Peterborough, Welling- borough and Lamport. The list might be enlarged. But, though many of these societies were short-lived, their foimdation illustrates the new spirit which animated farming at the close of the eighteenth century. a dead letter. The establishment of uniformity was difficult. In 1768 a Parliamentary Committee reported that there were in use in England four di&erent legcJ measures of capacity, the respective quantities being in the case of the bushel 2124, 2150, 2168, and 2240 cubic inches. The widest diSerences existed between the weights Emd measures of the same county. Thus in Cornwall, for instance, wheat was sold either by the double Win- chester of 16 gallons or the treble Winchester of 24 gallons ; oats were sold in the eastern district by the hogshead of 9 Winchesters, in the west by a double Winchester of 17 gallons ; a bushel of seed-wheat bought from a western farmer ran short of the eastern measure by between one emd two gallons. Butter was sold at 18 oz. to the pound, "tba customary perch was 18 feet in length instead of the statutory length of 16 J feet. O 210 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS The period from 1780 to 1813 was one of exceptional activity in agricultural progress. Apart from the flowing tide of enthusiasm, landlords and farmers were spurred to fresh exertions and a great outlay of capital and labour by the large returns on their expendi- ture. All over the country new facilities of transport and com- munication began to bring markets to the gates of farmers ; new tracts of land were reclaimed ; open arable farms and pasture commons were broken up, enclosed, and brought into more pro- fitable cultivation ; vast sums of money were spent on buildings and improvement. In spite of increased production, prices rose higher and higher, and carried rents with them. " Com," says Ricardo, " is not high because a rent is paid ; but a rent is paid because com is high." In certain circumstances — ^if the State is landlord, or if landowners could combine for the purpose — rents might raise prices. But the general truth of Ricardo's view was illustrated during the French War. From 1790 to 1813, rents rose with the rise in prices, until over a great part of Great Britain they were probably doubled. Even the larger yield from the land under improved methods of cultivation did not cheapen produce, reduce prices, and so cause lower rents. On the contrary, prices were not only maintained, but continued to rise. This continuously upward tendency in prices was unprecedented. It c^anot be attributed to the operation of the Com Laws.^ Down to 1815 that legislation had scarcely affected prices at all, and therefore could not influence rents. The rise was rather due to a variety of causes, some of which were exceptional and temporary. A series of unprosperous seasons prevailed over the whole available corn-area of Northern Europe. In England deficient harvests, though the shortage was to some extent mitigated by the increased breadth under com, reduced the home supply at a time when the growth of an artisan population increased the demand. The country throughout these years either stood, or thought that it stood, on the verge of famine. Prices were raised by panic-stricken com- petition. As the area of the war extended, foreign supplies became less and less available. The enormous increase in the war-charges for freight and insurance made Great Britain more aind more dependent on her own produce. Necessity compelled the full development of her existing resources, as well as the resort to inferior land. Larger supplies of home-grown com could only be ^ See chapter zii. HIGH PRICES DURING THE FRENCH WARS 211 obtained either by improved methods of cultivation or by bringing untilled land mider the plough. The one method powerfully stimulated the progress of agriculture, which may be summed up in increasing the yield and lowering the cost of production ; the other was the vaUd justification of the rapid enclosure of wastes, open-fields, and commons. Much of the land that now was sown with com could only be tilled at a profit when prices were high, because the outlay on its tillage was greater, and the return from its cultivation was less, than on ordinary land. Tet, as prices then stood, even this inferior soil was able to bear a rent, and by each step towards the margin of cultivation, the rental value of land of better quality was enhsmced. Thus Napoleon proved to be the Triptolemus or patron saint not only of farmers but of land- lords. Another cause of the high prices of the time was the state of the currency. When gold is cheap, commodities are dear. Any great increase in the production of gold for a time raises prices ; the sovereign becomes of less relative value ; it buys less than before, and more gold has to be paid for the same quantity. But this direct effect of gold discoveries was not then in operation ; it had spent its force, and at the close of the eighteenth century did not materially affect prices. Similar results were, however, produced by the immense extension of that system of deferred payment which is called credit. Paper money was issued in excessive quantities, not only by the Bank of England but by the private banks all over the country. A new medium of exchange was created. This addition to the circulating medium raised prices in the same kind of way as an actual addition to the quantity of coin. But there was this important difference. Paper money is only a promise to pay ; it is only representative money, and, unless it is convertible into gold, the credit which it creates is fictitious and may be excessive. The immense development of manufacturing industries and of the canal system, in the years 1785-92, required increased facilities for carrying on commercial transactions. But bankers, in their eagerness to create business, made advances on insufficient or inconvertible securities, discounted bills without regard to the actual value of the commodities on which the trans- actions were based, and issued notes far beyond tJie amount which tlieir actual funds justified. In 1793 came the first crash. The Bank of England, warned by the fall of the exchanges and the 212 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS outflow of gold, restricted their issue of notes. A panic followed. Out of 350 country banks in England and Wales, more than 100 stopped payment ; their promises to pay were repudiated ; and their paper was destroyed at the expense of the holder. The ruin and the loss of confidence were widespread ; those who escaped the crash hoarded their money instead of making investments in mercantile undertakings. But the destruction of so much paper temporarily restored the proportion between the gold in the country and the paper by which it was represented. In 1797 a second crisis occurred. Alarmed at a prospect of invasion, country depositors crowded to withdraw deposits and realise their property. There were runs on the country banks, and such heavy demands for their support were made on the Bank of England that, on Saturday, February 25, 1797, the stock of coin and buUion had fallen to under £1,300,000, with every prospect of a renewal and an iacrease of the run on the following Monday. On Sunday, February 26, an Order of Council suspended payments in cash until Parliament could consider the situation. The merchants of London came to the rescue of the bank. They guaranteed the payment of its notes in gold ; the national credit was saved, and the worst of the threatened crisis was averted. But the failures of country banks were again numerous. Once more the same process was repeated. Paper money in large quantities was destroyed at the cost of its holders, and the balance between the promise and the abiUty to pay was again readjusted. The experi- ence was not lost on agriculturists, who found that their land was not only the most remunerative but the safest investment. Under the Bank Restriction Act of .1797, the Bank of England suspended payment in coin. In other words a paper currency was created which was not convertible into gold. The Act was origin- aUy a temporary expedient. But it was not till 1821 that the bank completely resumed payment in specie. No doubt the effect of the Act was to aggravate the tendency of prices to rise. Yet the measure was probably justified by the exceptional circum- stances of the war and of trade. It supplied the Government with gold for the expenses of our own expeditionary forces, as well as for the payment of subsidies to oiu- allies. It also enabled the country to carry on the one-sided system of trade to which we were gradually reduced by the Continental blockade. Our exports of manufactured goods were excluded from Eiuropean ports. Con- FINANCIAL CRISES 213 sequently the materials which we imported were paid for ia cash instead of in goods, and the vessels which conveyed them to our ports returned in ballast. There was thus a constant drain of gold from the country. So long as the power to issue inconvertible notes was sparingly used, the paper currency maintained its nominal value. But from 1808 onwards such large quantities of paper were issued, not only by the Bank of England but by country banks, that it rapidly depreciated as compared with gold. It is probable that from 1811 to 1813 one-fifth of the enormous prices of agri- cultural produce were due to the disordered state of the currency. In 1814, owing partly to the abundant harvest of the previous year, partly to the collapse of the Continental blockade, prices rapidly fell. A financial crash followed which caused even more widespread ruin in country districts than the paroxysm of 1793. Of the country banks, 240 stopped payment, and 89 became bank- rupt. The result was a wholesale destruction of bank-paper, the reduction of thousands of families from wealth to destitution, and the gradual restoration of the equilibrium of the currency. The seasons, the war, the growth of population, the disorders of the currency, combined to raise and maintain at a high level the prices of agricultural produce in Great Britain. At the same time the prohibitive cost of transport prevented such foreign sup- plies as were then available from reducing the prices of home-grown com. Circumstances thus gave British agriculturists a monopoly, which, after 1815, they endeavoured to preserve by legislation. Land was not only a most profitable investment, but the fate of speculators had again and again convinced both landlords and tenants that land was the safest bank. Thus business caution, as well as business enterprise, prompted the outlay of capital on agri- cultural improvement. Economic ideas pointed ia the same direc- tion. The doctrine of John Locke,^ that high rents were a symptom of prosperity still prevailed among politicians. It was also main- tained that high rents were a necessary spur to agricultural progress. So long as land remained . cheap, farmers rested satisfied with antiquated practices ; the dearer the land, the more energetic and enterprising they necessarily became. Tonng went so far as to say that the spendthrift, who frequented London club-houses and 1 " An infallible sign of your decay of wealth is the falling of rents, and the raising of them would be worth the nation's caie " {Worka, ed. 1823, voL v. p. 69). 214 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS raified rents to pay his debts of honour, was a greater benefactor to agriculture than the stay-at-home squire who Uved frugally in order to keep within his ancestral income. No economist of the day had conceived any other method of satisfying the wants of a growing population except by improving the existing practices of farmers or bringing fresh tracts of land under the plough. Advanced Free Traders like Porter ^ never imagined that a progressive country could become dependent on foreign nations for its daily food. It was to the continuous improvement in agricultural methods that he looked for the means of supplying a population, which, he cal- culated, would, at the end of the nineteenth century, exceed 40 millions. Nor did he entertain any doubt that, by the progress of skill and enterprise, the quantity raised in 1840 could be increased by the requisite 150 per cent. Encouraged by high profits, approved by economists, jiistified by necessity, agriculture advanced rapidly on the new lines of large farms and large capital. The change was one side of a wider movement. In the infancy of agriculture and of trade, self- supporting associations had been formed for mutual defence and protection. Manorial organisations like trade guilds had begun to break up, when the central power was firmly established. Now, once more, agriculture and majiufacture were simultaneously reorganised. Division of labour had become a necessity. Domestic handicrafts were gathered into populous manufacturing centres, which were dependent for food on the labour of agriculturists. Farms ceased to be self-sufficing industries, and became factories of beef and mutton. The pressure of these conditions demanded the utmost development of the resources of the soil. The cultiva- tion of additioiial land by the most improved methods grew more and more necessary. Enclosures went on apace. Yet, even in favourable seasons, it was a struggle to keep pace with growing needs ; scarcity, if not famine, resulted from deficiency. During part of the period, foreign suppUes might be reUed on to avert the worst. But throughout the Napoleonic wars tins resource grew * " To supply the United Kingdom with the single article of wheat would call for the employment of more than twice the amount of shipping which now annually enters our ports, if indeed it would be possible to procure the grain from other countries in sufficient quantity ; and to bring to our shores every article of agricultural produce in the abundance which we now enjoy, would probably give constant occupation to the mercantile navy of the whole world " {Progreaa of the. Nation, ed. 1847, p. 136). RAPID INCREASE OF ENCLOSURES 215 yeaxly more uncertain and more costly. The pace of enclosure was immensely accelerated. In the first 33 years of the reign of George m., there were 1355 Acts passed ; in the 23 years of the wars with France (1793-1815) there were 1934. It is easy to attri- bute the great increase of enclosures during this last period solely to the greed of landlords, eager to profit by the high prices of agricultural produce. That the land would not have been brought into cultivation unless it paid to do so, may be admitted. But it must in justice be remembered that an addition to the cultivated area was, in existing circvmistances, one of the two methods, which at that time were alone available, of increasing the supply of food, averting famine, and reducing prices. Economically, enclosures can be justified. But the processes by which they were sometimes carried out, were often indefensible, and socially their effects were disastrous. On these points more will be said subsequently. Here it will be enough to reiterate the statement that enclosure meant not merely reclamation of waste ground, but partition of the com- mons and extinction of the open-field system. It has been suggested, on the authority of passages in his tract on Wastes, that Arthur Young learned to deplore his previous crusade against village farms, when he saw the effect of enclosures on rural life. What Young deplored was the loss of a golden opportunity of attaching land to the home of the cottager. But he never faltered in his con- viction of the necessity of breaking up the open-fields and dividing the commons. In the tract on Wastes he emphatically asserts his wish to see all commons enclosed, and he was too great a master of his subject not to know that without pasture the arable village farms must inevitably perish. The other method of increasing the food supplies of the country consisted of agricultural improvements. Here also the preparation of the ground involved changes which bore hardly on small occupiers of land. The new sjrstem of fanning required large holdings, to which a new class of tenant of superior education and intelligence was attracted. It was on these holdings that capital could be expended to the greatest advantage, that meat and com could be grown in the largest quantities, that most use could be made of those mechanical aids which cheapened production. Costly im- provements could not be carried out by small hand-to-mouth occupiers, even if their obstinate adherence to antiquated methods would have allowed them to contemplate the possibility of change. 216 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS But this coQSolidation of holdings threw into the hands of one tenant land which had previously been occupied by several. If the land was laid dawn to grass, and in the case of heavy land, down to 1790, this was the most profitable form of enclosure, — ^there was also a diminution in the demand for labour, and a consequent decrease in the population of the village. If, on the other hand, the land was cultivated as an arable farm, there was probably a greater demand for labour and possibly an increase in the nimibers of the rural population. Arthur Young in 1801 ^ shows that, out of 37 enclosed parishes in an arable county like Norfolk, population had risen in 24, fallen in 8, and remained stationary in 5. It cannot therefore be said that either enclosures, or the consolidation of holdings, necessarily depopulated country villages. Whether this result followed, or did not follow, depended on the use to which the land was put, though even on arable farms the gradual intro- duction of machinery, at present limited to the threshing machine, tended to diminish the demand for labour. If the country was to be fed, more scientific methods of farming were necessary. The need was pressing, and both enclosures and the consoUdation of large farms prepared the way for a new stage of agricultural progress. Hitherto bucolic life had been the pastime of a fashionable world, the relaxation of statesmen, the artificial inspiration of poets. But farmers had neither asked nor allowed scientific aid. The dawn of a new era, in which practical experience was to be combined with scientific knowledge, was marked by the lectures of Humphry Davy in 1803. In 1757 Francis Home* had insisted on the dependence of agriculture on " Chymistry." Without a knowledge of that science, he said, agriculture could not be reduced to principles. In 1802 the first steps were taken towards this end. The Board of Agriculture arranged a series of lectures on " The Connection of Chemistry with Vegetable Physiology," to be delivered by Davy, then a young man of twenty-three, and recently (July, 1801) appointed Assistant Professor of Chemistry at the Royal Institution of Great Britain. He had already made his mark as the most brilliant lecturer of the day, attracting round him by his scientific use of the imagination such men as Dr. Parr and ^ Inquiry into the Propriety of applying Wastes to the Better MairUenance and Support of the Poor. • The Princvples of Agriculture and Vegetation, by Francis Home, M.D., 1767. SIR HUMPHRY DAVY 217 S. T. Coleridge, and the talent, rank, and fashion of London, women as well as men. His six lectures on agricoltun^ chemistry, com- mencing May 10, 1803, were delivered before the Board of Agri- culture. So great was their success that he was appointed Professor of Chemistry to the Board, and in that capacity gave courses of lectures during the ten following years. In 1813 the results of his researches were published in his Elementa of AgricuitunU Chemistry. The volume is now out-of-date, though the lecture on " SoUs and their Analyses," in spite of the progress of geological science and the adoption of new classifications, remains of permanent interest. Many passages that were then listened to as novelties are now com- monplaces ; others, especially those on manures, have been com- pletely superseded by the advance of knowledge. But if the book has ceased to be a practical guide, it remains a historical landmark, and something more. It is the foundation-stone on which the science of agricultural chemistry has been reared, and its author was the direct ancestor of liebig, Lawes, and Gilbert, to whose labours, in the field which Davy first explored, modem sigriculture is at every turn so deeply indebted. It was Davy's work which inspired the choice by the Royal Agricultural Society (founded in 1838) of its motto " Practice with Science." In Thomas Coke of Norfolk ^ the new system of large farms and large capital found their most celebrated champion. In 1776, at the age of twenty-two, he came into his estate with " the King of Denmark " as "his nearest neighbour." Wealthy, devoted to field sports, and already Member of Parliament for Norfolk, it seemed improbable that he would find time for farming. But as an ardent Whig and a prominent supporter of Fox in the House of Commons, he was excluded by his politics from court life or political office. In 1778 the refusal of two tenants to accept leases at an increased rent threw a quantity of land on his hands. He deter- mined to farm the land himself. From that time till his death in 1842, he stood at the head of the new agricultural movement. On his own estates his energy was richly rewarded. Dr. R^by,' writing in 1816, states that the annual rental of Holkham rose from £2,200 in 1776 to £20,000 in 1816. When Coke took his land in hand, not an acre of wheat was > Coke of Norfolk and his Frienda, bjr A. M. W. Starling, 2 vola. 1910. * The Pamphleteer, voL ziii. pp. 469-70 ; Hoffcham and its Agrieu^ure, 3rd edition, 1818, pp. 25, 28. 218 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS to be Been from Holkham to Lynn. The thin sandy soil produced bnt a scanty yield of rye. Naturally wanting in richness, it was still further impoverished by a barbarous system of cropping. No manure was purchased ; a few Norfolk sheep with backs like rabbits, and, here and there, a few half-starved milch cows were the only live-stock ; the Uttle muck that was produced was miser- ably poor. Coke determined to grow wheat. He marled and clayed the land, purchased large quantities of manure, drilled his wheat and turnips, grew sainfoin and clover, trebled his live-stock. On the light drifty land in his neighbourhood the Flemish maxim held good : " Point de fourrage, point de bestiaux ; sans bestiaux, aucun engrais ; sans engrais, nulle recolte." " No keep, no live- stock ; without stock, no manure ; without manure, no crops." It is, in fact, the Norfolk proverb, " Muck is the mother of money." In the lafit quarter of the eighteenth century the value of bones as fertilisers was realised.^ The discovery has been attributed to a Yorkshire fox-himter who was cleaning out his kennels ; others assign it to farmers in the neighbourhood of Sheffield, where rofuse heaps were formed of the bones which were not available for the handles of cutlery. By the use of the new discovery Coke profited largely. He also introduced into the county the use of artificial foods like oil-cake, which, with roots, enabled Norfolk farms to cany increased stock. Under his example and advice stall-feeding was extensively practised. On Bullock's TTill near Norwich, during the great fair of St. Faith's, drovers assembled from all parts of the country, especially from Scotland, with herds of half-fed beasts which were bought up by Norfolk farmers to be fattened for London markets. The grass lands, on which the beef and mutton of our ancestors were raised, were deserted for the sands of the eastern counties, from which under the new farming practice, the metro- polis drew its meat supplies. Numbers of animals fattened on nutritions food gave farmers the command of the richest manure, fertilised their land, and enabled them not only to grow wheat but to verify the maxim " never to sow a crop unless there is con- dition to grow it luxuriantly." In nine years Coke had succeeded in growing good crops of wheat on the land which he farmed himself. He next set himself to improve the live-stock. After patient trial of other breeds, and ' Bones were ground at a mill in Lancashire in 1704 by a local farmer who sold his surplus to his neighbours. COKE OF NORFOLK 219 especially of Shorthorns among cattle and of the New Leicesters and Merinos among sheep, he adopted Devons and Southdowns. His efforts were not confined to the home-farm. Early and late he worked in his smock-frock, assisting tenants to improve their flocks and herds. Grass lands, till he gave them his attention, were wholly neglected in the district. If meadow or pasture wanted renewal, or arable land was to be laid down in grass, farmers either allowed it to tmnble down, or threw indiscriminately on the gromid a quantity of seed drawn at haphazard from their own or their neighbour's ricks, containing as mnch rank weed as nutri- tions herbage. It was a mere chance whether the sour or the sweet grasses were aided in their struggle for existence. StUling- fleet, in 1760, had distinguished the good and bad herbage by excellent illustrations of the kinds best calculated to produce the richest hay and sweetest }>asture. The Society of Arts, Manu- facture and Commerce had offered premiums for the best collections of the best kinds, and in Edinburgh the Lawsons were experimenting on grasses. But Coke was the first landlord who appreciated the value of the distinctions by applying them to his own land. In May and June, when the grasses were in bloom, he gave ids simple botanical lessons to the children of his tenantry, who scoured the countiy to procure his stocks of seed. Impressed with the community of interest among owners, occu- piers, and labourers. Coke stimulated the enterprise of his tenants, encouraged tibem to put more money and more labour into the land, and assisted them to take advantage of every new invention and discovery. Experiments with drill husbandry on 3,000 acres of com land convinced him of its value in economy of time, in saving of seed, in securing an equal depth of sowing, and in facilitating the cleaning of the land. He calculated that he saved in seed a bushel and a half per acre, and increased the yield per acre by twelve bushels. As with the drill, so with other innovations. He tested every novelty himself, and offered to his neighbours only the results of his own successful experience. It was thus that the practice of drilling tnniips tmd wheat, and the value of sainfoin, swedes, mangel- wurzel, and potatoes were forced on the notice of Norfolk farmers. His fann-boildings, dwelling-houses, and cottages were models to other landlords. On them he spared no reasonable expense. They cost him, during his tenure of the property, more than half a million of money. By offering long leases of twenty-one years. 220 LARGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS he guaranteed to improving farmers a return for their energy and outlay. Two years before the expiration of a lease, the tenant was informed of the new rent proposed, and offered a renewal. " My best bank," said one of his farmers, " is my land." At the same time he guarded against the mischief of a long unrestricted tenancy by covenants regulating the course of high-class cultivation. Though management clauses were then comparatively unknown in English leases, his farms commanded competition among the pick of English farmers. " Live and let Uve " was not only a toast at the Holkham sheep-shearings, but a rule in the control of the Holkham estate. Cobbett was not prejudiced in favour of landlords. Yet even he was compelled to admit the benefits which Coke's tenants derived from his paternal rule. " Every one," he writes in 1821, " made use of the expressions towards him which affectionate children use towards their parents." One great obstacle to the improvement of Norfolk farming remained. Farmers of the eighteenth century lived, thought, and farmed like farmers of the thirteenth century. Wheat instead of rye might be grown with success ; turnips, if drilled, were more easily hoed and yielded a heavier crop than those which were sown broadcast ; marl and clay might help to consolidate drifting soil. But the neighbouring farmers were suspicious of new methods, and distrusted a young man who disobeyed the saws and maxims of their forefathers. Politics ran so high that Coke's Southdowns were denounced as " Whiggish sheep." It was nine years before he found anyone to imitate him in growing wheat. " It might be good for Mr. Coke ; but it was not good enough for them." As to potatoes, the best they would say was, that " perha})s they wouldn't poison the pigs." Even those who had given up broad- cast sowing still preferred the dibber to the drill. Sixteen years passed before the implement was adopted. Coke himself calculated that his improvements travelled at the rate of a mile a year. The Holkham sheep-shearings did much by ocular demonstration to break down traditions and prejudices. These meetings originated in 1778, in Coke's own ignorance of farming matters ; small parties of farmers were annually invited to discuss agricultural topics at his house and aid him with their practical advice. Before many years had passed, the gatherings had grown larger, and Coke had become a teacher as well as a learner. The Holkham sheep- THE HOLKHAM SHEEP-SHEARINGS 221 shearing in Jtine, 1806 is described in the Farmer's Magazine ^ in the stilted language of the day, as " the happy resort of the most distingnished patrons and amateurs of Georgia employments." In 1818 open house was kept at Holkham for a week ; hundreds of persons assembled from aU parts of Great Britain, the Continent, and America. The mornings were spent in inspecting the land and the stock ; at three o'clock, six hundred persons sate down to din- ner ; the rest of each day was spent in discussion, toasts, and speeches. The Emperor of Russia sent a special representative, and among the learners was Erskine, who abandoned the study of Coke at Westminster HaU to gather the wisdom of his namesake at Holkham. At the sheep-shearings, year after year, were col- lected practical and theoretical agriculturists, farmers from every district, breeders of every kind of stock, who compared notes and exchanged experiences. In many other parts of England similar meetings were held by great landlords, like the Duke of Bedford at Wobum,* or Lord Egremont at Petworth, who in their own localities were carrying on the same work as Coke. At Holkham and Wobum sheep-shearings, both landlords and farmers were learners ; both required to be educated in the new principles of their altered business. It was by no means uncommon to find landlords who prevented progress by refusing to let land except at will, or bound their tenants by restrictive covenants to follow obsolete practices. There was, moreover, a tendency among the land-owning class to expect from rent-payiog tenants a greater outlay on the land than a farmer's capital could bear or an occupier was justified in making. The question of improvements had not yet assumed the compUcated forms which have developed under modem agricultural methods. But it had already been raised in the simpler shape. The habiUty for improvements of a permanent character required to be defined ; no distinction was yet drawn between changes which added some lasting benefit to the holding and those whose effects were exhausted within the limits of a brief occupation. Expenditure which might legitimately be borne by landlords was often demanded from tenants at will or even from year to year. Thousands of acres still lay unproductive because owners looked to occupiers for the reclamation of waste, the drainage of ^ Farmer's Magazine, August, 1806. 'For a deeciiption of a Wobum sheep-Bhearing, or "this truly rational Agricultural Fete," see Farmer' » Magazine for July, 1800. 222 LAEGE FARMS AND CAPITALIST FARMERS swamps, or an embankment against floods. It was one of the lessons which were taught by the agricultural depression after the peace of 1816 that landowners must find the money for lasting improvements effected on their property. That farmers should have realised the possibility of improving traditional practices weis a great step in advance. The new race of men, who were beginning to occupy land, were better educated, commanded more capital, were more open to new ideas and more enterprising than their predecessors. Their holdings were larger, and offered greater scope for energy and experiment. The Reporters to the Board of Agriculture on Northumberland (1805) lay stress on the size of the farms, and on the spirit of enterprise and in- dependence which now animated the tenants. " Scarcely a year passes without some of them making extensive tours for the sole purpose of examining modes of culture, of purchaaing or hiring the most improved breeds of stock, and seeing the operations of new- invented and most useful implements." The Reporter on Middle- sex (1798) emphasises the stagnation of farming among small occupiers. " It is rather the larger farmers and yeomen, or men who occupy their own land, that mostly introduce improvements in the practice of agriculture, and that uniformly grow much greater crops of com, and produce more beef and mutton per acre than others of a smaller capital." The Oxfordshire Reporter (1809) says : "If you go into Banbury market next Thursday, you may distinguish the farmers from enclosures from those from open fields ; quite a different sort of men ; the farmers as much changed as their husbandry— quite new men, in point of knowledge and ideas." Elsewhere in the same Report, — ^it is Arthur Young who writes, — occurs the following passage : The Oxfordshire farmers " are now in the period of a great change in their ideas, knowledge, practice, and other circumstances. Enclosing to a greater pro- portional amount than in almost any other county in the kingdom, has changed the men as much as it has improved the country ; they are now in the ebullition of this change ; a vast amelioration has been wrought, and is working ; and a great deal of ignorance and barbarity remains. The Goths and Vandals of open-fields touch the civilisation of enclosures. Men have been taught to thinik, and till that moment arrives, nothing can be done effectively. When I passed from the conversation of the farmers I was recom- mended to call on, to that of men whom chance threw in my way. THE NEW RACE OF TENANTS 223 I seemed to have lost a century in time, or to have moved a thousand miles in a day. Liberal communication, the result of enlarged ideas, was contrasted with a dark ignorance under the covert of wise suspicions ; a sullen reserve lest landlords should be rendered too knowii^, and false information given under the hope that it might deceive, were in such opposition, that it was easy to see the change, however it might work, had not done its business. The old open-field school must die off before new ideas can become generally rooted." In Lincolnshire, in the early years of George m., Arthur Young had found few points in the management of arable land which did not merit condemnation. The progress, which he noted as Reporter to the Board of Agriculture in 1799, was largely due to the changed character of the farmers. " I have not," he says, " seen a set more liberal in any part of the kingdom. Industrious, active, enlightened, free from all foolish and expensive show, . . . they live comfortably and hospitably, as good farmers ought to live ; and in my opinion are remarkably void of those rooted prejudices which sometimes are reasonably objected to this race of men. I met with many who had moimted their nags, and quitted their homes purposely to examine other parts of the king- dom ; had done it with enlarged views, and to the benefit of their own cultivation." CHAPTER XL OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS (1793-1815). Condition of open-field arable land and pasture commons as described by the Reporters to the Board of Agriculture, 1793-1815 ; (1) The North and North- Western District ; (2) West Midland and South- Western District ; (3) South-Eastem and Midland District ; (4) Eastern and North-Eastem District ; (6) the Fens ; the cumulative effect of the evidence ; procedure under private Enclosure Acts ; its defects and cost ; the General enclosure Act of 1801 ; the Inclosure Commissioners ; the new Board of Agriculture. It might perhaps be supposed that in 1793 the agricultural defects of the ancient system of open arable fields and common pasture had been remedied by experience ; that open-field farmers had shared in the general progress of farming ; that time alone was needed to raise them to the higher level of an improved standard ; that, therefore, enclosures had ceased to be an economic necessity. In 1773, an important Act of ParUament had been passed,^ which attempted to help open-field farmers in adapting their inconvenient system of occupation to the improved practices of recent agriculture. Three-fourths of the partners in viUage-farms were empowered, with the* consent of the landowner and the titheowner, to appoint field-reeves, and through them to regulate and improve the cultiva- tion of the open arable fields. But any arrangement made under these powers was only to last six years, and, partly for this reason, the Act seems to have been from the first almost a dead letter. At Hunmanby, on the wolds of the East Riding of Yorkshire,* the provisions of the Act were certainly put in force, and it is 1 13 Geo. III. c. 81. ' Isaac Leatham's General View of the Agriculture of the East Riding of York- shire (1794), p. 46. Thomas Stone, in his Suggestions for Rendering the In- dosure of Common Fields and Waste iLands a source of Population and Riches (1787), says that he knew of no instance in which the Act had been put in force. CONDITION OF OPEN-FIELDS AND COMMONS 225 possible ihait it was also applied at Wilburton in Cambridgeshiie. With these exceptions, little, if any, nse seems to have been made of a well-intentioned piece of legislation. Small prepress had in fact been made among the cultivators of open-fields. Here and there, the new spirit of agricnltoral enter- prise had influenced the occupiers of village farms. In rare instances improved practices were introduced. But the demand for increased food supplies had become, as our ancestors were experiencing, too pressing for delay. Any continuous series of adverse seasons created a real scarcity of bread, and more than once during the Napoleonic wars, famine was at the door. Unless food could be produced at home, it could not be obtained elsewhere. An extension of the cultivated area was the quickest means of adding to production. Agriculturists at the close of the eighteenth century were convinced that no adequate increase in the produce of the soil could be obtained, unless open-field farms were broken up, and the commons brought into more profitable cultivation. If they were right in that belief, the great agricultural change was justified, which established the uniform system with which we are familiar to-day. The point is one of the greatest importance. The uncritical praises lavished by sixteenth and seventeenth century travellers on open-field {arming are of little value because they had no higher standard with which to compare its results. Such a standard had now been to some extent created. It may therefore be useful to illustrate, from the contemporary records supplied by the Reports to the Board of Agriculture,^ the condition of open arable land and of pasture-commons in the years 1793-1815. The material is arranged according to the four districts into which, for statistical purposes, the English counties are usually divided. The cumulative force of the evidence is great. But some of it relates to wastes which were not attached to village farms, although common of pasture and fuel was often claimed over the area by the inhabitants of the neighbourhood. As to the reliability of the whole evidence, it * The Reports to the Board aie extant in two forms. The quarto editions were drafts, intended for private circulation and for correction by practical agriculturists belonging to the district under survey. They all belong to the years 1793-94-96. The octavo editions are the Reports in their final form. They were published at various dates, ranging from 1795 in the case of Holt's Loneathire, to 1816 when Quayle's Channel Islands was issued. In some cases the Reports are practically the same in their draft and final forms. Sometimes, on the other hand, they were re-written by other Reporters with scarcely any reference to the original Survey. P 226 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS would be only fair to add that the Reporteis were not likely to be prejudiced in favour of open-field farms or unappropriated commons. 1. In the North and North-Westem District, enclosure had gone on apace since 1770. In Northumberland, for instance (1805), very little common land was left which could be made profitable under the plough. 120,000 acres were said to have been enclosed " in the last thirty years." ^ In Durham, it is stated that " the lands, or common fields of townships, were for the most part inclosed soon after the Restoration." The Reporter laments " that in some of the rich parts of the county, particularly in the neighbourhood of the capital of it, large quantities of land should still he totally deprived of the benefit of cultivation, in commons ; and that ancient indosures, by being subject to the perverse custom of intercommon, be prevented from that degree of fertilization, to which the easy opportunity of procuring manure, in most cases, would certainly soon carry the improvement of them ; in their present state, little or no benefit is derived to any person what- soever, entitled either to common, or intercommon, from the use of them." * The waste lands of the West Riding of Yorkshire • are calculated at 265,000 acres capable of cultivation. The Reporter proposes to " add to these the common fields which are also exten- sive, and susceptible of as much improvement as the wastes." The man on inclosed land " has not the vis inertiae of his stupid neighbour to contend with him, before he can commence any alteration in his management ... he is completely master of his land, which, in its open state, is only half his own. This is strongly evident in the cultivation of turnips, or other vegetables for the winter consump- tion of cattle ; they are constantly cultivated in inclosures, when they are never thought of in the open fields in some parts." In the North Riding " few open or common fields now remain, nearly the whole having long been inclosed." * But on the commons the practice of surcharging is said to have increased to " an alarming degree." It had become a frequent custom for persons, often dwelling in distant townships, to take single fields which were entitled to common rights, and stock the commons with an excessive quantity of cattle. In Cumberland (1794),^ there were still 160,000 1 NorOamberland, by J. BaUey and O. Culley (Srd edition, 1805), p. 126. * Granger's Durham (1704), p. 44. ■ Broom's Wat Biding of Yorkthire (1799), pp. 131, 133. * Take's North Riding (1800), pp. 90, 199. * OumberJond, by J. BaUey and G. Culley (1794), pp. 202, 215, 236. NORTH AND NORTH-WESTERN DISTRICT 227 acres of improvable common, which were " generally oreistocked." " No improvement of breed was possible, while a man's ewes mixed promiscuously with his neighbour's flocks." There were "few commons bnt have parts which are liable to rot, nor can the sheep be prevented from depastoring it." " If any part of the flock had the scab or other infectious disease, there was no means of preventing it from spreading." A large part of these commons was good corn-land ; if enclosed, and part ploughed for grain crops, not only would there be an increased supply of com, but, instead of " the ill-formed, poor, starved, meagre animalH that depasture it at present," there might be " an abundant supply of fat mutton sent to our big towns." In Cheshire (1794),^ there were said to be of " common fields, probably not so much as 1000 acres." StafEordshire ^ in 1808 contained Uttle more than 1000 acres of open- fields, which " are generally imperfectly cultivated, and exhausted by hard tillage." Since the reduction of their area, the general produce of the county is stated to be greater, the stock better, and the rent higher by 5s. an acre. The county was " emerging out of barbarism." But, thirty years before, on some of the " best land of the county," the rotation had been " (1) fallow ; (2) wheat ; (3) barley ; (4) oats ; and often oats repeated, aiid then left to Nature ; the worst lands left to pasture and spontaneous rubbish ; tamips and artificial grasses scarcely at all known in farming." In Derbyshire ' (1811), a list of the thirteen open arable fields which remained is given. " Many of them," aa-ya the Reporter, " must remain in their present open, unproductive, and disgraceful state, (though principally in the best stratum in the County) " owing to the expense of enclosure. There were, however, still thirty-six open commons, such as Elmton, with its " deep cart-ruts, and every other species of injury and neglect that can, perhaps be shown on useful land ; part of it has been ploughed at no distant period, as completely exhausted as could be, and then resigned to Weeds and Paltry " ; or Hollington, which, " though overgrown with Rushes through neglect, is on a rich Red Marl soil " ; or Roston, " miserably carted on, cut up, and in want of Draining ; in wet seasons it generally rots the sheep depastured on it ; . . . pro- bably injurious, rather than beneficial, in its present state, both to the Parishioners and the Public." I Wedge's Cheshire (1794), p. 8. * Pitt's Staffordthire (1808), pp. 13. 61. 313. * Fszejr's Derbyshire (1813). voL ii. p. 77. 228 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS 2. In the West Midland and South-Weatem District, Shropshire (1794) ^ " does not contain much common field lands, most of these having been formerly enclosed, and before acts of parliament for that purpose were in use ; but the inconvenience of the property being detached and intermixed in small parcels, is severely felt, as is also the inconvenience of having the farm buildings in villages." There still remained large commons of which the largest were Giun Forest and Morfe Common, near Bridgnorth. The Reporter strongly advocates their enclosure. " The idea of leaving them in their unimproved state, to bear chiefly gorse bushes, and fern, is now completely scouted, except by a very few, who have falsely conceived that the inclosing of them is an injury to the poor ; but if those persons had seen as much of the contrary effects in that respect as I have, I am fully persuaded their opposition would at once cease. Let those who doubt, go round the commons now open, and view the miserable huts, and poor, ill-cultivated, im- poverished spots erected, or rather throum together, and inclosed by themselves, for which they pay 6d. or Is. per year, which, by loss of time both to the man and his family, affords them a very trifle towards their maintenance, yet operates upon their minds as a sort of independence ; this idea leads the man to lose many days work by which he gets a habit of indolence ; a daughter kept at home to milk a poor half -starved cow, who being open to tempta- tions, soon turns harlot, and becomes a distressed, ignorant mother, instead of making a good useful servant." Herefordshire^ (1794) contained a great number of open-field farms, occupying some of " the best land of the coimty," and puiBuing the " invariable rotation of (1) fallow, (2) wheat, (3) pease or oats, and then fallow again." Speaking of the waste lands at the foot of the Black Mountains above the Golden Valley, the Reporter says : " I do appeal to such gentlemen as have often served on Grand Juries in this county, whether they have not had more felons brought before them from that than from any other quarter of the county." He attributes this lawlessness to the right, which the cottager possessed in virtue of his arable holding, of turning out stock on the hills, and to the encouragement which this right afforded him of living by any means other than his labour. 1 Bishton's Bhropahin (1794), pp. 8, 24. 2 Clark's Henfordthirt (1794), pp. 69, 28. WEST MIDLAia) AND SOUTH-WESTERN DISTRICT 229 Worcest^ahire ^ (1794) contained from 10,000 to 20,000 acres of wastes, "in general depastuied by a miserable breed of sheep, bdonging to the adjoining cottagers and occupiers, placed there for the sake of their fleeces, the meat of which seldom reaches the market, a third fleece being mostly the last return they live to make." Tet, adds the Reporter, " most of the common or waste land is capable of being converted into tillage of the first quality." Gonsid^able tracts still lay in open-fields, especially in the neigh- bourhood of Bredon, Ripple, and to the east of Worcester. " The advantages from inclosing common fields . . . have been very considerable ; . . . the rent has always risen, and mostly in a very great proportion ; the increase of produce is very great, the value of stock has advanced almost beyond conception ; . . . indeed it is in incloBOT^ alone, that any improvement in the fine of breeding in general can be made." Speaking of the district towards the Gloucestershire border, it is stated that " the lands being in com- mon fields, and property much intermixed, there can be of course but little experimental husbandry ; being, by custom, tied down to three crops and a fallow. . . . The mixture of property in our fields prevents our land being drained, and one negligent farmer, from not opening his drains, will frequently flood the lands of ten that lie above, to the very great loss of his neighbours and com- munity at large. Add to this, that although our lands are naturally well adapted to the breed of sheep, yet the draining etc. is so little attended to in general, that, out of at least 1000 sheep, annually pastured in our open fields, not more than forty, on an average, are annually drawn out for slaughter, or other uses ; infectious disorders, lot, scab, etc. sweep them oS, which would not be the case if property were separated." Of the pasture commons, it is said that they are " overstocked," " produce a b^garly breed of sheep," and " are of little or no value." Again, it is stated that, where enclosures " have been completed fifteen or twenty years, property is trebled ; the lands drained ; and if the land has not been converted into pasture, the produce of grain very much increased ; where converted into pasture, the stock of sheep and cattle wonderfully improved. Where there are large commons, advantages are innumerable, to population as well as cultivation, and instead of a horde of pilferers, yon obtain a skilful race, as well of mechanics as other labourers." ' Pomeioy'B Woree»tenhire (1794), pp. 17, 16, App. pp. 2, 3, 5. 230 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS In Gloucestershire ^ (1794) common fields and common meadows stiU prevailed over extensive districts. Of the Gotswold district the Reporter says : " probably no part of the kingdom has been more improved within the last forty years than the Cotswold Hills. The first inclosures are about that standing ; but the greater part are of a later date. Three parishes are now inclosing ; and out of about thirteen, which still remain in the common field state, two, I understand, are taking the requisite measures for an inclosure : the advantages are great, rent more than doubled, the produce of every kind proportionably increased." Of the Vale of Gloucester he says : " I know one aere which is divided into eight lands, and spread over a large common field, so that a man must travel two or three miles to visit it all. But though this is a remarkable instance of minute diviraon, yet, it takes place to such a degree, as very much to impede all the processes of husbandry. But this is not the worst ; the lands shooting different ways, some serve as headlands to turn on in ploughing others ; and frequently when the good manager has sown his com, and it is come up, his slovenly neighbour turns upon it, and cuts up more for him, than his own is worth. It likewise makes one occupier subservient to another in cropping his land ; and in water furrowing, one sloven may keep the water on, and poison the lands of two or three industrious neighbours." Lot meadows were numerous in the county, on which the herbage was common after hay-making. Several tracts such as Corse Lawn, Huntley and Gorsley Commons were practically wastes, " not only of very little real utility, but productive of one very great nuisance, that of the erection of cottages by idle and dissolute people, sometimes from the neighbourhood, and sometimes strangers. The chief building materials are store-poles, stolen from the neighbouring woods. These cottages are seldom or never the abode of honest industry, but serve for harbour to poachers and tiueves of all descriptions." In the Vale of Tewkesbury the common fields were " very subject to rot. . . . Though it is reckoned they (farmers) lose their flocks once in three years on average, there is a considerable quantity kept, the farmers being persuaded they could not raise com without them. The arable fields after harvest are stocked without stint. When spring seedtime commences, they are confined to the fallow quarter of the field, and stinted in pro- portion to the properties ; they are folded every night, and kept > Tomer's Olouealenhire (1794), pp. 10, 39, 49. GLOUCESTERSHIRE IN 1794 AND 1807 231 BO hard, that scarce a blade of grass or even a thistle escapes them ; and this management is thought essentially necessary, especially on the stifi soils, to keep them in good order, such soils being too hard to plough in very dry weather, and, of coarse, not eligible in wet. The grass and weeds, without this expedient, would often get so much ahead as not to be afterwards conquered." Another agricultural Report on Gloucestershire^ was presented in 1807. The Reporter mentions that, in the reign of George m., " more tiian seventy Acts have passed the ParUament for inclosing or laying into severalty." " By these proceedings, the landlord and occupier are benefited ; the former in an advance of rent, the latter in the increase of crops. On the Ootswolds, many thousand acres are brought into cultivation, which before were productive of Uttie more than furze and a few scanty blades of grass. In the Vale, by the inclosure of common fields, lands have been laid together, and rescued from the immemorial custom, or routine of crops — ^wheat, beans, and fallow ; and the farmers have found, to their great advantage, that clover, vetches and turnips may be raised in the fallow year, which was before attended only with labour and expense." The Reporter enumerates five advantsiges resulting from enclosure of common field farms : — (1) an increase of crops and rent ; (2) the commutation of tithes ; (3) the drainage of the land ; (4) the removal of the injury and cause of disputes occasioned by turning on the head- and fore-lands of neighbours ; <5) the encouragement of population. Of the advantages of enclos- ing common pastures or wastes he is equally convinced ; " the common or waste lands in the Vale are seldom stinted to a definite quantity of stock in proportion to the number of acres occupied ; but the cottager claims by custom to stock equally with the largest landholder. It is justly questioned whether any profit accrues to either from the depasturing of sheep, since the waste commons, being under no agricultural management, are usually poisoned by stagnated water, which corrupts or renders unwholesome the herbage, producing rot, and other diseases in the miserable animals that are turned adrift to seek their food there." Since 1794 Ciorse Common had been enclosed. From the results the Reporter of 1807 illustrates some of the benefits of enclosure. " The supposed advantages derived by cottagers, in having food for a few sheep and geese on a neighbouring common, have usually been brought f or- I Badge's GlfiueegtersMre (1807). pp. 89, 260. 232 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS watd as objectioiis to the enclosing system. This question was much agitated with regard to the inclosure of Corse Chaoe in this county; but if the present state and appearance of it, since the inclosure in 1796, be contrasted to what it was before, or its present produce of com to the sheep that used to run over it, Uttle doubt can remain of the advantageous result in favour of the community ; 1350 acres of wet and rushy waste were inclosed, and, in the first year of cultivation, the produce was calculated at 20,250 bushels of wheat, or of some other crop in equal proportion. If it could even be proved that some cottagers were deprived of a few trifling advantages, yet the small losses of individuals ought not to stand in the way of certain improvements on a large scale." The Reporter also quotes two Cotswold parishes, formerly open-fields, but now enclosed, as examples of increased produce. In Aldsworth, the annual produce of com rose from 720 quarters to 2300 quarters ; in Eastington, it increased from 690 quarters to 2100 quarters. He adds that enclosures encouraged labour. " Labourers, who formerly were under the necessity of seeking employment in London and other places, now find it in sufficient quantity at home in. their respective parishes." In Somersetshire ^ (1797) the two largest districts of waste land were the Brent Marsh and King's Sedgmoor. The Reporter describes the Brent Marsh as a country which had " been hereto- fore much neglected, probably on account of the stagnant waters,. and unwholesome air. But of late many efforts have been mad& to improve the soil, by draining and enclosing, under a variety of Acts of Parliament. The benefit resulting therefrom has beea astonishing." The total area was over 20,000 acres, of which many thousands, " heretofore overflown . . . and of little or no value, are become fine grazing and dairy lands." Besides the- general improvement to the health of the district, " scarcely & farmer can now be found who does not possess a considerable landed property ; and many whose fathers lived in idleness and sloth, on the precarious support of a few half-starved cows, or a few limping geese, are now in affluence." On the South Marsh, chiefly formed by the river Parret, " near thirty thousand acres of fine land are frequently overflown for a considerable time together, renderings the herbage unwholesome for the cattle, and the air imhealthy to the inhabitants." An Act of ParUament had been recently (1791 > 1 BillingBley's BomeraeUiMre (1797), pp. 167-73, 188. DORSETSHIRE AND WILTSHIRE 23* obtained for draming a portion of this fen called King's Sedgmoor, containing " aboat 20,000 acres." The Doisetshiie ^ commons in 1794 were " generally overrun with fnize and ant-hills," worth 8s. an acre unenclosed, bat " highly proper to cultivate, and, if converted, would be worth from 18s. to 20s. an acre." A second Report on Dorsetshire waa issued in 1812.* The Reporter calls attention to the " half year meads." One person has the hay, and another person the " after-shear." These meadows were not near commonable fields, and the origin of the claim is not clear. Obviously, neither of the persons who shared the produce was likely to attempt to improve the herbage. In Wiltshire • (1794) the Reporter fixes on four disadvantages of open-field husbandry : (1) the obligation to plough and crop all soils alike ; (2) the impossibility of improving sheep ; (3) the diffi- culty of raising food for their winter keep ; (4) the expense, trouble, and excessive number of horses required to cultivate detached dispersed lands. On the south-east side of the county lay a con- siderable tract of open-fields, and in the north-west, in the centre of the richest land of the district, were scattered numerous commons. The open arable fields are said to be in "a very bad state of husbandry," and the common pastures in a " very neglected unimproved " condition. " There are," says the Reporter, " numerous instances in which the common-field arable land lets for less than half the price of the inclosed arable adjoining ; and the commons are very seldom reckoned worth anything, in valuii^ any estate that has a right on them." For the last half-century very little land had been enclosed, " although the improvement on the lands, heretofore inclosed, has been so very great." " The reason seems to have been the very great difficulty and expence of making new roads in a country naturally wet and deep, and where the old public roads were, till within the last few years, almost impassable." Good turnpike roads had now been introduced ; villages were energetic in repairing the approaches to them ; and " it is to be hoped that so great an improvement as that of inclosing and cultivating the commonable lands will no longer be neglected." The crying need was the want of drainage. The common pastures 1 daridge's Dorsetshire (1793), p. 43. > Stevenson's Dorsetshire (1812), p. 307. * Davis' Wiltshire (1794), p. 136. This is, perhaps, the beet of all the agri- cnltoral Reports. 234 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS from Westbuiy to Orioklade were in a " wet rotten state," depas- tured by an " unprofitable kind of stock," but " wanting only inclosing and draining to make them as good pasture land as many of the surrounding inclosures." Some of the cold arable fields would have been much more valuable if turned to pasture, and, in their undrained state, even the driest were " not safe for sheep in a wet autumn." 3. From the Sovth-Eastem and Midland District the evidence is the fullest, because the district was still in a great measure farmed on the open-field system. In Berkshire^ (1794) there were 220,000 acres of open-fields, and downs, to 170,000 acres of inclosed land. Half of the county " is still lying in common fields ; and though it is not divided into such very small parcels as in some other counties, the farmer labours under all the inconvenience of commonable land ; and by that, is withheld from improving or treating his land, so as to return the produce which it ought to do, if entire, and under a good course of husbandry." " We generally see on all the commons and waste lands, a number of miserable cattle, sheep, and horses, which are a disgrace to their respective breeds, and the cause of many distempers." In Buckinghamshire^ (1794) 91,906 acres remained in open- fields. The Reporters point out that " the slovenly operations of one man are often of serious consequence to his neighbours, with whose property his lands may lie, and generally do lie, very much intermixed. Every one is aware of the noxious quality of weeds, whose downy and winged seeds are wafted by every wind, and are deposited upon those lands which are contiguous to them ; and which before were perhaps as clean as the nature of them would admit, to the manifest injury of the careful and attentive farmer. Inclosures would, in a certain degree, lessen so great an evil ; they would also prevent the inroads of other people's cattle, as particularized in the parish of Wendover, and in which one man held eighteen acres in thirty-one different allotments." Oxfordshire ' in 1794 contained " upwards of an hundred unin- olosed parishes or hamlets." The Reporter enumerates several advantages of enclosure. " The first of these is getting rid of the 1 Pearce'B Berkshire (1794), pp. 13, 49, 69. > Jamee' and Malcolm's Buekinghanuhire (1794), pp. 32, 68. > Davis's Oxfordshire (1794), pp. 22, 30. OXFORDSHIRE IN 1794 AND 1809 236 restrictions of the former coarse of husbandry, and appropriating each of the various sorts of land to that use to which it is best adapted. 2. The prevention of the loss of time, both as to labourers and cattle, in travelling . . . from one end of a parish to another ; and also in fetching the horses from distant commons before they go to work. 3. There is a much better chance of escaping the distempers to which cattle of all kinds are Uable from being mixed with those infected, particularly the scab in sheep. This circum- stance, in common fields, must operate as a discouragement to the improvement of stock. ... 5. The great benefit which arises from draining lands, which cannot so well, if at all, be done on single acres and half acres, and would effectually prevent the rot amongst sheep, so very common in open field land. 6. Lastly the preventing of constant quarrels, which happen as well from the trespasses of cattle, as by ploughing away from each others' land." Otmoor, near IsUp, containing " about four thousand acres," is mentioned as the largest and most valuable tract of waste in the county. " This whole tract of land lies so extremely flat, that the water, in wet seasons, stands on it a long time together, and of coiuse renders it very unwholesome to the cattle, as well as the neighbourhood. The sheep are thereby subject to the rot, and the larger cattle to a disease called the moor evil. The abuses here (as is the case of most commons where many parishes are concerned) are very great, there being no regular stint, but each neighbouring householder turns out upon the moor what number he pleases. There are flocks of geese likewise kept on this common, by which several people gain a livelihood." In 1809, Arthur Young reported on Oxfordshire,^ where he found that, in proportion to its extent, more land had been enclosed since 1770 in the county than in any other part of England. Otmoor and Wychwood Forest were still uninclosed wastes. Apart from the question of productiveness, he urged that the enclosure of the latter district was necessary on moral grounds. " The vicinity is filled with poachers, deer-stealers, thieves, and pilferers of every kind ; offences of almost every description abound so much, that the offenders are a terror to all quiet and well-disposed persons ; and Oxford gaol would be uninhabited, were it not for this fertile source of crimes." Nearly one hundred parishes still remained in open-fields. " It is," says Young, speaking of open-field practices, 1 Young's Oxford»h4re (1809), pp. 87, 236, 239. 102. 236 OPEN-FIELD FABMS AND PASTURE COMMONS " a well-known fact that men have ploughed their land in the night for the express purpose of stealing a furrow from their neighbour ; and at all times it is a constant practice in some to plough from each other." " I have known," says one of his informants, " years wherein not a single sheep totally kept in the open field has escaped the rot." Yet on this same land, enclosed and drained, not one sheep died from the rot in nineteen years. In 1770, the South and East of Warwickshire had mainly con- sisted of open-fields. Now (1794) ^ there still remained 50,000 acres. But in 1813 ^ it is reported that a very small area continued in an unenclosed state. Northamptonshire,^ in 1794, contained 89 parishes still in opeh- fields. There was, therefore, " above one third of the whole (county) by no means in the best state of cultivation of which it is susceptible." The commons did not " yield pasturage," " at the highest computation," which was worth more than " 6s. an acre. Indeed, if the calculation was fairly made, the occupiers are not benefited to the extent of half that sum, as the stock which they send to depasture upon these commons is liable to so many diseases and accidents, as, one year with another, nearly counterbalances any advantages which can be derived from possessing this right. . . . By every information that could be procured, it appeara that the stock is not kept with a view to any profit that can possibly arise from the sales, but merely as the means of cultivating and manuring the soil. Indeed, long experience has evinced, that no species of stock kept in these open fields can be carried to market on terms nearly so advantageous as the same articles raised by those farmers who occupy inclosed lands ; nor is it to be supposed, considering the manner in which the stock is treated, that the owners will pay much attention to the improvement of the different breeds." As to the arable land, " the several occupiers must con- form to the ancient mode of cultivation of each division or field in which their lands are respectively situated ; from which it will appear that one obstinate tenant (and fortunate must that parish be accounted, where only one tenant of that description may be found) has it in his power to prevent the introduction of any improve- ment. . . . The tillage lands are divided into small lots of two or 1 Wedge's WarwickalwrR (1794), p. 20. < Murray's Wanmckahire (1813), pp. 62, 144. 3 Donaldson's Northantt (1794), pp. 24, 29, 68. SOUTH-EASTERN AND MIDLAND DISTRICTS 237 three old-fashioned, broad, crooked ridges (gathered very high towards the middle, or crown, being the only means of drainage that the manner in which the lands are occupied will admit of), and consequently the farmer possessing 100 acres must traverse the whole extent of the parish, however large, in order to cultivate this small portion." In Leicestershire ^ (1800) very little open-field land was left "not more than 10,000 acres." In Nottinghamshire* (1798) enclosure was proceeding rapidly. " Good land, with extensive commons," is said to be most capable of improvement ; " clay land with small commons," to have been the least capable. Midway between the two came " clay land with large commons." But " even the worst " may be increased in value by a fourth, after deducting all improvements. In Middlesex' (1794) many thousands of acres of wastes lay unenclosed — " an absolute nuisance to the public." The commons of Enfield, Edmonton, and Tottenham were frequently flooded ; but no efiort was made to keep the ditches scoured. In 1798 there were still 17,000 acres of " common meadows, all capable of improve- ment, not producing to the community in their present state more than 4s. an acre." To the Reporter's eyes the commons were " a real injury to the public," partly because they tempted the poor man to settle on their borders, build a cottage out of the material they afforded, and trust to his pigs and poultry for a living ; partly because they became " the constant rendezvous of gypse;^, strollers and other loose persons . . . the resort of footpads and highway- men." The arable land of the county is estimated at 23,000 acres, of which, in 1798, 20,000 were in open-fields. In Hampshire* (1813) the Reporter foimd the commons so over- stocked as to produce little or no substantial benefit to those who enjoyed the grazing rights, and the surface " shamefully deterio- rated " by the exercise of rights of turbary or paring turf for fuel. He hopes to see " every species of intercommonable rights extinguished," and, with them, " that nest and conservatory of sloth, idleness, and misery, which is uniformly to be witnessed in > Pitt's Leioesterthire (1800), p. 68. > Lowe's Nottingtianukire (1798), pp. 19, 166. • Foot's Middlesex (1794), pp. 30, 32, amd Middleton's Middltsez (1798), pp. 98, 103, 138. •Vancouver's Hampthirt (1813), pp. 318, 496. 238 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS the Tioinity of all commons, waste-lands, and forests throughout the kingdom." 4. In the Eastern and North-Eaetem counties, neither Essex nor Hertfordshire possessed many commons or open-field farms. A description of the inhabitants of the neighbourhood of Epping and HaJnault Forests in Essex (1795) has been already quoted.^ In Hertfordshire ' (1795) the Reporter notes that the few remaining open-fields had been freed from the old restraints, and were cul- tivated as if they were held in separate occupation. Speaking of pasture commons, he says : " Where wastes and commons are most extensive, there I have perceived that cottagers are the most wretched and worthless ; accustomed to reUe on a precarious and a vagabond subsistence, from land in a state of Nature, when that fails they recur to pilfering. . . . For cottagers of this descrip- tion the game is preserved and by them destroyed." Of Cheshunt Common * (1813) it is stated that " the common was not fed by the poor, but by a parcel of jobbers, who hired cottages, that they might eat up the whole." Two-thirds of the county of Huntingdon* in 1793 lay in open- fields. Proprietors rarely had more than two or three acres con- tiguous. " The residue Ues in acres and half acres quite disjointed, and tenants under the same land-owner cross each other con- tinually in performing their necessary daily labour. . . . The sheep of the common fields and commons are of a very inferior sort, except in some few instances, and httle if any care is taken either in the breeding, feeding or preserving them ; and from the neglected state of the land on which they are depastured, and the scanty provision for their support in winter, and the consequent diseases to which they are liable, their wool is also of a very inferior quality." On the uplands of Lincolnshire ^ (1794) there were but few open- field farms. " The sheep of the common fields," says the Reporter, " I do not bring into this account from the circumstances of hard- ship, attending the scantiness of their food, the wetness of their layer, the neglect of a proper choice in their breed, their being overheated in being (where folded) dogged to their confinement, > See p. 154. > Walker's Hertfordihire (170S), pp. 48, 63. * Young's Hertfordthire (1804), p. 46. < Stone's Htmtingdonthire (1703), pp. 8, 17, 16. > Stone's Lineoinahire (1704), p. 62. LINCOLNSHIRE AND THE EAST RIDING 239 where they are often too much crowded ; the scab, the rot, and every circumstance attend them, which can delay their being profitable ; so that it may be reasonably concluded, that they are of less value than those bred in inclosures, from 10s. to 15s. per head, and their fleeces are equally unproductive." Five years later Arthur Young reported on this part of the county.^ He describes the true Lincolnshire cattle which he found on open- field farms as a " wretched " breed ; " they all run together on a pasture, without the least thought of selection." At three years old, they were worth little more than half what they fetched on enclosed land. Open-field farmers " breed four or five calves from a wretched cow before they sell it, so that a great quantity of food is sadly misapphed." It was from this " post-legged, square-buttocked breed of demi-elephants," to use Marshall's description, that the Navy beef of England was chiefly provided. The open-field sheep had not improved. " I never," says Young, apparently with surprise, " saw a fold in the county, except in a few open fields about Stamford ; . . . but the sheep are miserably bad ; in wool 8 or 9 to the tod." In the East Riding ' of Yorkshire (1794) the pasture commons varied " in extent from two hundred to two thousand five hundred acres, and all of them may be con- verted into useful land by drains, sub-divisions, plantations, and other improvements. . . . When commons are not stinted in proportion to the stock they are capable of keeping, very little benefit is derived from them. ... It is not a Uttle extraordinary to see a starving stock upon a common of five hundred acres soaked with water, when the expense of a few shillings for each right, prudently laid out in drains and bridges, would double its value. Such is the obstinacy of men, and so difScult is it to induce them to form the same opinion ; though an union of sentiment would much more materially promote their intei-est." Norfolk ' in 1796 contained 80,000 acres of unimproved commons, and about one-fourth of the arable area of the county was tilled on the common or open-field system. " There is," says the Reporter, who was the well-known Nathaniel Kent, " still a considerable deal of common-field land in Norfolk, though a much less proportion than in many other counties ; for notwithstanding common rights > Young's Lincolnthire (1799), pp. 303. 374. ' Leatham's Eatt Riding (1794), p. 39. > Kent's NorfdUc (1796), pp. 6. 32, 72, 73, 81. 1S8. 240 OPEN-FIELD FARMS AND PASTURE COMMONS for great cattle eadst in all of them, and even sheep-walk privileges in many, yet the natural industry of the people is such, that, when- ever a person can get four or five acres together, he plants a white- thorn hedge round it, and sets an oak at every rod distance, which is consented to by a kind of general courtesy from one neighbour to another." " Land," he elsewhere remarks, " when very much From 1801 to 1810 the average amount of wheat annually imported was 600,946 quarters, or about 2 pec^ per head ; from 1811 to 1820 it was only 468,678 quarters. ' An Inguiry into the State of National Srtbsistenee, Appendix xxv. tINPROSPEROUS SEASONS 267 3,160,000 acres, and the produce, adopting Young's average rate, would be 9,480,000 quarters. In other words, while the population had increased by three millions, the wheat production had increased by only one million quarters. This calculation, however, allows nothing for the increased productiveness of the soil under improved management, does not take into account the surplus wheat obtain- able from Scotland and Ireland, and is at first sight contradicted by the large acreage which enclosures had added to the cultivated area. Evidence indeed exists to prove that the first effect of enclosures of open-field farms was often to diminish the com area. Against this decrease must be set the quantity of land which, under the spur of the high prices of the Napoleonic war, were brought under the plough and tilled for com. Comber's calculation of the wheat area appears to be extremely low ; but it is impossible to prove the suspected under-estimate. It is probably safe to say that, while in an average season enough wheat was grown in England and Wales to feed ten million people, the surplus was so small as to expose the country to panic prices whenever a deficiency in the normal yield was anticipated. This conclusion is confirmed by a closer examination of the yield of com harvests during the period. The seasons from 1765 to 1815 were far less favourable than those from 1715 to 1764 ; the former were as imiformly prosperous as the latter were uniformly adverse. Both in this coimtry, and throughout Europe, the harvests of 1765-67, 1770-74, fell much below the average. Prices rose high. Exports dwindled, and imports increased in volimie.^ In the decennial period 1765-1774, for the first time in the history of English farming, imports of foreign wheat exceeded the home- grown exports. Since that period they have never lost their pre- ponderance. For the next eighteen years (1775-1792) the seasons were irregular. Thus the harvest of 1779 was long famous for its productiveness. On the other hand, the years 1782-3-4 were most unfavourable, the winters unusually severe, and the spring and summer cold and ungenial. There ws/S a general scarcity of food. In 1782 the imports of wheat (584,183 quarters) were the largest yet known, and the figure was only once (1796 : 879,200 quarters) ' 1766-74, Exports (in round numbers) 610,000 quarters ; imports, 1,341,000, 1776-84, exports, 1,366,100 ; imports, 1,972,000. 1785-94, exports, 1,306,386 ; imports, 2,016,000. 1796-1804, exports, 636,000 ; imports, 6,686,000. 1806- 14, exports, 693,000 (nine years only, the records of 1813 having been destroyed) ; imports, 6,782,000. 268 THE ENGLISH CORN LAWS exceeded in the eighteenth century. Writing ia August, 1786, Arthur Young says : " Last winter, hay, straw, and fodder of all kinds were scarcer and dearer than ever known in this Kingdom. Severe frosts destroyed the turnips, and cattle of all kinds, and sheep suffered dreadfully ; many died, and the rest were in ill plight to fatten early in this summer." The crops of 1789 again were deficient. Exports were prohibited, and free imports permitted. But in France the scarcity almost amounted to famine. The Government spent large sums in the purchase of wheat, and Con- tinental prices ruled considerably above those of England. Against the deficient harvests of 1790 and 1792 may be set the season of 1791, which was so favourable that, for the last time in the history of the corn-trade,* the exports of the following year exceeded the imports. It will be seen that the yield of fourteen of the harvests during the twenty-eight years 1765-92 fell so far below the average as to create a scarcity ; that several others were defective ; and that only two (1779 and 1791) were really abundant. Yet, during the whole period, the total excess of imports of foreign wheat over the exports of home-grown produce only amounted to 1,661,000 quarters, or an average of little more than 59,000 quarters a year. It may, therefore, be reasonably assumed that, if England had enjoyed seasons as imiformly favourable as those of 1715-64, she would have been able to feed her growing population at low prices and yet to remain a grain-exporting country. The fact is a striking proof of her agricultural progress. It is more than doubtful whether such an expansion of her powers of production wotdd have been possible if the open-field system of farming had been maintained. In February, 1793, war was proclaimed with France. It continued with two brief intervals till 1816. As the struggle progressed the area of conflict was widened until it embraced America as well as Europe, and not only became a naval and military war in which all the Powers were engaged, but developed into a commercial blockade directed against this country. During the whole period the Com Laws were practically inoperative. The progress of the war created conditions of supply which alone would suffice to explain an unprecedented rise of prices. But the situation was through- ' 1792, exports, 300,278 quarters ; imports, 22,417. The statement in the text is not literally true. In 1808 the exports exceeded the imports by 13,116 quarters (98,006 to 84,889). But the exportation was to the Peninsula for military purposes and for the supply of our own troops. A CHRONIC CONDITION OP PANIC 269 ont aggravated by an unusual recurrence of unproductive seasons. The wheat harvests in the twenty-two years 1793-1814 ^ may be thus analysed. Fourteen were deficient ; in seven out of the fourteen, the crops failed to a remarkable extent, namely, in 1795, 1799, 1800, 1809, 1810, 1811, 1812. Six produced an average yield. Only two, 1796 and 1813, were abundant ; but the latter was long regarded as the best within living memory. Towards the close of the period, the increased extent of the wheat area to some degree com- pensated for the comparative failure of the crops. But the repeated deficiencies created an almost continuous apprehension of real scarcity which was expressed in abnormal prices. To a generation which draws its supplies from sources so remote that climatic con- ditions vary almost infinitely, the panic may seem unintelligible. It was not so in the days of the Napoleonic wars. The quantity available from the United States was scanty, and over the com areas of Europe a similar series of unproductive seasons seems to have prevailed. To this, however, there was one notable exception. The harvests of 1808 and 1809 were remarkably favourable in France and the Netherlands, and, at the very height of the struggle with Napoleon, it was from the French cornfields that England obtained her additional suppUes. The deficiency of the home harvests and the consequent fear of scarcity naturally raised prices of com. The upward tendency was in various ways enormously increased by the progress of the war and the commercial blockade which it developed. No doubt the struggle in which the country was engaged quickened the activity and industry of the population, stimulated agricultural improve- ments, sharpened the inventive faculties to economise both in money and in labour. On the other hand, the war raised the rate of interest, added to the burden of taxation, increased the cost of corn-growing, and withdrew into improduotive channels a con- siderable portion of the capital and labour of the country. Besides these ordinary results, the peculiar character which the struggle gradually assumed threatened to deprive England of any alternative supply of foreign grain which could supplement the resources that she derived from her own soil, from Scotland, and from Ireland. Again and again the political situation was reflected in Mark Lane. I Tooke's History of Prices, ed. 1867, Appendix vi. " Seasons 1792-1866 " ▼oL vi. pp. 471-83, 2 and 3 Philip and Maiy, u. 8. 282 HIGHWAYS by compulsory labour. Four days of eight hours eaoh^ were appointed for the work, the parishioners providing carts, teams, implements, and labour, according to their means. Like other Tudor legislation, the Act failed in its administration. Though neglect to discharge the Uabihty was punishable by fines, little efiect was produced. After the Restoration further efforts were made to improve facilities of communication. Stage, or long, waggons had begun in 1564 to ply between the metropolis and the principal towns in the provinces ; private carriages were increasing ; about 1645 stage- coaches were established. Travelling on wheels was recommended for its " admirable commodiousness," and many of those who thus traversed the roads to London were " persons of quality " who could make their influence felt. Some means, in addition to statute labour, was required to maintain the roads in repair for the increasing traffic. During the first ten years of the reign of Charles 11. it seemed probable that this supplement would be provided by the development of highway rates, which had been introduced in 1656. Eventually a new auxihary to statute labour was devised, which arrested the growth of rates, and prolonged the life of the old system by a century and a half. Li 1663 the first Turnpike Trust * was established on the Great North Boad by the erection of toll- bars at Wadesmill, Caxton, and Stilton, and by the exaction of toll from those who used the highway. This portion of one of the principal roads in the country is described in the Act as " ruinous and almost impassable." The inhabitants of the adjoining parishes were too poor to put or keep the highway in repair, and though the Act did not relieve them from their liability, the toUs raised a fund towards the maintenance of the road. Other turnpike trusts were established on the same principle. Their creation was unpopular. Biots broke out, like those subsequently associated with the name of Rebecca in Wales ; toll-bars were frequently pulled down and burned ; and the opposition was only checked by an Act passed in- the reign of George n. (1728) which made their destruction a felony. Turnpike Trusts multiplied rapidly, till in 1760 it was true to say that " no cit, nor doivn. Can gratis see the country or the town." » In 1862, by 6 Eliz. c. 13, the " statute labour," as it was called, was in- creased from 4 to 6 days. « 16 Car. n. c. 1. THE PERILS OP TRAVELLING 283 TraveBing still continued to be a peril. The number of patents that were taken out to prevent coaches from overturning is some evidence of the risk. Nor were the inventions always effective. They did not prevent George 11. and his queen from being upset in 1730 near Parsons Green on their way into London. In October, 1736, the queen was advised to leave Kensington Palace for St James's, because the road was so " infamously bad " as to separate her from her Ministers by " an impassable gulf of mud." If travelling was so difficult for royal personages over roads in the neighbourhood of London, the perils of penetrating rural districts may be imagined. In the winter months carriage traffic was suspended . Only horsemen could make their way. Judges and lawyers rode the circuits, chasing John Doe and Richard Roe from assize town to assize town on horseback. Few Quarter Sessions passed without some district being " presented " for non-repair of roads, and heavy were the fines inflicted by bruised and shaken judges, who, thinking that the majesty of the law was ill-supported by top-boots, endeavoured to reach their destination in carriages. Even after Turnpike Trusts were generally established, travelling stOl continued to be neither swift, nor easy, nor safe. Guide-posts were almost unknown, and the way was frequently lost. In the reign of Charles 11., the stage had taken two days to reach Oxford from London, and the journey to Ezeter occupied four days. A century later, the one stage-coach, which phed once a month between Edinburgh and London, accomplished the journey in from twelve to fourteen days. Family coaches, lumbering and jolting over the uneven roads, for steel springs were not applied to carriages before the middle of the eighteenth century, made twenty miles a day. They set out provisioned and armed as if for a siege. When Sir Francis Headpiece travelled to London, he carried with him in his coach " the fanuly basket-hilt-sword, the Turkish scimetar, the old blunder-buss, a good bag of bullets, and a great horn of powder." ^ Such precautions were not always effectual against a well-mounted highwayman, expert in the use of handier weapons ; and the slow pace at which vehicles travelled, unless they were defended with determination, made them easy victims. Off the frequented lines of communication, and often even on these, the condition of the eighteenth century roads, as has been ' Vonbrngh's Jmumey to London, produced on the stage by Cibber, in 1728, nnder the title of the Provoked Husband. 284 HIGHWAYS shown in a previous chapter, rendered travelling in the winter months difficult, and sometimes, except for horsemen, impossible. But after 1760 a determined efiEort was made at improvement. Here and there some local genius, like " Blind Jack " Metcalf of Knaresborough, had already anticipated the methods of Telford and McAdam. In other parts of England, the turnpike trusts were placing portions of the highways in better repair. But the districts for which they were formed were often too small to be useful. Thus the main road from Shrewsbury to Bangor (85 miles) was in the care of six trusts, most of them in debt, all too poor to pay for skilled labour, and each too jealous of the others to co-operate. The multiplication of these turnpike trusts, though it often defeated its own object, affords strong evidence of the ertent to which pubUc attention had been called to the need for improved facilities of communication. Between 1760 and 1774 no less than 452 Turnpike Acts were passed, and in the sixteen years from 1785 to 1800 this number was increased by 643. Two General Highway Acts were passed in 1773 ^ which consolidated the previous legislation on the subject of parochi^.! Ua- biUty for road repair, transferred the appointment of surveyors to the justices of the peace out of lists of names submitted by each parish, allowed the compulsory statute labour for six days to be commuted by money payments, and authorised the levy of a rate, not exceeding 6d. in the pound, for the provision of road materials. In 1784 Palmer organised the service of mail-coaches. But letters were often stiU left at inns on main thoroughfares, where they remained in the bar till the ink had faded and the wrapper had turned the colour of saffron. The arrival of the pedlar was still eagerly expected in country villages, where he did not always appear as the philosophical enthusiast of the poet's licence. Rather he was the milliner of rural beauties, the arbiter of fashion to village bucks, the newsagent of the alehouse politician, the retailer of the most recent gossip, the vendor of smuggled tea, the purveyor of the latest amorous ditty. He was typical of the times when villages were isolated, self-sufficing, dependent on his summer foid winter circuits for their knowledge of the world beyond the parish boundaries. Both Young and Marshall note the improvement which was made during the last quarter of the eighteenth century in the roads of certain districts. Yet their writings, as well as the reports to the Board of Agriculture (1793-1815), afford abundant evidence that else- 1 13 Oeo. m. cc. 78 and 84. SLOW PROGRESS OF IMPROVEMENT 285 where much remained to be done. For the slow progress made there were many reasons. Country gentlemen used the same arguments against new roads which were afterwards employed against railways. " Merry England " would be merry no longer if her highways ceased to be miry. They dreaded the disturbance of their game, feared the intrusion of town manners, resented the sacrifice of their interests to those of wealthy traders. As magistrates they were reluctant to enforce the law of road-repair against their own tenants. Statute labour was deservedly unpopular. Surveyors, forced into oflSce against their will, only called upon their neighbours to fulfil their liabilities as a last resource, and at seasons when agricultural work was slack. Urban and rural interests were opposed. Market towns might demand metalled roads for the transport of their merchandise ; but self-sufficing villages were content with the drift- ways which were sufficient to enable them to house their crops, and to drag their flour from the mill through the same ruts which their ancestors had worn. Even when a parish was active in road-repair, its energies were generally misdirected. Roads were unguarded at the sides. Drainage was often provided by cutting open grips across their surface. If any convexity was attempted, it was so exaggerated as to be dangerous ; the sides sloped like the roof of a house. Hence the whole traffic fell on the centre, which soon wore into ruts. Many roads were undrainable, because the continual scraping of mud from the surface had sunk them below the level of the adjoining land. Hence they were always wet, and, from the rapid decay of material, expensive to maintain. Where a parish was apathetic, the least possible mending was done in the worst possible way. A faggot, or a bimdle of broom or heather, powdered with gravel, served to stop a bad hole ; if beyond repair by such means, mud, scraped from the sides of the roads and ditches, was thrown on the centre of the road, and into this bed was shot a cartload of large unbroken stones. Not infrequently the road material, raised and carted at the parish expense, missed its destination, and made good, not the road, but the gateways or the yard of some neighbouring farmer. The system of road maintenance was proving inadequate for modem requirements. Responsibihty ceased at the parish boun- daries, and no uniformity was possible. The statute labour was everywhere enforced with difficulty. It was also exhausted at one particular season, and nothing more was done till the period recurred. It was a system of occasional outlay without continuous repair. 286 HIGHWAYS Surveyors were not appointed for their skill, but were compelled to serve against their will. The experience which they gained in their twelve months' service was wasted by their retirement at the end of the year when their successors were appointed. Already in France, Pierre de Tr^saguet (1716-74) had set an example to European countries, laid down the principles of the construction of broken- stone roads, organised his corps of day-labourers, and substituted the principle of continuous upkeep for that of periodic repair. Already both Ireland and Scotland had gained a lead over England in the matter of road improvement. In Ireland statute labour was abolished in 1765,^ and road-making entrusted to the County Grand Juries. Arthur Young says that before the Act was passed, Irish roads, " like those of England, remained impassable under the miserable poUce of the six days' labour ; . . . now the effect in all parts of the Kingdom is so great, that I found it perfectly practicable to travel upon wheels by a map. I will go here, I will go there ; I could trace a route upon paper as wild as fancy could dictate ; and everywhere I found beautiful roads, without break or hindrance, to enable me to realise my design." * In Scotland, in 1803, Com- missioners were appointed for making roads in the Highlands. The expense was defrayed in equal portions by grants from Parha- ment and local contributions ; the assistance of Telford was secured, and more than 900 miles of good roads were constructed. England, however, still lagged behind. Various alterations in the law were proposed and discussed. It was suggested that the labour service should be commuted for a money payment, and that, even if only a quarter of the equivalent were obtained in money, the roads would gain. On the other hand, it was said that commutation would be certainly unpopular with farmers, who would regard the pecuniary liability as a new tax. It was urged that large districts should be formed by uniting a number of parishes ; that surveyors should be appointed for their knowledge of road-making, and should be paid salaries ; or that, as Mace had suggested in 1675, " daymen " should be continuously employed upon the roads at weekly wages. It was not, however, till twenty years after the peace of 1815 that any substantial legislative changes were made. Before that time the science and practice, as well as the expense, of road-making and repair had made considerable advance. From 1811 onwards Parliamentary Committees sat almost continuously to hear evidence 1 Irish Acts, 6 Geo. III. o. 14. * Tour in Iretfmi, part ii. p. 40. McADAM AND TELFORD 287 and to report. It was gradually realised that the constmction of a good road required an unusual combination of practical and scientific knowledge, and that the task was not only above the abilities of inexperienced surveyors, but beyond the means of the inhabitants of an ordinary parish. Pubhc money was voted for the improvement of national highways, and the services of the most celebrated engineer of the day were enlisted in the work. Telford in 1814 was employed to make good the road from Glasgow to Carlisle and in the following year to reconstruct the road from Shrewsbury to Holyhead. In his opinion and practice, it was necessary to make a regular bottoming of rough close-set pavement, on which a hard, smooth, inelastic surface could be laid, so as to minimise the labour of traction by offering the least resistance. The rival system was advocated by McAdam. To him the " Telford pavement " seemed unnecessary for the preparation of a suitable surface. In his view an elastic subsoil was even superior to a sohd foundation ; he preferred a bog to a rock, provided that the bog was sufficiently solid to bear a man's weight. As Surveyor-General of the Bristol roads (1815), he was already putting his theories into practice on an extensive scale. His practical success, his evidence before Parhamentary Committees, and his skdU with the pen * persuaded the English public of the sound- ness of his theory. But the battle was hotly contested, and the very heat of the controversy served a useful purpose. It kept the improvement of English roads prominently before the pubUc. Scientific opinion, here and abroad, was on the side of Telford ; but McAdam was the popular favourite. In 1827 he was appointed Surveyor-Greneral of roads in Great Britain. His influence was paramount, and men, in their gratitude for the unwonted luxury of safe and smooth travelling in fast coaches, were not disposed to criticise too closely the scientific principles of the road magician. Turnpike toUs provided some of the cost of road maintenance, and served as auxiharies to statute labour. For a time they satisfied the urgency of the need. But the heavy interest on the loans raised by the turnpike trustees, the excessive cost of management, the profits exacted by those who farmed the toUs, left, at the best, small margins for road expenditure. To increase the income, toll-bars were multiplied or scales of payment raised. The inequality of the burden was strongly felt. In one district, five tolls might be paid • A Practical Essay of the Scientific Repair and Preservation of Ptiblie Roads (1819) ; Remarks on the Present System of Road-making {1&20, 6th edition 1822). 288 HIGHWAYS in twelve miles ; in another, thirty might be travelled without a single payment. The financial chaos of the trusts, as well as the inadequacy of the statute laboiu*, gave a fresh impulse to the ultimate triumph of the rival principle of a rate. Already Justices in Quarter Sessions had been empowered to levy a rate, assessed on the principle of the poor-rate, for general purposes of highway maintenance when other means proved insufficient, for the purchase of road material, and to buy land for the widening of highways. Already also the liabiUty for statute labour might be compounded by the payment of a money equivalent. In 1835 these principles were extended by an Act^ which abolished statute labour and substituted highway rates for the maintenance of all minor roads. The abolition of statute labour was a severe loss to the turnpike trusts, to whom the legislature still looked for the repair of important highways. In 1839, four years after the passing of the Highway Act, a Select Committee reported that in some instances the creditors of turnpike trusts had seized the toUs to secure payment of the interest on -their mortgages, and that nothing was available from that source for road-repair. The development of railways struck the trusts another blow, for the decay of the coaching-traffic deprived them of one of the chief sources of their revenue. Their financial position went from bad to worse. Drastic action was needed. The powers of the Home Office to refuse the renewal of Turnpike Acts were in 1864 transferred to a Select Committee of the House of Commons. TTie new authority acted with vigour. Boads were dis-tumpiked at the average rate of 1,500 miles a year. The extinction of turnpike trusts threw upon local ratepayers a heavy burden. Their existence had not reUeved the parish from its old liability : their removal revived that Uability in the form of increased rates. In rare instances, individuals were liable by tenure or prescription for the repair of portions of public roads. But, speaking generally, the parish was always responsible for the main- tenance of the highways within its area. For a time, turnpike roads had been partly maintained by the tolls which the trustees were authorised to raise. Yet whenever the trusts neglected their work, became bankrupt, or were extinguished, it was the inhabitants of the parish, not the trustees, who were subject to indictment for failure to maintain the roads. Tolls were subsidiary to local labour and local rates ; they were substitutes for neither. Now that they were 1 6 and 6 Wm. IV. c. 50. HIGHWAY DISTRICTS AND MAIN ROADS 289 withdrawn, the whole burden fell on the locality. Some relief was urgently needed. In order to distribute the burden more equitably, the parishes were grouped into Highway Districts. Within each area the cost was equalised. But parochial districts remained responsible for the maintenance of roads within their areas, legally liable for the extra burden if the expense was disproportion- ately heavy, legally entitled to the special benefit if the cost was disproportionately light. Further relief to local ratepayers was required. It came in the form of excepting main roads from the general law of district liability. Under the Highways and Loco- motives Acts Amendment Act, 1878, the turnpike roads, whose trusts had been dissolved, were made main roads, and half the cost of their maintenance was transferred to the county authority, then Quarter Sessions. The remainder of the liability for the repair of main roads still rested on the parochial districts, a grant-in-aid being made by the Government. Under the Local Grovemment Act, 1888, the Cbunty Council became the county authority, and parochial districts were relieved of the remaining half of their liability for the maintenance of main roads, wherever situated, and the cost of their upkeep was transferred to the county generally. But under the PubUc Health Act, 1876, the urban authorities were already responsible for the maintenance of highways within their areas. The effect of the two Acts of 1875 and 1888 was that urban authorities might elect either to maintaia the main roads within their area themselves, or to call upon the County Council to do the work. If they elected to maintain the roads themselves, the measure of the Coimty Council's liability was a contribution towards the cost properly incurred in the maintenance and reasonable improvement of the main roads within the area. CHAPTER XIV. THE RURAL POPULATION. 1780-1813. Effect of enclosures on the rural population ; no necessary reduction in the number of small owners, but rather on increase ; consoUdation of farms, either by purchase from small owners, or by throwing tenancies together ; the strict letter of the law ; small occupiers become landless labourers ; depopulation of villages when tillage was abandoned for pasture ; scarcity of employment in open-field villages ; the literary controversy ; the mate- rial injury inflicted upon the rural poor by the loss of the commons ; no possible equivalent in cash-value : the moral injury ; the simtdtaneous decay of domestic industries ; the rapid rise after 1790 in the price of provisions ; a substantial advance in agricultural wages. I>DitmG the thirty-three years from 1780 to 1813, the industrial tevolution, which in agriculture was expressed by the new methods and spirit of farming, influenced rural hfe in two opposite directions. Far-reaching changes were made which were justified, and even , demanded, by national exigencies. As, in trade, the capitalist manufacturer displaced the small master-workman and domestic craftsman, so, in agriculture, land was thrown together in large holdings at the expense of small occupiers. Both manufacture and agriculture became businesses which required the possession of capital. Without money, workers, whether in trade or on land, lost the prospect of themselves becoming masters or employers. But the same changes which brought unexampled prosperity to land- owners and large tenant-farmers, combined with other causes to plunge the rest of the rural population into almost imparaJleled misery. The rapid growth of manufacturing towns created a new demand for bread and meat ; it raised the rents of land- owners ; it swelled the profits of fanners. For a long series of years the war, by practically excluding foreign com, main- tained a high level of agricultural prices in spite of increased production. But to labourers who neither owned nor occupied land, the rise of prices brought no compensating advantages. On the AN AGRARIAN REVOLUTION 291 contrary, they paid more dearly for all necessaries of subsistence, and the increased cost of Uving was not adequately met by a corre- sponding rise in wages. At the same time, the steps which were required for the adoption of those agricultiu'al improvements, by which the manufacturing industries as well as large owners and occupiers of land were profiting, multiphed the numbers and increased the sufFerings of landless labourers. The extinction of open-field farms reduced numbers of small occupiers to the rank of hired wage- earners ; the appropriation of commons deprived many cottagers, not only of free fuel, but of the means of supplementing wages by the profits of their live-stock, their poultry, and their geese. In the eighteenth as in the sixteenth century it was still partially true that " enclosures make fat beasts and lean poor people." The structure of rural society was affected to its very foundations by the agrarian revolution which was in progress. A great popula- tion, standing on the verge of famine, and beginning to gather in industrial centres, cried aloud for food. Technical improvements in farming had been tested, which promised to supply the new demand for bread and meat, if only free play were allowed to the modem methods of production. It was from this point of view that agri- cultural experts, almost to a man, were unanimous in requiring the removal of mediaeval obstacles to progress, and the addition of every possible acre to the cultivated area. As open-field arable farms were broken up, as pasture-commons were divided, as wastes were brought into cultivation, the face of the country altered. The enclosing movement was attacked on various grounds. To its effects were attributed the disappearance of the yeomanry, using the words in the strict sense of farmer-owners ; the monopoly of farms, or, in other words, the consoUdation of a number of holdings into single occupations ; the depopulation of rural villages ; the material and moral loss which was alleged to be inflicted on the poor. Bound these different points raged the contest of the latter half of the eighteenth century. Meanwhile the work of enclosure went on without interruption. At the present day the changes seem to have been surprisingly rapid ; but to men who were living under the stress of war and scarcity, they appeared ahnost criminally slow. They so appeared to William Marshall, perhaps the most experienced and the least bigoted of the agricultural observers of the day. Writing in 1801, before the fuU pressure of famine prices had been felt, he says : " Through the uncertainty and expense attending private 292 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 acts, a great portion of the unstinted common lands remain nearly as nature left them ; appearing in the present state of civilisation and science, as filthy blotches on the face of the country ; especially when seen under the threatening clouds of famine which have now repeatedly overspread it." ^ It does not appear that the necessary result of the enclosing movement was to diminish the number of occupying owners. On the contrary, the first effect of an enclosure was to increase the free- holders, since rights of open arable field occupation and of pasture common were often replaced by allotments of land in separate ownership. After 1689, the decline in the number of owners of small estates begins to be noted by contemporary writers.* "At the Revolution," says a " Suffolk Gentleman," ' " there existed a race of Men in the Country besides the Gentlemen and Husbandmen, called Yeomanry, Men who cultivated their own property, consisting chiefly of farms from forty to fourscore pounds a year . . . the Pride of the Nation in War and Peace . . . hardy, brave, and of good morals." Their alleged disappearance can only have been remotely due to enclosure, if, as the " Suffolk Gentleman " says, " by the influx of riches and a change of manners, they were nearly annihilated in the year 1750." On the other hand, a considerable body of evidence exists to show that, after the accession of George m., a reaction had set in, and that small owners were not only numerous, but actually increasing in numbers. Thus Marshall, writing in 1790 of small freeholders both in Yorkshire (Vale of Pickering) and in Leicestershire, says : " Some years back, the same species of frenzy, — Terramania — showed itself here, as it did in other districts. Forty years purchase was, then, not unfrequently given."* The Reports to the Board of Agriculture (1793-1815) show that in many parts of the countiy small owners not only held their ground, but once more were buying land. Thus of the north- eastern counties generally, Young " states that " farmers have been very considerable purchasers of land." Norfolk (1804) is said to ' Tha Appropriaiion and IwK/oaure of Oommonatie and Intermixed Land* (1801). 'Authorities ore quoted in The Dtsappearanee of the SnuiB. Landowner, by the Rev. A. H. Johnson (1909), pp. 136-8. » Iietter to Sir T. O. Bwnhwry, Bart., on the Poor Rates and tite High Price of Proviaiont (1796). ■ Rural Economy of the Midland CounUea, vol. i. p. 16. I Young's Hertfordshire (1804), p. 18. OCCUPYING OWNERS 293 contain " estates of all sizes, from nearly the largest scale to the little freehold ; one of £25,000 a year ; one of £14,000 ; one of £13,000 ; two of £10,000 ; many of about £5,000 ; and an increasing number of all smaller proportions." ^ In Suffolk (1797) " the rich yeomanry " are described as " very numerous . . . farmers occup3rLng their own lands, of a value rising from £100 to £400 a year." * In Essex (1807), " there never was a greater proportion of small and moderate- sized farms, the property of mere farmers, who retain them in their own immediate occupation, than at present. Such has been the flourishing state of agriculture for twenty or thirty years past, that scarcely an estate is sold, if divided into lots of forty or fifty to two or three hundred a year, but is purchased by farmers. . . . Hence arises a fair prospect of landed property gradually returning to a situation of similar possession to what it was a hundred or a hundred and fifty years ago, when our inferior gentry resided upon their estates in the country." * In the South-Eastern and East Midland counties, no marked decrease in the number of small estates is noticed. " One third " of Berkshire * is said to have been occupied in 1813 by the proprietors of the soil. Owners of landed property from £200 to £600 a year were " very numerous." Oxfordshire (1794) contained " many proprietors of a middling size, and many small proprietors, par- ticularly in the open fields." ^ In Nottinghamshire (1798) " some considerable, as well as inferior yeomen occupy their own lands." * Of late years in Hampshire (1813) " a considerable subdivision of property has taken place." Speaking of the farmers on the chalk hills of the county, the Reporter says that " many of them are the possessors of small estates which their thrifty management keeps upon the increase." ' In Kent, up to at least 1793, the number of owners of land seemed annually on the increase, " by the estates which are divided and sold to the occupiers. There is no description of persons who can afford to give so much money for the purchase of an estate as those who buy for their own occupation. Many in the eastern part of this county have been sold, within these few years, for forty, and some for fifty years purchase, and upwards." * » Young's NorfoVc (1804), p. 17. » Young's SuffoUe (1797), p. 8. •Young's Easex (1807), vol. i. pp. 39, 40. « Mavor's Berkshire (1808), p. 113. ' Davis' Oxfordshire (1794), p. 11. • Lowe's Nottinghamshire (1798), p. 8. ' Vancouver's Hampshire (1813), pp. 61, 80. » Boys' Kent (1796), p. 26. 294 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 In the West Midland and South- Western district, small owners were at least holding their own. In North Wilts (1794), where a considerable number of enclosures had been made, " a great deal of the property has been divided and sub-divided, and gone into the hands of the many." ^ Brent Marsh in Somersetshire (1797) was a district of 20,000 acres which the stagnant waters rendered un- wholesome to man and beast. Within the last twenty years much of this land had been enclosed and drained under a variety of Acts of Parhament. " Scarcely a farmer," says the Reporter, " can now be found who does not possess a considerable landed property ; and many, whose fathers Uved in idleness and sloth, on the precarious support of a few half -starved cows, or a few limping geese, are now in affluence, and blessed with every needful species of enjoyment." * Devonshire (1794) continued to be a county of small properties.* In Gloucestershire (1807), " the number of yeomen who possess free- holds, of various value, is great, as appears from the Sheriff's return of the poU at the election for a county member in 1776, when 5790 freeholders voted, and the number since that period is much in- creased." * Landed property in Shropshire (1803) is " considerably divided. . . . The number of gentlemen of small fortune living on their estates, has decreased ; their descendants have been clergymen or attomies, either in the country, or shopkeepers in the towns of their own county ; or more probably in this county emigrated to Birmingham, Liverpool, to Manchester, or to London ; but then the opulent farmer, who has purchased the farm he hves upon . . . is a character that has increased." ^ The North and North- Western districts afford similar evidence, though in two counties a decrease is conspicuous. In Staffordshire (1813) the best and most improving farmers were " the proprietors of 200 or 300 acres of land, who farm it themselves." * Derbyshire (1794) possessed numerous small occupiers, who eked out the profits of the land by mining, spinning, and weaving ; but there were also occupiers of another description, " very properly styled yeomen ; men cultivating their own estates with a sufficient capital." ^ In Cheshire (1808) " the number of small land-owneis is not apparently less than in other counties. The description of this latter class has, » I>e,TriB'untry Gentleman, 1772. 7. An Inquiry into the Reasons For and Against incHoaing Open Fields, by Stephen Addington, 2nd edition, 1772. 8. An Inquiry into the Connection between the present price of provisions and the Size of Farms, by a Farmer [John Arbuthnot], 1773. 9. Four Tracts, together with Two Sermons, on political and commercial subjects, by Josiah Tucker, 1774. 10. Hints to Oentlemen of Landed Property, by Nathaniel Kent, 1777. JH. An Enquiry into the Advantages and Disadvantages resvUing from BiUs of Indosure, etc.. Anon, 1780. 12. Observations on a Panvphlet entitled An Enquiry into the Advantages, etc.. Anon, 1781 (an answer to the foregoing). 13. Cursory Remarks on the Importance of Agriculture, by W. Lamport, 1784. 14. A PolMctA Enquiry into the Consequences of Enclosing Waste Lands, Being the sentiments of a Society of Farmers in shire, 1785. 16. An Enquiry into the Influerux which Enclosures have had upon the Popula- tion of England, by John Hewlett, 1786. 16. Cursory Remarks on Inclosures, etc., by a Country Farmer, 1786. 17. Enclosures a Cause of Im/proved Agriculture, etc., by John Hewlett, 1787. 18. Suggestions for rendering the Indoswre of Camimnn Fields and Waste Lands a source of Population and Riches, by Thomas Stone, 1787. An apparent exception is one of the most interesting works on the subject, namely : 19. TIte Case of Labourers in Husbandry Stated and Considered, by David Davies, 1796. But the material was collected in 1787. The high prices of com, 1766-74, seem to have given an impulse to enclosures and produced a crop of literature. 304 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 industrial changes and the operation of the Poor Law, were disas- trous to a large number of open-field farmers, cottagers, and commoners who had lost their hold upon the land. The strongest argument against enclosures was the material and moral damage inflicted upon the poor. In comparatively rare instances commoners who exercised com- mon-rights were not put to strict proof of their legal title. Even where this lenient poUcy was adopted, or where the right was established at law, the claim was often supposed to be satisfied by the gift of a sum of money, or by an allotment of land. Money, to a man who had no power of investment, was a precarious pro- vision, which generally was soon spent. Land was a better sub- stitute ; but the allotment might be too small to repay the cost of fencing, or too distant to be of real benefit ; it was seldom enough for the summer and winter keep of a cow. The land and the cow were often sold together, as soon as, or sometimes before, the award was made. Sometimes, again, legal principles were set aside, and -allotments of land, more or less inadequate, were made for cottage building, or for the benefit of the poor of the parish to supply pasture or fuel. But probably less than 5 per cent, of the enclosure Acts made any provision of this kiud. The injury inflicted on the poor by the loss of their common of pasture, whether legally exercised or not, was indisputably great. It was admitted by those who, on other grounds, were the strongest supporters of enclosures. Arthur Young himself, though he never swerved from his advocacy of large enclosed holdings, had been converted to the principle of an admixture of occupying ownerships for small farmers. His travels in France had shown him the " magic of property " at work. In England he had witnessed its effects in the Isle of Axholme. " In respect of property," he writes,^ " I know nothing more singular respecting it, than its great division in the isle of Axholm. In most of the towns there, for it is not quite general, there is much resemblance of some rich parts of France and Flanders. The inhabitants are collected in villages and hamlets ; and almost every house you see, except very poor cottages on the borders of commons, is inhabited by a farmer, the proprietor of his farm, of from four or five, and even fewer, to twenty, forty, and more acres, scattered about the open- fields, and cultivated with all that minutisB of care and anxiety, by 1 LmeolnsMre (1799), p. 17. COW-KEEPING ON COMMONS 305 the hands of the family, which are found abroad, in the countries mentioned. They are very poor, respecting money, but very happy respecting their mode of existence. Contrivance, mutual assist- ance, by barter and hire, enable them to manage these httle farms though they break aU the rules of rural proportion." On these Hues, he urged in 1800 ^ that every scrap of waste and neglected land should be converted into possessions for the poor, and that aU labourers should be assigned gardens and grass-land for the keep of a cow. In 1801 * he proposed that labourers should be allowed to absorb for themselves the small commons which were situated in the centre of enclosed districts, and that all Acts of Parliament for the reclamation of wastes should attach enough land to every cottage to provide summer and winter keep for a cow, the land to be inalienable and vested in the parish. He based these recommendations on his own personal observations of the effect of the enclosure of commons. " Many kept cows that have not since " is his frequent summary of results. Out of 37 parishes, he found only 12 in which the poor had not suffered.* " By nineteen Enclosure Acts out of twenty, the poor are injured, in some grossly injured. . . . The poor in these parishes may say, and with truth. Parliament may be tender of property ; aU I know is I had a cow, and an Act of Parliament has taken it from me." ^ The Board of Agriculture printed evidence to the same effect.^ Out of 68 Enclosure Acts, 53 had injured the poor, who had lost their cows, and could no longer buy milk for their families. The same point is frequently noticed by the Beporters. Nathaniel Kent, for example, dweUs upon it in his Beport on Norfolk, and urges " all great farmers ... to provide comfortable cottages for two or three of their most industrious labourers, and to lay two or three acres of grass land to each to enable such labourer to keep a cow and a pig." * Yet even when the opportunity to keep a cow occurred, it was not invariably used. " Cottagers," says Kent, "who Uve at the sides of the common generally neglect the advantage they have before them. There is not, perhaps, one out of six, * Qviestium of ScarcHy plainly stated (1800). * Inquiry into the Propriety of applying Wastes to the better Maintenanee and Support of the Poor (1801). • Ibid, p 19. • Ibid. p. 42. ' General Beport on Enclosures, 1808, pp. 160-2. • Kent's Norfolk, p. 172. U 306 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 apon an average that keeps even a cow." ^ Nor was the disappear- ance of the cow invariably due to the loss of commons. Some- times commercial motives operated. At Baldon, in Oxfordshire, " many cottagers had two, three or four acres, and they kept cows ; now, stiU having the land, they keep no cows ; their rent from 30s. to 42s. per acre and all applied as arable."^ In this instance, at all events, the cheapness of butter and the high price of wheat had tempted these men to plough up their grass-land. Whatever exceptions there may have been, the loss of the cow generally followed the loss of the commons. Nor was this the only injury which the cottager suffered. He lost his free firing, and the run for his geese and poultry. It is, in fact, impossible to meeisure in terms of cash equivalents the benefits derived from the commons, or the loss infiicted by their withdrawal. The case is well sum- marised by Barnes, the Dorsetshire poet of rural life : Thomas (tog.) : Why, 'tis a handy thing To have a bit o' common, I do know. To put a little cow upon in spring. The while woone's bit ov orchard grass do grow. John : Aye, that's the thing, you zee. Now I do mow My bit o' grass, an meake a little rick ; An' in the zummer, while do grow, My cow do run in common vor to pick A bleade or two o' grass, if she can vind em, Vor tother cattle don't leave much behind em. An' then, bezides the cow, why we do let Our geese run out among the emmet hills ; An' then, when we do pluck em, we do get Vor zeale zome veathers an' zome quills ; An' in the winter we do fat em well. An' car em to the market vor to zell To gentle-volks An' then, when I ha' noth^n else to do, AVhy, I can teake my hook an' gloves, an' goo To cut a lot o' vuzz and briars Vor het^n ovens or vor lighten viers ; An' when the childem be too young to earn A penny, they can g'out in zunny weather. An' run about, an' get together A bag o' cow-dung vor to bum. The material loss inflicted on the poor was great : still more serious was the moral damage. It is probably true that the com- mons had attracted to their borders numbers of the idle and dissolute. But it is equally certain that they also afforded to hard-working and thrifty peasants the means of supplementing ' HiMa to Gentfcmen (1776), p. 112. « Young's Oxfordshire, p. 23. MORAL DAMAGE FROM LOSS OF COMMONS 307 their weekly wages. They gave the man who enjoyed rights of common, and Uved near enough to use them, an interest in the land and the hope of acquiring a larger interest. They encouraged his thrift and fostered his independence. Men who had grazing rights hoarded their money to buy a cow. They enabled wage- earners to keep live-stock, which was something of their own. They gave them fuel, instead of driving them to the baker for every sort of cooking. They formed the lowest rung in the social ladder, by which the successful commoner might hope to climb to the occupation of a holding suited to bis capital. Now the com- mons were gone, and the farms which replaced them were too large to be attainable. Contemporary writers who comment on the increasing degradation of the labouring classes too often treat as its causes changes which were really its consequences. They note the increase of drunkenness, but forget that the occupation of the labourer's idle moments was gone ; they attack the mis- chievous practice of giving children tea, but forget that milk was no longer procurable ; they condemn the rising generation as incapable for farm labour, but forget that the parents no longer occupied land on which their children could learn to work ; they deplore the helplessness of the modem wives of cottagers who had become dependent on the village baker, but forget that they were now obliged to buy flour, and had lost their free fuel ; they denounce their improvident marriages, but forget that the motive of thrift was removed. The results were the hopelessness, the indifference, and the moral deterioration of the landless labourer. " Go," says Arthur Young, " to an ale-house kitchen of an old enclosed country, and there you will see the origin of poverty and the poor-rates. For whom are they to be sober ? For whom are they to save ? (such are their questions). For the parish ? If I am dihgent, shall I have leave to build a cottage ? If I am sober, shall I have land for a cow ? If I am frugal, shall I have half an acre of potatoes ? You offer no motives ; you have nothing but a parish ofl&cer and a workhouse. Bring me another pot." ^ The same point is urged, with less vivacity and picturesqueness of statement, by the best writers of the day, especially by Howlett and Davies. The displacement of numbers of cottagers, commoners, and open- field farmers came at a difficult crisis. Hitherto rural labourers in many parts of the country had regarded day work for wages » Annala of Agriculture, vol. xxxvi. p. 608. On Wastes (1801), pp. 12, 13. 308 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 on the land of farmers as a by-employment, which eked out the profits of their other industries. Now the commons were gone, and at the same time their own domestic handicrafts were being superseded by manufactured goods. It was now that the industrial population was shifting from the South to the North ; that spinning and weaving deserted the home for the factory ; that old markets were exchanged for the new centres of trade which gathered round the water-power or the coal and iron fields of the North. In the closing years of the eighteenth century, widespread complaints are made of decaying industries, of the loss of employment in rural districts, of the mass of pauperism bequeathed to small towns and villages by the departure of trades. Industries, which in 1800 were concentrating in the large towns of the North, had been previously scattered over a wide extent of coimtry districts. Even where the trade maintaiaed its ground, the introduction of machinery reduced the amount of employment, and transferred it from the cottage to the factory. At the same time many local manufactories were brought to the verge of ruin by the war, which limited the export trade. As the restilt of these changes in the conditions of rural life, poor-rates rose to an enormous height. Marshall, in his Beview of the Beports to the Board of Agriculture, mentions the instance of CoggeshaU in Essex, once a fiourishing village, where the poor-rates, owing to the ruin of the baize trade, had risen to 16s. in the pound. This burden, increased as it was by the provision for the maintenance of the wives and famihes of militiamen, enlisted soldiers and sailors, crushed out of existence many small freeholders, who, because they employed no labour, derived no advantage from the operation of the Poor Law, but were assessed on the rental value of their land. As the local industries declined, or were concentrated in towns, or substituted machinery for manual work, the demand for labour waa reduced in rural villages. Fewer opporttmities for supplementing weekly wages by other employments were afforded. It was now that the South and South Midlands fell hopelessly behind the North. It is difficult to give any adequate impression of the degree in which, under the dying system of seU-contained communities, indus- trial employments other than those of agriculture had been distri- buted among rural villages. Counties which at first sight seem purely agricultural, possessed a number of local iudustries, which, in addition to dyeworks, malthouses, breweries, mills, and tanneries. LOCAL INDUSTRIES AND HOME CRAFTS 309 gave considerable employment. Bedfordshire had its osier baskets, its reed matting, its straw plaiting ; its spinning of hemp had died out in 1803, but men as well as women still made pillow lace. Straw- plaiting extended along the borders of Buckinghamshire, Hertford- shire, and Cambridgeshire. The best, that is, the weakest straw, commanded high prices, and sold for from 2d. to 4d. the pound. In Cambridgeshire and Huntingdonshire, woollen and worsted yam was also spun for Norwich and the northern markets. Lincolnshire wove fabrics for women's dresses ; Epworth made sack-cloth ; coarse linen or hempen cloth was woven in many parts of the county. Suffolk had its spinning and combing of wool ; and in the district round Beccles, where hemp was largely cultivated, quantities of hempen cloth were manufactured. Essex was famous for its baizes. But the trade was for the time ruined by the war. In the neighbourhood of Colchester, where during peace 20,000 persons had found employment, only 8,000 were now employed. At Halstead, Dedham, Booking, and the surrounding villages, the industry had so decayed that numbers of hands were out of work, and the rates rose to over 20s. in the pound. Hampshire was not a manufacturing county. But it had a variety of industries ranging from manufactories of cloth, shalloons and coarse woollens, to bed-ticking and earthenware pottery. Kent was the county of hops ; yet Canterbury and the villages round wove silk ; Dover and Maidstone made paper ; Cra37ford bleached linens and printed calicoes ; Whitstable had its copperas works. Sandwich its salt-works, Faversham and Deptford their powder mills. Along the banks of the Wandle in Surrey were paper, oil, snuff and flour mills, mills for grinding logwood, as well as leather, parchment, calico, and printing works. The Mole turned iron mills at Cobham and flatting mills at Ember Court. The Wey collected on its banks many paper mills. In the Weald there still lingered iron-workers and charcoal burners. Godalming and the neighbour- hood had its patent fleecy hosiery, its works for wool-combing, for blankets, tilts, and collar-cloths. Sussex formerly sent every year quantities of iron by land-carriage to London ; but the trade was dying fast. It still remained one of the chief centres of the charcoal industry and of powder making. In Berkshire the woollen manu- factures were dwindling. They were deserting Newbury, leaving behind a " numerous poor." But in the town and neighbourhood, kerseys, cottons, calicoes, linen and damask were still made, and the 310 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 introduction of the manufacture of blankets was attempted. At OaJdngham there were established silk-spinning and silk-weaving manufactories, and a considerable trade was carried on in hat-bands, ribbons, watch-strings, shoe-strings, sarcenets, and figured gauzes for women's dresses. Li Oxfordshire the shag-weavers of Bloxham and Banbury were out of employment and on the parish. The coarse velvet trade of Banbury was travelling north. The blankets of Witney still held their own ; but the introduction of machinery had thrown two-thirds of the workmen out of employment, and the rates had risen to lis. in the pound. The glove trade of Woodstock flourished ; but the polished steel trade had migrated to Birmingham and Sheffield, and leathern breeches, no longer worn, had ceased to be made. Northampton and the surrounding neighbourhood were already famous for boots ; Daventry manufactured whips and wove silk stockings ; in Wellingborough and the surrounding villages lace- making employed from 9,000 to 10,000 persons, the thread being imported from Flanders and distributed to the workers in their houses. Since the war, the worsted manufactories of Kettering had decayed ; instead of from 5,000 to 6,000 hands, only half were employed, and the remainder fell upon the rates. Warwickshire, Nottinghamshire, and Staffordshire were becoming manufacturing counties. Machinery was being introduced, and, as a consequence, their industries were being withdrawn from the villages and con- centrated in towns. Outside Birmiagham, there were the ribbon and tammy trades of Coventry, the horn combs of Kenilworth, the nails of Bromwich, the needles of Alcester, the worsted works of Warwick, the linen trade of Tamworth. For miles round Notting- ham the villagers were stocking-makers ; in different parts of the county were scattered mills for combing and spinniog wool, or silk spinning and weaving, for polishing marble, as well as works for the manufacture of pottery, starch, and sail-cloth. Few cottagers were without a web of home-spun cloth. Shropshire had a great variety of local industries, such as garden pots at Broseley ; fine china at Oaughley ; china, ropes, and chains at Coalport ; glass works at Donnington ; dye-works at Lebotwood ; Shrewsbury and the neighbourhood maintained spinning and fulling mills, a trade in finishing Welsh flannels, manufactures of coarse linens and linen threads. In many cottages and farm-houses pieces of linen cloth were got up for sale. The glove trade of Worpester employed a CLOTH TRADE IN THE SOUTH-WEST 311 large number of men and women in the city itself, and in the " comity romid to the extent of seven or eight miles." Kidderminster and the neighbourhood were carpet-makers. On the borders of Stafford- shire and Warwickshire many were employed in making nails, needles, and fish-hooks. Over the greater part of Gloucestershire, and especially in the Cotswold Hills, there was much spinning of wool. The trade in the fine broad-cloths of Stroud and the surrounding parishes was in 1794 at a stand-still ; but in the coarser quaUty required for army clothing it was brisk. Even here the introduction of machinery " has thrown many hands out of employment," and caused the poor- rates to rise " to six shillings in the pound and upward." At Cirencester in 1807 many labouring people were stiU employed in sorting wool from the fleece ; but the wool trade had much decreased in the last forty years, as also spinning woollen yam and worsted since the introduction of machinery. Tewkesbury had its stocking- frame industry ; Dursley and Wotton-under-Edge made wire cards for the use of clothiers ; iron and brass wire, tin-plate, pins, rugs and blankets employed other districts of the county. But the decline of trade made itself felt in the great increase of rates. " In the clothing district," says Rudge, " the weight of parochial assess- ments f aDs uncommonly heavy on landed property. During the late scarcity, the average charge might be 4s. 6d. through the county ; while at the same time it amoimted to at least three times that proportion in some of the parishes where the clothing manufacture is carried on." ^ In Somersetshire, the teade iu woollen cloth and worsted stockings of Frome and Shepton Mallet had given employ- ment, not only to the two towns, but to " a vast number of the lower order of people in the adjacent villages." But in 1797 the restriction of the export trade by the war, the introduction of machinery, and the competition of the North, had begun to injure the trade and lessen the demand for labour. Taunton had lost its woollen manufactures, though they still flourished at Wellington and Wiveliscombe. In Cornwall, carding and spinning were in 1811 dying out, and " to the total decline of this business must, in some measure, be attri- buted the progressive increase of the rates of the county." * From Devonshire in 1808 came the same complaint of the failure of em- ^ OUmcesteriihire (1807), p. 346. ' Worgan's ComvxiU (1811), p. 33, 312 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 ployment, though in the eastern part of the county lace-making still flourished.^ In Dorsetshire the principal manufactures were in the neighbourhood of Bridport and Beaminster, where in 1793, " all sorts of twine, string, packthread, netting, cordage, and ropes are made, from the finest thread used by saddlers, in lieu of silk, to the cable which holds the first-rate man of war." ' In this neigh- bourhood also were made the sails for shipping, sacking for ham- mocks, and all kinds of ba^ and tarpaulin. Here too were braided nets for the Newfoundland fishery and for home use. At Loders sail-cloth was woven. At Shaftesbury and Blandford, and in the surrounding villages on all sides, to seven or eight miles distance, was carried on the manufacture of shirt-buttons. Two other changes were in progress which in a minor degree added to the misfortunes of the labouring classes in country districts. In the first place, trade in agricultural produce was rapidly becoming wholesale instead of retail. Dairy-farms contracted for the supply of milk to towns, and milk was more easily obtained by the urban than the rural population. The produce of corn-farms was sold in bulk to corn-dealers or millers. Labourers could rarely purchase a bushel of wheat direct from the farmer. They could no longer carry their com to the miller, pay for grinding, and take away the pure flour, and the ofials for the pigs. Now they were obliged to buy from the miller or the baker, not only the flour, but the bran, with the profits of each trader added to the price of both. In the second place, a number of crops, some of which required much labour for their cultivation or special preparation, were dying out, because the industries which they served had migrated, or from some change of taste or fashion. As the linen trade became more concentrated in particular localities, flax was more rarely cultivated. The hemp- yards, which were once attached to many cottages and farm-houses, were similarly abandoned. The use of teasels by clothieis was displaced by machinery, and the crop was no longer cultivated. Woad, madder, and safEron found cheaper substitutes. Liquorice disappeared from Nottinghamshire, camomile from Derbyshire, canary seed from Kent, carraway seed from Essex. The rapid increase in the price of provisions from 1793 onwards struck yet another, and a crushing, blow at the position of the land- less labourer. The rise came with startling suddenness, and it 1 Vanoouver'B Devonthire (1808), p. 464. * Claridge'B Doraetthire (1793), p. 37. RISE IN AGRICULTURAL WAGES 313 found him defenceless. Without the commons he was entirely dependent on purchased food ; without domestic industries he had less money to buy the means of existence. The greater the distance from London, the lower the wages and the higher the prices. This was certainly true of the West and South- West of England. Thus, the labourer had more to buy, less money to buy it with, and what money he had did not go so far as formerly. In yet another way, the great rise in prices afiected the rural population for the worse. It no longer paid the farmer to board servants in husbandry. In the North, the system still survived, partly because of the high wages of day-labour, partly because the diet which custom accepted was more economical, and barley-broth and porridge were staple foods. Elsewhere the number of servants who were boarded and lodged in farm-houses dwindled ; they became day-labourers, living how and where they could. Another opportunity for saving and another restraint on improvident marriage were thus removed. To a certain extent the rise in the prices was met by a substantial advance in wages. It is always easy to raise wages ; it is extremely difficult to lower them. The reluctance of farmers to increase wages, when an advance in prices may be only temporary, is therefore intelligible. How far wages rose is a difficult field of enquiry. The remuneration of labour varies with the diSerent seasons, with the different occupations of the men, with diSerent contracts of service, with different districts of the same county. The one outstanding point is that the real earnings of agricultural labourers are not now, and, to a greater extent, were not then, represented only by the weekly sums which are paid in cash. To these weekly payments must be' added earnings at piece-work, at hay and com harvest, perquisites, allowances in kind, cottages and gardens, either rent free or rented below their economic value. On these points the Reports to the Board of Agriculture, 1793-1815, supply no reliable evidence. Most of them speak of a considerable rise in wages ; they rarely mention the point from which the advance is measured. They register the averages of the daily or weekly payments ; they seldom give the method by which the rate is calculated. Failing the Reports to the Board of Agriculture, the enquirer is thrown back on Young's generaUsations. As the result of his calculations in the Farmers' Tours of 1767-70, it may be estimated that the average rate of wages was Is. 2d. a day, — more in the 314 THE RURAL POPULATION, 1780-1813 neighbourhood of London, less in more distant counties, least in the West and South. Prom 1770 to 1790 there does not seem to have been any appreciable and general rise. Li the next twenty-five years a striking advance was made. Tooke states that agricultural wages were " doubled or nearly so." ^ Young calculated that, taking the " mean rate " of wages in 1770 at 7s. 4Jd., the " price of labour had in forty years about doubled."^ Both he and Tooke state that the wages of agricultural labourers had reached the level of those of artisans. It is difficult to accept these estimates. Few of the Reports to the Board of Agriculture really belong to the later part of the period 1793-1815, and the only county in which the Reporters to the Board state that wages had doubled between 1794 and 1812 is Warwickshire. In Essex, however, there is some indication of wages having doubled, if the Is. 2d. of 1770 is taken as the starting-point. In the Report for 1794, the average of summer and winter wages is given as 9s. l|d. a week; in that for 1807, at 12s. 7d. The evidence of the subsequent rise comes from another source. On an Essex farm the rate of wages paid to an ordinary labourer, who had not the care of stock, rose from 10s. 6d. a week in 1800 to 12s. a week in 1802, and to 15b. a week in 1812.^ Whatever weight may be attached to the general- isations of Tooke and Young, it is certain that a very important advance in agricultural wages was made during the period of the Napoleonic wars. Unfortunately, it is equally certain that, even * History of Priees, voL i. p. 329. * Enquiry into the Rise of Priees in Europe during the last twenty-five years (1816), p. 216. * Board of Trade Report on Agrioulitural Wages (1900), Cd. 346, p. 238. In the Oommunications to the Board of Agriculture (vol. v. part i.), the average weekly wages of agriculturtil labourers in 1803 are stated at lis. lid. In Arthur Young's Enquiry into the Rise of Prices in Europe, the weekly wages in husbcmdry are stated to be 148. 6d. in 181 1. J. C. Curwen, M.F., moving in the House of Commons for a Committee to consider the Poor Laws (May 28, 1816), speaks of agricultural wages at that time as ranging from 10s. to 16s. (PompWeteer, vol. viii. p. 9). A. H. Holdsworth, M.P. (Letter on the Present Situation of the Oountry (1816), Pamphleteer, voL viii. p. 428), speaks of agri- cultural labourers receiving 2s. 6d. a day before the reductions of 1814. William Clarkson (Irupnry into the Poor Rates ( 1816), Pamphleteer, vol. viii. p. 392) gives the average rate of wages in 1812 at 16s. ; but thinks that as wages are much lees in Wiltshire, Devonshire, and Cornwall, this figure is over-stated as an average. It is not suggested that this class of evidence is at all conclusive ; but it leaves the impression that, if agricultural wages in 1760 averaged 7b., they had approximately doubled in 1812 in many parts of the country, sad that the average rise cannot be put at less than two-thirds. IF WAGES DOUBLED, POOD-PRICES TREBLED 315 if wages had doubled, the price of provisions had trebled. In other words, effective earnings had diminished by a third. It is the suddenness of this advance in prices that explains, though it does not justify, the makeshift expedients for relief which were adopted by administrators of the Poor Law. CHAPTER XV. AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND THE POOR LAW. 1813-37. War taxation : peace and beggary ; slow recovery of agriculture ; the harveat of 1813 ; reaUty and extent of distress ; the fall of prices ; bankruptcies of tenant-farmers ; period of acute depression, 1814-36 ; ruin of small owners ; misery of agricultural labourers ; reduction in wages and scarcity of employment ; allowances from the rates ; general pauperisation : the new Poor Law, 1834, tmd its administration. ENQLA2TD in 1815 had emerged from the Napoleonic wars victorious. But she paid the price of victory in her huge National Debt, her excessive taxation, her enormous Poor-Rate, her fictitious credit, her mass of unemployed and discontented labour. Though it is estimated that one in every six male adults was engaged in the struggle by land or sea, the population of England and Wales had risen from under 8f millions in 1792 to about 10| millions in 1815. Within the same period the National Debt grew from £261,735,059 to £885,186,323, and the annual expenditure, including interest on the public debt, from under 20 miUions to £106,832,260.^ The wealth and resources of the nation are shown by the comparative ease with which the money was found and the increased burden met. Yet the strain of the struggle had been intense, and on no class had it told more severely than on agricultural labourers. If their wages had approximately doubled, the cost of living had nearly trebled. Of their distress the rise of the expenditure on poor-relief afiords evidence. It advanced from £1,912,241,^ which was the » Porter's Progress of the Nation (1847), p. 482. > Eden's State of the Poor, vol. i. pp. 363-72. In 1776 the expenditure had been £1,656,804. After 1786 no Returns were made till 1803, when poor-rates stood at £4,077,891. See Load Taxation Returns printed by order of the House of Commons, 1839. To the sums assessed and disbursed in relief of the poor must be added the annual sums derived from charities appropriated to the same object. These amoimted, apart from educational charities, to £1,209,396 PEACE AND BEGGARY 317 triennial average for 1783-4-5, to £6,418,845 in 1815. Nor did the expenditure cease to rise with the close of the war. It continued to increase, in spite of falling prices. In 1818 it had grown to £7,870,801, the highest point which it reached under the old law.^ For six years after the end of the war the proverbial association of " Peace and Plenty " proved a ghsistly mockery to aU classes of the community. To agriculturists peace brought only beggary. In the first rush of complaint, some allowance must be made for dis- appointment at the immediate results of the end of the war. But the evidence of commercial depression was real and widespread. The disordered state of the currency continued to injure credit, to disturb trade, to create wild speculation instead of sound business. The labour market was glutted. Discharged sailors, soldiers, and miUtiamen swelled the ranks of the imemployed. The store, transport, and commissariat departments were put on a peace footing. Industries to which the war had given a feverish activity languished. Thousands of spinners, combers, and hand-loom weavers were thrown out of work by the increased introduction of machinery into manufacturing processes. Continental ports were once more opened to English trade ; but money was scarce, and foreign merchandise excluded by heavy customs duties. It was soon found that home manufactures had exceeded the demand. Ware- houses were overloaded, markets overstocked. Produce was unsold, . or unpaid for, or bought at prices unremunerative to the producers. Only with America was increased business done. The growing imports of raw cotton were paid for by exports of British goods. After 1821 the commercial depression began to disperse. Difficul- ties of the currency had been, to some extent, adjusted ; credit and confidence were reviving. Progress was for a time suspended by the financial crash of 1825. But the interruption was temporary. Trade improved, at first slowly, then rapidly. Agriculture recovered more gradually ; for a protracted period it endured an almost unexampled misery. Landlords, tenant-farmers, and labourers suffered together. It was not till 1836 that any gleam of returning 12s. 8d. a year. [See Report of the GharUy Oomimiaaioners, 1842.) No estimate can be formed of the additional smns annually contributed by the charitable. The great increase in the Poor Rate cannot be wholly attributed to an increase in the number of paupeis. It was largely due to the greater cost of provisions and to more lax administration. See Appendix H. 1 NichoU'a History of the Poor Law, ed. H. G. Willink (1898), voL ii. p. 165, and Porter's Progress of the Nation (ed. 1847), p. 627. 318 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW prosperity appeared. Duiing the war, farming improvements had been stimulated by the prospect of increased profits. In peace, when once the new conditions were accepted, and some degree of confidence restored, adversity proved an efficient goad. Without improved practices there was no prospect of any profits at all. Yet down to the accession of Queen Victoria there is no substantial progress to chronicle. The characteristics of the period are a great loss of ground and a partial recovery. The inflated prices of the war had conferred, from one point of view, a great advantage on the agriculture of the coimtry. They brought under the plough districts which, but for their stimulus, might never have been brought into cultivation, — areas that were forced into productiveness by the sheer weight of the metal that was poured into them. Money made by farming had been eagerly reinvested in the improvement of the land. For the same purpose banks had advanced money to occupiers on the security of crops and stock which every year seemed to rise in value. Farmers had been able to meet their engagements out of loans, and wait their own time for realising their produce. Better horses were kept, better cattle and sheep bred. Land was hmed, marled, or manured. Wastes were brought under cultivation ; large areas were cleared of stones in order to give an arable surface ; heaths were cleared, bogs drained, buildings erected, roads constructed. The histoiy of Northumberland strongly illustrates these brighter aspects of a gloomy period. John Grey of Dilston,^ " the Black Prince of the North," one of the most enterprising and skilful agriculturists of the day, played a conspicuous part in the transformation of his county. Bom in 1785, and early called through the death of his father to the management of property, he hved in the midst of the agricultural revolution. When his father first settled in Glendale, the plain was a forest of wild broom. He took his axe, and, like a backwoodsman, cleared a space on which to begin his farming operations. The country was then wholly unenclosed, without roads or signposts. Cattle were lost for days in the broom forests. The inhabitants were as wild as their home, — ^the Cheviot herdsmen " ferocious and sullen," the rural population " uneducated, ill-clothed, and barbar- ous." But the character of the soil was such as to attract skill and industry. Men of the same stamp as Grey, or the Culleys, settled in the fertile vales, and by their spirited fanning transformed into > Memoirs of John Qrey of DUaton, by Josephine E. Butler (1869). RAPID FALL IN PRICES 319 cultivated land wide districts, like the rich valley of the Till, which before the period of war prices were wildernesses of underwood. Between 1813 and the accession of Queen Victoria falls one of the blackest periods of English farming. Prosperity no longer stimu- lated progress. Except in a few districts, falling prices, dwindling rents, vanishing profits did not even rouse the energy of despair. The growing demoralisation of both employers and employed, which resulted from the administration of the Poor Law, crushed the spirit of agriculturists. " Many horses die while the grass is grow- ing." The men who survived the struggle were rarely the old owners or the old occupiers. They were rather their fortimate successors who entered on the business of land-cultivation on more favourable terms. Prices had begun to fall with the abundant harvest of 1813. The suddenness of the decline is illustrated from the contracts made on behalf of the Royal Navy. At Portsmouth in January, 1813, the price paid for wheat was 123s. lOd., in Novem- ber, 67s. lOd. In February, 1813, at Deptford, flour was contracted for at 100s. 3d. per sack, in November, at 65s.^ This rapid fall could not at that time have been due to any prospect of peace. It was rather due to over-production, which the House of Commons Committee on the Com Trade (1814) found to have increased within the last ten years by a fourth. Besides English com, Scottish and Irish com were in the market. Since 1806 Irish grain had been admitted into the country free, and it poured into the western counties in considerable quantities. Deficient harvests in 1809-10- 11-12 had concealed the potential yield of the incres/sed area under com ; its full productive power stood revealed by the favourable season of 1813. The two following harvests, 1814 and 1815, were not above the average ; but prices of wheat dropped to 74s. 4d. and 65s. 7d. per quarter respectively. As compared with 1812, the actual receipts of farmers diminished by one hundred millions, and the value of the farming stock was reduced by nearly one- half. The evidence of widespread distress is ample.* But it is * Speech of Chas. C Western, M.P., on moving that the House shotUd resolve itself into a Committee of the Whole House to take into Consideration the Dis- tressed State of the Agriculture of the United Kingdom, March 7, 1816 (Parn^h- leteer, vol. vii. p. 608). ' E.g. 1. A Review of the present Ruined Condition of the Landed and Agri- cultural Interests, etc., by R. Preston, M.P. (1813). 2. Letters on the Distressed State of Agriculturists, by R. Brown (1816). 3. Further Observations on the State of the Nation, etc., by B. Preston, M.F. (1816). 320 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW improbable that its extent was understated. Agricultural witnesses and writers were anxious, not only to prevent any relaxation of the Com Laws, but, if possible, to increase their stringency. The depression, therefore, " lost nothing in the telling," though its depth and reaUty remain imquestionable. Brougham, speaking on agricultural distress in the House of Commons, April 9, 1816, said : " There is one branch of the argument which I shaU pass over altogether, I mean the amount of the distresses which are now universally admitted to prevail over almost every part of the Empire. Upon this topic all men are agreed ; the statements concerning it are as unquestionable as they are afSicting . . . and the petition from Cambridgeshire presented at an early part of this evening, has laid before you a fact, to which all the former expositions of distress a£Eorded no parallel, that in one parish, every proprietor, and tenant being ruined with a single exception, the whole poor-rates of the parish, thus wholly inhabited by paupers, are now paid by an individual whose fortime, once ample, is thus swept entirely away." ^ With wheat standing at over 60s. a quarter, it is difficult to realise that the landed interests could be distressed, and it might be supposed that farmers had made enough in prosperous times to tide over a period of depression. But though the rise in prices had been enor- 4. On the Stale of the Country in December 1816, by the Bt. Hon. Sir John Sinclair (1816). 6. AgrioiUtural State of the Kingdom in February, March, and April, 1816. Being the Svbatcmce of the Replies to a Circidar Letter sent by the Board of AgriouUvre (1816). 6. An Inquiry into the Causes of AgricultiwrcA Distress, by W. Jacob, F.R.S. (1817). 7. Observationa on ihe Present State of Patuperism in England, by the Bev. George Glover (1817). 8. Speech of J. C. Curwen, M.P., in the House of Commons on May 28th, 1816, on a Motion for a Committee to take into Consideration the State of the Poor Laws (1816). 9. Two Letters on the Present Situation of the CourUry, by A. H. Holdsworth, M.P. (1816). 10. Letters on the Present State of the AgriouMwral Interest, by the Bev. Dr. Crombie (1816). 11. On Famine and the Poor Laws, by W. Bichcurdson, D.D. (1816). 12. An Inquiry into Pauperism and Poor Bates, by William Clarkson (1816). 13. Observations . . . on the Condition of the Lc^iotiring Classes, by John Barton (1817). 14. Inquiry into the Causes of the Progressive Depreciation of Agricutfural Labour, by the Same (1820). * " Speech on Agricultural Distress." Speeches of Henry, Lord Brougham, vol. i. pp. 603-4 (1838). HEAVY TAXATION OF LAND 321 mous, the increase in pnblic burdens had more than kept pace. During the ten years ending in 1792, the average price of wheat had been 47s. per quarter ; the national expenditure under twenty millions a year ; the poor-rate less than If millions ; there was also no propertiy tax. During the ten years ending in 1812, wheat averaged 88s. a quarter. While wheat had thus not quite doubled, wages had risen by two-thirds ; the national expenditure had mnltipUed five-fold ; tithes had increased by more than a fourth ; a property tax had been imposed on owners and occupiers of land. The poor-rate had quadrupled ; the county-rate had risen seven- fold ; the permissive charge of 6d. in the pound for the road material of highways had been of late years habitually levied. A very lai^e proportion of this public burden was borne by agriculturists. Upon the landed interests fell more than half the new property tax,' the greater part of the county-, poor-, and highway-rates, the war duties on hops and malting barley, the tax on agricultural horses, and an exceptional share of the tax on leather, which swelled the cost of every kind of harness gear. Thus the rise of the price of agricultural produce was to a great extent discounted by the growth of taxation, and it was the war, not the Com Laws, which had given agricultural producers the monopoly of home markets. In other respects circumstances were exceptional. During the war, the social advantages of landownership and its apparently remunerative character, as well as the large fortunes realised in recent trade, combined to give land a fancy value. New capitalists gratified both their ambitions and their speculative instincts by 'The Property Tax for 1814 produced Gross £16,326,720, and Net £14,646,279. It was made up thus : Sched. A (lands, tenements and hereditaments) £4,297,247 Sched. B (occupiers of land) - - - 2,176,228 Tax on houses ... . 1,626,939 Total - - - £8,099,414 Sched. C, Funded property .... £3,004,861 Sched. D, Profits on Trades and Professions - 3,021,187 Sched. E, Naval, military, and civil lists together with provincial offices . . 1,113,244 Total . - - - £7,139,292 Supplementary account v duties, penalties, etc. 87,014 Total £16,326,720 This tax was repealed in 1816. The number of agricultural occupiers contributing to the property tax under Sched. B was 474,696, as against 162,926 assessed under Sched. D. X 322 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW becoming purchasers. Their biddings forced existing owners into ruinous competition ; they mortgaged their ancestral acres to buy up outlying properties or round oS their boundaries. As much as forty-five years' purchase was given for purely agricultural land. The same spirit of competition prompted farmers to ofEer extravagant rents for land. Farms were put up to auction, and the tenancy fell to the highest bidder. The more prudent had left business in 1806. Many of the new men entered on their holdings with insufficient or borrowed capital. Money was still made in farming ; but, instead of being realised, it was put back into the land, where, so long as prices rose, or were even maintained, it proved a profitable invest- ment. Among all classes, including landowners and farmers, a higher standard of fiving prevailed. Country mansions had been built, rebuilt, or enlarged, and costly improvements effected in the equipment of farms, — often by means of loans ; heavy jointures and portions had been charged on estates ; farmers and their wives had either altered their simpler habits, or brought with them into their new business more luxurious modes of life. The whole fabric rested on the continuance of the war-prices. When these began to fall, the crash came. Profits were reduced by a haU ; burdens remained the same. Tenants-at-wiU could at least quit their hold- ings. But tenants occupying under long leases found themselves in a difficult position. Landlords could not meet their habilities, unless their rents were maintained ; without reductions of rent, the bankruptcy of their tenants seemed inevitable. In the period 1814-16 the agricultural industry passed suddenly from prosperity to extreme depression. At first farmers met their engagements out of capital. When that was exhausted, their only resource was to sell their com as soon as it was threshed, or their stock, for what it would fetch. The great quantity of grain thus thrown on the market ia a limited time lowered prices for producers, and the subsequent advance, which benefited only the dealers, suggested to landlords that no reductions of rent were necessary. Farms were thrown up ; notices to quit poured in ; numbers of tenants absconded. Large tracts of land were untenanted and often uncultivated. In 1815 three thousand acres ia a small district of Huntingdonshire were abandoned, and nineteen farms in the Isle of Ely were without tenants. Bankers pressed for their advances, landlords for their rents, tithe-owners for their tithe, tax-collectors for their taxes, tradesmen for their bills. Insolvencies, composi- RUIN OF MANY FARMERS 323 tions, execntions, seizures, arrests and imprisonments for debt multiplied. Farmhouses were fuU of sheriffs' officers. Many large farmers lost everything, and became applicants for pauper allowances. Even in Norfolk the number of writs and executions rose from 636 in 1814 to 844 in 1815 ; in Suffolk from 430 to 850 ; in Worcester from 640 to 890. In the Isle of Ely the number of arrests and executions increased from 57 in 1812-13 to 263 in 1814-15. In the same district several farmers failed for an aggregate sum of £72,500, and the creditors in hardly any instance received a dividend. Between 1815 and 1820, 52 farmers, cultivating between them 24,000 acres, failed in Dorsetshire. Agricultural improvements were at a stand-stall. Live-stock was reduced to a TniTiinrnTn Lime-kilns ceased to bum ; less manure was used on the land ; the least possible amount of labour was employed. The tradesmen, innkeepers, and shopkeepers of country towns suffered heavily by the loss of custom. Blacksmiths, wheelwrights, collar makers, harness makers, carpenters, found no work. At first the depression had been chiefly felt in corn-growing districts, especially on heavy land. But by 1816 it had spread to mixed and grass farms. In that year, bad seasons created a temporary scarcity ; the rise of wheat to the old prices aggravated rural distress without helping any persons except dealers, and the wealthier farmers who could afford to wait; the potato crop, which had recently become important in England, failed ; perpetual floods in the spring and summer were succeeded by a winter of such unusual severity, that the loss of sheep in the North was enormous. Landlords, whose land was thrown upon their hands, or who had laid charges on their estates, found themselves confronted with ruin. The alternative was hard. If the mortgagee foreclosed, the estate sold for a sum which barely recouped the charges. Preston,^ in 1816, states that " in Norfolk alone landed property to the value of one million and a half is on sale, without buyers for want of money." One property, for which " £140,000 was offered two years ago, is now on sale at £80,000." In a second pamphlet ' he states that " some of the best estates of the kingdom are selling at a depreciation of £50 per cent. One of the finest grass farms in Somersetshire sold lately at 10 years purchase." " There ' Beview of the Present Ruined Condition of the AgriciJltunii and Landed imereats, by Richard Preston, M.P. (1816), {Pamphleteer, vol. vii. pp. 149, 167). ■ Further Observations on the State of the Nation (1816), {Panvphieteer, voL ix. p. 127.) 324 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW are now estates," says Glover,^ " in the most fertile parts of England, nay even within 60 miles of London, which are an absolute loss to the possessor." The natural reluctance of landlords to lower rents may have involved tenants in their fall ; but by 1816 they are stated to have lost 9 millions a year by rent reductions alone.* For the next twenty years the same record of depression is con- tinued. The attention of Parliament was continually called to the distress of the landed interests. Petitions covered the table of the House ; innumerable pamphlets and letters demanded remunera- ting prices for agricultural produce. Some exaggeration there probably was, for the struggle of Free Trade against Protection had begun. But the account which has been given of farming conditions in the years 1814-16 was substantially confirmed by numerous witnesses who gave evidence on the continuance of the distress before a series of Select Committees in 1820, 1821, 1822, 1833, and 1836. Rural conditions were deplorable. Even as late as 1833, it was stated that, in spite of rent reductions, which in Sussex amotmted to 53 per cent., there was scarcely a solvent tenant in the Wealds of Sussex and Kent, and that many fanners, having lost all they had, were working on the roads. Violent fluctuations in prices con- tinued to overthrow all calculations ; the wheat area alternately expanded and contracted ; the sliding scale of 1829, soon exploited for their own profit by foreign importers, only increased the specu- lative character of the agricultural industry. On heavy clays less capital and less labour were expended ; wet seasons prevented ' Observations on the Present State of Pa/uperism in England, by the Bev. G. Glover {Pamphleteer, vol. x. p. 384). * If this statement is correct, it approximately restored the rental of land in Great Britain to the figure at which it stood in 1806. In that year a sub- division for the first time was made of the classes of property the income of which was assessed under Schedule A to the Property Tax. At^ti iih.! Income from 1. Property from Lands - 2. Property from Houses - 3. Amount of Tithes 4. Profits from Manors 6. Fines on Leases . ■ - - 6. Profits of Quarries 7. Profits of Mines . . - - 8. Profits of Iron Works 9. General Profits, etc. 1806 1814 £29,834.484 £39.406.706 11.913.613 16.269.399 2.012,064 2.732.898 43,621 71.672 72.602 216.646 32,466 70.378 363.863 678.786 84,616 647,686 477.762 66,260 £44,834,770 £60,148,330 DISTRESS, DISCONTENT, AND DISTURBANCES 326 fanners from getting on the land, and caused the discontinuance of manure, excessive cropping, and the impoverishment, even the abandonment, of the heavier soils. To add to the difficulties of clay farmers, the rot of 1830-1, which is described as the most disastrous on record, " swept away two million sheep." Every- where wages were lowered and men dismissed. Work became so scarce that, in spite of the fall of prices, starvation stared the agricultural labourer in the face. Distress bred discontent, and discontent disturbances, which were fostered by political agitation. While the Luddites broke up machinery, gangs of rural labourers destroyed threshing machines, or avenged the fancied conspiracy of farmers by burning farm-houses, stacks, and ricks, or wrecking the shops of butchers and bakers. In the riots of 1830-31, when " Swing " and his proselytes were at work, agrarian fires blazed from Dorsetshire to Lincolnshire. The evidence before the Select Committee of 1836 shows that prosperity was beginning to revive. But the long period of depression left its permanent mark on the relations of landlord and tenant, as well as on the conditions of rural society. It was not merely that progress had been lost, or that much of the land was impoverished, or that farm buildings fell into ruinous con- dition. A great expenditure was needed to reorganise the industry, and it was the owner of the land who found the money. Necessity compelled landed proprietors to realise their position. Tenants had little capital left ; they were also more cautious of risks. Recent experience had created a profound distrust of long leases. Without security of tenure for a prolonged term of years, no man of ordinary prudence would make an outlay on the costly works which his predecessors had eagerly undertaken. It was now that the distinction becomes clearly marked between landlord's and tenant's improvements. Even in the latter class, it was already evident that, where the benefits were not exhausted at the expira- tion of the tenancy, compensation was payable, and that local customs afforded insufficient protection. On these new lines agri- culture once more began to advance. At the accession of Queen Victoria the worst of the crisis was over. Rents had been adjusted to changed conditions. The industry had been relieved from some of the exceptional taxation. The Tithe Commutation Act of 1836 had removed a great obstacle to progress. The new Poor Law of 1834 reduced the burden of the rates, and began to re-establish the 326 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW self-respect of the labourer.* The rapid growth of the manufac- turing population not only created an increasing demand for agricultural produce, but relieved the glut of the labour-market. To small freeholders, whether gentry, yeoman-farmers, or peasant proprietors, the Napoleonic war, with its crushing load of taxation and subsequent collapse of prices, had been fatal. The evidence before the Agricultural Committee of 1833 proves that some still held their own in every county. But it was in the first thirty years of the nineteenth century that their numbers dwindled most rapidly. Some had consulted their pecuniary interests by selling their land at fancy prices, which they took into business. Others sold and embarked their capital as tenant-farmers in hiring larger areas of land, on which they could take fuller advantage of the price of com. Those who remained on their own estates were for the most part ruined. Many had raised mortgages to buy more land, or to improve their properties, or to put their children out in the world. Prices fell ; but the private debt, as well as the pubUc burdens, remained. The struggle was brief ; farming deteriorated ; buildings fell out of repair ; creditors pressed ; finally the estate was sold. Even where land was free from charges, owners could not stand up against the burden of poor-rates, which was most crushing to those who employed no labour but their own. " That respectable class of English yeomanry," writes Glover* in 1817, " whose fathers from generation to generation have lived on the same spot and cultivated the same farms are now rapidly dwindling into poverty and decay, sinking themselves into the class of paupers." The purchasers were not men of their own class. After 1812 small capitalists no longer invested their savings in land. Their place as buyers was taken by large landowners or successful traders. In Yorkshire the number of small proprietors was dwindling ; formerly, if one freeholder went, another took his place ; but this had now ceased to be the case. The same report is made of Shropshire, Worcestershire, and Wiltshire. In Kent and Somersetshire it is stated that, though many freeholders retained their land, it was only by the practice of the most rigorous self-denial and by entirely ceasing to employ labour. Throughout ' In 1837 the expenditure dropped to the lowest point as yet recorded in the century, £4,044,741. ' ObservaUona on the Preaent State of Pawperitm, etc. {Pamphleteer, vol. x. p. 386). ALLOWANCES IN AH) OP WAGES 327 the country, it is evident that most of the small landowners, who, in addition to taxes and rates, had to pay annuities or interest on mortgages, were forced to sell their properties. Everywhere large estates were bmit up on the ruin of small proprietors. Morally, if not materially, no class suffered more from the pro- longed period of depression than agricultural labourers. They had bitter reason to deplore the shortsighted humanity which in the last twenty years of the eighteenth century had swept away the old barriers against pauperism.^ Where Gilbert's Act had been adopted, every man was now secure of employment from the parish or, in any case, of maintenance. In every parish, also, outdoor relief for the able-bodied poor was now compulsory on the overseers. Already in some districts men out of regular work were " on the Rounds," offering their labour from house to house, paid, if employed, partly by the householder, partly by the parish, and if unemployed, wholly by the parish. Even men in full employ- ment were drawn within the net. When iu 1795-6 the price of provisions rose to famine height, wages were supplemented by allowances from the rates. A scale of these allowances was pro- claimed by the Berkshire magistrates, proportioned to the price of bread and the size of families. From the wages of the unmarried labourer, which were zero, the scale ascended, varying with fluctua- tions in the cost of the quartern loaf and the number of the children of the married labourer. Similar scales of allowances were adopted in many other counties. Thus able-bodied men, whether in or out of work, became dependent on the rates. That, from the first, these allowances delayed the natural rise of wages, lowered earnings by making the needs of immarried men the most important factor, and encouraged improvident marriages, is certain. But these evils were held in check till 1813. So long as the war and the high prices continued, the demand for labour was brisk ; distress was prac- tically confined to those who suffered from enclosures, or from the decline of local industries other than the cultivation of the land. Agricultural wages rose substantially ; employment increased owing to the extension of tillage ; even the high prices of provisions affected labourers less than might have been expected, since the provisions, in several parts of the country, were suppUed to them at a lower cost than the market rates. Except for winter unemployment the allowance system was sparingly used. But during the depression • See Appendix II. The Poor Law. 328 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW farmeiB were driven to economise in their labour bills. Wages were greatly reduced or even ceased altogether. The replies to the Circular Letter of the Board of Agriculture insist on the deplor- able scarcity of employment. Preston^ speaks of the daily increase in the number of paupers, and of " a large part of the community ... in want of employment though willing to labour." " At no period in the memory of man," writes Jacob,* " has there been so great a portion of industrious agricultural labourers absolutely destitute as at the present moment." It was now that the Poor Law was most perniciously relaxed ; now also that the demoralising system of allowances became the most conspicuous feature in its administration. The immediate effects of the depressed condition of agriculture was a great reduction in the rates of wages, and in the demand for permanent labour. Unless the farmer could lessen his costs of production, he was rapidly sinking into bankruptcy. The Poor Law, as it was administered in 1813-34, in two ways came to his assistance. It enabled bim to reduce wages to the lowest possible point, because it made good the deficiency out of allowances from the rates. Men discharged as supernumeraries were taken on again as soon as they were on the poor-book. It also provided him with an inexhaustible supply of cheap and temporary labour. Bound to defray the whole cost of maintaining the able-bodied poor, the parish gladly accepted any payment, however small, in part relief of their Uability. It became almost impossible for a farmer to keep a man in permanent employment at reasonable wages. If he did, he was only saving the rates for neighbours, who put their hands into his pockets to pay their labour biUs. Sometimes the ratepayers in the parish arranged among themselves to employ and pay a number of men proportionate to the rateable value of their property. Sometimes the parish agreed with employers to sell the labour of so many paupers at a given sum, and paid the men the difference between the agreed price and the scale allowance awarded to them according to the cost of bread and the number of their children. Sometimes the paupers were paraded by the overseers on a Monday morning, and the week's labour of each 1 Review of the Present Rvined Condition, etc., by R. Preaton, M.P. (1816), (ParrvpMieteer, vol. vii. p. 129). * Inquiry into the Owisea of the AgnouHtwral Diatreaa, by W. Jacob, F.R.S. (1817), {PampKkteer, vol x. p. 411). DEMORALISATION OF LABOUR 329 individnal was offered at auction to the highest bidder. Sometimes the parish contracted for the execution of a piece of work at a given sum, and performed it by pauper labour, paying the men according to the allowance scale. If men were still unemployed, they were formed into gangs under overseers, occupied in more or less unpro- ductive work ; it was among these men that the riots of 1830-1 are said to have originated.^ Against the mass of subsidised labour, free labourers could not hope to compete. It was so cheap that men who tried to retain their independence were undersold. Those who had saved money or bought a cottage, could not be placed on the poor-book ; they were obliged to strip themselves bare, and become paupers, before they could get employment. Every agency that could promote the spread of pauperism seemed brought into play. The demoralisa- tion gradually extended from the southern counties to the North. In the most practical fashion, labourers were taught the lessons that improvidence paid better than thrift ; that their rewards did not depend on their own exertions ; that sobriety and efficiency had no special value above indolence and vice. All alike had the same right to be maintained at the ratepayers' cost. Prudence and seK-restraint were penalised. The careful were unemployed, the careless supported by the parish ; the more recklessly a man married and begot children, the greater his share of the comforts of life. The effect was seen in the rapid growth of population. Among unmarried women morality was discouraged, and un- chastity subsidised. The more illegitimate children, the larger the allowance from the parish ; at Swaffham a woman with five illegi- timate children was in receipt of 18s. a week. The demoralisation was BO complete that it threatened to overthrow the whole social fabric. Voluntary pauperism became a profession, and a paying one. Recipients considered themselves as much entitled to parish allowances as they would have been to wages that they had earned by their industry. A generation was springing up which knew no source of income but poor relief. When once the spirit of independence and self-respect was numbed, and the instincts of parental responsibility and fiUal obhgation were weakened, a paui>er's life, with its security of subsistence, its light labour, its opportunities of idleness, had attractions for the vicious and easy- * For these varieties of the Labour Bate, the Roundsmen and Parish Em- ployment, see the Report on the Poor Laws (1834), pp. 42, 31-32, 36. 330 AGRICULTURAL DEPRESSION AND POOR LAW going. Riots were not always protests against the existing system ; they were sometimes means of enforcing its continuance, and parochial allowances were maintained by the establishment of a reign of terror, by threats, violence, and incendiarism.^ Rural conditions were fast becoming intolerable. Fortunately, there still remained a leaven of agricultural labourers who resented pauper dependence as a curse and a disgrace. Fortunately, many farmers were learning by experience that cheap labour was bad labour, and that quantity was no efficient substitute for quality. Fortunately, also, there were districts which a wiser administration of the Poor Law had rescued from the general demoralisation. In four parishes, Southwell, Bingham, Uley, and Llangattock, the principle had been adopted, with marked success, of refusing reUef to the able-bodied, except in well-regulated workhouses. Some sixty others had been practically depauperised (e.g. Welwyn, Leck- hampstead, and Carlisle) by stopping allowances, and exacting hard work, at low pay, under strict supervision, as a condition of parish reUef. On the other hand, the parish of Cholesbury in Buckinghamshire afforded the typical illustration of the extreme consequences to which the existing system was necessarily leading. Out of 98 persons, who had a settlement in the parish, 64 were in receipt of poor relief, and the rates exceeded 24s. in the pound. Only 16 acres remained in cultivation. When able-bodied paupers were offered land, they refused it on the ground that they preferred their present position. The parish was only able to exist by means of rates-in-aid levied on other parishes in the hundred. Similar conditions prevailed elsewhere. It was evident that the fund from which the rates were provided must become exhausted. Rents were already disappearing. The Poor Law had destroyed the confidence of tenants, deteriorated the moral character of the labourer, forced large areas out of cultivation, driven capital to seek investment everywhere but in land. A drastic remedy was needed. In 1832 a Commission of Inquiry was appointed to examine into existing conditions, and suggest the lines of legislative reform. On the recommendations of this Commission was based the Act of 1834 " for the Amendment and better Administration of the Laws relative to the Poor in England and Wales." A central authority was constituted to regulate local administration. The » Extracts from, the Information received by H.M. Commitsionerg as to .. .the Poor Laws (1833), p. 3. THE POOR LAW OF 1834 331 orders issued by the new authority proceeded on the main principle of restoring the old Poor Law, without the relaxations which the legislation and practice of George m. had introduced. The workhouse test for the able-bodied was revived. If a man chose to depend for subsistence on the parish rates, instead of on his own resources, he was obliged to enter the workhouse and submit to its regulations. Out-door relief for the able-bodied was dis- couraged, and allowances in add of wages were prohibited. At the same time the laws of settlement were modified, in order that labour might become more mobile and more easily transferable in obedience to the laws of demand and supply. The effect of these and other changes was soon manifest. Expenditure upon poor relief feU from £7,036,968 in 1832 to £4,044,741 in 1837. Wages rose, though for many years they remained miserably low. Land- owners again poured their capital into the land ; farmers regained confidence ; agricultural progress was resumed. The evidence laid before the Select Committee of 1836 proves that signs of returning prosperity were beginning to appear, and that the distress waa now practically confined to clay land. CHAPTER XVI. TTTHES. The incidence of tithes under the old law ; the historical origin of tithes ; a free-will offering ; a customary payment ; the appeal to conscience ; ecclesiastical penalties for non-payment ; a legal liability : tithes as parochial endowments ; the Reformation ; the collection of tithes in kind unpopular, and expensive to tithe-owners ; substituted forms of payment ; the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836 ; its object and machinery. A SBBions obstacle to the progress or recovery of agriculture was presented by the incidence of tithe upon the produce of the land. Tithe-owners were sleeping partners in the cultivation of the soil. They contributed neither capital nor labour to the enterprise of the farm ; they risked nothing in the venture. But they shared the profits derived from increased productiveness. While agriculture remained stationary, the burden was light. As soon as farming began to advance, and to demand a greater outlay, the grievance was acutely felt. In times of prosperity the incidence on produce discouraged improvement. In days of adversity, when every penny was important to struggling agriculturists, it retarded recovery. Since the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836, much of the ancient law of tithes has retained only an antiquarian interest. But the long history of the payment has left an indelible mark on rural life. Historically, tithes were a tenth part, taken yearly, of all produce of the land, of the stock nourished upon the land, and of the clear profits of the personal industry of tradesmen, artificers, miUers, and fishermen. In other words, tithes were, as lawyers distinguished them by their sources, predial, mixed, or personal. Predial tithes were derived directly from the soil, such as com, hay, beans, peas, turnips, hemp, flax, saffron, rushes, fruits, and wood of various kinds. Mixed tithes arose from the increase or produce of animals maintained by the fruits of the earth, as of cattle, sheep, pigs, poultry or their eggs, wool, milk or cheese. Personal tithes on the ORIGINALLY A FREE-WILL OFFERING 333 clear gain of the labour of man had early fallen into disuse. Manu- facturers were never Uable for the payment, which only survived in such forms as a tenth of the fisherman's catch, or a tenth of the miller's clear profits on meal ground in all but ancient mills. Another classification, distinguished between great and small tithes according to the nature of the produce on which they fell. Thus great or rectorial tithes iacluded com, beans, peas, hay, and wood ; all the other predial tithes, together with all mixed tithes, were small or vicarial. The legal obligation to pay tithes, as distinct from the older moral duty of giving them, dates back to a remote period of history. No real dispute arises respecting their origin, until the point is reached where the offering passed from a free-will gift into a liability enforced by l^al penalties. From the fourth century onwards, throughout the Christian world, the practice of dedicating fractional parts of produce to religious objects was recognised by the faithful as a moral duty. As a matter of conscience, the gift was enjoined by Councils of the Western Church, and enforced by appeals to the rewards and punishments of religion. Thus the practice gradually acquired something of the binding force of custom. The final stage was reached when the State recognised as a civil duty the religious practice of giving tithes, and compelled payment, not by appeals to conscience, nor even by spiritual penalties, but by temporal sanctions. This last step, by which tithes passed from moral obligations into legal habihties, was taken at different dates by the different countries of Christian Europe. Before the landing of Augustine in England (597), and before the introduction of Christianity into this country, the moral duty of giving tithes had been enjoined on the Continent by at least one Church Council. As a matter of conscience, therefore, the first missionaries to Anglo-Saxon England preached the consecration of a tenth of produce to the service of God, and as a religious custom the practice was established by their successors among their Chris- tian followers. The appeal was the more forcible since it came from men who were beUeved to hold the keys of heaven and of hell. But there were as yet no divisions into parishes, no parish churches, no parochial clergy, and no parochial endowments. The cathedral, monastery, and "mother church," generally conventual, of the local- ity, were mission centres, from which radiated itinerant missioners, who preached under rude crosses the rudiments of Christianity 334 TITHES to the inhabitants of outlying districts. Into the hands of the Bishop or monastic bodies were paid all the ofEerings of the faithful. The married clergy, outside the cloister, were slowly and with difficulty obtained. They were for the most part ignorant, uncouth men, recruited from the lower classes of native converts, entrusted only with the humbler offices of the ministry. They taught the Lord's Prayer and the Apostles' Creed in remote hamlets, watched by the bedsides of dying penitents, and in special cases administered the rites of baptism. It is not strange that, on earth at least, their lowly labours should have been ignored or forgotten. Very different was the fate of the monastic bodies. To them fell power, riches, credit. Kings were their nursing-fathers, queens their nursing] mothers ; the wealthy nobles vied with one another in the munifi- cence of their endowments. In comparison with existing civilisation, the monastic bodies attained a standard of wealth, refinement and culture which was at least as high as that of later times. They laid acre to acre, and field to field. For miles round their farms, bams, flocks, herds, fish-ponds, and dovecotes dotted the country. They entranced the senses by the beauty of their architecture, their music, their ritual ; they commanded respect by their learning ; they inspired awe by the austerities of their lives. They alone could offer an inviolable resting-place for the dead, since there were no parochial burial-grounds, and they practically monopolised rights of sepulture. Thus in death, as well as in life, they appealed irresistibly to the favour of the world. Till the closing period of the Anglo-Saxon Church, there were, as has been said, no resident parochial clergy. Ecclesiastical organisation proceeded downwards, not upwards. It was provincial, diocesan, conventual, before it became local and parochial. The cathedrals of the dioceses and the conventual churches of the monasteries at first provided for the religious wants of the people. Yet the material was ready for the introduction of the parochial system. Townships suggested the necessary divisions, and village communities, on the self-sufficing system of these agrairian societies, had probably been accustomed to provide for their pagan priests. From the first the rulers of the Church felt the need of continuous local ministrations, though, probably, the earliest advances towards a parochial system were forced upon the country by external causes. From the ninth century onwards Danish invasions struck a series of staggering blows at the monastic organisation. Monasteries ORIGIN OF PAROCHIAL ORGANISATIONS 335 were the first objects of the invaders' attack ; their wealth and their defencelessness made them an easy, as well as a tempting, prey. They were sacked, pillaged, burned, and their inmates either dis- persed or massacred. To save rural Christianity from extinction by a relapse into paganism it became necessary to encourage local efforts, to favour the erection of private chapels, to enlarge the powers of the rural priests or chaplains by whom they were served, even to consecrate as burial-grounds the precincts in which they stood. Thus a permanent resident clergy began to grow up on the rural estates of great nobles in connection with private chapels and oratories. With the gradual extension of this local provision for permanent religious ministrations begins the increased importance attached to the payment of tithes as parochial endowments. Early documents confirm this explanation of the growth of parochial tithes. On the one side, the Church, backed by all her supposed power over the destinies of man, urged the consecration of tenths to the service of God. On the other hand, the earthly influence of the Crown, sometimes by royal admonitions, coupled with threats of loss of favour, sometimes by attesting and confirm- ing the decrees of synods, sometimes even by treaties of peace with the Danes, supported the demand of the Church, and assisted in making the custom of paying tithes universal. Under this double pressure the practice grew. But it was not tiU 944 that King Edmund's synod at London for the first time made non-payment of tithes an ecclesiastical offence to be punished by excommunication. Henceforward the Chtuxih claimed as an ecclesiastical right what she had hitherto received, if at all, as a free-will offering. The moral duty had become a religious obligation, enforced by spiritual The payment of tithes was not yet a legal liabilii^, enforced by temporal sanctions. Nor were tithes, or any part of them, as yet, ecclesiastically or l^ally, appropriated as parochial endowments. But the times were ripening for both changes. Volimtary dedica- tions of free-wiU offerings had been acted upon by the religious bodies to whom they had been made. On the faith of their con- tinuance cathedrals had been erected and a diocesan system established ; monasteries had been founded ; manorial churches had been built and some local provision made for their service : the dim outline of a future parochial system could be discerned. By these voluntary dedications the original donors had alienated 336 TITHES portions of their own property. K neither appeals to conscience nor threats of excommunication sufBced to obtain payment, the State might not unreasonably be asked to enforce it as a legal liability, either against the original donors or against their repre- sentatives who had inherited estates already subject to the dedica- tion of the consecrated portion. In the reign of Edgar the Peaceful, during the primacy of Dunstan, the payment of tithes was made a legal Uability, universal in its application. At the same time a step was taken towards the appropriation of a portion to the maintenance of district churches of a particular class. At Andover, in 970, the Tring and his Witen- agemot issued an ecclesiastical ordinance, which was to all intents and purposes an Act of Parliament. The ordinance creates no tithes. On the contrary it presupposes their existence. It regulates the times when they were to be paid, and makes their payment a legal liability, enforced by a pecuniary penalty and a power of distraint. It does not profess to give them to the clergy. The first article ran as follows : — " That God's churches be entitled to every right ; and that every tithe be rendered to the old minster, to which the district belongs ; and be then so paid, both from a thane's Mand (i.e. land granted in the lord's own hands), and from geneat-land {i.e. land granted out for services), so as the plough traverses it." Un- doubtedly, the law not only protects the Church in the possession of tithes already dedicated, but transforms the moral duty, religious custom, and ecclesiastical obligation into a legal liability. A reason is suggested by the passages which regulate their division. The general right of the " old minster," the mother church of the district — ^whether collegiate or conventual — to the local tithes was recognised. But an exception was allowed. If any landowner had built on his private estate a church with a burial-place attached, he was to assign to its support one-third of the local tithes. The remaining two-thirds were to be paid to the " mother church." If the landowner had built on his estate a church or oratory without a burial-place, the local tithes went to the " mother church," and he might provide privately for the priest of his private chapel. In other words, the old diocesan and monastic system still remained in force ; but, side by side with it, had grown up manorial churches, providing " shrift districts " with burial-grounds, and therefore claiming some more permanent support than the caprice of the builder or of his successors. They were not yet parish churches ; CONSECRATION OF PARISH CHURCHES 337 but they were their original type, and in the private chapela or " field churches " of the greater landowners are seen the germs of a further extension of a parochial system. The law of Edgar remained unaltered at the Conquest. Practically re-enacted by Canute and by Edward the Confessor, it was accepted by WiUiam the Conqueror. As years passed, district or parochial churches were multipUed by their voluntary founders ia various parts of the country. Some were built by kings or great nobles as private chapels ; some by bishops, some by monastic houses, some by landowners, some by freemen on the landowners' estates. Church-building proceeded on no general system, and without any uniformity of date. There was a gradual growth under var3dng circumstances ; but the people, acting through the legislature in a national capacity, neither built, nor endowed, nor repaired these churches. As with the buildings, so with the endowments. They were gradually appropriated to particular churches, in different proportions, without either system or uniformity. No priest serving a district could enforce any claim to local tithes, except for the third which was appropriated only to churches with burial-grounds. Though the payment had become a legal Uabihty, the dedication of tithes to particular parochial uses is, therefore, still unexplained. Something more remained to be done. The final steps were taken between the eleventh and thirteenth centuries. The chief instrument by which local endowments were secured to parish churches was consecration. A founder desired to build a church on his estate, and to have it consecrated. But the bishop could refuse to consecrate, unless proper provision was made for its maintenance. Between the bishop and the founder, who ia building the church was a free agent, there might be bargaining. There might also be opposition from outside. The neighbouring monastery perhaps resented the intrusion of a new church and a new priest into the field which it had regarded as its own. But at no stage, either in the bargain or in the opposition, does the national will express itself. Throughout, the founder was at first practically master of the situation. There was no compulsion on him to build a church at all. If he did, not only did he himself nominate and invest the priest, with or without the consent of the bishop, but he could delay appointing to vacancies, and thus leave the church without services. Even where local endowment had been secured to the parochial church at consecration, the system was thus in- T 338 TITHES complete. Both points were settled by ecclesiastical discipline at the close of the twelfth century, The necessity for institution by the bishop was established, and the bishop's right to appoint to vacant benefices, after a certain period of delay, was vindicated. A further step was stUl required. The legal habihty for the payment of tithes was satisfied it, with the exception of the third secured to the parochial churches which possessed burial-grounds, payment was made to any ecclesiastical body. A patron might increase the pittances of the poor priests at his door, or offer it to the collegiate cathedral, or heap the grain in the bam of a monastery, or sell the tithes issuing from his estate to any reUgious body that he chose, or even, by collusion, store the com in the granaries of himself or his lay friends. Even after the formation of parishes had become general, and after the claim of parochial churches was commonly recognised, it was stUl possible, and still usual, to grant the local tithes to distant houses of rehgion. The same causes were at work which in Anglo-Saxon times sacrificed the secular clergy to the monasteries. Norman landlords preferred to assign their tithes to monastic bodies, with whom they were more in sympathy than with the native priests of rural districts. The increase of monasticism after the Conquest necessarily aUenated a large part of the local tithes which naturally would have increased the local provision for religious services. This option on the part of land- owners is inconsistent with the theory of the endowment of parishes by an exercise of the national will, expressed in some general law. It was not tUl the thirteenth century, and then not by any statute or Act of ParHament, but by the growth of custom, that the land- owner's freedom of choice was limited. No doubt the growth of the custom was aided by the practice of such specific dedications of tithes to the parochial church as those of Hay and Exhall. At common law the courts presumed that the parish church was primd facie entitled to the tithes which issued from the lands of the parish. By this presumption the burden of proof was thrown on tithe-payers or other claimants to show that the local tithes had been either paid to some collegiate or conventual body for so long a period as to create a prescriptive right, or had been by express grant aUenated to some other religious body. It was to custom that the parochial clergy appealed ; other claimants rehed on immemorial usage or express grant. This fact is in itself of extreme importance. Had any enactment of the TITHES AS PAROCHIAL ENDOWMENTS 339 national assembly established the primd facie right of the parochial clergy to the tithes of the parish, they would have relied, not on custom, but on statute. If, as parochial endowments, tithes were statutory in their origin, we should expect to find that they commence with the legislation by which they are alleged to be created, and that the payment was certain in practice, uniform in amount, identical in source. If, on the other hand, the endowment of parish churches with tithes originated in a series of voluntary dedications, and if the State merely protected a property which was none the less real because it began as a free-will offering, we should expect to find that customary payments preceded any recorded legislation, and were uncertain in practice, varying in amount, irregular in source. Historical facts confirm the second view. The volimtary payment of tithes in this country preceded, by upwards of three centuries, parochial organisation, as well as both ecclesiastical and secular legislation. The first secular enactment on the subject assumes the prior existence of the charge, and for more than two centuries afterwards allows tithe-payers a wide freedom in the choice of the religious body to which payment was made. When this freedom was limited, it was restricted not by legislation but by the growth of custom. Both in respect of the persons to whom tithes were due, and of the produce on which they were payable, the practice was not certain, but uncertain. The amount paid was varying, not uniform. The sources from which the payment Was derived, are not identical, but irregular. If, therefore, the State endowed parochial churches with tithes, all those signs, which would naturally accompany such a national act, are conspicuously absent. On the other hand, all those signs, which naturally indicate the legislative protection of customary practices, ate con- conspicuously present. The gradual, piecemeal, and discretionary endowment of parochial churches with the tithes of the parish has left its mark on the existing organisation. It explains, for instance, as no other assump- tion can explain, the freedom from the payment which the " Hall," " Court," or " Manor " farm frequently enjoyed ; it lies at the root of the distinction between rectorial and vicarial tithes, and between ecclesiastical appropriators and lay impropriators ; it suggests the reason why land in one parish should be charged with tithes for the benefit of the church of another parish. Many of the old anomalies in the law of tithes have been smoothed into comparative uniformity 340 TITHES by the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836. But the previous history of the charge renders it di£S.cult to believe that the nation ever by a legislative action endowed parochial churches with the local tithes. The Bicformation left the parochial organisation untouched. But it made an important change, which greatly embittered objections to the payment of tithes. It ahenated a considerable portion of the tithes from religious uses. Rectories, together with the local tithes, might be, and often had been, " appropriated " to a monastery or other reUgious corporation, which appointed vicars to discharge the religious duties attached to the endowment. Originally the stipend of the vicar was arbitrary. But gradually it was recognised that the person responsible for reUgious ministrations in the parish ought to have some fixed determinate means of support. This was gener- ally made by endowing the vicarage with land, or by assigning to it some portion of the great tithes, or the whole of the small tithes, or by a combination of all three methods. At the Dissolution of the Monasteries all the rectorial tithes in their possession, which had not been already allocated to the support of vicarages, passed into the hands of the Crown, and were subsequently granted out by letters patent to lay subjects. These lay grantees were called " lay rectors," or " impropriators," in order to distinguish them from the original " appropriators," who were of necessity spiritual persons or ecclesiastical corporations. When the Tithe Commutation Act was passed in 1836, and tithes of produce were commuted into rent- charges, it was found that nearly one-fourth of the annual value had thus been diverted from religious purposes into the hands of laymen.^ There is strong evidence that the lay impropriators or their lessees, who were generally absentees, and without other interests in the parish, exacted their legal dues with a strictness which was relatively rare among clerical tithe-owners. Tithes in themselves, and apart from their incidence, could scarcely be regarded as a legitimate grievance by either owners or occupiers of land, especially as no attack was as yet made on the religious objects to which they were devoted. No landlords could honestly believe ' The net annual value of the tithes, after a deduction of 40 per cent, from the gross value, was in 1836 estimated at £4,063,986 6s. S^d. Of this total sum £962,289 15s. were then in the hands of lay impiopiiators. But this figure does not take into accotmt the large amount of lay tithes which had been, in the coiuse of three centuries, extinguished by purchases on the part of landowners, or bought and given back to the parochial clergy, or restored by those who, like Spelman, considered their retention by laymen a sacrilege. TITHES IN KIND 341 that the payment robbed thenx of any part of the rents to which they were justly entitled. For centiuies, in every transfer of land, whether by purchase or inheritance, the estimated value of tithes had been previously deducted from the value of the estate so bought or inherited. Nor could any tenant honestly complain that tithes increased the burden of his rent. Land only commands what it is worth. If 100 acres of land fetched £1 per acre, it made no pecuniary di£Eerence to the farmer whether he paid £100 to the landowner or £90 to the landowner and £10 to the tithe-owner. But the real prac- tical grievance was the incidence of the charge upon the produce of the land. In this way tithes become a charge which was increased by good farming, or diminished by bad, — a tax on every additional outlay of money and labour, — a check upon enterprise and improvement. Tithes in kind were admittedly out of date. Though rents and wages had long been placed on a money basis, a tithe-owner could still exact pajrment in the ancient fashion. As a fact, however, the Reports to the Board of Agriculture (1793-1815) prove that, at the close of the eighteenth century, comparatively httle tithe was collected in kind. Especially was this the case when the tithe was in the hands of clerical owners. For this change of practice there were many reasons. Collection in kind was extremely unpopular. Where it prevailed, farmers showed their dishke to the system in various ways. Many tenants so greatly resented putting money into the pockets of tithe-owners that they preferred to lose it them- selves, and refused to plough up pastures which would have been more profitable under tillage. Sometimes the tenant left his tith- able land unmanured. A Hertfordshire farmer, for instance, occupied land in two parishes, in one of which a reasonable composi- tion was paid, while, in the other, tithe was collected in kind. The result was that he farmed one part of his occupation with spirit on improved methods, and that the dung-cart never reached the other portion of his land. Sometimes the tenants made the collection as inconvenient as possible. Thus a Hampshire farmer gave notice to the tithe-owner that he was about to draw a field of turnips. When the tithe-owner's servants, horses and waggons had come on the land, the farmer drew ten turnips, gave one to the tithing-man, and said that he would let his master know when he drew any more. In a wet season the collection was often the cause of heavy loss. Notice had to be given to the tithe-owner to set out the tithe. Farmers risked a lawsuit, if they carried their crops before the 342 TITHES process was completed. Consequently, in catchy seasons the rain often outstripped the slow progress of the titbing-man, and the crops were ruined. The collection of tithes in kind, regulated as it was by the subtle and technical distinctions of case-made law, provoked endless bicker- ings, disputes and Utigation. If tithe-owners were clergymen, living in their parishes, they naturally welcomed any reasonable system of payment which enabled them to live on friendly terms with their parishoners. Non-resident pluralists, or lay impropriators who let out the tithes to proctors, could better afford to defy the public opinion of the neighbourhood. But they were not always proof against business arguments. The heavy cost of collecting tithes in kind suggested the conunercial prudence of adopting other arrangements. Bams must be built and repaired for the storage of produce. The weekly wages of servants must be met. Waggons and horses, with the necessary cart-sheds and stabling must be provided and maintained. The cost, not only of collecting, but of threshing, dressing and marketing com had to be met. The net profits of a crop were thus reduced to a TniniTniini by the duphcation of expenses. Various forms of payment were therefore substituted for collection in kind. Sometimes, and especially under enclosures of open fields, tithes were extinguished by allotments of land of equivalent value. Sometimes it was considered that the increase of the area of land held in mortmain or the difficult position of clerical landowners were objections to the exchange of tithes for their equivalent in landed property, and a corn-rent was substituted. Sometimes tithes were commuted for a composition calculated on the acre or on the pound of rent paid, and either fixed for a term of years or based on an annual estimate of the value of the crops. Sometimes farmers had the option of taking the tithable portion at the sur- veyor's valuation or leaving it to be collected by the tithe-owner. Sometimes, in a few fortunate parishes, a modus had by immemorial usage taken the place of tithes. Moduses were payments of definite sums, which had been permanently fixed in amount at a time when the purchasing power of money had been far greater than it had since become. They were, therefore, advantageous to the tithe- payer. A modus of Id. on every fleece shorn in the parish was no real equivalent to a tenth of the value of the wool.^ 1 For various methods of collecting tithes in the different counties 1793- 1816, see Appendix VII. THE BARREN LANDS ACT 343 No variety in forms of payment conld entirely remove the reason- able objection to a tithe of produce in kind. So long as farming remained stagnant the grievance was imperceptible. It became acute when progressive methods of agriculture were generally adopted. Here and there tithe-owners recognised the altered con- ditions by allowing deductions from their tithes to meet the cost of all purchased manures. But the practice was by no means general. The fair adjustment of compositions was in other wajre extremely difScult. Tithable crops were of greater value to farmers, who could collect and market them at a small additional expense, than they were to tithe-owners, whose necessary outlay diminished their net profits by a half. The difference allowed a large margin for dispute. Even when compositions were reasonable, they tithed the increased produce of improved husbandry. Land, highly cultivated, might be valued at 3s. 6d. an acre ; soil of the same natural quality, under slovenly management, might escape with Is. 6d. In the case of waates, the objection to tithes on produce was strongly felt as an obstacle to improvement. When land, which at the best had afforded only rough pasture, was reduced to cultivation, owners and occupiers risked labour and money on a venture which might succeed or fail. In either event tithe-owners were safe ; they profited by the success, and lost nothing by the failure. The legis- lature had endeavoured to meet the case. Under the Barren Lands Act,^ barren heaths and waste grounds were exempted from tithes for seven years after they had been reduced for the first time to cultivation. But the decisions of the law courts deprived improvers of the benefits which they expected from the Act. Only land which was so barren that it paid no tithe by reason of its barrenness was held to be exempt. The initial cost of draining fen-lands, or grub- bing and stubbing wood-lands, or of paring and burning moors and heaths was not to be taken into consideration. Whatever the cost at which the land had been fitted for cultivation, the only question to be aaked was whether, when ploughed and sown, it was so naturally fertile as to produce a crop, or so naturally barren that it would yield nothing without an extraordinary expenditure on liming, chalking, marling, dunging, or manuring. Only in the latter case could the seven years' exemption be legally claimed. The law of tithes needed complete revision. Its inadequacy to meet changed conditions had long been felt. The necessity for a I 2 and 3 Ed. VI. c. 13. 344 TITHES large expenditure of capital in order to recover the ground which had been lost during a long period of disaster forced the question to the front. In 1836 the difficulty was solved. Peel in 1835 had proposed the voluntary commutation of tithe. Lord John Brussell, adopting in his Bill the machinery which Peel had sketched, made commutation compulsory. When once this point was decided, party considerations were for the moment subordinated : Whig and Tory loyally co-operated to frame a workable scheme. The aim of legislators was to commute tithe of produce in kind for a variable money payment charged on the land, to make the commuted sum fluctuate with the purchasing power of money, to preserve the existing relations between the values of tithable produce and the cost of Uving. It never attempted to fix the payment, once and for all, at the sum which represented the value that tithe then possessed. On the contrary, it converted tithes into a corn-rent, fluctuating in value according to the septennial average of the prices of wheat, barley and oats. The first step was to determine the value of the tithes ; the second to adjust the purchasing power of the money payment at which they were commuted. Within a limited time tithe-owners and tithe-payers of any parish might agree upon the total sum to be paid ia lieu of tithes. This agreement was first to receive the assent of the patron ; secondly, to be communicated to the bishop ; and, thirdly, to be approved and ratified by the Commissioners. If no agreement was arrived at, a local enquiry was held on the spot by the Commissioners or their assistants, who estimated the value of the tithe, taking as their basis the actual receipts of the tithe-owner during the preceding seven years ; framed their draft award ; deposited it for the in- spection of interested parties ; and, finally, confirmed their award, which from that time was binding upon tithe-owners and tithe- payers. The mode in which the purchasing power of money was intended to be preserved was as follows. The average of the gross annual value of the actual receipts of the tithe-owner was ascertained in money for the seven preceding years. The net annual value, arrived at by deducting all just expenses, was taken as the permanent commutation of the great and small tithes of the parish. This net sum was divided into three equal parts, and the average value for the seven years ending with 1835 was taken for wheat, barley and THE PRINCIPLE OF COMMUTATION 345 oats. It wafi then asked how many bushels of wheat could be bought at cost price by one of these equal portions, how many of barley by the second, how many of oats by the third. Each £100 of tithe was divided into three equal sums of £33 6s. 8d. ; the septennial averages for the three grains were respectively 7s. OJd. for a bushel of wheat ; 3s. lljd. for a bushel of barley ; 2s. 9d. for a bushel of oats. In 1836 at those prices £33 6s. 8d. bought 9496 bushels of wheat, or 16842 bushels of barley, or 242*42 bushels of oats. These have been the fixed multipliers in use ever since. Each year the average prices for the last seven years are multiplied by these fixed quantities, and the result is the tithe rent charge for the coming year. It wiU be noticed that the charge is affected most by variations in the price of oats, and least by those of wheat. One other point requires to be mentioned. Lord Althorp in 1833, Sir Hobert Peel in 1835, Lord John RusseU in 1836 were agreed that the payment should be transferred from occupiers to owners of land. Section 80 of the Act of 1836 empowered tenants to deduct the rent- charge from the rent payable to the landlord. But the section was permissive only. For mutual convenience tenants paid the rent charge direct to the tithe-owner, and their other rent to the landlord was calculated on this basis. By the Tithe Hent Charge Recovery Act of 1891 the tenant was no longer permitted to be the conduit- pipe for the payment. The liability to pay the tithe rent charge was transferred to the landowner ; the tithe-owner's remedy of distress was altered into a process through the coimty court ; and, instead of the com averages absolutely determining the amount of tithe rent charges, provision was made in certain cases for a reduced payment when the charge exceeded a certain proportion of the annual value of the land. CHAPTER XVIL HIGH FARMING. 1837-1874. Condition of agriculture in 1837 ; current explanation of the distress ; pre- paration for a new start in farming ; legislative changes ; development of a railway system ; live-stock in 1837 ; the generaj level of farming ; foundation of the Boyal Agricultural Society ; notable improvements, 1837-74 ; extension of drainage ; purchase of feeding stufis ; discovery of artificial fertilisers ; mechanical improvements and inventions ; Repeal of the Com Laws ; the golden age from 1853 to the end of 1862 ; rapid progress in the " Fifties " ; pedigree mania in stock-breeding. The reign of Queen Victoria began in the midst of a transition stage from one state of social and industrial development to another. A complete change of agricultural front was taking place, which necessitated some displacement of the classes that had previously occupied or cultivated the soil. The last ten years of the present century have raised the question whether agriculturists are not now passing through another transition stage which, like its predecessor, may effect another agricultural revolution and result in another disruption of rural society. Roughly speaking, the first thirty-seven years of the new reign formed an era of advancing prosperity and progress, of rising rents and profits, of the rapid muItipUcation of fertilising agencies, of an expanding area of com cultivation, of more numerous, better bred, better fed, better housed stock, of varied improvements in every kind of implement and machinery, of growing expenditure on the making of the land by drainage, the construction of roads, the erection of farm buildings, and the division into fields of convenient size. So far as the standard of the highest farming is concerned, agriculture has made but httle advance since the " Fifties." The last'twenty-six years of the reign, on the other hand, were a period of agricultural adversity — of falling rents, dwindling profits, con- AN OLD EXPLANATION OF DISTRESS 347 tracting areas of arable cultivation, HiminiahiTig stock, decreasing expenditure on land improvement. In 1837 the farming industry had passed through a quarter of a century of misfortunes, aggravated by a disordered currency, bank failures, adverse seasons, labour difficulties, agrarian discontent. During times of adversity it has always been the practice to charge landowners, farmers, and even labourers with extravagance, to trace distress to their increased luxury, to attribute their domestic diffi- culties to their less simple habits. The explanation is as old as the hills. Arthur Young, writing in 1773 On the Present State of Waste Lands, remarks that the landed gentry were beggared by their efforts to rival their wealthier neighbours who had amassed fortunes in trade. The rural frog burst in his efforts to equal the proportions of the civic ox. " The antient prospect which afforded pleasure to twenty generations is poisoned by the pagodas and temples of some rival neighbour ; some oilman who builds on the soHd foundation of pickles and herrings. At church the Uveries of a tobacconist carry all the admiration of the village ; and how can the daughter of the antient but decayed gentleman stand the competition at an assembly with the point, diamonds and tissues of a haberdasher's nieces ? " Their tenants did not escape from similar charges. In 1573 Tusser had alluded to farmers with " hawk on hand " who neglected their business for sport ; in the nineteenth century it was said to be the hunting-field or the racecourse which attracted them from the farm or the market. In 1649 Walter BUth had attributed the rural depression of that day to the " high stomachs " of the farmers. So in 1816 the wiseacres of the London clubs vehemently contended that farmers had only to return from claret to beer, and their wives from the piano to the hen-house, and agricultural distress would be at an end. It was reserved for an imaginative versifier in 1801 to charge them with soaking five- pound notes instead of rusks in their port wine. Somewhat similar in tone was the outcry against labourers. " We hear," writes Borlase, the Cornish antiquary, in 1771, " every day of murmurs of the common people ; of want of employ ; of short wages ; of dear provisions. There may be some reason for this ; our taxes are heavy upon the necessaries of life ; but the chief reason is the extravagance of the vulgar in the unnecessaries of life." Among the tinworkers in his parish were three-score snuff-boxes at one time ; of fifty girls above fifteen years old, forty-nine had scarlet cloaks. " There is 348 HIGH PAEMING, 1837-1874 scarce a family in the parish, I mean of common labourers, but have tea, once if not twice a day. ... In short, all labom-ers live above their conditions." The same explanations with regard to all classes of agriculturists were repeated in 1837, and have been periodically offered ever since. The diagnosis of disease would not be so popular if it were not easy and to some extent true. It is, to say the least, iaadequate. When the standard of living rises for all classes, agriculturists are not the only men who spend money more lavishly than the prudence which criticises after the event can justify. But the true explanation of the distress lay in the fconditions already described. The old instru- ment of farming had failed ; the new had not been perfected. An agricultural revolution was in progress, which was none the less complete in its operation because it was peaceful in its processes. In 1837 agriculture was languishing ; farming had retrograded ; heavy clay-lands were either abandoned or foul, and in a miserable state of cultivation. Indifferent pasture, when first ploughed, had produced good com crops from the accumulated mass of elements of fertility which they had stored. But this savings bank of wealth had been soon exhausted. At peace-prices half crops ceased to be remtmerative, and the newly ploughed arable area was now recover- ing itself from exhaustion to grass as best it could without assistance. Lighter soils had suffered comparatively Uttle ; turnips, and the Norfolk system had helped the eastern counties to bear the stress of the storm, yet, even there, farmers had " had to put down their chaises and their nags." Much of the progress made between 1790 and 1812 had been lost. Nor was this the worst feature. The distrust which prevailed between farmers and their men had ex- tended to tenants and their landlords. Men who had contracted to pay war rents from peace profits were shy of leases. For at least a generation confidence was shaken between landlord and tenant. The brighter side to the picture was that, in the midst of much suffering, the ground had been prepared for new conditions. Small yeomen, openfield farmers, and commoners could never have fed a manufacturing population. They could not have initiated and would not have adopted agricultural improvements, of which some were still experimental, and of which all required an initial expenditure. It was from these classes that the most bigoted opponents of " Practice with Science " were recruited, and their contempt was heartily sincere for the innovations of the " apron-string " farmer. Socially RESULTS OF AGRICULTURAL DISTRESS 349 valuable though they were, they were becoming commercially dis- credited. Their disappearance was a social loss ; but it had become an economic necessity. The land could no longer be cultivated for the needs of a scanty, scattered population, occupied in the tillage of the soil, or engaged in one-man handicrafts. So long as England depended for food on her own produce, — a condition which lasted a quarter of a century after the repeal of the Com Laws, — ^it was requisite that farming should be transformed from a self-sufficing domestic industry into a profit-earning manufactory of bread, beef, and mutton. Food, upon the scale that changed conditions demanded, could only be produced upon land which had been prepared for the purpose by the outlay of capitalist landlords and the intelligent enterprise of large tenant-farmers. In other respects, also, the distress of 1813-37 produced good results. So long as war prices prevailed, prosperous years had brought wealth to slovens, and sluggards had amassed riches in their sleep. The coUapse of prosperity spurred the energies and enter- prise of both landlords and tenants, who could only hold their own by economising the cost and increasing the amount of production. Within certain limits, low prices and keen competition compelled improvement. Again, though the attraction of war-prices had driven the plough through much valuable pasture, it had also supplied the incentive which added hundreds of thousands of acres of wastes to the cultivated area of the country. Finally, during the era of Protection, landlords and farmers had learned to rely too entirely upon ParUamentary help in their difficulties. They had been prone to expect that alterations in the protective duties would turn the balance between the success and failure of their harvests. Now,, disappointment after disappointment had taught them the useful lesson that they could expect no immediate assistance from legis- lative inteiierence, and that, if they wanted aid, they must help themselves. Meanwhile legislation had been active in many useful directions. The agricultural revolution, and the effects alike of war and peace, had completely disorganised the labour market. Parliament co- operated with industrial changes in redressing the balance between demand and supply and in adapting the relations of capital and labour to new conditions. For agricultural labourers the Poor-Law of 1834 did what the Factory legislation of 1833 had done for artisans. The change produced immediate effect. The number of paupers 350 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 steadily diminished, and the poor-rates fell from seven minions in 1832 to four millions in 1837. New means of transport had been provided by the opening up of canals. Increased facilities of communication had been supplied by progress in the art of road- construction. Though Turnpike Trusts were proving inefficient on the great highways, the first step towards the improvement of minor roads had been taken by the Act of 1835, which substituted a rate for the old statute labour. Another legislative result of the pro- longed agricultural distress had been the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836. The incidence of the charge was shifted ; it no longer operated as a check to the expenditure of capital or a discouragement to skilful and enterprising farming. It was a period of preparation, the full significance of which was then imperfectly understood. Few persons in 1837 could have foreseen the imminence of social and industrial changes which introduced to British farming an unexampled era of prosperity, or could have foretold that new markets would not only be opened up, but brought to the doors of agriculturists. Signs of better times were indeed faintly visible. Manufacturing progress was beginning to tell upon agriculture ; steam navigation was stimulating trade ; joint-stock banks helped farmers to face their difficulties ; the new system of poor-law administration was restoring the labour market to healthier conditions ; beef, mutton, wool, barley, and oats sold briskly. Above all, the whole country was beginning to respond to the vast impulse which the introduction of railways gave to its intelligence, its intercourse, its enterprise, its agriculture, manu- facture, and commerce. Without assistance or control by the State, in the face of many difficulties and prejudices, railways were being built piecemeal by private energy and capital. They were still in their infancy. It was not till 1821 that the Act for the construction of the Stockton and Darlington Railway had been passed. The Liverpool and Manchester Railway was opened in 1830, and the line from London to Birmingham was completed in 1838. Between those two dates fifty-six Acts had been already passed for laying 1,800 miles of rails. The era of railways had begun. The real innovations lay in the application of steam as the motive power to movable engines, the construction of new and iudependent lines of communication, the conveyance not only of goods but of passengers. Rail-ways to faciUtate the transport of heavy weights had been in use for nearly WOODEN RAIL-WAYS 351 two centuries. They seem to have been first employed in the New- castle district to convey coal from the pits to the shipping stages on the Tyne. Wooden rails, laid on continuous parallel lines, were pegged down to wooden sleepers, which were set two feet apart, the intervals being filled in with stones or ashes. On these tracks, high hopper-shaped waggons, set on soUd wooden wheels, were either propelled by their own weight or drawn by horses. Log ways, thus constructed, were called in eighteenth century Acts of ParUa- ment " dram roads." They were in fact true tram-ways,^ though the word " tram " has been transferred from the material out of which the rails were originally constructed to the vehicle which passes over them. Successive improvements were made in their construction. Thus iron plates or iron fianges were fixed by " plate-layers " to the rails to lessen the friction at the curves or to keep the waggons on the track. About 1767 the rails began to be made entirely of iron, which were generally cast with an iron flange on the inner side. Similarly the wheels were made of cast iron, though for some years the rear wheels continued to be made of wood in order to strengthen the grip of the brake. In 1788 a still more important change was made. The projections of the flanged rail were found to be dangerous obstructions wherever lines crossed highways. To meet this diflSculty, flanged wheels were introduced, and the rails were made smooth. By the latter half of the eighteenth century, there were few collieries in the north which were not provided with their own rail- ways, often carried, in order to secure easy gradients, through hills and over valleys by means of cuttings, bridges, or embankments. They were private roads, to which the pubHc had no access. Rail-ways laid by Canal Companies under the powers of Acts of Parhament were in a different position. Constructed by canal proprietors to feed their traffic from potteries, furnaces, collieries, and quarries, • Whether " tram-way " is derived from the material out of which the road is contracted, or from the carriage which passes over it is doubtful. A will dated 1555 mentions the repair " of the higheway or tram " in Bttmard Castle. This use of the word, like the " dram-road " of eighteenth century Acts of Parlicunent, suggests the log-way. On the other hand, the road may have taken its name from the application of the word " tram " in the North of England to a small carriage on four wheels, possibly gaining this meaning through the Lowland Scottish use of the word for the " shaft " of a cart. In either case, " tram " is Scandinavian in origin ; Norwegian, tram = a door-step of wood; troom^a wooden frame, and Swedish tromm=a log, or a summer sledge. See Skeat's EtymoVagical Dictionary of the English Langiuige. 352 HIGH FAKMING, 1837-1874 they were public highways, maintained, like turnpike roads, by the payments of those who used them. The Canal Companies provided no rolling stock. On payment of the stipulated tolls, any trader might transport his goods over the flanged rails in his own vehicles to the wharves. In the development of these Unes, which were subsidiary to inland waterways, the lead was taken by the valley of the Severn, the Western Midlands, and South Wales. The utiKty of the system was at once apparent. Rail-ways multiphed rapidly, not as rivals, but as aids, to the canals which they eventually destroyed. Numerous rail-ways, either in private hands or feeders to canals, existed at the end of the eighteenth century. The first public independent rail-way was constructed by Act of ParKamant in 1801. The Surrey Iron Rail-way connected Croydon and the mills on the Wandle with the Thames at Wandsworth. Originally intended to ran to Portsmouth, it was never carried beyond Merstham. Nearly twenty years later an Act of Parhament (1821) was obtained for the construction of the Stockton and Darlington Rail-way. On this line all the stages in the transformation of the ancient rail-way into the modem type were exemplified. Hitherto speed had not been regarded as an object. Horses were generally employed, and, where steam had been introduced as the motive power, its use had been practically confined to stationary engines, placed at the top of inclines, wtlich by means of ropes or chains drew waggons up the ascent and regulated the pace of their descent. In poetry, Erasmus Darwin ^ had anticipated the coming triumph of steam : " Soon shall thy arm, unconquered Steam ! afar Drag the Blow barge, or drive the rapid car ; Or on wide-waving Wings expanded bear The fljnng chariot thro' the fields of air ! " But in 1820 the vision of the " rapid car," drawn by steam, still seemed as extravagant as the dream of the " flying chariot " appeared to a later generation familiar with fast trains. The projectors of the Stockton and Darlington Railway hesitated between wooden or iron rails, between animal or steam power, between stationary or movable engines. When the line was opened in 1825, the waggons, under the advice of George Stephenson, were drawn over iron rails at an average pace of five miles an hour by steam locomotives, designed on the model of the engines which he had successfully » The Botanic Garden, Part I. 289. TRIUMPH OF MODERN RAILWAYS 353 introduced at KiUingworth Colliery. Groods traffic only was at first undertaken by the railway company. The conveyance of passengers was left to private enterprise ; coaches drawn by one horse ran over the rails, on payment of stipulated toUs, at intervals when the goods trains were not running. It was not till 1833 that the Company bought out the coach proprietors, and, a year later, issued notices that they proposed to provide not only carriages for goods, but " coaches " for the conveyance of passengers, drawn by steam locomotives. Before this final stage was reached in the County of Durham, the Liverpool and Manchester Railway had been opened (1830). The project of the proposed line originated in dissatisfaction with the cost and delay of canal transport. It was directly designed not to feed but to rival the water way, and to break down a monopoly in the carriage of heavy goods. Canal companies all over the country became aJive to their danger. So strong was the opposition that the first Bill was defeated. A second Bill was introduced, and passed in 1826. Like the Stockton and DarUngton Company, the projectors hesitated over the choice of motive power. They were stiU undecided when the new line was approaching completion. To solve the problem they offered a premium of £500 for the best locomotive engine which should satisfy certain conditions. It was not to exceed £550 in price and siz tons in weight ; it was also to draw three times its own weight, at a speed of ten miles an hour on level ground, The famous Rainhill trial (October 8, 1829), when Stephenson's Bocliiet won the prize, sealed the fate of canals and inaugurated the triumph of railways. Without their aid the modem organisation of industry would have been impossible. The factory, the modem farm, and the railway went hand in hand in development, and were not dissimilar in their economic results. With the ground thus prepared for a new start, but in gloom and depression, agriculturists entered on the new reign. In comparing agriculture in 1837 with that of 1912, the most striking feature is the general level of excellence which now prevails. If we leave on one side the achievements of chemical science and the triumphs of mechanical invention, there are few improvements in the methods and practices of agriculture which had not been anticipated by individuals seventy years ago. But the knowledge which was then, at the most, confined to one or two men in a county is now generally practised. The best farmers of that day could not have explained 354 fflGH FARMING, 1837-1874 the reasons for their methods ; they farmed by experience and in- tuition. Judgment is still all-important ; but practice has now been reduced to principles and rules, which make the best methods more nearly common property, or at least place them within reach of all. The best arable farms in 1837 were cropped much as they are now, except that rotations were more rigid and inelastic. Pedigree barleys and pedigree wheats were already experimented upon by Patrick ShirrefE, Dr. Chevallier, and Colonel Le Couteur. By the most enterprising of our predecessors all the kinds of farm produce which are raised to-day were raised seventy years ago. Live-stock has doubtless immensely improved since the accession of Queen Victoria. Specialisation did away with " general utility " animals, and successfully developed symmetry, quality, early maturity, or yield of milk among cattle. But the value and im- portance of improving breeds had been thoroughly appreciated by the best farmers before 1837. Though only one herd-book — Coates's Shorthorn Herdbook (1822) — ^had begun to appear, the followers of Bakewell, — such as Charles and Robert Colling, Thomas Bates, of Kirklevington, the Booths, and Sir Charles Knightley with the Shorthorns, — Benjamin Tomkins, John Hewer, and the Prices with the Herefords, — ^Francis Quartly, George Turner, WiUiam Davy, and Thomas Coke of Norfolk with the North Devons, — ^had already brought to a high degree of perfection the breeds with which their names are respectively associated. Flockmasters, Uke cattle- breeders, had recognised the coming changes. Before 1837 Bakewell's methods had been extensively imitated. The Lincolns, the Border Leicesters of the Culleys, the Southdowns of EUman of Glynde and Jonas Webb of Babraham, the Black-faced Heath breed of David Dun, the Cheviots of Robson of Belford were already firmly estab- lished ; and some of the best of the local varieties of sheep, enum- erated by Sir John Sinclair in his Address to the British Wool Society (1791), were beginning to find their champions. Nor were pigs unappreciated. The reproach was no longer justified which, at the close of the eighteenth century, Arthiir Young had directed against farmers for their neglect of this source of profit. Here, again, Bakewell had led the way. Efforts were being made to improve such native breeds as the Yorkshire Whites, the Tamworths, the reddish-brown Berkshires, or the black breeds of Essex and Suffolk. Oxen were still extensively used for farm work. It is therefore IMPROVEMENT IN FAEM-HORSES 355 not surprising that comparatively little attention had been paid to horses for agricultural purposes. Yet here, too, some progress was made, particularly from the point of view of specialisation. The Clydesdales were coming to the front as rivals to old English breeds. Beauty was not the strong point of the " Sorrel-coloured Suffolk Punch." Nor was he any longer suited to the pace required in the modem hunting-field or on the improved roads. But in 1837 it was recognised that his unrivalled power of throwing his whole weight into the coUar fitted Vn'm pre-eminently for farm work. A wifnilar change was passing over the Cleveland Bay. Threatened with extinction by the disappearance of coaches, he was found to be invaluable on light-soil farms. So also a definite place was assigned to another breed known to the sixteenth century. The " Large Black Old English Cart-horse," which Young calls " the produce principally of the Shire counties in the heart of England," was, to some extent, experimented upon by BakeweU. But the develop- ment of the breed belongs to a later date than the first half of the Victorian era, and it is as a draught-horse that the Shire has been, since 1879, patronised by Societies and enrolled in stud-books. It has been said that while the general standard of farming was still extremely low, the best practice of individual farmers in 1837 has been little improved by the progress of seventy years. Pro- duction has been considerably increased ; but the higher averages are due to the wider diffusion of the best practices rather than to any notable novelties, and it is in live-stock that real advance is most clearly marked. If, however, we turn from the highest practice of farming to the general conditions under which it was carried on, or to the processes by which crops were cultivated, harvested, and marketed, the contrast between 1837 and 1912 is almost startling. In 1837 the open-field system still prevailed extensively. Hold- ings were in general inconvenientiy small, though in some parts of the country farms had been, consolidated. Farm-buildings, often placed at the extreme end of the holding, consisted of large bams for storing and threshing com, a stable and yard for cart-horses, a shed for carts and waggons. But the cattle, worse housed than the waggons, were huddled into draughty, rickety sheds, erected without plan, ranged round a yard whence the liquid manure, freely diluted from the unspouted roofs, ran first into a horse-pond, and thence escaped into the nearest ditch. In these sheds the live-stock sub- 366 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 aisted during the winter months on starvation allowance. Fat cattle, instead of being conveyed by rail quickly and cheaply, were driven to distant markets, losing weight every yard of the way. Long legs were still a consideration for sheep which had to plough through miry lanes. Farm roads were few and bad. Where land had been early enclosed, the fields were often small, fenced with high and straggling hedges. Very little land was drained, and, except in SofFolk and Essex, scarcely any effort had been made to carry off the surface-water from clay soils. Little or no machinery was employed in any operation of tillage. In remote parts of the country, even on light soils and for summer work, heavy wooden ploughs with wooden breasts, slowly drawn by teams of five horses or six oxen, attended by troops of men and boys, still lumbered on their laborious way, following the sinuous shape of boundary fences, or throwing up ridges crooked like an inverted S, and laid high by successive ploughing towards the crown. In more advanced districts, less cumbrous and more effective im- plements of lighter draught, wheel or swing, were employed. But not a few discoveries of real value fell into disuse, or failed to find honour in the land of their birth, till they returned to this country with the brand of American innovations. The mistake was too often made of exaggerating the universal value of a new implement in the style of modem vendors of patent-medicines. Enthusiasts forgot that provincial customs were generally founded on common- sense, and that farmers reasoned from actual instances which had come within their personal experience. The boast that a two-horse plough, with reins and one man, could, on all soils and at all seasons, do the work of the heavy implement dear to the locality only made the ancient heirloom more precious in the eye of its owner. It was with antiquated implements, heavy in the draught, that most of tiie soil was still cultivated. Harrows were generally primitive in form and inefEective in operation, scarcely penetrating the ground and powerless to stir the weeds. To keep the seed-bed firm agaifast the loosening efiects of frost the only roller was a stone or the trunk of a tree heavily weighted. When the bed was prepared for the crop, the seed was stiU sown broadcast by hand, or, more rarely, either dibbed or drilled. The Northumberland drill for turnips, and the Suffolk drill for cereals, which travelled every year on hire as far as Oxfordshire, had already attained something more than local popularity. But com and roots, even in 1837, were seldom either HARVESTING AND MARKETING CROPS 357 drilled or dibbed. The advantages of both methods were still hotly denied. A man who used a drill would be asked by his neighbours when he was going to sow pepper from a pepper-caster. Prom the time the seed was sown and harrowed in, the infant crops waged an internecine and unaided strife with weeds. Even the hand-hoe rarely helped cereals in the struggle, for the cost was heavy, and the work, unless carefully supervised, was easily scamped. In 1837 hand-labour alone gathered the crops. Com was cut by scythes, fagging hooks, or sickles ; if with the first, each sc3rtheman was followed by a gatherer and a binder ; a stooker and raker com- pleted the party. When a good man headed the gang, with four men to each scytheman, two acres a day per scythe were easily completed. Threshed by the flail, the grain was heaped into a head on the floor of the bam. The cha£E was blown away by means of the draught of wind created by a revolving wheel, with sacks nailed to its arms, which was turned by hand. Thus winnowed, the grain was shovelled, in small quantities at a time, into a hopper, whence it ran, in a thin stream, down a screen or riddle. As the stream descended, the smaller seeds were separated and removed. The wheat was then piled at one end of the bam, and " thrown " in the air with a casting shovel to the other extremity. The heavy grain went furthest ; the lighter, or " tail," dropped short. To some of the com in both heaps the chaff still adhered. These " whiteheads " were removed by fanning in a large basket tray, pressed to the body of the fanner, who tossed the grain in the air, at the same time lower- ing the outer edge of the tray. By this process the whiteheads were brought to the top and extremity of the fan, whence they were swept by the hand. Lastly the com was measured, and poured into four-bushel sacks, ready for market. The operation of dressiag was slow. As the sun streamed through a crack in the bam-door, it reached the notches which were cut in the wood-work to mark the passage of time and the recurrence of the hours for lunch and dinner. The operation was expensive as well as slow, costing from six to seven shillings a quarter. Hay was similarly made in all its stages by hand, and with a care which preserved its colour and scent. The grass, mown by the scythe, fell iato swathes. These were broken up by the haymakers, drawn with the hand-rake into windrows, first single, then double. The double windrows were pulled over once, put first into small cocks, then into larger which were topped up and trimmed so as to be shower proof, and finally 358 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 arranged in cart-rows for pitching and loading. Women, working behind the carts, allowed scarcely a blade to escape their rakes. The farmer in 1837 had a reaper at his command, but he did not value the gift. Its sudden popularity illustrates a point which is perpetually recurring in the history of agricultiu-al machinery. As soon as the want is created, the machine is not only discovered but appreciated. Many attempts were made to perfect a reaper. But none met with any real success tiU machines not only cut the com but laid it in sheaves, tiU fields were enlarged, till thorough drainage was adopted, and, as a consequence, the old high-ridging system abandoned. It is a sign, and a consequence, of changes in farming that the Bev. Patrick Bell's reaper, invented in 1826, was not really appreciated tUl it was manufactured (1853) by Crosskill aa the "Beverley Beaper." Threshing and winnowing machines were to be found on a few large farms, or travelled the country on hire, worked by horse, water, or steam power. For feeding stock, chaS-cutters and tumip-sUcers were already known ; but they made their way slowly into use. Chafi was stiU generally cut, and turnips split, by a chopper. If cattle or sheep were unable to bite, they ran the risk of being starved. No one who studies the agriculture of 1837 can fail to notice the perpetual contrast, often in the most glaring form, between the practices of adjoining agriculturists. A hundred farmers plodded along the Elizabethan road, while a solitary neighbour marched in the track of the twentieth century. Discoveries in scientific farm- ing, put forward as novelties, were repeatedly found to be in practice in one district or another. The great need was the existence of some agency which would raise the general level of farming by making the best practices of the best agriculturists common knowledge. The problem was not readily solved. To diffuse scientific and practical information among agriculturists was difficult seventy years ago. Books were expensive, and those for whom they were written were often unable to read. Few of the agricultural works published before the reign of Victoria were produced by men of practical experience. Extravagant promises or incorrect science too often discounted the value of useful suggestions. What was really wanted was ocular demonstration of the superiority of new methods, or the example of men of authority who combined scientific with practical knowledge. Some of the agricultural societies already in existence were doing good work in communicating the results of experiments. THE ROYAL AGRICULTURAL SOCIETY 359 organismg shows, and encouraging discoveries ; others met rather for the consumption of meat and drink than for the discussion of their production. The Board of Agriculture had established a strong claim to the gratitude of farmers by providing Davy's lectures on agricultural chemistry in 1803-13. But its dissolution in 1822 had been one of the symptoms of distress. The foundation of the Royal Agricultural Society of England, projected in 1837, established in 1838, and incorporated by Royal Charter in 1840, with Queen Victoria as patron, was at once a sign of revival and a powerful agent in restoring prosperity. Among the founders of the Society were many of the best-known landowners and most practical agriculturists of the day. Their association in a common cause carried weight and authority through- out the whole country. Their recognition of their territorial duties and enthusiasm for the general advancement of agriculture were communicated to others, and commanded success by their sincerity. The Society met a recognised want in the right way. It proclaimed the alliance between practical farmers and men both of capital and of science ; it indicated the directions in which agriculture was destined to advance. The wise exclusion of politics, though for a moment it threatened to endanger the existence of the new institu- tion, eventually secured it the support of men of every shade of political opinion. By the comprehensiveness, elasticity, and fore- sight, with which its lines of development were traced, it has been enabled to meet the varying needs of seventy years of change. It has encouraged practical farming on scientific principles ; it has also encouraged agricultural science to proceed on practical lines. It has by premiums and pecuniary aid promoted discovery and invention ; by its shows it has fostered competition, stimulated enterprise, and created a standard of the best possible results, methods, processes, and materials in British agriculture. Its Journal disseminated the latest residts of scientific research at home and abroad, as well as the last lessons of practical experience. In its pages wiU be found the truest picture of the history of farming in the reign of Queen Victoria. Starting as it did under pecuharly favourable circum- stances, and supported by writers like Philip Pusey and Chandos Wren-Hoskyns, it commanded the pens of masters in the lost art of agricultural literature — ^men who wrote with the knowledge of specialists and with the forcible simpUcity of practical men of the world. Without exaggeration it may be said that the general 360 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 standard of excellence to which fanning has attained throughout the kingdom has been to a considerable extent the work of the Boyal Agricultural Society. For more than seventy years it has been the heart and brain of agriculture. The local associations which now compete with it in popularity are in great measure its own creations, and it can contemplate with pride, unmixed with envy, the sturdy growth of its own children. From 1840 to 1901, Queen Victoria was the patron, and to Her Majesty's patronage the Society owed much of its prestige and con- sequent utihty. It has been said that " agriculture " is " the pursuit of kings " ; yet the feeling certainly had existed that farming weis beneath the dignity of gentry. Fortunately for British farming,^ landlords have had a truer perception of their territorial duties as well as of their pecuniary interests. In taking the lead they have made a vast outlay of private capital. Windsor, Osborne, Babnoral, Sandringham, and the home-farms of large landowners have set the fashion, and afforded the model, to hosts of agriculturists. They have helped not only to raise the standard of British farming, but also to make a costly industry a fashionable yet earnest pursuit. A detailed history, for instance, of the Windsor farms would epito- mise the history of agricultural progress in the nineteenth century. Boads were laid out. Liebig's discovery that warmth is a saving of food was acted upon, and substantial buildings were erected, designed to economise the expense and labour of cattle-feeding, and at the same time to preserve manure from waste or impoverishment. Skilfully selected herds of pure-bred Shorthorns, Herefords, and Devons were formed ; quantities of food were purchased ; the soil was drained on scientific principles ; the arable land, for the most part a stiff clay, was ameliorated and enriched by high farming ; the latest inventions in implements or machinery were tested and adopted ; the grass-lands were improved by experiment and careful management ; a model dairy, designed to meet the exacting require- ments of modem sanitation and convenience, was erected ; and, to supply the milk, a pure-bred herd of Jersey cattle was formed which soon became one of the most celebrated in the coimtry. The work which the Royal Agricultural Society was established to do was not done by it alone. Other societies, as well as associa- tions and farmers' clubs, assisted in spreading scientific and practical knowledge of farming. Among many other useful writers on the subject the Rev. W. L. Rham, Youatt, James Johnston, Henry ALLIANCE OF SCIENCE WITH PRACTICE 361 Stephens, Dr. Lindley, and John Chalmers Morton, as Editor of the AgricuUural Gaiette did excellent service. The school-master was abroad, and the foimdation of Cirencester Agricultural College in 1845 was a sign of the times. The need for agricultural statistics, which had long been severely felt, had been emphasised by Sir James (then Mr.) Caird in 1850-1. But it was not tiU 1866 that the want was supplied. Attempts had been frequently made to obtain statistical information, but without success. Fear of increased taxation closed the mouths of landowners and farmers. In 1855 a House of Lords Committee reconunended the compulsory collection of statistics through the agency of the Poor-Law officials. Eleven years later (1866) the Agricultural Returns of Great Britain for the first time supplied an accurate account of the acreage, the cropping, and the live-stock of the cotmtry. The new alliance of science with practice bore rich and immediate fruit. Science helped practical farming in ways as varied as they were innumerable. Chemists, geologists, physiologists, entomolo- gists, botanists, zoologists, veterinaries, bacteriologists, architects, mechanics, engineers, surveyors, statisticians, lessened the risks and multiplied the resources of the farmer. Steam and machinery diminished his toil and reduced his expenses. His land was neither left idle nor its fertility exhausted. Improved implements rendered his labour cheaper, quicker, surer, and more efEective. New means of transport and increased facilities of communication brought new markets to his door. Commodious and convenient buildings re- placed tumble-down bams and draughty sheds. Veterinary skill saved the lives of valuable animals. The general level of agriculture rose rapidly towards that which only model farms had attained in the previous period. Soimd roads, well-arranged homesteads, heavy crops, well-bred stock, skilled farmers, and high farming character- ised the era which adopted the Royal Agricultural Society's rule of Practice with Science. Cut ofE from their old resource of increasing production by adding to the cultivated area, deprived of the aid of Protection, agriculturists were compelled to adopt improved methods. The age of farming by extension of area had ended ; that of farming by intension of capital had begun. To trace out in full detail one single point in which science has helped farmers would be the work of a separate volume. Selection and outline are all that is possible. Probably the most striking con- tributions which, during the period under review, were made to the- 362 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 progress of agriculture are the extension of drainage, the discovery of artificial manures, the increased purchase of feeding stufEs for cattle, the improvement of implements, the readier acceptance of new ideas and inventions. Such an advance was impossible in the dajrs of pack-waggons. By the railways aU that farmers had to sell or wanted to buy, — com and cattle, coal, implements, machinery, manures, oil-cake, letters and newspapers, as well as the men them- selves, — ^were conveyed to and fro more expeditiously and more cheaply. Drainage was the crying need of the day both for pasture and arable land. If the land was heavy and undrained pasture, the moisture-loving plants overpowered the more nutritive herbage ; the over-wetness became in rajny seasons a danger to the stock ; the early and late growth of grass was checked ; the effect of autumn and spring frosts was more severely felt. If stiff, retentive, un- drained land was under the plough, it was cultivated at greater cost, on fewer days in the year, during a season shorter at both ends, than hghter soils ; unless the seasons were favourable, it produced late and scanty harvests of com and beans, was often unsafe for stock, could bear the introduction neither of roots nor of green- cropping, repeatedly needed bare fallows, wasted much of the benefit of manures and feeding stuff. For many years clay-farmers had been seeking for some expedient which would remedy the over- wetness of their land, and enable them to share in the profits that new resources had placed within reach of their neighbours on freer and more porous soils . It was upon them that the blow of agri- cultural depression from 1813 to 1836 had fallen with the greatest severity. Clay farms had fallen into inferior hands, partly because men of capital preferred mixed or grazing farms. Weaker tenants were thus driven on to the heavier land, on which they could not afford the outlay needed to make their holdings profitable. Yet their strong land, if seasons proved favourable, was still capable of yielding the heaviest crops. Some process was needed which would so change the texture of the soil as to render it more friable, easier to work, more penetrable to the rain, more accessible to air and manure, and therefore warmer and kindher for the growth of plant life. The usual expedient for carrying off the water from heavy soils was the open-field practice of throwing the land into high ridges, whence the rain flowed into intervening furrows, which acted as ANCIENT METHODS OF DRAINAGE 363 surface-drams. But this device not only stripped the land of some of its most valuable portions by washing the surface tilth into the furrows, it also robbed the soil of the fertilising agencies which rain-water holds in solution and by percolation carries downwards to the plants. For both these reasons the ancient practice of such coimties as Essex and Suffolk was a great advance. In those counties trenches were cut from 2 ft. to 2J ft. in depth at frequent intervals, filling the bottom of the cavity with boughs of thorn, heath, or alder, and the soil replaced. Sometimes, where peat or stones were easily available, they were used instead of bushes. Sometimes the filling was only intended to support the soil until a natural arch was consoUdated to form a waterway. For this more temporary purpose, twisted ropes of straw or hops, or a wooden plug, which was afterwards drawn out, were generally employed. In other counties, other materials or devices were adopted. Thus ia Leicestershire, a V-shaped sod was cut, the bottom end taken ofE, and the rest replaced. In Hertfordshire, at the lowest part of the field, a pit was sunk into a more porous stratum, filled up with stones, and covered in with earth. Many of the Suffolk and Essex drains lasted a considerable time ; but the arched waterways were apt to choke or fall in, and the depth at which they were placed was considered unsuitable for land under the plough. So Uttle was the practice known outside these two counties that in 1841 its existence was a revelation to so enlightened an agriculturist as Phihp Pusey. In tapping springs, caused by water meeting an impervious subsoil and rising to the surface, most useful work had been done by Joseph Elkington,^ a Warwickshire farmer in the latter half of the eighteenth century. Throughout the Midland counties his services were in such request that his crow-bar was compared to the rod of Moses. In 1797 he had received £1,000 from ParUament on the recommenda- tion of the Board of Agriculture, and an attempt was made to reduce his practice to rules. But his success was so much the result of his personal observation and experience that the attempt failed. The principles of drainage were not yet imderstood. In 1823 James Smith of Deanston, then a man of 34, began to cultivate the small farm attached to the Deanston Cotton Works of which he was manager. By his system of drainage and deep • An Account of the moat approved Mode of Draining Land according to Ihe System practised by Mr. Joseph Elkington, by John Johnstone, Land Sur- veyor, Edinburgh, 1797. 364 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 ploughing he converted a rush-grown marsh into a garden. Hia drains were trenches 2^ ft. deep, filled with stones and covered over, cut in parallel lines from 16 to 21 ft. apart. Agriculturists flocked to Perthshire to see with their own eyes the transformation and its causes. Smith's Remarks on Thorough Draining and Deep Ploughing (1831) were widely read, and in 1834 he was examined as a witness by the Committee which was then enquiring into the condition of agriculture. The value of his experience was recognised ; enquiry and discussion were excited. In 1843 Josiah Parkes, profiting by the knowledge which he had acquired in draining Chat Moss, laid down his principles of drainage. Thinking that Smith's trenches were too shallow, he advocated a depth of four feet, which would give a sufficient layer of warm meUow surface earth. On these principles miUions of acres were drained, and thousands of pounds wasted where drains were laid too deep. The necessary implements, were quickly perfected. But for some Uttle time a cheap conduit remained a difficulty. Stones were not everywhere available, and, if carted and broken, their use wiis expensive. In 1843 John Beade,^ a gardener by trade and a self-taught mechanic, produced a cylin- drical clay-pipe. Two years later (1845) Thomas Scragg patented a pipe-making machine which enabled the kilns to work cheaply and expeditiously. The capital and the soil of the country became acquainted on an extensive scale. Within the next few years, two large public loans for drainage, repaid by annual instalments, were taken up, and treble the amount was spent by private owners or advanced by private companies. Drainage became the popular improvement by which landlords endeavoured to encourage tenants who were dismayed by the repeal of the Com Laws. It gave clay farmers longer seasons and added to the number of the days on which they could work their land ; it increased the ease of their operations and the efficacy of their manures ; it secured an earUer seedtime and an earlier harvest, raised the average produce, and lowered the cost of working ; it enabled the occupiers of hundreds of thousands of acres to profit by past as well as future discoveries. Drainage was a necessary preliminary to profitable manuring. On undrained land farmers could not use to full advantage the new 1 In the Weekly Miscdlany for the Improvement of Husbandry, etc., for August 22, 1727, Stephen Switzer had recommended the use of pipes made of " potter's clay " for the conveyance of water, and advertised that the pipes were made by pipe-making machines which enabled the kihis to work cheaply and expeditiously. THE CHOICE OF MANURES 366 means of wealth which agricultural chemistry was placing at their command. But while drainage, in the main, helped only one class of farmers, the benefits of manure were universal. The practice of manuring is of immemorial antiquity. But it was in the extended choice of fertilising substances, in the scientific analysis of their composition and values, in their concentration and portability, and in the greater range of time at which they cordd be profitably apphed that a prodigious advance was made during the Victorian era. For inland farmers in rural districts the choice of manures was practically limited to the ashes of vegetable refuse which represented the food drawn by the plant from the soil, " catch-cropping " with leguminous crops, folding sheep, and farmyard manure. " Nothing like muck " had become a proverb when there was practically " nothing but muck " to be used. On the same poverty of fertilising resources were founded the severe restrictions against selling hay, straw, and roots off farms. In another sense the proverb is true — fortunately for the fertility of the country. Biich both in organic and inorganic substances, combining both nitrogen and minerals, possessing for the loosening of clay lands a pecuUar value, farmyard manure is the only substance which contains in itself all the con- stituent elements of fertility. Our predecessors thus commanded the most valuable of fertilising agencies, the most certain and the least capricious. But in their open unspouted, unguttered yards, in their ignorance of the importance of the Uquid elements, and with their straw-fed stock, the manure was both wasted and impoverished. Nor is it only in the quantity and quality of dung, or in its collection and treatment, that fanners have the advantage to-day. Formerly distant fields suffered when no concentrated and portable fertiliser existed, and, valuable though dung is, its uses are not unlimited. In the infancy, moreover, of agricultural science, men had little know- ledge of the composition of soils, the necessities of plant life, or the special demand that each crop makes on the land. It is in all these respects that modem resources axe multiplied. The supply of con- centrated portable manures, adapted by their varied range to all conditions of the soil, capable of restoring those elements of fertility which each particular crop exhausts, and applicable at different stages of plant life, is the greatest achievement of modem agri- cultural science. It is to the great German chemist Idebig that modem agriculture 366 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 owes the origin of its most striking development. In 1840 his Chemistry in its applications to Agriculture and Physiology ^ cleariy traced the relations between the nutrition of plants and the com- position of the soil. In his mineral theory he was proved to be mistaken ; but his book revolutionised the attitude which agri- culturists had maintained towards chemistry. So great was the enthusiasm of country gentlemen for Liebig and his discoveries, as popularised by men like Johnston and Voelcker, that the Royal Chemical Society of 1845 was in large measure founded by their efforts. But if the new agriculture was bom in the laboratory of Giessen, it grew into strength at the experimental station of Rotham- sted. To Sir John Lawes and his colleague Sir Henry Gilbert (himself a pupil of Liebig) farmers of to-day owe an incalculable debt. By their experiments, continued for more than half a century, the main principles of agricultural science were established ; the objects, method, and effects of manuring were ascertained ; the scientific bases for the rotation of crops were explained ; and the results of food upon animals in producing meat, milk, or manure were tested and defined. On their work has been built the modem fabric of British agriculture. With increased knowledge of the wants of plant or animal life came the supply of new means to meet those requirements. Arti- ficial manure may be roughly distinguished from dung as purchased manures. Of these fertilising agencies, farmers in 1837 already knew soot, bones, salt, saltpetre, hoofs and horns, shoddy, and such substances as marl, clay, lime and chalk. But they knew little or nothing of nitrate of soda, of Peruvian guano, of superphosphates, kainit, muriate of potash, rape-dust, sulphate of ammonia, or basic slag. Though nitrate of soda was introduced in 1835, and ex- perimentally employed in small quantities, it was in 1850 still a novelty. The first cargo of Peruvian guano was consigned to a Liverpool merchant in 1835 ; but in 1841 it was still so little known that only 1,700 tons were imported ; six years later (1847) the im- portation amounted to 220,000 tons. Bones were beginning to be extensively used. Their import value rose from £14,395 in 1823 to £254,600 in 1837. As originally broken in small pieces with a hammer, they were slow in producing their effect ; but the rapidity ' Orgame Chemistry in its applications to Agriculture and Physiology. By- Justus Liebig : edited from the manuscript of the author by Lyon Playfair, 1840. ARTIFICIAL MANURES 367 of their action was enormously increased by grinding them to a coarse meal. Bape-dust was not known in the South of England at the b^inning of the Victorian era. In 1840 liebig suggested the treat- ment of bones with sulphuric acid, and in 1843 Lawes began the manufacture of superphosphate of lime, and set up his works at Bow. So far the chemists ; the next step was taken by geologists. At the suggestion of Professor Henslow, the same treatment to which bones were already subjected was applied to coproUtes, and the rich deposits of Cambridgeshire and other counties, as well as kindred forms of mineral phosphates, imported from all parts of the world, were similarly " dissolved." Even Peruvian guano was subjected to the same treatment. Another important addition to the wealth of fertilising agencies was made by Odams, who about 1850 discovered the manurial value of the blood and garbage of London slaughter-houses, mixed with bones and sulphuric acid. It is in the means of applying appropriate manures to lands which are differently composed, and to crops which vary in their special requirements, that modern farmers enjoy exceptional advantages over their predecessors. The active competition of rival manufacturers assisted the adoption of the new fertilisers. Many men, who would not listen to the lectures of professors, or read the articles of chemical experts, were worried by persistent agents for the sale of patent manures into giving them a trial. Indirectly, their use led to clean farming. A farmer who had paid £10 a ton for manure was unwiUing to waste half its value on wet ill-drained land. He was less likely to allow it to fertilise weeds, and the more ready to buy a machine to distribute it carefully. Thus, as consequences of purchased fertilisers, followed the extensive use of the drain-pipe, the drill, the hand-hoe, and the horse-hoe. Yet chemical science did not at once fulfil the sanguine expectations which were formed of its capacity in the early " Fifties." The confident hope that the specific fertility extracted by a crop could be restored by a corresponding manure was scarcely confirmed by experience ; and many a farmer did himself as much harm as good by the appUcation of fertilisers which were unsuited to his land. Manure and drainage acted and reacted upon one another : the one encouraged the other. Previous rules of successive cropping were revolutionised ; more varied courses were gradually and universally introduced. The old exhausting system of two or three crops and a bare fallow was abandoned when land had been drained, and 368 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 fertilisers, portable, cheap and abundant, were placed at the com- mand of the fanner. Without manure the attempt to grow roots or clover failed ; their introduction only protracted the shift, and aggravated the difficulty of inevitable exhaustion. Now, however, the principle was gradually established that he who put most into his land got most out. Farmers recognised by experience, when the means were at their disposal, that, on the one hand, if they ruined their land their land ruined them, and that, on the other hand, only those who have lathered can shave. It was in readiness to invest capital in the land that one of the chief differences between the earher race of agriculturists and the modem type of farmer became most conspicuous. The main objects of the former were to feed their famihes and avoid every possible outlay of cash. Hard- living and hard-working, they rarely thought of spending sixpence on manure, still less on cattle food to make it. They gave Uttle to the land and received little. The consequent loss in the national means of subsistence can scarcely be exaggerated. Modem farmers, on the other hand, not only purchased thousands of tons of artificial fertilisers. They also bought for their hve-stock vast quantities of feeding-stuff, which supplemented their own produce. Roots, clover, beans, barley-meal, hay, chaff, as well as artificial purchased food, were supphed to the sheep and cattle, which once had only survived the winter as bags of skin and bone. Just as guano from Peru was turned into English com, or bones from the Pampas into English roots, so the Syrian locust-pod, the Egyptian bean, the Indian com, or the Russian linseed were converted into English meat. The gain to the nation was immense, and to the farmer it was not small. The return on his money was quickened. He sold his stock to the butcher twice within the same time which was formerly needed to prepare them once, and that less perfectly. At the same time his command of manure was trebled in quantity and quality, and on clay lands his long-straw muck was of special value. The changes which have been noticed in modem farming necessi- tated more frequent operations of tillage, which, without mechanical inventions would have been too costly to be possible. Here, again, science came to the aid of the farmer, and supplied the means of making his labour cheaper, quicker, and more certain. The Royal Agricultural Society may legitimately pride itself on the useful part which it has played in introducing to the notice of agriculturists the new appliances which mechanical skill has placed at their service. AGRICULTURAL MACHINERY 369 Yet, when the Society was founded, none of its promoters foresaw the importance of the mechanical department. At the Oxford show in 1839 one gold medal was awarded for a collection of implements ; three silver medals were allotted ; and a prize of five pounds was given for " a paddle plough for raising potatoes." At the show at Gloucest^ in 1853, 2,000 implements were exhibited. The modem system of farming had, in the interval of fourteen years, built up a huge industry employed in providing the agricultural implements that it required. In tilling the land, sowing, harvesting, and marketing their crops, modem farmers command a choice of effective implements for which their predecessors knew no substitute. Between 1837 and 1874, ploughs in every variety, light in draught, efficient, adaptable to all sorts of soil, were introduced. Harrows suited for different operations on different kinds of land, scarifiers, grubbers, cultivators, clod- crushers, came into general use. Steam supplied its motive power to the cultivator (1851-6) and to the plough (1857). As an auxiliary in wet seasons, or in scarcity of labour, or on foul land, or to back- wardness of preparation, the aid of steam may be invaluable. But few farmers can afford to own both horse-power and steam-power, and without horses they cannot do. The time may, however, be near at hand when agriculturists may find it not only invaluable, but indispensable, to rely on an arm that never slackens, never tires, and never strikes. Com and seed drills deposited the seed in accurate lines, and at that uniform depth which materially promotes the uniformity of sample so dear to barley growers. Rollers and land-pressers consoUdated the seed-bed. Manure drills distributed f^tUisers unknown to farmers in 1837. Hoise-hoes gained in popularity by improved steerage gear. Crosskill's Beverley reaper was followed within the next twenty years by lighter and more convenient machines. Mowing machines, haymakers, horse-rakes, shortened the work of the hay-field. Light carts or waggons super- seded their heavy, broad-wheeled predecessors. Elevators lessened the labour of the harvesters in the yard. Threshing and winnowing machines had been invented in the eighteenth century. But in the South of England, partly perhaps from the difficulty of supplying labourers with winter work, the fiail was still almost imiversal for threshing. From 1850 onwards, however, steam began to be appUed as a motive power to machines, and within the next ten years several makers were busily competing in the manufacture of steam- 2a 370 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 driven bam-machineiy, which threshed the com, raised the straw to the loft, winnowed and dressed the grain, divided it according to quality, delivered it into sacks ready for market, and set aside the tailings for pigs and poultry. Nor did mechanical science neglect the live-stock industry, the development of which, in connection with corn-growing, was a feature of the period. Here, too, machinery economised the farmer's labour. He already knew the turnip-cutter and the chafi-cutter ; but now the same engine which superseded the flail, pumped his water, ground his com, crushed his cake, split his beans, cut his chafE, pulped his turnips, steamed and boiled his food. Without the aid of mechanical invention farming to-day would be at an absolute standstill. No farmer could find, or if he found could pay, the staff of scarce and expensive labour without which in 1837 agricultural produce could not be raised, secured, and marketed. The improvements which have been indicated were not the work of a day. On the contrary, during the first few years of the reign — the only period passed under Protection — ^progress was neither rapid nor unchecked. Farmers in general were preparing for high farming ; they had not yet adopted its practices. Whatever advance had been made between 1837 and 1846 was probably lost in the five succeeding years. Abundant materials exist for com- parison. On the one side are the Reports of the Reporters to the old Board of Agriculture (1793-1815) ; and the Reports to the successive Commissions (1815-36) ; on the other, there are the Reports published in the early numbers of the Journal of the BoycU Agri- euUural Society, the evidence given before the Select Committee of 1848 on tenant-right and agricultural customs, the letters of Caird to The Times in 1860-1, afterwards embodied in his English Agri- culture in 1850-1, and the letters of the Commissioner to the Morning Chronicle during the same period. It is plain that in 1846 no universal progress had been effected ; that many landowners had made no effort to increase the productiveness of their land ; that high farming was still the exception ; that the new resources were not yet generally utilised ; and that more than half the owners and occupiers of the land had made but little advance on the ideas and practices of the eighteenth century. Another period of disaster, short but severe, forced home the necessary lessons, and ushered in the ten years, 1853-62, which were the golden age of English agri* culture. THE BEST SUBSTITUTE FOR PROTECTION 371 The railway maniaa and their collapse in 1845-7 had depressed eveiy industiy. The failnie of the potato crop in 1845-6 caused appaUing famine, and led to the Repeal of the Com Laws. When in 1846 Protection was abandoned for Free Trade, an agiicoltural panic was the result. Caird's pamphlet on High Farming . . . the best SvbslUvte for Protection (1848) pointed out the true remedy. But for the moment he preached in the wilderness. The discovery of guano and the aboUtion of the Brick and Timber Duties seemed no adequate set-ofi to the anticipated consequences of Free Trade in grain. Agriculturists predicted the ruin of their industry, and their prophecies seemed justified by falling prices in 1848-50. Many landlords and tenants had been encouraged by Protection to gamble in land. Extravagant rents had been fixed, which were not justified by increased produce. Caird calculated in 1850 that rentals had risen 100 per cent, since 1770, while the yield of wheat per acre had only risen 14 per cent. — ^from 23 to 26| bushels. In 1850 wheat stood at the same price which it had realised eighty years before (40s. 3d.). On the other hand, butter, meat, and wool had risen respectively 100 per cent., 70 per cent., and 100 per cent. The great advance which had been made was, in fact, in live-stock. Competition in farms had been reckless, and the consequences were inevitable when prices showed a downward tendency. Here and there rents were remitted, but few were reduced, day farmers, as before, were the worst sufferers ; dairy and stock farmers escaped comparatively lightly. But the loss was widespread. Much land was thrown on the hands of landlords, and efforts were made to convert a considerable area of arable into pasture. From 1863 onwards, however, matters rapidly righted themselves. Gold discoveries in Australia and California raised prices ; trade and manufacture throve and expanded ; the Free Trade panic subsided ; courage was restored. The Crimean War closed the Baltic to Russian com. During the " Sixties," while the Continent and Amraica were at war, England enjoyed peace. The seasons were uniformly favourable ; harvests, except that of 1860, were good, fair, or abundant ; the wheat area of 1854, as estimated by Lawes, rose to a httle over four million acres ; imports of com, meat, and dairy produce supplemented, without displacing, home supplies. Even the removal of the shilling duty on com in 1869 produced little effect. Counteracted as it was by the demand ior grain from France in 1870-71, it failed to help foreign growers to force down the price of 372 HIGH FARMING, 1837-1874 British com. Wool maintained an extraordinarily high price. Lincoln wool, for instance, rose from 13d. per lb. in 1861 to 27d. in 1864. Even when com began to decline in value, meat and dairy produce maintained their price, or even advanced. Money was poured into land as the best investment for capital. Men like Mechi of Tiptree Hall, who had made fortunes in trade, competed for farms, and became enthusiastic exponents of their theories of scientific agriculture. Bentals rose rapidly ; yet still fanners made money. Holdings were enlarged and consolidated ; farmhouses became labourers' cottages ; a brisk trade was carried on in machinery. High hopes were entertained of steam. Enormous and, as has since been proved, excessive sums were spent on farm buildings. Drainage was carried out extensively, and it was now that the general level of farming rose rapidly towards the best standard of individual farmers in 1837. Crops reached limits which production has never since exceeded, and probably, so far as anything certain can be predicted of the unknown, never will exceed. During the period from 1853 to 1874 little attention was in England paid to improvements in dairying. But in Uve-stock progress was great and continuous. The advance was the more remarkable as it was made in the face of outbreaks of the rinderpest, pleuro-pneumonia, and foot-and-mouth diseases. Foot-and-mouth disease had been more or less prevalent since 1839, and pleuro- pneumonia since 1840. But the scourge of rinderpest in 1865, commonly called the cattle-plague, compelled energetic action.^ In stamping out the pest the two other diseases were nearly ex- tinguished, so that good results flowed from a disaster which caused widespread ruin. The multipUcation of shows encouraged com- petition ; stock-breeding became a fashion, and " ped^ree " a mania among men of wealth. It was in cattle and sheep that the improvement was most clearly marked, though neither horses nor pigs were neglected. Not only did Shorthorns, Herefords, and Devons attain the highest standard 1 In the week ended Feb. 24, 1866, 17,876 cattle were returned as infected by the disease. The Cattle Diseases Prevention Act, dated Feb. 20, 1866, made the slaughter of diseased a-niTnala compulsory. The efiect was seen at once. In the week ending March 3, 1866, 10,971 cattle were attacked, and in the week ending March 10, 10,066 were killed. At the end of April the weekly tables showed 4,442 attacked ; towards the end of May, 1,687 ; in the last week of Jime, 338. In the last week of the year the number had dwindled to 8. Appendix J. to Report on CtMle Plague during the yeart 1866, 1866, 1867 (Parliamentary Paper of 1868, Cd. 4060), p. 4. PEDIGREE CATTLE 373 of excellence in symmetry, and quality, bat other breeds, now almost as well-known, were rapidly brought to perfection. Especially is this true of the Aberdeen-Angus, the Sussex, Ayrshire, and Channel Island breeds.^ Other breeds were similarly improved by societies and the compilation of herd-books. Thus the Black cattle of South Wales and the Norfolk and Suffolk Bed Polled breed have had their herd-books since 1874. In sheep the improvement was, perhaps, even more striking. The historic Leicesters, Cotswolds, and South- downs still held their own, but other breeds made rapid strides in the popular favour. The improved Lincolns, the Oxford Downs, Hampshire Downs, and Shropshires are almost creations of the period. Between 1866 and 1874 the number of cattle in Great Britain rose from under five millions to over six millions, and sheep had increased to over thirty millions in 1874. Nor was there only an increase in numbers. The average quality was greatly improved, and good sheep and cattle were widely distributed. 'The Shorthorn Society was fovmded in 1875: the Hereford Herd-book appeared in 1846, and the Hereford Herd-book Society was incorporated in 1878 : the Devon Herd-book appeared in 1851. The first volume of the Aberdeen- Angus Polled Herd-book was issued in 1862, and the second in 1872 : the Sussex Herd-book Society published its first volume (1865-78) in 1879 ; the Ayrshire Heid-book Society was established in 1877 and published its first volume in 1878; the Englidi Herd-book of Jersey Cattle was first issued in 1879, and the English Jersey Cattle Society was incorporated in 1883. CHAPTER XVIII. ADVERSITY. 1874-1912. SnrcE 1862 the tide of agricultural prosperity had ceaaed to flow ; after 1874 it turned, and rapidly ebbed. A period of depression began which, with some fluctuations in severity, continued through- out the rest of the reign of Queen Victoria, and beyond. Depression is a word which is often loosely used. It is generally understood to mean a reduction, in some cases an absence, of profit, accompanied by a consequent diminution of employment. To some extent the condition has probably become chronic. A decline of interest on capital lent or invested, a rise in wages of labour, an increased competition for the earnings of management, caused by the spread of education and resulting in the reduction or stationary character of those earnings, are permanent not temporary tendencies of civilisation. So far as these symptoms indicate a more general distribution of wealth, they are not disquieting. But, from time to time, circumstances combine to produce acute conditions of industrial collapse which may be accurately called depression. Such a crisis occurred in agriculture from 1875 to 1884, and again from 1891 to 1899. Industrial undertakings are so inextricably interlaced that agri- cultural depression cannot be entirely dissevered from commercial depression. Exceptional periods of commercial difficulty had for the last seventy years recurred with such regularity as to give support to a theory of decennial cycles.^ In previous years, each recurring period had resulted in a genuine panic, due as much to defective information as to any real scarcity of loanable capital. The historic failure of Overend and Gumey in 1866 and the famous " Black Friday " aSord the last example of this acute form of crisis. Better means of obtaining accurate intelligence, more 1JB.J. 1826-6, 1836-7, 1847, 1867, 1866, 1877-8. INFLATED PRICES AND RENTS 375 accessible sapplies of capital, the greater stability of the Bank of England have combined with other causes to minimise the risk of financial stampedes. But, though periods of depression cease to produce the old-fashioned panic, they are not less exhausting. Their approach is more gradual ; so also is the recovery. Disaster and revival are no longer concentrated in a few months. Years pass before improvement is apparent ; the magnitude of the dis- tress is concealed by its diffusion over a longer period. The Eigri- cultural depre^ons of 1875-S4 and of 1891-99 had all the characteristics of the modem type of financial crisis. In 1870 had begun an inflation of prices. The outbreak of the Franco-German War and the withdrawal of France and Germany from commercial competition enabled England to increase her exports ; the opening of the Suez Canal (1869) stimulated the ship- building trade ; the railway development in Germany and America created an exceptional demand for coal and iron. Expanding trade increased the consuming power of the population, and main- tained the prices of agricultural produce. The wisest or wealthiest landowners refused the temptation to advance rents on sitting tenants. But in many cases rents were raised, or farms were tendered for competition. Farmers became infected with the same spirit of gambling which in trade caused the scramble for the investment of money in hazardous enterprises. In their eagerness for land they were led into reckless biddings, which raised rentals beyond reasonable limits. In 1874 the reaction began. Demand had returned to normal limits ; but the abnormal supply continued. Over-production was the result. The decline of the coal and iron trade, the stoppage, partial or absolute, of cotton mills, disputes between masters and men, compUcations arising out of the Eastern question, the default on the Turkish debt, disturbances of prices owing to fluctuations in the purchasing power of gold and silver, combined to depress every industry. In 1878 the extent to which trade had been undermined was revealed by the failure of the Olasgow, Caledonian, and West of England Banks. One remarkable feature of the crisis was that it was not local but universal. New means of communication had so broken down the barriers of nations that the civilised world suffered together. Everywhere prices fell, trade shrank, insolvencies multipUed. In the United States the indirect consequences of the industrial collapse of 1873-4 proved to be of disastrous importance to English farming. A railway panic, 376 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 a fall in the price of manufactured articles, a decline in wages drove thousands out of the towns to settle as agriculturists on the virgin soils of the West. English farming suffered from the same causes as every other home industry. In addition, it had its own special difficulties. The collapse of British trade checked the growth of the consuming power at home at the same time that a series of inclement seasons, followed by an overwhelming increase of foreign competition,, paralysed the efEorts of farmers. For three years in succession, bleak springs and rainy summers produced short cereal crops of inferior quality, mildew in wheat, mould in hops, blight in other crops, disease in cattle, rot in sheep, throwing heavy lands into foul condition, deteriorating the finer grasses of pastures. In 1875-6 the increasing volume of imports ^ prevented prices from rising tO' compensate deficiencies in the yield of com. The telegraph, steam carriage by sea and land, and low freights, consequent on decliniog: trade, annihilated time and distance, destroyed the natural monopoly of proximity, and enabled the world to compete with English pro- ducers in the home markets on equal, if not more favourable, terms. Instead of there being one harvest every year, there was now a harvest in every month of each year. In 1877 prices advanced, owing to the progress of the Busso-Turkish War. But the potato- crops failed, and a renewed outbreak of the cattle-plague, though speedily suppressed, hit stockowners hard. The tithe rent-charge was nearly £12 above its par value. Bates were rising rapidly. Land-agents began to complain of the scarcity of eligible tenants- for vacant corn-land. During the sunless ungenial summer of 1879, with its icy rains, the series of adverse seasons culminated in one of the worst harvests of the century, in an outbreak of pleuro- pneumonia and foot-and-mouth disease among cattle, and among sheep a disastrous attack of the liver rot, which infiicted an enormous^ loss on flockmasters. The English wheat crop scarcely averaged 16^ bushels to the acre. In similar circumstances, farmers might have been compensated for the shortness of yield by an advance in price. This was no longer the case in 1879. America, which had enjoyed abundant harvests, poured such quantities (A wheat into the country as to bring down prices below the level of the favourable season of the preceding year. At the same time, American cheese so glutted the market as to create a record for cheapness. Thus,. * For the growth of foreign imports of food, eee Appendix VIII. FOREIGN COMPETITION 377 at the moment when English farmers were akeady enfeebled by their loss of capital, they were met by a staggering blow from foreign competition. They were fighting against low prices as well as adverse seasons. English farmers were, in fact, confronted with a new problem. How were they to hold their own in a treacherous climate on highly rented land, whose fertility required constant renewal, against- prodace raised under more genial skies on cheaply rented soils,, whose virgin richness needed no fertilisers ? To a generation familiar with years of a prosperity which had enabled English farmers to extract more from the soil than any of their foreign rivals, the changed conditions were unintelligible. The new position was at first less readily understood, because the depression was mainly attributed to the accident of adverse seasons, and becaus& the grazing and dairying districts had as yet escaped. Thousands of tenants on corn-growing lands were unable to pay their rents. In many instances they were kept afloat by the help of wealthy landlords. But every landowner is not a Dives ; the majority sit at the rich man's gate. In most cases there was no reduction of rents. Remissions, sometimes generous, sometimes inadequate, were made and renewed from time to time. Where the extreme^ urgency of the case was imperfectly realised, many old tenants- were ruined. It was not till farms were relet that the necessary reductions were made, and then the men who profited were new occupiers. If any doubt still existed as to the reality of the depression,, especially in corn-growing districts, it was removed by the evidence laid before the Duke of Richmond's Commission, which sat from 1879 to 1882. The Report of the Commission established, beyond possibility of question, the existence of severe and acute distress, and attributed its prevalence, primarily to inclement seasons, secondarily to foreign competition. It was generally realised that the shrinkage in the margin of profit on the staple produce of agriculture was a more or less permanent condition, and that rents must be readjusted. Large reductions were made between 1880 and 1884, and it was calculated that in England and Wales alone the annual letting value of agricultural land was thus decreased by 6f millions. Yet in many cases the rent nominally remained at the old figure. Only remissions were granted, which were uncertain in amount, and therefore disheaoiiening in effect. According to- 378 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 Sir James Gaiid's evidence given in 1886, before the Boyal Com- mission on Depression of T^nde, the yearly income of landlords, tenants, and labourers had diminished since 1876 by £42,800,000. The worst was by no means over. On the contrary, the pressure of foreign competition gradually extended to other branches of agriculture. The momentum of a great industry in any given direc- tion cannot be arrested in a day ; still less can it be diverted towards Another goal without a considerable expenditure of time and money. Unreasonable complaints were made against the obstinate con- servatism of agriculturists, because they were unable to effect a costly change of front as easily as a man turns in his bed. The aims and methods of farming were gradually adapted to meet the changed conditions. As wheat, barley, and oats declined towards the lowest prices of the century, increased attention was paid to grazing, dairying, and such minor products as vegetables, fruit, and poultry. The com area of England and Wales shrank from 8,244,392 acres in 1871 to 5,886,052 acres in 1901.1 Between the same years the area of permanent pasture increased from 11,367,298 acres to 15,399,025 acres. Yet before the change was complete farmers once more found themselves checkmated. The old adage " Down horn, up com " had once held tme. Now both were down together. Till 1885 the prices of fat cattle had been well maintained, and those of sheep till 1890. Both were now beginning to decline before the pressure of foreign competition. Up till 1877 both cattle and sheep had been chiefly sent in alive from European countries. Now, America and Canada joined in the trade, and the importation of dead meat rapidly increased. Consignments were no longer confined to beef and pigs' meat. New Zealand and the Republic of Argentina entered the lists. The imports of mutton, which in 1882 did not exceed 181,000 cwts., and chiefly consisted of meat boiled and tinned, rose in 1899 to 3^ million cwts. of frozen carcases. The importation of cheese rose by more than a third ; that of butter was doubled ; that of wool increased more than two-fold. Meanwhile the outgoings of the farmer were steadily mounting upwards. Machinery cost more ; labour rose in price and deteriorated in efficiency. The expenses of production rose as the profits felL Some attempt was made by Parliament to relieve the industry. The recommendations of the Richmond Commission were gradually ^ For statistios of ckgriculture, see Appendix IX. PROLONGED DEPRESSION 379 carried into effect. Grants were made in aid of local taxation. Measores were adopted to stamp out disease amongst live-stock, and to protect farmers against the adulteration of feeding-stuffs, and against the sale of spurious butter and cheese. The primary liability for tithe rent-charge was transferred from occupiers to owners (1891). The law affecting limited estates in land was modified by the Settled Lands Act (1882). A Railway and Canal Traffic Act was passed, which attempted to equalise rates on the carriage of home and foreign produce. The permissive Agri- cultural Holdings Act of 1875, which was not incorrectly described as a " homily to landlords " on the subject of unexhausted improve- ments, was superseded by a more stringent measure and a modification of the law of distress (1883). A Minister of Agriculture was appointed (1889), and an Agricultural Department established. But the legislature was powerless to provide any substantial help. Pood was, so to speak, the currency in which foreign nations paid for English manufactured goods, and its cheapness was an undoubted blessing to the wage-earning community. Thrown on their own resources, agriculturists fought the unequal contest with courage and tenacity. But, as time went on, the stress told more and more heavily. Manufacturing populations seemed to seek food-markets everywhere except at home. Enterprise gradually weakened ; landlords lost their abUify to help, farmers their recuperative power. Prolonged depression checked costly improvements. Drainage was practically discontinued. Both owners and occupiers were engaged in the task of making both ends meet on vanishing incomes. Land deteriorated in condition ; less labour was employed ; less stock was kept; bills for cake and fertilisers were reduced. The counties which suffered most were the corn-growing districts, in which high farming had won its most signal triumphs. On the heavy clays of Essex, for example, thousands of acres, which had formerly yielded great crops and paid high rents, had passed out of cultivation into ranches for cattle or temporary sheep-runs. On the light soils of Norfolk, where skill and capital had wrested large profits from the reluctant hand of Nature, there were widespread ruin and bankruptcy. Throughout the Eastern, Midland, and Southern counties, — wherever the land was so heavy or so light that its cultivation was naturally unremunerative, — ^the same conditions prevailed. The West on the whole, suffered less severely. Though milk and butter had fallen in price, dairy-farmers were profiting by the cheapness of 380 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 grain, which was ruining their corn-growing neighbours. Ahnost everywhere retrenchment, not development, was the enforced policy of agriculturists. The expense of laying land down to grass was shirked, and arable areas which were costly to work were allowed to tumble down to rough pasture. Economy ruled in farm manage- ment ; labour bills were reduced, and the number of men employed on the land dwindled as the arable area contracted.^ During the years 1883-90, better seasons, remissions of rent, the fall in tithes, reUef from some portion of the burden of rates, had arrested the process of impoverishment. To some extent the heavy land, whether arable or pasture, which wet seasons had deteriorated, recovered its tone and condition. But otherwise there was no recovery. Landlords and tenants still stood on the verge of ruin. Only a slight impulse was needed to thrust them over the border line. Two cold summers (1891-2), the drought in 1893, the unpro- pitious harvest of 1894, coupled with the great fall in prices of com, cattle, sheep, wool, butter, and milk produced a second crisis, scarcely, if at all, less acute than that of 1879. In this later period of severe depression, unseasonable weather played a less important part than before. But in all other respects the position of agri- culturists was more disadvantageous than at the earlier period. Foreign competition had relaxed none of its pressure ; on the contrary, it had increased in range and in intensity. Nothing now escaped its influence. But the great difference lay in the compara- tive resources of agriculturists. In 1879 the high condition of the land had suppUed fanners with reserves of fertility on which to draw ; now, they had been drawn upon to exhaustion. In 1879, again, both landlords and tenants were still possessed of capital ; now, neither had any money to spend ia attempting to adapt their land to new conditions. In September, 1893, a Boyal Commission was appointed to enquire into the depression of agriculture. The evidence made a startling revelation of the extent to which owners and occupiers of land, and the land itself, had been imjraverished since the Report of the Duke of Richmond's Commission. It showed that the value of produce had diminished by nearly one half, while the cost of production had rather increased than diminished ; that quantities of corn-land had passed out of cultivation ; that its restoration, while the presrait prices prevailed, was economically impossible ; that its adaptation 1 See Census Returns of Occupations, Appendix VII. ROYAL COMMISSION OF 1893 381 to other uses required an immediate outlay which few owners could afford to make. Scarcely one bright feature relieved the gloom of the outlook. Foreign competition had falsified all predictions. No patent was possible for the improved processes of agriculture ; they could be appropriated by aU the world. The skiU which British farmers had acquired by half a century of costly experiments was turned {gainst them by foreign agriculturists working under more favourable conditions. Even distance ceased to afford its natural protection either of time or cost of conveyance, for not even the perishable products of foreign countries were excluded from English markets. Yet the evidence collected by the Commission established some important facts. It proved that many men, possessed of ample capital and energy, who occupied the best equipped farms, enjoyed the greatest liberty in cropping, kept the best stock, and were able to continue high farming, had weathered the storm even on heavy land ; that small occupiers employing no labour but their own had managed to pull through ; that, on suitable soils, market gardening and fruit-farming had proved profitable ; that, even on the dereUct clays of Essex, Scottish milk- farmers had made a living. At no previous period, it may be added, in the history of farming were the advantages and disadvantages of English land-ownership more strongly illustrated. Many tenants renting land on encumbered estates were ruined, because their hard-pressed landlords were unable to give them financial help. At least as many were nursed through the bad times by the assist- ance of landowners whose wealth was derived from other sources than agricultural land. When the extent of the agricultural loss and suffering is con- sidered, the rranedies adopted by the legislature seem trivial. Yet some useful changes were made. Farmers were still further pro- tected against adulteration of cake, fertilisers, and dairy produce by the provisions of The Fertilisers and Feeding Stuffs Act (1893) and the Sale of Food and Drugs Act (1899). The Market Gardeners Compensation Act (1895) enabled a tenant, where land was specifi- cally let for market garden purposes, to claim compensation for all improvements suitable to the business, even though they had been effected without the consent of the landlord. The Improvement of Land Act (1899) gave landowners increased facilities for carry- ing out improvements on borrowed money. The amendment of the Contagious Diseases of Animals Act (1896), requiring all foreign 382 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 animals to be slaughtered at the port of landing, was a valuable step towards preventing the spread of infection. The Agricultural Bates Act (1896) and the subsequent Continuation Acts (1901, etc.). though they were only paUiatives which did not settle the many questions involved in the increasing burden of rates, rendered the load of local taxation for the moment less oppressive. After all, agriculturists received httle assistance from ParUament. They had to help themselves. Conditions slowly mended. More favourable seasons, rigid economy in expenses, attention to neglected branches of the industry have combined to lessen the financial strain. But the greatest rehef has been afforded by the substantial reduction in the rents of agricultural land, which has resulted in a fairer adjustment of the economic pressure of low prices as between owners and occupiers. The state of agriculture in 1901-2 has been described by a dis- tinguished man of letters, who is also a practical farmer. In the two portly volumes of his Rural England, Sir H. Bider Haggard hafi collected a mass of evidence, gathered from what he himself saw and heard in 27 coimties of England. The work is a monument of physical energy and endurance. It is also a contemporary record of rural facts and conditions, to which time will add historical vidue. Future generations will turn to Rurai England as the present generation turns to Arthur Young, or William Marshall, or James Caird. Yet the situation which Sir H. Bider Haggard described ten years ago has already improved. The problem of agricultural labour continues to be acute ; the btirden of rural rates has doubled. But no unprejudiced observer in 1912 would paint the picture of farming to-day in such gloomy colours. Owing partly to the reduction of rents, partly to the improvement in prices obtained for agricultural produce, partly to economies in management, the present financial condition of agriculture, as compared with 1901, may be described as prosperous. If he were not haunted by the unknown terrors of social legislation, and the consequent insecurity of his tenure, a tenant-farmer might possibly admit to himself in secret that his industry has not been in a sounder position for the last 36 years. Since the disasters of 1874-85, and under the continuous pressure of foreign competition, agriculture has profoundly changed. A loss of capital so great, a period of depression so prolonged, the intrusion of so new and disturbing an element in every calculation. VARIETY m FARM PRODUCE 38$ could scarcely fail to affect every side of farming. Yet at no time daring this trying period was improvement completely arrested. On the contrary, it not only continued in the old-established forms- of the industry, but extended to a variety of other branches. What were formerly the by-products of farming have assumed a new importance. When once landlords and tenants realised that the prospect of a rise in the prices of cereals was for years to com& remote, and when, more slowly, they became convinced that Pro- tection of food produce can never be revived on a scale which can really help corn-growers, they set themselves to develop the land on more varied lines. The area of corn-crops was reduced. Wood- lands, which were only valued for beauty or as game covers, began to be treated commercially on the principles of scientific forestry. The development of the milk trade, dairying, pasture-farming, flower-growing, market-gardening, poultry-keeping is characteristic of the new period. The Wobum experimental fruit-farm has collected a mass of tested experiments for the guidance of fruit- growers. Farmers grow potatoes, brussels, and other market- garden crops on their land. It is the day of small tldngs. If money could no longer be made in farming, it might stiQ be saved. Instead of the large stake and open-handed expenditure of the old- fashioned corn-grower, there are many small stakes and a careful attention to minute details. The eggs are not crowded into one basket, but are distributed in many baskets. Variety is one of the enforced improvements in modem farming ; attention to detail is another ; strict economy is a third ; the stoppage of leakages is a fourth. Farmers themselves have changed for the hebtet as captains of industry. To-day they are for the most part alert, receptive of new ideas, keenly sensible of their debt to science, eager to accept its latest suggestions. In all departments of agriculture it is now realised that the best produce commands the readiest sale, and a more general approximation to a high standard of farming may be legitimately r^arded as advance. In corn-growing there is no increased production. But prices, not skill and enterprise, are the chief bar to greater yields. Agriculture differs essentially from manufacture. The larger the output of goods, the lower the average cost of production to the manufacturer. It is not so with the farmer. The bushels that are added to the ordinary yield are those which are most expensive to raise and increase the average cost of production. Experiments at Rotham- 384 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 sted and Sawbridgeworth have shown that it is possible to grow >com year after year, without rotations of crops, without stock- keeping, and without deterioration of the soil. But the experiment has proved to be of little practical value, because at presient prices it is too costly to keep the land clean for continuous corn-growing. In live-stock, improvements have been continuous, and have even received a fresh impulse from the prolonged collapse of corn- growing. Old breeds have been revived and brought into com- petition with their established rivals ; societies and pedigree books have become almost universal. Some of the most important of the new foundations are the Hunter Improvement Society (1885), the Suffolk Stud-book Association (1877), the Hackney Horse Society (1884), the Qeveland Bay Society (1884), the Yorkshire Coach Horse Society (1887) ; the Galloway Cattle Society (1877), the H^hland Cattle Society (1884), the Guernsey Cattle Society (1886), the Kerry and Dexter Herdbook (1890 2), the Welsh Black Cattle Society (1904), the British Holstein Cattle Society (1909). Flock- books were published for Shropshire Sheep (1883), Oxford Downs (1889), Hampshire Downs (1890), Dorset Horns (1892) and Downs <1906),Lincola8 and Cotswolds(1892),Leicester8 and Cheviots (1893), Bomney Marsh (1895), Border Leicesters (1899), Welsh Mountain Sheep (1905). Cross-breeding for mutton with the hardy mountain breeds has been introduced into the North, and extensively prevails. The popularity of polo has created a new industry. The Polo Pony Society (1893) will probably develop and improve such hill and mountain breeds as those of Dartmoor, Exmoor, the New Forest, or Wales, all of which already have their associations or societies. The branches of farming which had been comparatively neglected in the past were naturally those in which recent improvements have been most marked. To the treatment of pastures, for example, increased attention has been paid since De Laune and Carruthers did their pioneer work. Their management is now better under- stood. In manuring grass-lands, the necessity of studying their characteristic vegetation, the different needs of meadows and pastures, the use of occasional liming, the value of basic slag (1883) have been demonstrated, and based on scientific principles. The increased importance of poultry-farming and market-gardening, again, has been illustrated by the care and pains bestOAyed on their improvement. In all the new as well as the old departments of -farming, science and mechanical ingenuity have not stood still. THE AID OF SCIENCE 385 Both have achieved notable triumphs. It speaka volumes for the energy of agriculturists that, in the face of much discouragement, so much has been accomplished. It is no slight proof of their practical ability that enterprise should have been so promptly directed into those branches of the industry which still promised profits. In its hour of need, agriculture found in science its most useful help. Over a long range of subjects science has established the relations of cause and effect, reduced practice to principles, sub- stituted certainties for surmises, laws for rules of thumb. Geology and chemistry have given to tillers of the soil their invaluable aid. Geology has taught the reasons which govern the superfluity or absence of bottom water, furnished definite classifications of soils, ascertained the composition of the different strata, explained the principles that control their capabilities and degrees of fertility. Chemistry by its analyses reveals the elements on which depend the agricultural values of land, studies its mechanical condition and its influence on crops, suggests how to remove differences or supply deficiencies, to equalise varieties in the character of the soil, or to restore its exhausted properties, analjrses fertilisers and feeding stuffs, assists husbandry at every stage and in the minutest details. In the Bothamsted experiments are summarised its triumphs. It is a matter of national congratulation that those experiments, each year more valuable from their continuity, have not been interrupted by the deaths of Sir John Lawes (bom 1814) in 1900, and of Sir Henry Gilbert (bom 1817) in 1901. The re-discovery of Mendel's theory of heredity, first published in 1865, has opened out new vistas of possibility to stock-breeders, helped to correct some of the abuses of continuous in-and-in breeding, promises to fix new variations, to blend useful characteristics in one type, to establish new strains of live-stock. Similar experiments are being conducted in the cross-fertihsation of crop and pasture plants, designed to produce new types of earlier maturity, increased vigour of growth, greater power to resist the attacks of insect pests or fungi, heavier weight, stronger yield, better quality. Through meteorology science is attempting to solve the perplexities of farmers by fore- casts of the weather. It has suggested the potential capacity of electricity to increase the fertility of the soil. In the prevention, if not in the cure, of disease science has made rapid advance. Veterinary skill every year prevents the loss of 2b 386 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 innumerable lives of valuable animals. The ancient cow-leech is superseded by practitioners, who detect bacilli almost as unerringly as their medical brethren. The cause of anthrax has, at least, been discovered, and a preventive suggested in inoculation ; the tuberculin test provides the means of detecting latent tuberculosis in cattle ; redwater has been traced to its source ; the minute agent of the virus in swine-fever is revealed ; acom-rfever, which proved fatal to numbers of young cattle in 1900, has been diagnosed and distinguished from mere indigestion. In foot-and-mouth dis- ease, the period of latency or incubation has been defined, though the nature, origin, and means of transmission of the infection still require investigation. In another, yet similar, direction science has achieved new successes peculiarly appropriate to this day of small things, when minute attention to detail often turns loss into gain. Miss Ormerod (1828-1901), for many years the friend and adviser of farmers on the subject of insect pests injurious to the health of animals and plants, left behind her as her life-work a systematised agricultural entomology, which subsequent research continues to enlarge and perfect. The various kinds and infectious natures of fungi which attack trees, fruit, and field or garden crops have been carefully investigated. A new impulse has been given to clean farming by the discovery that weeds, like docks and thistles, harbour the mangold fly ; or, like dandelions or plantains, foster eel-worms ; or, like charlock, house the turnip weevil, harbour the finger-and-toe fungus, feed the turnip fly, and offer winter-quarters to the chiysalids of the diamond-backed moth. Nor has science been content only to point out the dangers ; it has suppUed farmers, fruit-growers, and market gardeners with an armoury of remedies, preventives, and disinfectants. From 1882, when soft soap and quassia was first applied to hops, the nimiber of these weapons against the insect or the fungus has rapidly multipUed. Science has proved the value of formalin for the prevention of bhndness in oats or smut in barley ; it has tested the use as fungicides of the Bordeaux mixture and iron and copper sulphates, of arsenate of lead and Paris Green as insecticides, of naphthalene for eel-worm, of fumigation with hydrocyanic acid gas, of spraying potatoes with the Wobum Bordeaux mixture, of washing fruit-trees with the Wobum Wash, of destroying charlock at an early stage of growth by spraying with solutions of copper. In mechanical invention innumerable improvements have been NEW IMPLEMENTS 387 effected since 1874. That America should have gained the lead in this field is but another symptom of the depression of English agriculture and its loss of capital. No detailed list can be attempted. But, speaking broadly, progress has consisted rather ia variations of old principles than in the introduction of new implements. The reaper and binder is perhaps the most important of aU the mechanical novelties which have been introduced during the period. Wire- binders were brought over to Europe in 1873 ; but farmers and millers alike protested against the use of wire as a binding material. The Appleby string-binder (1878-9) removed the obstacle. Numerous varieties of the machine are now in general use as one of the most valuable and efficient substitutes for hand-labour. Scarifiers, clodcrushers, steam diggers, cultivators, and other implements of torture for the land, have been improved in different details ; in every stage in the cultivation and harvesting of cereals machinery has been brought to high perfection ; and the Tvel agricultural motor may be the forenmner of further developments. The increased importance of potatoes as a field crop is shown, not only by the experiments carried on at Garforth, Kew, and Cambridge, but by the invention of machines to plant and raise the produce. If potato-harvesters distinguished tubers from stones, their universal success would probably be assured. No substitute for hand-labour in thinning or lifting root-crops has yet been brought into practical use. Flockmasters have profited by the invention of sheep-shearing machines. Various oil-engines have proved them- selves valuable aids for aU sorts of work at the homestead. Power presses (1880), though chiefly designed to compress hay and straw for transport, have proved useful for storage pvuposes. Ensilage, warmly advocated in 1888 as a means of saving hay crops in good condition during wet and catchy seasons, has now been applied to storing green fodder crops for winter keep in seasons of drought or in case of the failure of roots. When originally introduced, the cost of constructing silos prohibited their adoption by hard-pressed farmers. Now, however, it has been found that the simpler and less costly process of stacking or clamping will make excellent silage. Mention must ako be made of the use of wire and corrugated iron for fencing and farm buildings. Where thousands of acres of land had to be adapted to new requirements the use of these materials enabled poverty-stricken agriculturists to effect changes which would have been impossible in more expensive materials. 388 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 In the years 1837-74, improvement in all the arts of cultivating, harvesting, and marketing cereals were the most distinctive feature. In the later period, progress, practical, mechanical, and scientific, in all the arts of managing milk produce has been most conspicuous. The British Dairy Farmers' Association and its Journal (1876), the British Dairy Institute, the prominence given by the Boyal Agri- cultural Society and other societies to shows of dairy appliances and the encouragement they have afforded to the study of the subject, travelling dairy and cheese schools, the dairy schools and technical classes of Agricultural Colleges and County Councils, the writings and practical work of a host of experts, and, above all, the absolute necessity of rivalling the skill of foreign competitors in the home markets, have all contributed to a vast advance in the practice and science of dairying. Foreign methods have been carefully studied, the comparative merits of the different breeds of milch cows investigated, and the same labour has begun to be bestowed upon the perfection of milk- ing qualities which has produced such great results in the fattening quaUties of cattle and sheep. Cheese-makers will prefer one breed, butter-makers another, milk-sellers a third. Yet there will always be a tendency to sacrifice something of the special purpose for the sake of a breed which promises to be saleable as beef when the milking days are over. It is the combination of milking and feeding quahties which makes the Dairy Shorthorn, whether pedigree or non-pedigree, and the Ayrshires such popular favourites. As butter-makers the Jerseys are probably pre-eminent. In every detail of management, from the premises and the water-supply down to the milkman and his utensils, the necessity of absolute cleanliness has been demonstrated. It is enforced by stringent legislation ; it is also based on science and common sense. No product changes its character more readily than milk. If con- taminated, it loses its freshness and the producer his customers. Milking machines have been invented ; but owing to the difficulty of cleaning the tubes, they have for the most part met with but moderate success. The Lawrence-Kennedy type, both the Simplex and the Duplex, has, however, succeeded both on the Continent and at home. Considering the provisions of the Sale of Food and Drugs Act and the Sale of Milk Regulations, and the risk of pro- secutions, it is surprising that milk records of the yield of each cow are not more regularly kept, and that milk is not more often tested MILK AND MILK PRODUCE 389 for hotter fat. Grood milkers are not more expensiye to keep than had ; hut the difference of their yield may range between 1000 and 300 gallons, or less, a year. Unless the yield is recorded, the owner may be ammaUy losing money by several animals in his herd. Similiurly, the percentage of butter fat is of the utmost importance both to the milk-seUer and the butter-maker. Without occasional tests, owners do not know which of their animals are lowering the average of the herd, and to what extent. On the Continent, it is not uncommon for the daiiy-farmers of a district to combine and contribute to the employment of a man who records and tests the yields of milk at so much an animal. Similar associations have been formed in Scotland for the same purpose, and County Educa- tion Committees in England might well include this object among the items of their expenditure. Such records are in other respects valuable. Nothing is more hereditary than milking quaUty. Strains of milkers, whose pedigrees were based on records of their performances, must command their price. In Denmark herd- books founded on this principle have been already adopted with success. In England the formation of the Dairy Shorthorn Associa- tion (1905) marked the establishment of a practice which is beginning to spread. Such Tnilfeing herds as those of Lord Rothschild, or of Messrs. Evens, Hobbs, or Watney, are already famous. In all the processes of dealing with milk, scientific principles and mechanical aids have made triumphant progress. Fifty years ago, in every stage from the chum, butter was made up and prepared for market by hand ; wooden utensils were in common use ; separators were unknown ; thermometers were rarely employed. The value of the butter largely depended on the personal element in the maker. Uniform quaUty and condition were impossible ; variety of both was the rule ; in winter months a regular supply was difficult. It was not perhaps surprising that wholesale buyers preferred the foreign products, on the uniformity of which they could depend. At the present day the personal element, though still all-important in the trade with private customers, is largely dis- counted by the adoption of scientific rules and the use of mechanical appliances. The separator has produced the greatest revolution in dairy management, and ranks with the reaper and binder as one of the chief novelties of the period. The principle of the centrifuge, invented in 1867 for separating Uquids from such sub- stances as paint, was applied to milk about 1879. It thus became 390 ADVEESITY, 1874-1912 the parent of the Laval, Lefeldt, Petersen, and other varieties of the separator. Improved by successive developments, it can now be purchased at a third of its former cost. In its wake have followed a variety of improved appUances — chums to suit every fancy, milk- testers, milk-coolers, centrifugal butter driers, butter workers, butter hardeners, steel pails, tin-lined utensils, down to grease- proof paper, and chip or paper boxes for marketing the produce. In recent years an efEort has also been made to compete with the soft cheeses of foreign countries. Excellent cheeses of the type of Brie, Camembert, and Gervais are now produced by English dairies. If there is a weak side to all tins progress, it lies in the fact that the processes of butter and cheese-making are becoming too elaborate and scientific for the ordinary run of agriculturists. There is certainly some risk that this branch of the farming industry may become confined to creameries and associations, and that wholesale dealers may refuse the products which have not come from a factory. In the science and practice of the various branches of farming, progress has been great, and it has been helped by a corresponding increase in the means of obtaining agricultural education. Through- out the country munerous centres have been established in addition to those previously in existence. Aspatria (1874), Downton (1880), the University College of North Wales (1884), followed by colleges, schools and institutes in South Wales, Kent, Yorkshire, Derbyshire, Shropshire, and other counties, at Cambridge, Reading, Penrith, Swanley, Uckfield, Chelmsford, and elsewhere, the Armstrong College at Newcaatle-on-Tyne, the Cheshire Agricultural and Horti- cultural Institute, the Harris Institute at Preston, the Eastern Counties Dairy Institute at Ipswich, the National Fruit and Cider Institute at Bristol, and similar institutions in various parts of England, offer new opportunities of practical and scientific training to future landlords, farmers, and land-agents. At many of these centres, degrees or certificates can be obtained. Examinations for National diplomas are conducted by the Boyal and Highland Agricultural Societies. The admirable leaflets issued by the Board of Agricidture supply the latest scientific discoveries in the shortest compass, either free or at the smallest possible cost. In local ex- penditure on technical education, instruction in agricultural subjects is represented, and the range of the lectures and classes organised by County Councils continues to extend. Instruction in forestry is AGRICULTURAL EDUCATION 391 given at the Universities of Oxford and Cambridge, at the University of North Wales, the Armstrong College, and in the PubUc Depart- ment of Woods and Forests in Alice Holt Woods and the Forest of Dean. Considerable sums are also expended by the Boards of Education and of Agriculture in subvention to colleges and institutes, and for the furtherance of agricultural training. Education on a scale so varied and extensive must in the long run produce results. Already its effect is visible. Unfortunately, for the children of agricultural labourers Uttle or nothing is done which does not xmfit them for their fathers' industry. They cannot afford to attend Colleges or Institutes. Continuation and night schools do not begin till the mischief is really done. What is most wanted is some form of elementary instruction in rural schools adapted to the needs of agriculturists. The problem is admittedly dif&ctdt. Teachers, as a rule, are not interested in country life. Here and there, an individual may succeed in implanting bis own rural enthusiasms iq his pupils. Text-books adapted to the surroundings of country children may prove a help. But the practical training is still wanting. School gardens are a step in the right direction. Rightly or wrongly, no effort has been made to imitate the con- tinental practice of closing rural schools from hay-time to harvest, and lengthening the winter hours. Whether some more suitable system of elementary rural education might not have helped to oheck rural depopulation may be an open question. School influences alone can never attract young persons to remain on the land. But at present they rather promote than discourage migra- tion into towns, and farmers not unnaturally grudge the growing expenditure on an education which assists in making rural labour At once more scarce and less efficient. Elementary education may not always produce this effect. In its present stage of transition, its disturbing influences are increased by the conditions of rural homes. The younger generation is better educated than the old, and both are conscious of the fact. This sense of disparity fosters in the chfldren a distaste for village life, and in the parents a desire that the superior attainments of their children should have wider opportunities than they themselves enjoyed. In another genera- tion, the disparity wiU have disappeared ; the atmosphere of the home will have become, it may be hoped, more educated. At this later stage of its development, education may tend rather to con- tentment than to discontent. It may in itself supply those fresh 392 ADVERSITY, 1874-1912 and endoiing sources of interest which make light of external con- ditions. If this ever becomes the influence of elementary education, it may help to repeople the country districts which it now tends to depopulate. The general record of English farming during the last seventy years is a legitimate source of pride to all who have contributed to its advance. It shows a marvellous progress in every department of agriculture, effected in the face of heavy sacrifices and innumerable difficulties. High farming has lost the buoyancy and enthusiasm of youth ; its later years were soured by losses and disappointments ; to-day, in spite of improved conditions, it views the future with alarm. Whatever the future may have in store, it has made land- lords and tenants better equipped to profit by prosperity or to combat misfortune than they have been at any previous period of history. 1888 AND 1912 COMPARED 39$ CHAPTER XIX. CONCLUSION. 1888 and 1912 : political agitation then and now ; the situation contrasted and compared ; the position of landowners ; of titheowneis ; of tenant- farmers ; tenttnt-right as a defence against sales ; agrioultoral labourers, their slow progress between 1834 and 1884, and their Unions ; their improved position in 1912. The problem of the future ; the reconstruction of village life : the necessity of an agricultural policy : the prospect of increased burdens on {Agricultural land. Maky persons cannot conceive it possible that, even in this century of rapid changes, any serious alterations in the existing systems of the tenure and cultivation of English land are really inuninent. To them it seems incredible that English farming can be destined, on any extensive scale, to revert towards conditions out of which it finally emerged in the Victorian era. They may be right or wrong- in their views. On that point no opinion need be here expressed. The task of sketching the story of ' ' English farming past and present' ' ends with the present day. Conjectures as to the future of farming,, or programmes for its reconstruction, belong rather to prophets and politicians than to chroniclers. Yet the existing conditions of farm- ing are already disturbed by anticipations, whether true or false, of coining change. In order to complete the sketch of English farm- ing down to 1912, it is, therefore, necessary to attempt a summary of the present position of landlords, tenants, and labourers. By way of contrast or comparison, four passages may be quoted from the first edition of this book, published 24 years ago under the title of TJie Pioneers and Progress of English Farming. At the time when the book appeared, agricultiure was still sufEering from severe depression. It was a middle period between the disasters of 1874- 1885 and those of 1891-1899. Some signs of revival had appeared ; but the outlook alike for landowners, tenants, and labourers wa& still gloomy. 394 CONCLUSION Many landlords had succeeded to estates which were heavily encumbered by settlements, charges and mortgages, laid on in more prosperous times. They could not dispose of their property, for land was a drug in the market ; rates and taxes swallowed up the residue of the rents which was left from interest and charges ; the so-called owner had become a conduit pipe between his tenants on the one side, and, on the other, his family, the mortgagees, rate- collectors, and tax-gatherers. Anyone who lived in the country at that period can call to mind numerous families who had curtailed their expenditure, cut down their establishments, let or closed their houses, or become absentees on the continent. Among farmers, arrears, bills of sale, hquidations, bankruptcies kept ever in advance of reductions and remissions of rent. Their numbers diminished.^ Many were farming as bailiffs instead of as tenants, or were appUcants for reUef from the Boyal Agricultural Benevolent Institution. Of those who remained in occupation, the most capable men, who were wide awake to every chance of profit, kept the master's eye upon their business, and in personal expenses had cut their coats to their cloth, were making farming pay ; but the majority were paying rent out of capital and holding on by their eyelids in hopes of better times. Labourers, as the area of corn-growing dwindled, and the labour-bill was reduced to a minimum, found employment hard to get and hard to keep : thrown out of work, or half employed, they crowded into the towns where their El Dorado proved to be the workhouse or worse. The landowner's expendable income was little or nothing, the farmer's fixed rent an improvident speculation, the labourer's wage uncertain and precarious. Conditions were favourable for violent change. For the moment the relations between landlord and tenant were embittered. Labourers, smarting under the recent defeat of their Unions, were hostile. In every direction poUtical agitators were active. Insecurity paralysed recovery ; it rendiered chronic the collapse which disas- trous seasons and foreign competition had produced. Many of the ideas and theories of advanced reformers in 1888 differed little from those of 1912 ; in language only have they become more precise or definite. " Crude panaceas are in vogue at the present day ; wild theories are promulgated for the redistribution of English land. In the days of her commercial and agricultural supremacy, England might safely ignore such demands for change. An ever-increasiag ^ See Appendix VIT. " Census Returns of the Agricultural Population." EFFECT OF POLITICAL UNREST 395 prosperity postponed the shock of antagonistic interests. But now, ivhen disastrous seasons and foreign competition paralyse the ener- gies of agriculturists, when commerce ceases to expand with sufficient rapidity to employ a growing population, land questions are not merely considered with curiosity, but the exclusive privileges of the few are discussed with deepening eagerness. The assailants of property may be noisy out of aU proportion to their numbers ; their confidence may rather proceed from ignorance than from the calm of reasoned conviction ; they may have given no proof, tested by success, that their schemes are feasible ; they may forget that the first and worst sufierers by economic blunders are the poor ; but it is idle to ignore the danger of an agitation which has already scared away capital from the land, and renders chronic the enfeebled con- dition of agriculture. . . . The cry is raised, and assiduously encourt^ed by political leaders, that landlords are a parasitical growth, a remnant of feudalism, a class that reaps what others sow. The misconception is industriously fostered that England is a solitary exception to the universal rule of European landholding. It is maintained with increasing vehemence that God made the land for the people, that land is an ager pvblicus, which the State has granted to landlords to administer, but which she may at pleasure resume. Men quote with approval Mirabeau's retort to the objection that he could not sell the landed property of the Church — ' Not sell it ! Then I will give it.' " ^ The effect of political unrest upon the agricultural industry in 1888 was the same as it is at the present day. " So long as wild proposals for compulsory redistribution of property received the support of prominent poUticians, no landlord would expend money on improvements, no capitalist, large or smaU, would invest in the purchase of land, no tenant would accept a lease, no labourer would put his heart into his work. While the intentions of the Legislature remained dubious and threatening, land continued to be unsaleable and half-farmed. Behind all legislative changes lurked the ominous question of confiscation. Land may be treated as private property, held so as not to prejudice the public welfare, but not to be taken from owners without fair compensation ; or it may be distinguished from private property, and the principles which guard private property held inapplicable to land. On which line was land legisla- tion to proceed ? Wild talk about State-ownership, ransom, and > Pioneert and Progress of English Faming (1888), pp. 126-7. 396 CONCLUSION natoial rights, societies to nationalise the land, heroic remedies of illogical half-disciples of Mr. Henry George, might be in themselves of little importance. But when the air was filled with vague threats, the attitude of Ministers remained studiously neutral. Agitators complained of conditions which they themselves rendered chronic. Meanwhile the continued insecurity was rapidly producing results which threatened the subversion of rural sbciety. Fortunately the example has been recently given that a patriotic fusion of political parties for the promotion of national interests is yet possible in party government. That restoration of confidence, which is the indispensable preliminary to agricultural revival, seems already to have begun, and to bear fruit in renewed energy. Arguments urged agajnst the artificial creation of a peasant proprietary scarcely apply to their natural growth. . . . Socially the advantages of a class of peasant owners are indisputably great. The rural economy of the nation would benefit by the diffusion of land ownership, and farming ofEers no exception to the rule that two strings to the bow are better than one. If legislation is only invoked to remove arti- ficial aids to the aggregation of large estates, the process will not foster that sense of insecurity which has paralysed the energies of landlords, and rendered chronic the enfeebled state of agriculture. Already signs appear of a tendency towards the multipUcation of small tenant-farmers, if not of small owners. Small holdings obstructed progress so long as capital was required for the re- clamation, enclosuie, drainage, and equipment of land. But at the present day this argument loses much of its force. So again, while England depended for grain on home supplies, com could be produced more economically on large farms. Now, when prices render its home production unremunerative, and foreign supplies are adequate to our wants, another argument for large farms is at least modified. Small farmers, content with small profits, depend- ing on gardens, Uve-stock, and dairies, commanding the unpaid labour of their own families, may make both ends meet, where larger capitalists go through the Court. If agriculture is tending in this direction, legislation must remove all hindrances to its natural coiuse ; landlords are sufficiently aUve to their own interests to do the rest." ^ In 1888 the country seemed to be standing on the verge of some great change. The development of high farming had been arrested I Pioneera and Progress 0/ Bnghth Farming (1888), pp. 170-180. SMALL HOLDINGS IN 1888 397 partly by nnremuiierative prices, partly by the unsolved problem of securing to tenants the unexhausted value of their own improve- ments, partly by the general want of confidence which political uncertainties had greatly encouraged. Large farms went begging for occupiers. Agriculture with its new risks of pecuniary loss, and its modem drudgery of close economy in manage- ment, of minute attention to details, and constant personal supervision, had ceased to attract men who possessed from £5,000 to £10,000 in capital. In these circumstances it seemed probable that, where landlords could command the money ior the initial outlay, they might with profit discard steam- ploughs and make spades trumps. As an alternative to allowing arable land to pass out of cultivation, and so in- «reasiiig agricultural unemployment, the multipUcation of small holdings, on suitable soils, in suitable districts, and in suitable hands, seemed to be a sound business proposition. Experience already showed that small farms were easier to let than large. They com- manded higher rents ; they were better adapted to reduced capital, more suited to new conditions. Socially and poUticaUy, as weU as economically, the establishment of closer relations between land and labour was advantageous. "A peasant proprietary increases the number of those who have something to lose and nothing to gain by revolution, encourages habits of thrift and industry, gives the owner of land, however small his plot, a stake in the country, and a vested interest which guarantees his discharge of the duties of a citizen. Combined with the partage ford, it checks population, for la plupart des Normands n'ontpas lu McMhus, maie ilspratiquent instinctivement see conseila. ... It affords a training to the rural population for which we in England have found no substitute. It checks the centralisation of pauperism, the overgrowth of population, and the migration into towns. The element of stability which it contributes to the State is more valuable to the French than ourselves. There the towns are inflammable as touchwood, while the country ignites more slowly. Yet even here it is useful to have a class of slow- thinking men, who will answer poUtical firebrands with Cela est bien, mats ilfavt cuUiver notre jardin." ^ Moreover, the movement of replacing the peasantry on those parts » Pioneers and Progrese of Engliah Farming (1888), p. 138. For details aa to peasant proprietors and the departments in France where they thrive or do not exist, see the writer's Pleatant Land of France (1908). 398 CONCLUSION of the land to which their industry is specially adapted would have gone far to satisfy their legitimate aspirations. Their memories are tenacious. Deeply hidden in the recesses of the labourer's mind lurk vague and often misunderstood traditions of the past conditions of rural life. He knows that he is tilling land as a wage- earner, which his forefathers farmed as occupiers. He does not realise that the change has been only a part of a great industrial revolution which affected manufacture as well as agriculture. In the multipUcation of small holdings there also lay the opportunity of mitigating the most depressing influences of his present position and future prospects. " Speaking generally, the worst aspects of his life at the present moment are the decreasing demands for agri- cultural labour, the absence of any reasonable prospect of emerging from the condition of hired service, and the pauper allowance which rewards the most industrious career. Some readjustment between the demand and supply for labour, some social ladder, and some better provision against old age are the true needs of the agri- cultural poor. So far from reheving the glut of labour, the new departure in the practice of farming will still further congest the market. Economical management and increased breadths of grass, whether permanent or temporary, mean a reduction of working expenses, which wiU take the form, not of less wages, but of less employment. Emigration affords the only other outlet for the excess of the labour supply." ^ Comparing the position of 1888 with that of 1912, it is obvious that there are resemblances as well as differences. Generally speaking, the problems remain the same ; time has only accentuated some and modified others. The great contrast between the two periods lies in the partial recovery of agriculture from acute depression. The great resemblance consists in the paralysing effect of the un- certainty of the political outlook, which is infinitely more menacing than in 1888. Were confidence once restored, the conditions of farming, given favourable seasons, might warrant anticipations of a considerable revival of the industry. The lapse of a quarter of a century has considerably changed the relative positions of the three agricultural classes. To many of them the depression of 1888 brought ruin. Of those who sur- vived, it meant to landlords a substantial reduction in the standard of living, to farmers a deprivation of comforts, to labourers a loss I Pioneers and Progress of English Farming (1888), p. 226. POSITION OF LANDOWKERS 399 of necessaries. In actual money, labourers suffered least ; but standing, as they do, nearer the border-line of starvation, it is probably true that they also suffered most. At the present day^ farmers have improved their position ; labourers, in spite of the recent rise in the price of provisions, are better ofi ; for landlords alone, although agricultural land readily commands both tenants and purchasers, the general conditions have materially changed for the worse. Financially crippled by recent taxation, land- lords are assailed with increasing vehemence. The attack upon the system of land-temure which they represent derives fresh strength from the poverty to which they are reduced by increased taxes. They have not the command of money necessary either to- give fair play to the system or to supplement it by creating small tenancies. At the same time, the attack is no longer aimed at them only as representatives of a system or as members of a class. The personal element is introduced ; venomous tongues attempt to poison the crowd against them as individuals. Courage in the face of odds has always characterised the landowning classes. They weathered the storm of 1888 ; they may " muddle through " the present crisis with equal success. Their prospects would be brighter, if they were more aUve to the reality of their position. Men are beginning to ask how many owners of land have troubled to master the intricacies of the undeveloped land duty, of the single tax, or of site values ; or have made themselves competent to explain their injustice, their fallacies, and their effects on rural districts. They are already wondering why landowners, up to the present moment, have formulated no alternative policy, and why they are still disunited, and still unable to agree on any concerted action. To most onlookers, it would seem the part of ordinary prudence, without further loss of time, to frame a compre- hensive progranmie of land reform on broad and generous lines, while maintaining the principle that private ownership is the only satisfactory system for progressive land-cultivation. Owners of agricultural land in England are numerically few. No doubt the paucity of their mmibers in times past enhanced their social position, as well as their power and influence. To-day it is a peril to stand where many envy and few sympathise. For many years in our history, landowners, as a class, took the most active part in the politics of the country, and conducted the whole adndnis- trative work of rural districts. They do not do so to-day. It may 400 CONCLUSION be contended that, either from poverty, from want of leisure, or from disinclination, they have, as a class, ceased to bear the burden of political life, or undergo the irksome drudgery of local administration. Instances may be urged to prove that their local influence has dwindled to a vanishing point. Where individual members of the class retain it, they exercise it as men rather than as landowners. Yet the weight which such men possess in their own districts suggests that the leadership is still open to those who care to earn it. Even in agricultural matters, the lead has to a great extent passed out of their hands. Up to 1889, all the improvements in English fanning which at one time had gained for this country an imdisputed supremacy in the art and practice of agriculture were effected by private capital, by individual enterprise, by personal initiation. Landlords were the pioneers of improvement. Now the State, for good or for evil, itself undertakes much of the control and expenditiu:e which formerly fell to the landowning class. This transference of responsibility from private persons to the public department of the Board of Agriculture has undoubtedly borne excellent fruit. No one denies its advantages. That is not the point. Its establishment may be construed as an important reversal of an old ideal, an acknowledgment by landlords of their partial defeat, a tacit admission of the fact that our existing land-system ■can no longer supply from its own resources the capital and direction required for the organisation of the industry.^ Private property in land is not so exceptional in its nature as to make its tenure legally assailable. But the moral title-deeds by which some of it is held are not, historically, without a flaw ; and no prescriptive rights, according to the modem reading of an ancient maxim, can be acquired against the People. The possession of land has for hun- dreds of years been honourably associated with the unpaid discharge of laborious public duties. If this association of service with privilege should be in any way weakened, the danger arising from the isolated position of landowners would be magnified, because substance and colour would be given to the allegation that land- owners are a parasitic growth which should be eradicated in the interests of national progress. It is alleged that, as a class, landowners are more ready than they once were to stand aloof trom the strenuous political life of the 1 See this danger pointed out in the author's article on " An Agricultural Department" in the Nineteenth Century for April, 1889. THE WANT OP CAPITAL 401 community, more willing to acquiesce in the loss of control over local affairs. If this is true, and if only a decreasing minority are still prepared to sacrifice their leisure and amusements to the discharge of pubUc duties, it is an unhealthy, if not a dangerous, symptom. Something of the same apathy is certainly visible in the management of many estates. Much ought to be done, which is left undone, to put land to its most profitable use and to adapt its equipment to the requirements of diversified farming. The impoverishment of landowners by the new burden of taxation, which not only cripples their incomes but cuts into their capital, is undoubtedly the main cause of the neglect. They have not the money with which to make the necessary changes. To say this, however, is only to say that the modem system of farming has broken down in one of its most essential features. Intensive cultivation means the expenditure on the land either of more money or of more labour. The Uberal apphcation of capital to land by both owner and occupier was one of the ideals at which high farming aimed from the close of the eighteenth century onwards. Landlords spent their money hberaUy on the up-to-date equipment of their land with houses, farm-buUdings, cottages, drainage, fences, roads ; mainly by their expenditure, directly or indirectly, prairie land has been converted into agricultural land. Tenants hired the use of all this capital at the moderate rate of interest which is represented by the rent, and spent their own money generously in working their fanns so as to obtain the largest possible return. So long as both parties were able to do their part, and so long as prices were remunerative, the system profited both. The nation also benefited by the increased amount and lessened cost of pro- duction. But during the last half of the reign of Queen Victoria, the rapid decline in the value of agricultural produce caused the collapse of the system. Both partners lost a large part of their capital. Prolonged depression compelled landlords to practise economies themselves and to acquiesce in the economies of their tenants. The land has suffered and is still suffering. Thousands of acres of tillage and grass-land are comparatively wasted, under- farmed, and undermanned. Countries, whose climate is severer than our own, and in which poorer soils are cultivated, produce far more from the land than ourselves. The gross receipts per cultivated acre in Great Britain have been calculated at only one-fifth of those of Belgium, and two-thirds of those of Denmark. 2c 402 CONCLUSION In these circumstances the demand is made that the other form of intensive cultivation should have its chance. If intensive capital is not forthcoming, let intensive labour try its hand on smaller areas. But here again landlords are in a dilemma. Whether the existing system is to be developed, or whether, in favourable situations, an extensive trial is to be made of the new, money is equally needed. Private lenders are suspicious of land as a security, and owners themselves are shy of adding by further investments on their land to the spoils of those who propose to tax them out of existence. They are naturally timid of depositing all their eggs in one rickety basket, the bottom of which may at any moment be pulled out. They might borrow from the State ; but the State, instead of assisting them to revive the old system or to make trial of the new, exercises its ingenuity in devising fresh schemes for their further impoverishment. The deadlock thus produced may be profitable to politicians ; but the drain on the national resources caused by its continuance is great, and the loss which is inflicted on both tenant-farmers and wage-earning labourers is daily increas- ing. Meanwhile, unless impoverished landlords can obtain State assistance, their only resource is to sell their estates. Where this course is adopted, the interests of tenant-farmers axe often seriously prejudiced. A sale forces them to adopt one of two courses. If they buy the land they occupy, they strip themselves of their working capital. If their farms are sold over their heads, they risk a still heavier loss. Purchase is the lesser of two evils. But, when the two alternatives are presented, they also stand in need of State assistance, which win enable them to borrow the whole purchase-money at moderate rates, and repayable by annual instalments. Besides the ordinary landlords, there is another class of owner whose position is serious. Clerical tithe-owners are threatened with the same general dangers as lay landowners, and they have besides their own special risks from the possible disendowment of the Church in England. They are powerless to sell. They can, at present, only await events. Yet in more stable and more prosperous times, it might have been possible to suggest an arrangement for tithe redemption which, with the help of the legislature, would be advantageous alike to them, to the tithe-payer, and to the community. The experiment might have been tried in Wales. As an alter- native to the proposed disendowment, it is a policy which would go far to satisfy some of the parties concerned. It would benefit THE POSmON OF TITHE-OWNERS 403 Welsh landloids, Welsh Ohurchmen, and the Welsh urban and rural population. It would remove the reluctance of many earnest Nonconformists to cripple the cause of Christianity by appro- priating to Caesar property dedicated to the service of Grod. Educationally and morally, 50,000 acres of land contiguous to the towns and villages of Wales would be of greater value than a wilder- ness of museums. It would be absurd to attempt to foretell the future price of com. But probabiUties seem to point to a gradual rise. On the other hand, for many years to come, the prospect of an approximation to par-value appears remote. Here there is room for compromise in settling the figure at which the net annual value of the charge, after deducting the necessary outgoings, should be redeemed. If this figure could be agreed upon, landowners might be encouraged to extinguish the whole tithe issuing from their land in the parish by the surrender of the acreage of land required to produce the same net annual income which is now derived from the rent-charge. Care should be taken that the land so surrendered is near the village. Otherwise the main advantage to the community would be lost. The amount of land thus rendered available cannot be accurately estimated till the figure is agreed ; but the total area would not be less than 2^ million acres. It is not suggested that tithe-owners should be transformed into landowners. The process of redemption would be gradual, not simultaneous. It would be put in operation whenever pubhc bodies required to buy land for small holdings or village reconstruction, and the purchase money would be paid over to a church body, constituted on the lines adopted in Ireland. Present conditions are favourable to such a transaction. The price of land enables owners to extinguish the rent-charge by the surrender of a reasonable acreage, and the low price of Consols enables investors to obtain a larger interest on their money. Landlords and tenants are confronted with a common danger. They stand or fall together. Tenant-farmers have nothing to hope for from theoretical land-reformers. The most they can expect from the single tax is a rise of rents and an increased number of sales. Neither of these changes would be acceptable to a class of men who, in spite of their traditional pose as licensed grumblers, would rather remain as they are. As compared with 1888, tenant-farmers have improved their position. From one point of view this might not appear to be the 404 CONCLUSION case. At the earKer period they were masters of the situation. The land was begging for them, not they for the land. They had a large choice of holdings, and on their own terms. But mastery of a half-bankrupt situation was worth little. To-day, though the demand for farms exceeds the supply, they are better off. In the general conduct of their business, the old difficulties continue ; some have even increased in seriousness. The pressure of foreign com- petition, for example, shows no sign of slackening ; labour has deteriorated in quality ; boys are hard to find ; railway rates require revision ; local taxation, which embraces such imperial objects as education, police, and main roads, has risen so greatly that it has already neutralised the advantages of the concession of partial exemption. But worse in its effects than these known evils is the uncertainty of their tenure produced by recent legislation and by the threat of more drastic measures. For many years, the most distiu:bing element in the relations between landlord and tenant was the difficulty of securing to the tenant the unexhausted value of improvements effected by his own capital. The question has been again brought into prominence in an altered form by the attack on the position of landlords. As soon as high farming began, tenant-right, in one shape or another, became an absolute necessity. But landlords and the legislature were slow to recognise the need. If tenants were to be encouraged to invest their capital in the land, they must in justice receive some security for their outlay. At law they had no more than the mediaeval farmer who spent nothing on his holding. The law presumed that everything done to, or put into, the soil became the property of the landowner, who by adding to the rent the annual value of the tenant's outlay could appropriate it to his own profit. Exceptions to the legal presumption were established by the growth of customs of the country. But the protection thus afforded varied in amount, and even in its strongest forms was inadequate. It was therefore generally realised that the law must be modified, if not reversed, either by special agreement or by conferring on tenants a statutory right of property in their own improvements. The necessary outcome of the changing conditions of modem farm- ing was recognised in 1843, when Lord Portman failed to obtain legal security for a tenant's expenditure of capital on improvements. Philip Pusey in 1847 waa equally unsuccessful. His Bill was, how- ever, referred to a select Committee of the House of Commons. TENANT-FARMERS AND TENANT-RIGHT 405 Evidence was offered, not only on the harshness with which the legal presumption operated, but on the small degree of protection afforded by existing customs . It appeared that in most districts no allowance could be claimed for such permanent improvements as drainage, or for those of a durable character like marling, liming, claying, or burning, or for those which were more temporary in their nature, such as the use of purchased manures, or the consumption on the land of oU-cake and other feeding-stuSs. In 1850 legislation was again refused. For twenty years the subject slumbered in Parlia- ment. Meanwhile, outside the House, the question was rapidly becoming a burning one, and the foundation of the Central and Associated Chambers of Agriculture in 1866 gave strength and cohesion to the opinion of agriculturists. At last the principle was recognised in the Agricultural Holdings Act of 1875. Though the measure, from its optional character, was only indirectly effectual, it proved the starting-point of future legislation. To men of that generation compulsion was stiU unfamiliar. They thought it more essential to preserve freedom of contract, and it was on this ground that notable agriculturists, like Albert PeU,^ resisted the compulsory recognition of tenant-right. Since 1875 legislation has been active in securing to tenants the right to recover, as compensation for any improvements legally made by them on their holdings, the full remaining unexhausted value of those improvements. To-day farmers are practically safe- guarded for their outlay by custom, agreements, and Acts of ParUa- ment. They are generally satisfied with the conditions of their tenancy, and ask nothing better than its continuance . But, recently, the break-up and sale of large estates, and compulsory acquisitions of land by public bodies under the Small Holdings Act, have rendered the holdings even of the best and most valued tenants insecure. In these new circumstances, the demand for another form of com- pensation haa been revived. It is urged that, in addition to the claims already conceded, farmers should be entitled to compensation for continuous good farming in excess of the standard which tenants are bound to maintain. The proposal bristles with practical difficulties. In the tenant's own interest, it is doubtful whether it would be wise to impose upon a landlord a new and uncertain burden. Wherever an estate is mortgaged, more land would be forced upon the market, and in self-defence every landlord would-be driven to I The BeminUcence» of AVbeH Peg (1908), p. 280. 406 CONCLUSION raise rents to their commercial, competitive level, and to reduce his expenditure on repairs and improvements. It is also practically impossible either to draw any definite line between the tenant's common law obligation to farm in a husbandlike manner and the continuous good farming which surpasses that standard, or to establish any permanent starting-point from which the increase or decrease in the letting value of the land, due to the tenant's good or bad cultivation, can be accurately measured. For this latter purpose it has been suggested that the optional record of condition provided by the Agricultural Holdings Act, 1908, might sufl&ce, if made com- pulsory. Apart from the difficulty created by the yearly deprecia- tion of the value of the evidence, and the expense of keeping it up to date by intermediate inventories, the record would be a two- edged weapon. Farmers do not press for its introduction with any enthusiasm or unanimity. They themselves are probably the best judges, whether they will, as a class, gain or lose most by a measure of valuation for the deterioration, as well as the improvement of their holdings. It would be far more to their advantage that, when faced with the alternative of buying or losing their farms, they should be able to obtain from the State on easy terms the whole of the money necessary to effect the purchase. If the loan took the form of a reducible mortgage, repayable by annual instalments, and secured by the right of levying a distress for arrears, there would be httle fear of any loss by the lender. No public loan of any magnitude would be immediately required for the purpose. Tenants do not want to buy so long as they can continue to rent under a good private landlord. Unless threatened legislation assumes a form which greatly accelerates the present progress of sales, the sum annually needed would be small. The funds accumulating in the hands of the Insurance Commissioners would supply any demand which may reasonably be anticipated. The interests of agricultural labourers apparently conflict with those of their employers. They want high wages and low prices : their employers want high prices and low wages. But the anta- gonism shades off into some identity of interest, for low prices mean less employment or reduced earnings. Agricultural labourers, like landlords and tenant-farmers, suffer from the present political uncertainty and its consequences. If an estate is sold and a farm changes hands, their employment, their wages, and their homes are endangered. Materially, they are without doubt better off than in AGRICULTURAL LABOURERS 407 1888, though their conditions are still capable of improvement. But their prosperity in 1912 is quite a different kind of prosperity from that which they enjoyed in the simpler and more leisured eighteenth century. Up to that time, the picture, drawn in the first chapter, of life in the self-supporting village still held true in many essential features. In remote rural districts, changes were slow and few. Suddenly, from 1760 onwards, over the whole of society swept the great industrial expansion. Domestic handi- craftsmen and small farmers alike were overwhelmed : industry, both manufacturing and agricultural, was reorganised on the new commercial lines which seemed best adapted for the greatest possible production at the least possible cost. The completion of the work of enclosure destroyed the inherited traditions of the peasantry, their ideals, their customs, their habits, their ancestral solutions of the problems of life, — all, in fact, that made up the native home-bred civilisation of rural England. With the disappearance of the primi- tive framework of village Ufe, vanished — ^for a time at any rate — many of the virtues of the class, their independence, pride, frugaUty, self-control. It is not surprising that for at least half a century they should have remained stupefied by the shock, gradually realising the full meaning of the change, and then either stoUdly acquiescing in their new existence, or impatient to escape on the first opportunity. Without a return to an extinct social and industrial system, the old conditions cannot be entirely rebuilt for them any more than they can be for other classes. The most that can be done is to revive as far as possible the best f eatiures of a form of life which has passed away and cannot be completely restored. From 1815, the moral, social, and probably the material, position of the agricultural labourer rapidly declined. He became more and more exclusively dependent on money wages,^ and these, though increased by pauper allowances, feU lower and lower every year after the peace. The Poor Law of 1834 marks the starting-point in the recovery. But the story of the slow steps by which labourers have climbed from the depths into which they had been plunged is a chequered record. For more than thirty years, wages had been sup- plemented from the rates, all the year round, whether the recipient was employed or not. Men with families had received allow- * See Appendix X. for weekly payments in cash. Calculations of agricultural wages must always be used with the utmost caution, and merely as general approximations to the facte. 408 CONCLUSION ances, at their own homes, proportioned to the number of their children. After 1834 parish relief was only given in workhouses, where husband and wife were separated. It was no longer the duty of the parish to find work or to provide means of subsistence ia aid of wages. The change entailed no small degree of sujffering, not only on the sick and aged, but on the able-bodied. Relatively to the demand for labour, there was a superabundant population, which the old administration of the Poor Law had encouraged, and the disproportion between supply and demand was increased by a considerable extension of the use of machinery on the land. Em- ployment was hard to get, and wages remained extraordinarily low. In the Northern Counties and the Midlands, the great industrial expansion and the rapid development of railways relieved the pressure. Without their assistance it is doubtful whether the Poor Law could ever have been brought into operation. Elsewhere ia England, migration or emigration seemed the only resource. Wages, reduced to a minimum, fluctuated with the rise or fall in the prices of necessaries. Years must necessarily pass before the glut in the rural labour-market could be absorbed. But the process of adjusting the relations between demand and supply was delayed by a new form of competition with adult male labour. In the increased employment of women and children in the fields, which had become a necessity ia order to supplement the family income, employers found a new supply of labour which to some extent neutralised any tendency of wages to rise. It was in these circumstances that the problem of raising wages by indirect means began to occupy the attention of Parliament. NaturaUy men's minds turned to allot- ments, which by their name perpetuate the compensation, often sold before the award was signed, allotted to claimants of rights of common. In 1796 a society had been formed " for Bettering the Condition of the Poor " by means of these field-gardens. In 1819, 1831, and 1832 Acts of Parliament had been passed enabling the Poor Law authorities or the parish to provide parish farms or allotments. Sufficient use of these powers had been made to justify the Poor Law Commissioners of 1834 in reporting the failure of parish farms and the success of allotments. Further evidence was offered before the Select Committee on Labouring Poor (Allot- ments of Land). Their Report (1843), and those of the Poor Law Commissioners (1842-1843), show that the acreage devoted to allotments was increasing in most of the agricultural counties, and SLOW RISE OF WAGES 409 that their extension was to the economic and moral advantage of the labourer. It was calculated that the net profit from the produce of a quarter of an acre of land added 2s. a week to wages. In addition to money made, there was money saved. Men spent less at the pubUc-house, and were less dependent on the shopkeeper for their provisions. Morally there was an added feeling of independence and self-respect. Hard though the men worked after their day's labour, their toil was more of a recreation than a task, because it was bestowed on land which they themselves occupied. In 1846 came the repeal of the Com Laws. In its first efEects, Free Trade was not favourable to agricultural labourers. Wages were lowered, and food prices did not fall sufficiently to counter- balance the loss. In the first impulse of despair at the anticipated effects of the loss of Protection, many tenants threw up their hold- ings. Much land was unlet. Employment became more and more difficult to obtain. The years 1849 to 1853, which immediately preceded the Crimean War and the era of agricultural prosperity, were a period of severe depression. Economy of production was necessarily the aim of employers. They naturally applied to their own business the Free Trade maxim, " Buy ia the cheapest market ; sell in the dearest." More machinery was introduced on the land. Small farms were thrown together. There was no diminution in the number of women and children employed ; the gang system, both public and private, prevailed extensively in the Eastern Counties ; the supply of labour was still largely in excess of the demand. The competition of female and child labpur continued to depress wages. It was not till some control of the gang system was established by the Gangs Act of 1867, and the employment of children regulated by the Education Acts of 1870, 1873, and 1876, that employers were deprived of the cheapest forms of labour. They were, therefore, driven to employ a larger number of adult males. But the population of rural districts still remained superabundant, in spite of a constant stream of emigration, and wages advanced little and slowly. PubUc opinion was beginning to realise the unsatisfactory position of agricultural labourers. Reports from Medical Officers of Health on the food, housiog, and sanitary conditions of rural districts aroused new feelings of sympathy. The men themselves began to entertain the idea of combining to enforce remedies. Between 1865 and 1871, in Scotland, Buckinghamshire, Hertfordshire, and Here- 410 CONCLUSION fordshire, unions were fonned. The ground was thus gradually prepaj%d for a movement which, when once started, spread with surprising rapidity. On February 7th, 1872, a trade union of agricultural labourers was founded at Wellesboume in Warwickshire by Joseph Arch. The tinder was ready, and the spark was struck. By the end of the following month, 64 branches had been organised in Warwickshire alone. In May a Congress, attended by delegates from many parts of the country, was held at Leamington, at which the National Agricultural Labourers' Union was formed, and Arch elected to be the first president. The prime objects of the new organisation were to raise wages, shorten hours, abolish payments in kind, regulate the employment of women and children, increase the number of moderately rented allotments. In other respects it made a new departure. Up to 1878, trade unions of the ordinary type had confined themselves to the improvement of industrial conditions. From the first, the Agricultural Union included political and social reforms. It demanded not only the parUamentary franchise for agricultural labourers, but changes in the land laws, the disestabUshment of the Church, enquiries into charitable endow- ments, the creation of peasant ownerships. It also introduced new weapons which were not employed by trade unions of the industrial type. It spent considerable sums of money in transferring labourers from congested districts to counties where there was a greater demand for labour both on land and in factories. By its aid also, in the first nine years of its existence, 700,000 persons emigrated to the British Colonies and elsewhere.^ One feature the Labourers' Union shared in common with the trade unions, and with disastrous results. It endeavoured to combine with its other objects the work of Friendly Societies. But the attempt proved to be beyond its powers, and became one of the chief causes of its ultimate collapse. The immediate success of the Labourers' Union was considerable. Wages certainly rose, though no statistical evidence can be reUed on to show the extent of the rise. It must be remembered that the better class of workmen had left the poorly-paid districts of the South and East, and that employers were asked to pay more money for labour which was inferior in quaUty and less in result, without the advantage of the better prices for their produce which were obtainable in the industrial centres of the North and Midlands. ' See the evidence of Joseph Arch before the Agricultural Commission in 1881, Qu. 68, 422. (Parliamentary Papers, 1882, vol. adv., p. 61.) UNIONS OF AGRICULTURAL LABOURERS 411 Combination was, therefore, met by combination. Strikes proved an ineffective weapon. Employers were able to supply the places of the strikers, either from the general labourers who stood outside the National Union of Agricultural Labourers, or from the un- employed and casually employed population of the towns. In July, 1874, after a prolonged struggle of six months, the Union suffered a severe defeat. Numbers, as well as funds, began to dwindle. Inside the Union there was a split. Between it and the more recent Federal Union (1873) arose more or less open hostility. The disastrous period of 1875-1884 began to tell on the position of labourers, in regard both to amount of wages and to regularity of employment. They could no longer maintain their weekly pay- ments, and their leaders advised against resistance to reductions. Much of the advance in wages which had been gained was lost ; but it was through the Union that the parliamentary franchise was won. Cynics may say that it was the parliamentary vote which gave the labourer his first real step upwards. It made him the most important of the three classes which constitute the agricultural interest, and, from that moment politicians have tumbled over one another in their eagerness to secure his support. Be this as it may, there can be no doubt of his substantial progress since 1884. Most men of the class are still poorly paid ; many are precariously employed and poorly housed ; among all, poverty is chronic, and, though destitution is certainly rare, the dread of it is seldom absent. But, speaking generally, labourers in 1912 are better paid, more regularly employed, better housed, better fed, better clothed. They are better educated and more sober. Their hours of labour are shorter. They are secure of a pension for themselves and their wives in their old age. They can, if they choose, make their influence felt in the government of their parish, the administra- tion of their county, the direction of the affairs of the nation and of the empire. Their wives and children are no longer driven by necessity to labour in the fields. What more can labourers want ? may be impatiently asked by some. Others, conscious that all is not yet well, may ask with anxiety — ^what more can be done ? It would be difi&cult to answer either question. Labourers, as individuals, may know what they want. It is generally some particular piece of land. But, as a class, they have not formulated their general aspirations in definite form : they are conscious of 412 CONCLUSION little more thaji discontent with a life which for them has lost its meaning and with that loss its savour. Yet perhaps a contrast between the past and the present conditions of rural villages may suggest some sort of answer. Under the old system, some of the existing evils prevailed, as well as others which are now removed. The village was not Arcadia. Its life was by no means idyllic. In one sense, at all events, it was on a lower level then than now. The peasant was too absorbed in his own surroundings to care for matters outside his own environment. He could rarely read ; he seldom thought of anything beyond his daily pursuits ; he had no ideas and few opinions except on the practical subjects in which he was interested. For many years, under the shock of change, the mind of the agricultural labourer was even less active and even more narrow. His daily work was less varied and more monotonous ; he had lost the opportunity of practising the manifold crafts in which his grandfather had been occupied ; he toiled exclusively for a master, not for himself. He fell into a half-dazed state of fatalism. Now this is changing. Labourers read, think, enquire. Their minds are awakening and curious for information. They are slowly beginning to extend their intellectual horizon beyond their own individual misfortunes or advantages, and to understand the meaning of economic laws. In this mental development, politics, honourably handled, and dealing with principles not personalities, might, and should, play an important part. A great responsibility rests on writers in the public press and on platform orators. The mental change in progress may account for the restlessness. It does not by itself explain the discontent. The peasant, under the old system, had a defimte independent place in the community. He commanded respect for his skill, judgment, and experience in his own industries. He was not cut o£E by any distinctions in ideas, tastes, or habits from the classes above. On the contrary, each grade shaded almost imperceptibly into the next. To-day, the intermediate classes have disappeared. Instead of the ascending scale of peasant-labourer, the blacksmith, carpenter, wheelwright, and carrier, the small-holder, the village shopkeeper, the small farmer, the larger farmer, the yeoman occupying his own land, and the squire, there are in many villages only two categories, — employers and employed. The gulf is wide enough. It has been broadened by the progress of a civilisation which is more and more based on the possession of money. All the employing classes have moved on ENTIRE DEPEKDENCE ON MONEY WAGES 413 and upwards in wealth, in education, in tastes, in habits, in their standard of living. Except in education, the employed alone have stood comparatively still. The sense of social inferiority which is thus fostered has impressed the labourer with the feeling that he is not regarded as a member of the community, but only as its helot. It is from this point of view that he resents, in a half-humorous, ha]f-sullen fashion, the kindly efEorts of well-meaning patrons to do him good, the restrictions imposed on his occupation of his cottage, as well as the paraphernalia of policemen, sanitary and medical inspectors, school-attendance officers, who dragoon and shepherd him into being sober, law-abiding, clean, healthy, and considerate of the future of his children. To his mind, it is all part of the treatment meted out to a being who is regarded as belonging to an inferior race. The economic side of the change further accentuates the dis- content and adds a practical to the sentimental grievance. The peasant worked as hard as, or harder than, his descendant. But his industry was more interesting to him, partly because it was more manifold, partly because much of it was for himself. He had less need of money. Living more on his own produce, he could satisfy some of his wants by exchanges in kind. When he had to buy, he obtained money either by sale of his own stufE or by working for an employer. But to earn weekly wages, or to be in regular employ- ment, was not for biT" an absolute necessity. He was little affected by the laws of demand and supply in relation to labour. The new commercial system, on the other hand, has made the agricultural laboiu%r entirely dependent on employment and money wages. Instead of producing much of his own food, he has to buy it nearly all. In order to live, he must sell his labour for cash, and under the stress of new exigencies which limit his power of bargaining. Now, if the labourer loses employment, or fails to find it, he has no resource on which to fall back. His livelihood, and, in case of tied cottages, his home, depend on a week's notice. A change in the ownership or occupation of the land on which he works may cut bim adrift. Against this uncertainty he cannot protect himself. But he may lose his wages in another way, and against this he can be partially secured out of his savings. For this reason, even his thrift is guided into new channels by the commercial spirit which necessarily controls his Ufe. The peasant's savings went into the purchase of a pig or a calf, or into some other 414 CONCLUSION form of reproductive investment. They meant a step upwards in well-being. But the labourer of to-day saves for a different object. His weekly earnings, on which depend his livelihood and home, are all-important. It is against sickness, therefore, that he tries to secure himself by painful thrift. What he pays for insurance is not an investment ; the money that he puts into a Friendly Society is not capital which he can ever use. Once paid, it is gone for ever. His savings do not in fact help ^™ to put his foot on the ladder of prosperity. They only serve to protect his family and himself against a possible adversity. The great number of labourers who insure in Friendly Societies is a pathetic proof of their total depend- ence on weekly earnings and of their haunting dread of the loss of wages through sickness. But the popularity of Slate Clubs shows their consciousness of the disadvantages of the ordinary insurance. By dividing out at the end of each year, they are at least able to secure the use of a portion of their annual savings as capital. Under the older system, peasants were rarely without some real stake in the agricultiu:al community ; they were not members of an isolated class ; they were not exclusively dependent on competi- tive wages for their homes and Uvelihood ; they were seldom without opportunities of bettering their positions ; they had not before them the unending vista of a gradual process of physical exhaustion in another's service. Under the modem commercial system, the conditions from which peasants were generally free are those under which the average agricultural labourer hves, though exceptional men may struggle out of their tyranny. They have no property but their labour. Even of that one possession, such are the exigencies of their position, they are not the masters. If they fail to sell it where they are now Uving, or if they lose employment by a change in the ownership or occupation of the land on which they work, they must move on. Their home is only secure to them from week to week. For all wage-earning classes, the modem conditions of industry are approximately the same. But in villages they are reUeved by few of the compensations which to the eyes of country visitors appear to be offered in towns. In money wages, artisans are better paid ; they have greater chances of rising to higher rates of remuneration ; they have larger facilities for recreation and amusement ; so far as their homes are concerned, they are less directly under the thumb of their employer ; they belong to a less isolated and more numerous class ; they live in the midst of a ACCESS TO THE LAND AS OWNERS 416 population which is still minutely graduated in the scale of social position ; they have no excuse for imagining that laws of police, sanitation, health, and school attendance are designed and ad- ministered for the vexatious control of their social and domestic habits. Agricultural labourers believe that there is life in the towns ; they know that in the villages there is none, in which they share as a right, or which for them has any meaning. They may be indispens- able, but it is only as wheels in another man's money-making machine. If the attractions of towns are to be counteracted, and agricul- tural labourers lifted from apathy and hopelessness into contentment and activity of interest, a reality, a purpose, a meaning must be given to village life. Probably this can only be done effectivdy by giving labourers readier access to the land, and access as ovmers. Tenancies may to a certain extent produce similar results. They may stimulate pride in work, provide variety of interest, offer scope for ambition. But the incentive of ownership is incomparably stronger. It is true that the Board of Agriculture notices that few appUcants for land express a desire to become owners. They certainly do not, so long as they must, imder the existing law, pay a deposit of 20 per cent, of the purchase price, which either absorbs their working capital or compels them to begin on borrowed money. But experience in the other direction is not entirely wanting. The Duke of Bedford's advertisement of seventeen small ownerships at Maulden, where no deposit was required, produced upwards of 500 applicants. The Small Holdings Act has provided a certain quantity of land. But its methods are so faulty, the rents which it requires are so high, the interest and instalments charged on such necessary improvements as roads are so excessive, that its operations are necessarily limited. Moreover, if once the demand under the Act was approximately satisfied, the pressure on County Council candi- dates for reductions of rent would be so severe as, in all probability, to result in considerable loss to the ratepayers. Finally, it may be observed that applicants under the Act have been, to a very large extent, men who are superior in financial position to those for whose benefit the measure was originally designed. Agricultural labourers, pure and simple, are generally afraid of the venture, unless they can form a co-operative society, from which the stronger men, financially and morally, hold themselves aloof. It is only by ownership that the atmosphere can be re-created in 416 CONCLUSION which the peasant became part of the land and the land part of him. Domestic handicrafts cannot be revived ; the old gradation of ranks cannot be exactly replaced ; the leisureliness and tran- quillity have passed away for ever in this more crowded and bustling age. To a greater extent than before, laws of competitive supply and demand must dominate labour and regulate rates of wages. But ladders of thrift and industry may, with the co-operation of the State, be planted in every village by which agricultural labourers might still climb upwards, gain a permanent stake in. the rural community, and escape that exclusive dependence on employment and cash earnings which renders their Uvehhood and homes at present insecure. But the bottom rung of the ladder must be placed low enough. The opportunity of buying a freehold cottage and garden appeals to every man, if the annual instalments do not exceed the annual rent current in the neighbourhood. The well-intentioned and useful restrictions imposed by landlords will probably be at once ignored. Lodgers will be taken in, possibly to the detriment of the cottage-owner ; pigs and poultry will be kept which may be a nuisance to neighbors. Such matters must be left to right them- selves. No one minds the smell of his own pigs or the noise of his own poultry. Allotments, brought within easy reach and moderately rented, should be universally provided, unless the undeveloped land duty raises their rent to a prohibitive height, and drives field gardens to a distance which renders them comparatively useless. No scheme is universally applicable to every locaUty. Small arable holdings or even farms may be suitable in some districts. In other parts of the coimtry bits of grass land may be of greater value. For the addition of the requisite pasture to arable holdings, a common, carefully stinted, and regulated by the small owners them- selves, as in the case of the Duke of Bedford's scheme at Maulden, may prove a useful expedient. In every village such a common, it properly managed, would be a boon by increasing the local supply of milk, which is scarcer in villages than in towns. ^On economic lines such as these, village life might in time be reconstructed, and intellectually placed on a higher level than the old. To each inhabitant would be offered the prospect of a career full of modest possibilities and varied interests. In the home and on the soil belonging to their parents, children might gain that love of country pursuits which is raxely acquired in later years, and that practical handiness in all details of the management of land without THE NEW CENTRE OP POWER 417 which they can never become efficient workers. Agricultural labourers are too well aware of what land will or wiU not do to demand an universal system of small holdings. Tenant-farmers would, therefore, still hold their own, and, in the supply of more effective labour, draw their own special advantages from the re- construction of village lite. Nor need the means of mental expansion be wanting. Co-operative societies for the wholesale purchase and retail sale of commodities, credit banks managed by the members themselves, approved societies in each village for the conduct of the business of national insurance, parish councils freed from the tutelage of larger public bodies, might give to the inhabitants new and wider opportunities of business training, which would make them more intelligent and therefore more useful citizens. The centre of power has shifted. It is no longer landowners or tenant-farmers, either alone or in combination, who hold the key to the rural situation. It is the agricultural labourer. It seems inevitable that, in the near future, sacrifices will be asked both from owners and occupiers of land. To the existence of both, the main- tenance of the principle of private property in land is vital. It is on that issue that the battle seems likely to be fought. The question for them to consider is, whether, by any reasonable sacrifice, they can strengthen their position by establishing ownership on a more democratic basis, or whether, without material concessions, they can successfully defend the existing system on its merits. For both views, something may be said ; for disimion, nothing. From their own knowledge and experience, agriculturists may unite in attempting to guide the movement in directions which may materially afEect their own position, but will at the same time benefit their industry as a whole, and save intact the principle of private property in land. If they give no practical lead, the direction of the move- ment seems likely to fall into the hands of reforming theorists, intent on repeating the time-honoured mistake of applying to agricultural problems remedies which are only appUcable, if at aU, to industrial or urban difficulties. To aU classes dependent on agriculture the consequences threaten to be disastrous, and, most of all, to agri- cultural labourers. In the extreme form of the proposal of the theorists, the whole taxation of the country would be ultimately thrown upon rent. In order to lighten the fiscal burdens of townsmen, agricultural labourers, whether in occupation of the land or not, would thus be reduced to a position to which, before the establish- 2d 418 CONCLUSION ment of British rule, the only parallel was afforded by the Egyptian feUaheen. In the modified form of the theory, the added burden on land must necessarily mean increased rents, and either reduced employment or lowered wages. Whichever form of the theory is adopted by a political party, the first step is, according to the argument of its advocates, to ascertain the bare unimproved value of agricultural land. For the purpose of this enquiry, unfor- tunately, the Valuation now in progress would be only a costly farce, if it were not also a serious injustice. LATIN WRITERS ON AGRICULTURE 419 APPENDIX I. CHRONOLOGICAL LIST OF AGRICULTURAL WRITERS DOWN TO 1700. BEFORE THE INVENTION OF PRINTING Latin WnUrs on Agriculture. — Cato, Varro, Columella, Palladius. M. Catonis Prisci de Re Rugtica liber ; Marcii Terentii VairomB Rerum Rusticarum, libri i.-iii. ; Lutii Junii Moderati Columelloe Rei Rueticot laber Primus — Tertius — Decimus, ed. G. Merula. Palladii Rutilii ^miliani de Re Rustica liber primus-liber ziii., ed. F. Colucia. Venice (1470 ?). U72. [Cato, commonly called the Censor, died B.C. 149. Varro flourished in the last century before Christ. Columella, whose agricultural writings are the most useful of the four Latin writers, flourished in the first century of the Christian era. He also wrote a treatise, De Arboribiis, Palladius, who seems to have written in the fourth century a.d., borrows largely from Columella. The above-mentioned book is the first printed edition of any part of the Roman writers on Agriculture, though many manuscripts probably existed in the libraries of English monasteries. Frequent editions were subse- quently published abroad, but none apparently in England. Translations were also printed abroad, e.g. of Columella into Italian by Pietro Lauro (1644), and into French by Charles Cotereau (1666). But none seems to have been printed in England till 1726, when Richard Bradley, F.R.S., Professor of Botany in the University of Cambridge, published his Survey of Ancient Husbandry and Oardening collected from Cato, Varro, Columella, etc. A manuscript translation of Palladius into English verse belonging to the fifteenth century (1420) was edited by Messrs. Lodge and Herrtage, under the title of PaOadius on Hosbondrie for the Early English Text Society, 1873 and 1879.] Thirteenth Century Manuacripta. — ^Walter of Henley's Husbandry. Together with an anonymous Husbandry, Seneschaude, and Robert Grosseteste's Rules. (Ed. Elizabeth Lamond. Royal Historical Society, 1890.) [It is stated by Mr. Donald M'Donald (Agricultural Writers, 1200 to 1800 (1908), p. 11) that Walter of Henley's Husbandry was reproduced in James Bellot's Booke of Thrifte, 1689. The book does not appear in the British Museum Catalogue. But the Library contains another work by James Bellot of Caen, entitled Le Jardin de Vertu, etc. (1681), containing extracts in French and English from the " best and wisest books."] Gabdinis (Matsteb Ion). The Feate of Oardening. [Edited from the original fifteenth century manuscript by the Hon. Alicia Amherst (Mrs. Evelyn Cecil), AnAoeoiogia, vol. liv.] 420 APPENDIX I. PRINTED BOOKS, Cbescemtius or Petbus db Cbescentus. (Bom 1233 : died 1320.) Opua Suralium Commodontm give de Agrieidtura. Libri xii. Augsburg^ 1471. [This work was translated into Italian, 1478 ; into French, 1486 ; into German, 1493.] L1TTI.BT0N (Sib Thomas). LeteUun Tenuria new eorrecte. 1616. [The ediUo princepe is a folio volume printed by Letton and Machlinia without date or title. The work begins : " Tenant en fee simple est," etc. Another edition, also without date or title, was published by Machlinia, probably later {« it contains fewer abbreviations. The first dated edition (1516) is in Norman French. The first edition in English is published by Berthielet : LyttUton Tenures traely tranalated into Englytahe, 1638.] MoBE (Sm Tbouas). LibeUita vere aureus, nee minus salutaria quam festivus de optima rei pubUcae statu, deque nova Insula Utopia. 1616. [ThiB first edition of Utopia was printed at Louvain. The book was translated into English under the title of A fruiteful, and pleasant worke of the heste state of a puhlyque weale, and of the newe yle called Utopia, by " Ralph Robynson Citizein and Goldsmithe of London," 1661.] FrrzEEBBEBT (John). 1. The Bohe of Huabondrye. 1623. "Here begynneth a newe tracte or treatyae mooste pftable for all husbade men." [Book of Husbandry, ed. W. W. Skeat. English Dialect Society, 1882.] 2. Ttie Boke of Surueyeng and Improu/vemlete. 1523 " Here beg3mneth a ryght frutefuU mater : and hath to name the boke of surueyeng and improuvemets." Benese (Bichass), " chtumon of Herton Abbey besyde London." This boke sheweth the maner of lande, as weU of woodUmde, as of lande in the f Me, and comptynge the true nomhre of acres of the same, etc. 1637. TUBNEB (WiDLIAM). Libellus de Be Herbaria Nomts, in qu/o herbarum aliquot nomina greca, latina, is Anglica habes, etc, 1638. [The first English version was entitled The names of herbes in Qrehe, Latin, Englishe, Duche and Frenche, wyth the commune names that Herbariea and Apotecaries use. Gathered by William Turner. 1648. The second edition of the work appeared as A new Herball, wherin are eonteyned the names of Herbes in Oreke, Latin, etc. etc. 1661.] 8. (W.) or Hams (John). The Oompendious or brief e Examination of certayne ordinary complaints of divers of our countrymen m these our times. 1649. [First printed in 1681 but edited (1893) from the MS. of 1649 by Elizabeth Lamond.] DiooES (Leonard). A Book named Tectonicon, briefly shewing the exact measuring and ipedie reckoning aU maner of Land, Square Timber, etc. 1656. [This book continued to be republished at intervals till the close of the seventeenth century: e.g. 1634, 1637, 1656, 1692.] AGRICULTURAL WRITERS, 1557-77 421 TuasEK (Thomas). A hundreth good poirUes of husbcmdrie. 1067. Subsequently amplified into Fiue hundreth good Pointea of Hiubandry, untied to as many of good Euawifery. 1673. BLX7in>EVILLE (ThOHAS). 1. A newe booke containing the arte of ryding and breakynge greats horses, etc. [Translated from the Italian of F. Grisone.] 1660. 2. The fower chiefyst offices belonging to Horsemanshippe. That is to saye, the office of the Breeder, of